Transaction Costs and Interest Parity

advertisement
Chapter 11
Interest Parity
The Investment and Borrowing Criteria
Determining the Currency of Investment
An Example: Comparing of Investments
Determining the Currency in Which to Borrow
Borrowing and Investing for Arbitrage Profit
The Covered Interest Parity Condition
Mathematical Statement of Interest Parity
Market Forces Resulting in Covered Interest Parity: A Graphical
Presentation
TM11-1
Combining PPP and Interest Parity
The Uncovered Interest Parity Condition
The Expectations Form of PPP
The Interrelationship of the Parity Conditions
Why Covered Interest Differences Persist
Transaction Costs and Interest Parity
Political Risk and Interest Parity
Taxes and Interest Parity
Liquidity Differences and Interest Parity
Effect of the Reasons for Interest Disparity on Investment and borrowing
Decisions
TM11-2
1. The Covered Interest Parity Condition
(1) Definition: It states that when steps have been taken to avoid foreign
exchange risk, costs of borrowing and rates of return on financial
investment will be equal irrespective of the currency investment or the
currency borrowed.
(2) Rationale: How shopping around for the highest investment yield or lowest
borrowing cost pushes yields and costs in different currencies towards
equality.
2. Some Useful Terms
(1) Money Market: This is the market in which short-term securities such as
treasury bills and commercial paper are traded.
(2) Foreign Exchange Risk and Exposure: It is the result of uncertainty in asset
or liability values, or in income flows, due to unexpected changes in
TM11-3
exchange rates.
(3) Aviva Corporation
◎ is a manufacturing company
◎ is headquartered in the United States
◎ has uneven cash flows; on some occasions it has surplus funds to invest,
and on other occasions it needs to borrow
TM11-4
The Investment and Borrowing Criteria -- Determining the Currency of
Investment
1. Background
(1) Aviva Corporation has some funds to place in the money market for 3
months
(2) Choices:
◎ invest in securities denominated in its own domestic currency at an
interest rate on locally traded commercial paper or treasury bills
◎ invest in foreign currency-denominated securities
2. Securities
(1) Many countries have money markets in which financial securities
denominated in the countries’ own currencies are actively traded. For
example: Canadian dollar securities in Canada
TM11-5
(2) In the large international financial centers such as London and New York,
there are active markets in securities denominated in a variety of different
currencies. For example: in London there are active markets in U.S.
dollar securities, Japanese yen securities, and so on.
3. How an exchange-risk-free investment decision is made
r$ is the annualized U.S. dollar interest rate
r£ is the annualized interest rate on 3-month British pound bank deposits
S($/£) is the spot exchange rate; the number of dollars per pound
F1/4($/£) is the 3-month forward rate at the time of investment
(1) Investing in a dollar-denominated (domestic currency) bank deposit
each dollar will provide $ (1+r$/4)
(2) Investing in a pound-denominated (foreign currency) bank deposit
◎ $1 will obtain in 1/S($/£) British pounds, assuming that there are no
TM11-6
transaction costs
◎ each dollar will receive £ [1/S($/£)] (1+r£/4) after 3 months
This certain number of pounds represents an uncertain number of
dollars, but a forward contract can offer a complete hedge and
guarantee the number of dollars that will finally be received.
◎ at the time of buying the 3-month pound-denominated deposit, Aviva
sells forward the amount of pounds to be received at maturity
the number of dollars received $ [F1/4($/£)/S($/£)] (1+r£/4)
◎ The purchase of the spot pounds, the investment in the
pound-denominated deposit, and the forward sale of pounds all take
place at the same time, and there is no doubt about the number of
dollars the will be received.
