When Does Diffusion Matter? Explaining the Spread of Structural Pension Reforms Across Nations Sarah M. Brooks The Ohio State University When and where is cross-national diffusion an important determinant of policy innovation? I posit that the characteristics of a policy innovation—whether it imposes high or low “sunk” costs on adopters—and country attributes such as wealth, mediate the importance of diffusion in domestic policy choices. Competing risks analysis of two structural pension reform models in 71 developing and industrialized countries supports these hypotheses. Peer diffusion weighs heavily in the adoption of the costly “funded” defined-contribution pension reform model, and does so principally among middle-income nations, while the less-costly “notional” defined-contribution pension reform is not governed by diffusion. A n important source of policy innovation is the process by which governments learn from each other. Although the emulation of social practice across distant societies was long enchained by the cost of physical movement and communication, technological advances have eased such barriers in recent decades, slashing the cost of transmitting information to vast corners of the world. As a result, cross-national ties have become both more extensive and intensive (Keohane and Nye 2000), while evidence of common movements in policy choice has burgeoned. In step with this trend, a productive stream of scholarly research has yielded important insights into the nature and causes of international policy diffusion, or the process by which the probability of adoption of an innovation in one location is conditioned by prior adoptions of the innovation elsewhere (Bennett 1997; Braun and Gilardi 2006; Dolowitz and Marsh 1996, 2000; Jordana and Levi-Faur 2005; Meseguer 2004; Simmons and Elkins 2004). As valuable as this research trajectory has been, it has left important questions unanswered. First, while much is known about the channels and mechanisms of diffusion, the domain of innovations over which diffusion forces are likely to hold sway has been less fully explored. Are all policy choices subject to the influence of prior innovation decisions abroad? Or, is diffusion more influential in some types of innovation decisions than others? In most cases, where the limits of diffusion are examined, these are taken to be instances in which policies fail to “catch on” in other locations. But this definition is not altogether satisfactory; for we may observe close correlations in the location or timing of innovations even when such decisions are not interdependent, or causally linked. The task that remains thus is to define when and where diffusion becomes causally relevant in domestic policy choice. Second, while extant research has focused overwhelmingly on the subset of diffusion processes in which governments confront a single policy or innovation choice within a given issue area, it is more common that multiple alternatives are available from which policy makers may choose. Another major task that remains for the study of diffusion thus is to understand how state actors select among competing policy innovations that respond to a common problem. I address these questions through analysis of the cross-national spread of two distinct models of structural pension reform. In the last quarter century, rising demographic and economic pressures have prompted governments around the world to apportion greater responsibility for old-age pension provision to workers through the creation of individual savings accounts. Two alternative reform models have emerged within this trend, which differ in the way that pension accounts are managed and funded. In the first model, called the funded defined-contribution (FDC) pension reform or “privatization,” individual The Journal of Politics, Vol. 69, No. 3, August 2007, pp. 701–715 © 2007 Southern Political Science Association ISSN 0022-3816 701 702 sarah m. brooks retirement accounts are managed by private sector firms and invested in real assets (i.e., the accounts are fully funded). In the second model, called notional defined-contribution (NDC) pension reform, the state retains management of the pension accounts, which are financed on a pay-as-you-go basis (i.e., they are unfunded) like many traditional state pension systems. While responding to a common problem using similar principles, these two policies vary critically in the irrecoverable political and financial costs of adoption, that is, in the “sunk” costs associated with each innovation: whereas the FDC model is costly to enact and difficult to reverse, NDC reforms impose a lighter up-front financial toll on governments, and may be more easily revised or repealed ex post. This difference, I argue, bears powerfully on the question of when diffusion matters in policy innovation processes, while also shaping the domestic political economy of reform. Diffusion research has posited two principal mechanisms that link innovation decisions across space and time: information and competition. My argument about when and where diffusion matters thus examines how the significance of these two factors is mediated in domestic policy choices by (1) characteristics of the innovation itself, namely whether it entails high or low sunk costs, and (2) by country attributes associated with national wealth. I expect that as the irreversible political and financial burdens of adopting an innovation rise, informational and competitive concerns, and thus diffusion itself, should weigh more heavily in domestic policy choices. I also expect diffusion to be more influential in policy decisions among lower-income nations compared to more affluent countries. This is, in short, a theory of when political leaders will rely on internationally transmitted