Capital Structure: Basic Concepts Chapter 16 16-0 Key Concepts and Skills Understand the effect of financial leverage (i.e., capital structure) on firm earnings Understand homemade leverage Understand capital structure theories with and without taxes Be able to compute the value of the unlevered and levered firm 16-1 16.1 Capital Structure and the Pie The value of a firm is defined to be the sum of the value of the firm’s debt and the firm’s equity. V=B+S • If the goal of the firm’s management is to make the firm as valuable as possible, then the firm should pick the debt-equity ratio that makes the pie as big as possible. S B Value of the Firm 16-2 Stockholder Interests There are two important questions: 1.Why should the stockholders care about maximizing firm value? Perhaps they should be interested in strategies that maximize shareholder value. 2.What is the ratio of debt-to-equity that maximizes the shareholder’s value? As it turns out, changes in capital structure benefit the stockholders if and only if the value of the firm increases. 16-3 16.3 Financial Leverage, EPS, and ROE Consider an all-equity firm that is contemplating going into debt. (Maybe some of the original shareholders want to cash out.) Current Assets $20,000 Debt $0 Equity $20,000 Debt/Equity ratio 0.00 Interest rate n/a Shares outstanding 400 Share price $50 Proposed $20,000 $8,000 $12,000 2/3 8% 240 $50 16-4 EPS and ROE Under Current Structure Recession Expected Expansion EBIT $1,000 $2,000 $3,000 Interest 0 0 0 Net income $1,000 $2,000 $3,000 EPS $2.50 $5.00 $7.50 ROA 5% 10% 15% ROE 5% 10% 15% Current Shares Outstanding = 400 shares 16-5 EPS and ROE Under Proposed Structure Recession Expected Expansion EBIT $1,000 $2,000 $3,000 Interest 640 640 640 Net income $360 $1,360 $2,360 EPS $1.50 $5.67 $9.83 ROA 1.8% 6.8% 11.8% ROE 3.0% 11.3% 19.7% Proposed Shares Outstanding = 240 shares 16-6 Financial Leverage and EPS 12.00 Debt 10.00 EPS 8.00 6.00 4.00 No Debt Advantage to debt Break-even point 2.00 0.00 1,000 (2.00) Disadvantage to debt 2,000 3,000 EBIT in dollars, no taxes 16-7 Assumptions of the M&M Model Homogeneous Expectations Homogeneous Business Risk Classes Perpetual Cash Flows Perfect Capital Markets: ◦ ◦ ◦ ◦ ◦ Perfect competition Firms and investors can borrow/lend at the same rate Equal access to all relevant information No transaction costs No taxes 16-8 Homemade Leverage: An Example Recession Expected Expansion EPS of Unlevered Firm $2.50 $5.00 $7.50 Earnings for 40 shares $100 $200 $300 Less interest on $800 (8%) $64 $64 $64 Net Profits $36 $136 $236 ROE (Net Profits / $1,200) 3.0% 11.3% 19.7% We are buying 40 shares of a $50 stock, using $800 in margin. We get the same ROE as if we bought into a levered firm. Our personal debt-equity ratio is: B $800 2 = = 3 S $1,200 16-9 Homemade (Un)Leverage: An Example Recession Expected Expansion EPS of Levered Firm $1.50 $5.67 $9.83 Earnings for 24 shares $36 $136 $236 Plus interest on $800 (8%) $64 $64 $64 Net Profits $100 $200 $300 ROE (Net Profits / $2,000) 5% 10% 15% Buying 24 shares of an otherwise identical levered firm along with some of the firm’s debt gets us to the ROE of the unlevered firm. This is the fundamental insight of M&M 16-10 MM Proposition I (No Taxes) We can create a levered or unlevered position by adjusting the trading in our own account. This homemade leverage suggests that capital structure is irrelevant in determining the value of the firm: VL = VU 16-11 16.4 MM Proposition II (No Taxes) Proposition II ◦ Leverage increases the risk and return to stockholders Rs = R0 + (B / SL) (R0 - RB) RB is the interest rate (cost of debt) Rs is the return on (levered) equity (cost of equity) R0 is the return on unlevered equity (cost of capital) B is the value of debt SL is the value of levered equity 16-12 MM Proposition II (No Taxes) The derivation is straightforward: RW ACC = B S × RB + × RS B+S B+S B S × RB + × RS = R0 B+S B+S T h e n s e t RW ACC = R 0 B+S multiply both sides by S B+S B B+S S B+S × × RB + × × RS = R0 S B+S S B+S S B B+S × RB + RS = R0 S S B B × RB + RS = R0 + R0 S S B RS = R0 + ( R0 − RB ) S 16-13 Cost of capital: R (%) MM Proposition II (No Taxes) R0 RS = R0 + RW ACC = B × ( R0 − RB ) SL S B × RB + × RS B+S B+S RB RB Debt-to-equity Ratio B S 16-14 What do we learn from MM I&II without tax You use OPERATIONAL CASH FLOWS to evaluate the Projects The value of the Firm is the Present Value of those Cash Flows The Cash Flows are independent of the Capital Structure the Firm chooses. 16-15 So, in different Capital Structures you are discounting the same Cash Flows and getting the same Present Value of Cash Flows, this means that: the discount you are using is the same for different capital structures which is WACC! 16-16 What is happening is the following: ◦ When you increase Debt in the Firm, Equity becomes more expensive ◦ But, you are using less of the more expensive capital (Equity) and more of the more cheap capital (Debt) ◦ In the end, they compensate exactly, leaving the WACC constant. 16-17 The second Modigliani-Miller Proposition tells us what is the cost of Equity for different Capital Structures We know two facts: ◦ The Cost of Equity increases with more Debt ◦ The WACC remains constant 16-18 16.5 MM Propositions I & II (With Taxes) Proposition I (with Corporate Taxes) ◦ Firm value increases with leverage VL = VU + TC B Proposition II (with Corporate Taxes) ◦ Some of the increase in equity risk and return is offset by the interest tax shield RS = R0 + (B/S) 16-19 MM Proposition I (With Taxes) The total cash flow to all stakeholde rs is ( EBIT − RB B ) × (1 − TC ) + RB B The present value of this stream of cash flows is VL Clearly ( EBIT − RB B) × (1 − TC ) + RB B = = EBIT × (1 − TC ) − RB B × (1 − TC ) + RB B = EBIT × (1 − TC ) − RB B + RB BTC + RB B The present value of the first term is VU The present value of the second term is TCB ∴VL = VU + TC B 16-20 MM Proposition II (With Taxes) Start with M&M Proposition I with taxes: Since VL = VU + TC B VL = S + B ⇒ S + B = VU + TC B VU = S + B (1 − TC ) The cash flows from each side of the balance sheet must equal: SRS + BR B = VU R0 + TC BR B SRS + BR B = [ S + B (1 − TC )]R0 + TC RB B Divide both sides by S B B B RS + RB = [1 + (1 − TC )]R0 + TC RB S S S B Which quickly reduces to RS = R0 + × (1 − TC ) × ( R0 − RB ) 16-21 S The Effect of Financial Leverage Cost of capital: R (%) RS = R0 + RS = R0 + B × ( R0 − RB ) SL B × (1 − TC ) × ( R0 − RB ) SL R0 RW ACC = SL B × RB × (1 − TC ) + × RS B+SL B + SL RB Debt-to-equity ratio (B/S) 16-22 All Equity Total Cash Flow to Investors EBIT Interest EBT Taxes (Tc = 35%) Levered Total Cash Flow to S/H EBIT Interest ($800 @ 8% ) EBT Taxes (Tc = 35%) Total Cash Flow (to both S/H & B/H): EBIT(1-Tc)+TCRBB Recession $1,000 0 $1,000 $350 Expected $2,000 0 $2,000 $700 Expansion $3,000 0 $3,000 $1,050 $650 $1,300 $1,950 Recession $1,000 640 $360 $126 $234+640 $874 $650+$224 $874 Expected $2,000 640 $1,360 $476 $884+$640 $1,524 $1,300+$224 $1,524 Expansion $3,000 640 $2,360 $826 $1,534+$640 $2,174 $1,950+$224 $2,174 16-23 Total Cash Flow to Investors All-equity firm S G Levered firm S G B The levered firm pays less in taxes than does the all-equity firm. Thus, the sum of the debt plus the equity of the levered firm is greater than the equity of the unlevered firm. This is how cutting the pie differently can make the pie “larger.” -the government takes a smaller slice of the pie! 16-24 Summary: No Taxes In a world of no taxes, the value of the firm is unaffected by capital structure. This is M&M Proposition I: VL = VU Proposition I holds because shareholders can achieve any pattern of payouts they desire with homemade leverage. In a world of no taxes, M&M Proposition II states that leverage increases the