TM11-7
(3) The rule for deciding the currency in which to invest
U.S. dollar deposit Pound deposit
ˇ
>
1+r$/4
=
[F1/4($/£)/S($/£)] (1+r£/4)
indifferent
Indifferent
ˇ
<
◎ a general form (1+rd) = [F(d/f)/S(d/f)] (1+rf)
(4) From the equality above, with cancelation and rearrangement we get
(11.4)
r$ = r£ + 4 {[F1/4($/£) – S($/£)] / S($/£)} (1+r£/4)
by dropping the term {[F1/4($/£) – S($/£)] / S($/£)} (r£/4); which is a
small number
(11.5)
TM11-8
r$ = r£ + 4 [F1/4($/£) – S($/£)] / S($/£)
◎ the first term on the RHS is the annualized pound interest rate
◎ the second term on the RHS is the annualized forward premium on
pounds
◎ Investors should be indifferent between home- and foreign-currency
denominated securities if the home-currency interest rate equals the
foreign-currency rate plus the annualized forward exchange
premium/discount on the foreign currency.
TM11-9
An Example: Comparing Investments
1. Table 11.1. Exchange Rates and Interest Rates on Different Currency-Denominated
3-Month Bank Deposits
(1) The Covered (Hedged) Yield: The yield on foreign currency-denominated
deposits when the proceeds are sold forward.
£ Covered yield = r£ + 4 {[F1/4($/£) – S($/£)] / S($/£)} (1+r£/4)
◎ This yield is slightly higher than the yield on U.S. dollar deposits.
(2) The highest yield shown in this Table is the yield on British pound deposits.
(3) If Aviva were to invest its $10 million for 3 months in the British pound
deposits, covered in the forward market, it would receive back
$10,000,000 (1+0.046167/4) = $10,115,415
TM11-10
Determining the Currency in Which to Borrow
1. The rule for deciding the currency in which to borrow
(1)
Costs of Borrowing
U.S. dollars
ˇ
>
1+r$/4
=
Pounds
[F1/4($/£)/S($/£)] (1+r£/4)
<
indifferent
Indifferent
ˇ
(2) Aviva should borrow in dollars: the amount to be repaid is lower from a
dollar loan than from a pound loan.
(3) The borrowing decision criterion is seen to be the same as the investment
criterion with the inequality reversed.
TM11-11
Borrowing and Investing for Arbitrage Profit
1. Covered Interest Arbitrage
(1) Definition: Borrowing and investing with foreign exchange exposure hedged
in order to profit from differences in yields/borrowing costs on securities
denominated in different currencies.
(2) The company has begun with no funds of its own, and has taken no risk.
Borrowing in dollars and simultaneously investing in pounds will result in
a profit if the number of dollars received from the hedged pound
investment exceeds the repayment on the dollar loan, that is, if
1+r$/4 < [F1/4($/£)/S($/£)] (1+r£/4)
(3) The reverse activity, borrowing in pounds and investing in dollars, will be
profitable if the reverse inequality holds.
TM11-12
The Covered Interest Parity Condition -- Mathematical Statement of Interest
Parity
1. The Covered Interest Parity Condition
(1) If we allow for compound interest, investors and borrowers will be
indifferent between the dollar and pound for investing and borrowing when
(11.10)
(1+r$)n = [Fn($/£) / S($/£)] (1+r£)n
(2) When equation (11.10) holds, no covered interest arbitrage is profitable.
TM11-13
Market Forces Resulting in Covered Interest Parity: A Graphical Presentation
1. The Covered Interest Parity Diagram
(1) Covered Interest Parity: From (11.4)
(11.11)
r$ - r£ = 4 {[F1/4($/£) – S($/£)] / S($/£)} (1+r£/4)
(2) Figure 11.1. The Covered Interest Parity Diagram
◎ The vertical axes: The annualized 3-month forward premium on the
pound
◎ The horizontal axes: The annualized interest advantage of the dollar
versus the pound
TM11-14
A pound forward premium
A pound forward premium
A dollar interest disadvantage
A dollar interest advantage
A pound forward discount
A pound forward discount
A dollar interest disadvantage
A dollar interest advantage
◎ The parity condition is represented by a 45-degree line in which traces
the points where the two sides of equation (11.11) are equal.
2. Inequality
(1) Suppose we have the following inequality
(11.12)
r$ - r£ < 4 {[F1/4($/£) – S($/£)] / S($/£)} (1+r£/4)
It is profitable for an interest arbitrager to borrow dollars and make a
covered investment in pounds.