information that looks both to the particular characteristics of the reform that is being considered and to features of the nation itself. Global Pension Reform Patterns Structural pension reform emerged in the last quarter of the twentieth century as a policy means through which governments could reduce long-term pension costs, which rise as populations age. This category of policy innovations supplants the traditional “definedbenefit” pension rules, in which the state (i.e., society as a whole) bears the cost and risk of providing a fixed level of retirement income for the elderly, with a “defined contribution” (DC) principle, in which each worker’s pension depends on her own contributions to a personal retirement account. By legislating only the contribution rate to individual pension accounts, the DC principle transfers an array of income and longevity risks to individuals, whose pension is equal only to the sum of her savings during working life and some return to those contributions. The losers in this shift thus are the beneficiaries of redistribution in traditional social insurance pension systems, including lowincome workers and those with interrupted earnings. While in the funded (FDC) model, the return to invested pension savings is based on financial market trends and the wisdom of individual investment choices, it is the state that determines the interest rate applied to pension contributions in the NDC scheme (Palmer 2002, 14). The first national FDC pension reform was implemented in Chile in 1981 by the military dictatorship of Augusto Pinochet. Although interest in that reform was slow to ignite, Chile’s private pension system captured the attention of policy makers internationally following the nation’s transition to democracy in 1990, when high rates of growth and a thriving new stock market set Chile apart from its recessiongripped neighbors. By 2005, some degree of FDC pension reform had been adopted in 23 countries from the United Kingdom to Kazakhstan, while similar measures were underway in Estonia, Lithuania, and the Dominican Republic. The NDC model emerged much more recently, but has spread even more quickly than the FDC model did in its early years. Although it was initially proposed in Sweden in the early 1990s, an NDC reform was first legislated in Italy in 1995. Within a decade, NDC-style pension reforms had been adopted in seven additional countries from Poland to Brazil (see the appendix for a full list of adopters of each model). Thus, by the start of the twenty-first century, the question facing policy makers was not simply whether to enact a structural pension reform, but rather, which model to adopt? As Figures 1 and 2 illustrate, moreover, the spread of each pension model reveals striking temporal and geographic correlations, raising important questions about the extent of interdependence among domestic political processes across adopters of these reforms. Given that structural pension reform is a policy choice, rather than an inevitability, I begin by examining the principal actors and their motives in the decision-making process. Theories of Policy Diffusion At the heart of diffusion research is the concept of interdependent decision making. In this process, a when does diffusion matter? FIGURE 1 703 Adoptions of FDC Pension Reform 1980–2002 30 25 Total Number 20 Latin America OECD Post-Communist Total 15 10 5 FIGURE 2 19 19 80 81 19 82 19 83 19 84 19 85 19 86 19 87 19 88 19 89 19 90 19 91 19 92 19 93 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 0 Adoptions of NDC Pension Reform 1980–2002 9 8 7 Total Number 6 Latin America OECD Post-Communist Total 5 4 3 2 1 19 80 19 81 19 82 19 83 19 84 19 85 19 86 19 87 19 88 19 89 19 90 19 91 19 92 19 93 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 0 decision in one location is conditioned to some degree by similar choices made elsewhere in the social system. Where public policy is concerned, such processes typically involve the transfer of knowledge from one location to the next, which shapes the course of policy development (Dolowitz and Marsh 1996, 344). While the enactment of formal policy change in democracy rests ultimately in the hands of elected legislators, the task of identifying and analyzing alternative policy models typically falls to the executive, and in 704 particular to highly trained policy specialists, or “technocrats” within the government (Heclo 1974; Mintrom 1997). A critical objective of these analysts is to determine the appropriateness of a policy innovation to their own nation’s problem and context, and the likely consequences of its adoption. Whether and how such judgments are conditioned by analogous decisions abroad is central to understanding the channels and importance of diffusion in domestic policy processes. Information. In his pioneering study of the politics of diffusion, Jack Walker observed that “Uncertainty and the fear of unanticipated consequences have always been formidable barriers to reform” (1969, 890). Subsequent research has upheld this view, demonstrating that diffusion is closely linked to the process of “social learning” (Heclo 1974), wherein potential adopters draw lessons from previous experiences at home or abroad. In this view, governments that are uncertain about an innovation will examine the outcome of previous reforms in order to gain information about its likely effects. As the number of previous adoptions of an innovation rises, uncertainty is said to decline, increasing the likelihood of subsequent adoptions of the policy innovation (Jordana and Levi-Faur 2005; Meseguer 2004; Simmons and Elkins 2004). From whom do government actors acquire such information? Although information about policy choices made in far corners of the world may be available to government