REVIEW OF TRANSMISSION AND DISTRIBUTION PRICING SUBMISSION TO NECA by ACTEW CORPORATION March 1998 The NECA Review ACTEW has reviewed the documents issued by NECA as part of its inquiry into network pricing and regulation. ACTEW notes that NECA “ is likely to recommend change to the current regulatory and pricing arrangements” as a result of this review. ACTEW is keen that NECA not lose sight of the important issue of pricing and regulatory principles, in its quest to get the details right. Network pricing is a complex matter with many vested interests. The current network pricing code reflects the need for pragmatism in getting the national market process up and running. ACTEW supported this pragmatic approach as a basis for moving forward, whilst recognising there are many failings, some of which are documented in the discussion paper released by NECA. One major area in which the pricing and regulatory principles was never properly addressed in the draft code of conduct, concerns the role and powers of the price regulator. This also affects the degree of price prescription necessary in the code. This matter is the main focus of ACTEW’s submission. Price Regulation The Hilmer Committee (1993) provided no ambiguity on the matter. They stressed the need for light handed regulation as an outcome of their review into competition policy. This position was later endorsed by the Industry Commission (1995). Their view was that regulatory oversight should be confined to monitoring or surveillance of prices, rather than setting prices. The Hilmer committee made it clear that regulatory “oversight would provide for prices monitoring or surveillance, but not prices control” (p289) and envisaged that “to the maximum extent possible, pricing decisions should be made by individual firms rather than regulators” (p277).1 The IC also concluded that price determination be left "in the hands of GBE managers subject to appropriate surveillance and monitoring" p53. The 1 Hilmer Committee of Inquiry, National Competition Policy, August 1993 IC argued that adherence to the principle of light handed regulation "implies adoption of restricted price surveillance and monitoring rather than price control mechanisms" p72.2 Yet a survey of the powers of the state and territory regulators across Australia reveals that most have the ‘heavy handed’ power to set prices (actual prices or price caps). There isn’t even a right of appeal for regulated entities to price determinations by regulators, nor is this suggested anywhere in the network pricing part of the code. Yet the price control power exercised by the state and territory regulators is at odds with the powers of the ACCC, which will take on responsibility for transmission price regulation in the near future. Under the Prices Surveillance Act, the ACCC only has the power to monitor prices or give pricing recommendations (price surveillance). To date, the regulated entities have been silent on this very important issue. The points identified in the material prepared by NECA are really subservient to this issue - how much power should regulator’s have and to what extent does this regulatory power provide guidance on the level of prescription required in the code of conduct. ACTEW’s View on Price Regulation ACTEW supports light handed regulation, where the firm retains the power to set network prices. However, ACTEW agrees this should be done within a regulatory framework of pricing oversight, where price regulation takes the form of monitoring or surveillance, but not price control. If price regulation is to take the form of price control, then there must be a right of appeal available to the regulated entity, as in the UK. In keeping with this view, ACTEW believes the code of conduct on network pricing should be much less prescriptive, focussing solely on network pricing objectives and principles. In turn regulators must be accountable for their decisions so that there is more of a balance of power between the regulator and the regulated entity. This can be by way of a right of appeal (if the regulator has price control powers) or by veto (if the regulator only has the power to recommend prices). Either way, the regulator must face their responsibility in an open and accountable way. It should be noted the code does refer to light handed regulation, but only in terms of the form of regulation. It is stated that CPI+/- X is light handed, when what really matters is the Regulator’s power to enforce a determination, not the type of cap imposed. 2 Industry Commission, Implementing the National Competition Policy: Access and Price Regulation, 1995 Outcomes of the Current Regulatory Approach It is ACTEW’s contention that one of the outcomes of the price control approach has been for the industry to develop a highly prescriptive pricing code to limit the power of the regulator. In ACTEW’s view, this is a case of fixing one problem with another, without recourse to the principles. In effect, the code attempts to lock in a set of pricing outcomes for network owners by specifying in detail the principles to be taken into account in setting price caps and guidelines for cost allocation and price setting. This appears to have been an attempt to reduce their risks (to a fall in business value particularly) and does this under the veil of independent price regulation. The NGMC itself appeared confused on the issue, arguing that a prescriptive code for network pricing would safeguard the interests of consumers given the natural monopoly characteristics of network businesses. They argued that prescription would provide price stability, regulatory certainty and transparency.3 In so doing, they were effectively arguing that price regulators couldn’t be trusted to deliver in these areas. It is ACTEW’s belief that a less prescriptive code and much more light handed regulation (such as price surveillance) would provide a far better model than the muddled and inconsistent approach adopted to date. It would also make the transition of network transmission prices in the future to the ACCC, compatible with the current federal price regulation regime. Code Prescription and Distribution Price Regulation - A NSW Case Study It is worth considering network pricing outcomes under the current approach to see how the present regime works. ACTEW has documented the situation in NSW, where the NSW price regulator has price control powers and the NSW distributors have no right of appeal to the price determination. This case example is provided for information only, and should not in any way be perceived as a criticism, implicit or otherwise, of the work of the NSW price regulator. Under the present operating regime, it would be expected that regulatory outcomes for the NSW distributors would be relatively equal. NGMC, Rationale for application of “CPI minus X” regulation of transmission charges in the National Electricity Market, December 1995, p.12 3 Yet in NSW we can observe that one of the distributors (referred to as A) is treated very differently. This particular distributor (A) maintains relatively low network charges for large commercial and industrial demand customers and relatively high charges for small, ‘captive’ domestic customers. A’s prices have been compared to the average of B,C and D’s in the following comparison. 28% 1% NSW Average (B,C,D) Domestic General LVD HVD -18% -12% A’s network charges to domestic customers are 28% higher than the average of the other three (B,C and D) while its prices to big customers are up to 18% lower. In the absence of significantly different economic costs of network supply, this outcome is open to question. This would appear to provide A with a real but subtle competitive network advantage. A is less likely to risk losing its big customers that may be capable of network by-pass. These customers would also have less incentive to seek a lower negotiated network price than they would in the jurisdictions of B,C and D. The main point of this example is in relation to pricing power of the regulator and the degree of price prescription in the code. The supporters of code prescription would argue for more prescription on cost allocation and price setting to reduce the scope for such inconsistencies. However, ACTEW would contend that less, not more regulation would prevent such outcomes. A distributor that was able to appeal against (or ignore) a determination, particularly in the light of evidence re treatment of others, would help ensure regulators were more focussed on outcomes and much more accountable for their decisions - leading to a balancing of power and better pricing outcomes in the first place. Summary and Conclusion At present the NEM code of conduct implicitly endorses the need to give network pricing regulators full power to determine network prices, both for transmission and distribution. This is backed up by regulatory legislation in NSW, Vic, and ACT which gives the regulator price control power. There is not even any provision for a right of appeal by the regulated entity. This is clearly inconsistent with the principle of light handed regulation endorsed by COAG and laid down in the competition principles agreement. It is also inconsistent with the powers held by the future regulator of network prices, the ACCC, which (appropriately) does not yet have price control powers. The disparity between the regulatory price principles which require a genuine light handed approach, and the actual outcomes in the code of conduct and in state/territory regulatory legislation is a matter that warrants the highest priority in the NECA review.