(2) The actions taken by arbitragers would lead to the following activities
TM11-15
◎ Borrow dollars, perhaps by issuing and selling a security—and thus
tend to increase r$
◎ Buy spot pounds with the borrowed dollars—and thus increase S($/£)
◎ Buy a pound security—and thus reduce r£
◎ Sell the pound proceeds forward for U.S. dollars—and thus reduce
F1/4($/£)
All four steps of arbitrage occur simultaneously, all the forces shown by the
arrows occur simultaneously.
(3) Inequality (11.12) can be represented in Figure 11.1 by points such as A, B,
and C that are above and to the left of the 45-degree line. We find that
above the covered interest parity line, flows of funds from dollars to
pounds push us back toward it, and below the line, flows of funds from
TM11-16
pounds to dollars also push us back toward it.
(4) Table 11.2. Points off the Interest Parity Line
◎ The covered margin: The advantage, if any, from engaging in covered
interest arbitrage.
TM11-17
Combining PPP and Interest Parity -- The Uncovered Interest Parity Condition
1. The Approximation of the Forward Exchange Rate
(1) Definition: the expected future spot exchange rate
Sn*($/£) is the expected spot exchange rate between the dollar and the
pound in n years time.
(2) Speculation will make the forward exchange rate approximately equal to the
expected future spot rate.
(11.13)
Sn*($/£) = Fn($/£)
2. The Uncovered Interest Parity Condition
(1) Substituting equation (11.13) into equation (11.10),
(11.14)
(1+r$)n = [Sn*($/£) / S($/£)] (1+r£)n
(2) By definition
(11.15)
TM11-18
Sn*($/£) ≡ S($/£) (1+S*-dot)n
where S*-dot is the average annual expected rate of change of the spot
exchange rate
(11.16)
(1+r$)n = (1+S*-dot)n (1+r£)n
(11.17)
1 + r$ = 1 + S*-dot + r£ + S*-dot × r£
(11.18)
r$ - r£ = S*-dot
That is, the interest differential should approximately equal the expected rate of
change of the spot exchange rate.
TM11-19
The Expectations Form of PPP
1. The PPP Condition in terms of Expextations
(1) From Chapter 10
(10.12)
PUS*-dot – PUK*-dot = S*-dot
*: expectations; dot: the rate of change
e.g., PUS*-dot is the expected dollar return from holding commodities in the
United States; the expected U.S. rate of inflation
◎ The expected return in terms of dollar from buying and holding the
basket of commodities in the United States will be equal to the expected
return in terms of dollars from buying and holding the same basket of
commodities in Britain.
TM11-20
The Interrelationship of the Parity Conditions
1. From equations (10.12) and (11.18), we have
(11.19)
r$ - r£ = PUS*-dot – PUK*-dot
(11.20)
r$ - PUS*-dot = r£ – PUK*-dot
(1) The real interest rate is the nominal interest rate minus the expected rate of
inflation.
(2) Equation (11.20) is called the Fisher-open condition which is the condition
that the real interest rates are equal in different countries.
2. The interdependence of Exchange Rates, Interest Rates, and Inflation Rates
(1) Mathematical representations
◎ Uncovered interest parity:
◎ Expected PPP:
TM11-21
r$ – r£ = S*-dot($/£)
PUS*-dot – PUK*-dot = S*-dot($/£)
◎ Fisher-open:
r$ - PUS*-dot = r£ – PUK*-dot
(2) Figure 11.2.: Any one of these conditions can be derived from the other two.
TM11-22
Why Covered Interest Differences Persist
The failure to achieve exact covered interest parity could occur because in actual
financial markets there are:
1. Transaction costs
2. Political Risks
3. Potential tax advantages to foreign exchange gains versus interest earnings
4. Liquidity differences between foreign securities and domestic securities
TM11-23
Transaction Costs and Interest Parity
1. Sources of transaction costs
(1) The cost of transaction in foreign exchange is reflected in the bid-ask spread
in exchange rates.