analysts, many are highly constrained in the time and resources that they can devote to such analysis. Rather than undertaking exhaustive searches for the “best” policy alternative, therefore, decision makers are said to “satisfice” (Simon 1976) by looking for cues from prior experiences (Walker 1969; Weyland 2005). Even in the process of cue taking, however, government actors are unlikely to give equal consideration to all prior innovation experiences. Instead, they tend to weigh more heavily the information drawn from a subset of prior adopters that they consider most relevant to their own country. These have been shown to be political entities that are geographically proximate and thus which share political networks and economic and social linkages (Berry and Berry 1992; Mintrom and Vergari 1998; Rogers 1995; Walker 1969; Weyland 2005). Such “peers” also may be defined by cultural ties and shared economic status (Brune and Guisinger 2006; Simmons and Elkins 2004). In both cases, the likeness among peers makes information drawn from them more credible and relevant to the task of discerning a policy model’s appropriateness at home. sarah m. brooks While scholars have focused considerable attention on delineating the sources and channels of information shortcuts, less attention has been paid to the question of whether such cues are decisive in all policy reform decisions. Where such heterogeneity has been considered, it is typically defined solely in spatial terms, focusing on variations in the rates of diffusion across geographically defined areas (e.g., Anselin 1988). Yet, uncertainty about the benefits of a new policy is likely to vary across types of innovations as well, as some new policies may generate more uncertainty than others. Such uncertainty, in turn, should raise the value of information drawn from prior experiences abroad and thus make diffusion a more powerful factor in that policy process. The next step, then, is to examine how and when uncertainty and external cues—and thus diffusion itself—might vary in importance across types of innovations. Competition. The adoption of an innovation may not always be motivated solely by the appeal of the direct functions of the new technology, as research has shown that the desire to gain secondary, competitive rewards such as improved status or material gains also lends powerful impetus to diffusion (Berry and Berry 1992; Gray 1973; Mintrom 1997; Simmons and Elkins 2004; Walker 1969). Where material benefits are concerned, such as the expansion of a firm’s market share, these rewards typically are attributed to inherent features of the innovation. But in the case of public policy, competitive benefits for governments more often arise from an innovation’s effect on the reputation or international status of the government. Policy innovations, in this sense, may be desired not only for their direct domestic ends, but also for the “signal” that the new policy transmits about the state—such as about its business-friendliness, modernity, democratic credentials, or the like. Given that one country’s international standing is conditioned perforce by that of other nations, reputation and status gains are inherently competitive. Often, however, there is more at stake than relative status alone. Where a policy innovation—be it human rights legislation or economic reform—is salient to international audiences, the potential gains from its adoption can raise one nation’s status over that of its peers, promising greater access to a host of excludable goods such as international investment, aid, or admission into international organizations. Although previous research has shown that fear of falling behind or being perceived as a “laggard” may prompt governments to enact policy changes that have been previously adopted by comparable nations (Dolowitz 1997, 26), we know less about the types of policies over when does diffusion matter? which these competitive dynamics are likely to hold sway. Nor is it clear that reputation concerns will carry equal weight in domestic policymaking processes across all countries; indeed, it is likely that they will not. The task that remains thus is to examine how the characteristics of a policy innovation, and the country itself, shape the weight of competitive concerns in its adoption. The next section offers two hypotheses in response to these questions. The first posits that as the irreversible or “sunk” political and financial costs of adopting an innovation rise, the informational and competitive mechanisms of diffusion will more powerfully shape domestic policy choices. The second suggests that these two diffusion forces should be more influential among developing countries than for the advanced industrial nations.Whereas the first hypothesis limits diffusion effects to specific types of innovation decisions, the second narrows the domain of interdependent effects even further among potential adopters of an innovation. When and Where Is Policy Choice Interdependent? Innovation is a costly and risky endeavor, not just financially, but in political terms as well (RoseAckerman 1980). Indeed, recognition of the dampening effects of such costs has justified an array of public interventions in markets to encourage and reward technological and scientific advances. But the risks and uncertainties that inhere in innovative processes do not fall exclusively on the original innovator; they also beset subsequent adopters of the innovation (Geroski 2000). The nature and magnitude of such risks are likely to vary systematically across types of innovations with the cost and ease of reversing the decision. Costs here are understood in very broad terms, encompassing both the financial expense associated with the policy change, the disruption in current policy