risk and return to stockholders. B RS = R0 + × ( R0 − RB ) SL 16-25 Summary: Taxes In a world of taxes, but no bankruptcy costs, the value of the firm increases with leverage. This is M&M Proposition I: VL = VU + TC B Proposition I holds because shareholders can achieve any pattern of payouts they desire with homemade leverage. In a world of taxes, M&M Proposition II states that leverage increases the risk and return to stockholders. B RS = R0 + × (1 − TC ) × ( R0 − RB ) SL 16-26 Example Green Manufacturing plans to announce that it will issue $2m in perpetual debt and use the proceeds to repurchase common stock. The bonds will sell at par with a 6% annual coupon rate. Green is currently an all-equity firm, worth $10m with 0.5m shares. After the sale of the bonds, Green will maintain the new capital structure indefinitely. Green currently generates annual pretax earnings of $1.5m. This is supposed to continue in perpetuity and the tax rate is 40% 16-27 What is the expected return on Green’s equity before the announcement? b) What is Green’s market value balance sheet before the announcement? What is the price per share? c) Construct Green’s market value balance sheet after the announcement? d) What is the price share after the announcement? a) 16-28 e) How many shares will Green repurchase? f) Construct the market value balance sheet after the announcement g) What is the required return on equity after the re-structuring? 16-29 You may think the new structure will be Debt $2m and Equity $8m, but that will not happen. You may think that the proceeds from the bond issue will buy 100,000 shares, but that will not happen. 16-30 a) In order to answer the question, we just need to calculate the Cash Flow that the stockholders will receive The pretax earnings are $1.5m. After taxes of 40% it becomes $900,000. So the rate of return on equity is $900,000 divided by $10,000,000. It’s 9% 16-31 b) The company is only equity. So the balance sheet is simply Assets Total $10,000,000 $10,000,000 Debt $0 Equity $10,000,000 Total $10,000,000 The price per share is only $10m divided by 0.5m shares. It is $20. 16-32 c) After the announcement of the issue of the $2m bonds, the efficient market hypothesis and the MM propositions tell you that the tax shield of the debt will be incorporated in the value of the firm. Because, there is only equity in the firm, the equity will absorb this gain in value. 16-33 The debt is perpetual. It is sold at par, with a coupon rate of 6%. This means the debt will pay a perpetual coupon of 6% of $2m. Since it is at par, to get the present value of the tax shield , we discount it using 6% too. As we saw in previous class this means the present value of this tax shield is t*B=40%*$2m=$0.8m 16-34 The balance sheet of Green will now look like Assets $10,000,000 Debt $0 PV tax shield $800,000 Equity $10,800,000 Total $10,800,000 Total $10,800,000 16-35 d) The new price will reflect this new value being incorporated. So, the Equity is worth $10.8m and there are still 0.5m shares. The price is $21.6 e) The number of shares repurchased is the quantity of shares that, at the new price, add up to a value of $2m. This number is 92,593. There will the 407,407 shares left. 16-36 f) After the re-structuring, the value of the equity is reduced by the amount it was repurchased ($2m). The value of the firm will not change, because any changes in value coming from this operation is already incorporated. Assets $10,000,000 Debt $2,000,000 PV tax shield $800,000 Equity $8,800,000 Total $10,800,000 Total $10,800,000 16-37 Notice that 407,407*$21.6=$8,800,000 g) From part a) we know that R0 is 9%. We also know RB is 6%, B is $2m and S is $8.8m. So, we just need to apply MM Proposition II B RS = R0 + (R0 − RB )(1 − t ) S $0.8m RS = 9% + (9% − 6% )(1 − 0.4 ) = 9.41% $2m 16-38 Suggested problems (Chapter 16) 9, 12, 19, 20, 23, 24 16-39