(2) Covered investment or borrowing involve two foreign exchange transaction
costs-one on the spot market and the other on the forward market.
(3) There are additional transaction costs of interest arbitrage due to interest-rate
spreads. This is because the borrowing interest rate is likely to exceed the
investment interest rate.
2. Situations off the interest parity line
(1) It SEEMS that there could be large deviations from interest parity by up to
the extra transaction costs of investing or borrowing in foreign currency
before the benefits of the foreign alternative are sufficient to compensate
TM11-24
for the added costs.
◎ interest rate spread
◎ foreign exchange transaction costs
3. Reasons for the recognition that transaction costs DO NOT contribute to deviations
from interest parity
(1) One-way interest arbitrage
Figure 11.3. One-way and Round-trip interest arbitrage
[skip]
◎ For round-trip interest arbitrage to be profitable it is necessary to
overcome the transaction costs in the foreign exchange markets and the
borrowing-lending spread on interest rates.
◎ Figure 11.4. Interest Parity in the Presence of Transaction Costs,
TM11-25
Political Risk, or Liquidity Premiums
A band around the interest parity line within which round-trip interest
arbitrage is unprofitable.
◎ One-way interest arbitrage
Look at equation (11.25) on p.277.
Either method of going from $0 to £n requires buying pounds, the only
difference being whether they are purchased on the spot or the forward
market.
Therefore, transaction costs will be paid whatever the choice.
(2) The choice faced by third-country borrowers and investors
◎ The Japanese or Germans pay foreign exchange costs whatever the
currency of their investment or borrowing, i.e., $ or £, and compare
investment or borrowing rates in the two currencies.
TM11-26
(3) Summary
For the reasons described above, we can expect deviations from interest
parity to be too small for round-trip arbitrage to ever occur. We conclude
that transaction costs are probably NOT a cause of deviations from interest
parity.
TM11-27
Political Risk and Interest Parity
1. Definition:
Political risk involves the uncertainty that while funds are invested in a foreign
country, they may be frozen, become inconvertible into other currencies, or be
confiscated.
2. Alternative situations
(1) Usually, the investment that involves the least political risk is at home.
(2) It is possible that for investors in some countries, it is politically less risky to
send funds abroad.
For example, people in some volatile countries have
invested in Switzerland and the United States for political safety.
3. It is important to remember that political risk relates to the country, not the currency,
of investment.
(1) The extra spread when political risk is faced versus when it is not faced is a
TM11-28
measure of the political risk premium.
4. Even when covered yields are on instruments which trade in different countries,
third-country investors might force interest rates and exchange rates onto the
interest parity line.
◎ Japanese investors view the United States and Britain as equally risky
politically
◎ If conditions are driven onto the interest parity line, this will encourage U.S.
and British investors to keep funds at home, because neither is receiving
compensation for the perceive risk of investing in the other country.
TM11-29
Taxes and Interest Parity
[skip]
TM11-30
Liquidity Differences and Interest Parity
1. Definition:
The liquidity of an asset can be judged by how quickly and cheaply it can be
converted into cash.
2. Sources of Costs
Situation: a covered foreign-currency 90-day investment is sold after only 50
days
(1) The brokerage costs for selling a security
(2) Transaction costs are faced when investors convert the foreign exchange
from the hedged foreign-currency security on the spot market.
(3) When a security is sold prior to maturity and the funds are converted into
domestic currency, there is still the matter of honoring the original forward
contract to sell the foreign exchange at the maturity of the foreign currency
TM11-31
investment.
◎ to buy spot foreign currency at the date of maturity
◎ to buy a new forward exchange contract of 40 days maturity
3. The amount of extra required return and hence the potential width of the band due to
liquidity preference depend on the likelihood that the funds will be needed early
and on whether these funds can be borrowed by using the original covered
investment to secure the loans.
◎ The more uncertainty there is concerning future needs and alternative
sources of short-term financing, the higher are the premiums that should be
required before venturing into foreign-currency securities.
TM11-32
Effect of the Reasons for Interest Disparity on Investment and Borrowing Decisions
[skip]
TM11-33
Download