practices, and the outlay of political capital to build public and legislative support for the new policy. In particular, the “sunk” cost of policy change should matter critically for questions of diffusion. These are costs that cannot be recouped either because the political or financial price of reversal is exceedingly high or because the decision itself cannot be easily undone, once taken. Sunk costs are especially relevant where policy reform initiates a path-dependent process, as in the case of old-age pension systems (Pierson 2001). Such costs, moreover, should mediate the effect of both information and competitive con- 705 cerns in systematic ways depending on the type of innovation and the country in question. Information. Economists have shown that sunk costs, along with uncertainty, are a major source of investment lags. This is because uncertainty about the value of a costly or (effectively) irreversible decision, such as clearing a forest or purchasing a steel mill, creates an important benefit for the potential adopter to wait for more information about the investment (Arrow and Fisher 1974, 317; Pindyck 1991). This benefit is known as the “option value” of the investment, which is surrendered when an irreversible action, or one that is effectively irreversible due to its high sunk costs, is taken. The option value is particularly high for such decisions precisely because there is an ability to learn about the innovation’s worth by waiting (Bernanke 1983). In financial markets, for instance, the right to reverse a decision not to invest (a “call option”) is given a monetary value for which investors are willing to pay. By surrendering the option to wait for more information about a policy choice, decision makers in effect pay an opportunity cost in choosing to take an irreversible course of action. In deciding to adopt a costly innovation when its merit is uncertain, therefore, decision makers must lower their overall expected benefits of the endeavor to reflect the loss of the option that such an action entails (Arrow and Fisher 1974, 319; Pindyck 1991, 1112). Critically, the option value of a decision is at its highest early in the learning process, when the possibility of gaining valuable information from others’ experiences is greatest. As time goes on and information is acquired, the value of waiting declines, reducing in turn the cost of taking the course of action, and thus raising the overall expected value of the project (Abel et al. 1996, 74–75; Bernanke 1983, 95). It is in this respect that the option value of a policy choice bears upon the question of diffusion. For technocrats weighing the enactment of a policy with high sunk costs, the value of waiting for more information about its merit should be greatest when few countries have enacted the measure, and thus when its effects are most uncertain. Accordingly, forbearance becomes the best decision early in the diffusion process where costs are of concern to decision makers. As more information about the innovation is acquired with subsequent adoptions, declining uncertainty should diminish the value of waiting to adopt it, raising both the expected benefits of the project, and the confidence of government actors in their judgment of the new policy. Since the value of waiting for information about a course of action is greatest for policies or investments that are both uncertain and that have very high sunk 706 costs, social learning should be a more influential component in innovation decisions for policies that are both costly and difficult to reverse, all else being equal. Further, since the value of waiting diminishes with the acquisition of information from the social system, we should observe that the diffusion of very costly innovations is quite slow initially, but increasing steadily as information becomes available with additional adoptions, and as the value of the option to wait falls. By comparison, less costly innovations should experience a more rapid spread across the social system early in the process, owing to the lower initial value of waiting for more information about its merit. Competition. The sunk cost of adopting an innovation should also mediate the weight of competitive rewards associated with that decision. This effect works primarily through the consequence of a measure’s political and financial cost on external perceptions of the credibility of a policy, i.e., the likelihood that it will be maintained (Fearon 1997; Martin 1993). Schelling first linked cost and credibility by noting that in international politics, “actions speak louder than words” (1966, 150) because actions entail the incursion of costs, which are irrevocable (cf. Martin 1993). This view has found broad support in political science research. As Martin (1993, 415) has shown, sanctions are credible when the actors who impose them bear significant costs, including the outlay of political capital to build domestic coalitions in support of the action. Fearon (1997) also found that actions with high sunk costs are more credible. This is not only because such costs would deter uncommitted governments, but also because any reversal would be seen as a political failure, imposing a heavy “audience” cost on the government. Innovations that are more burdensome to adopt may in this way provide a costly signal that carries more powerful reputational payoffs and thus may be subject to emulation by competing nations. Similarly, because less-costly or easily reversed innovations are more likely to be dismissed as mere “cheap talk,” these should be less powerfully subject to competitive emulation. Country Heterogeneity. Not only may diffusion effects vary across different types of innovations, but they should also differ in importance across nations of distinct political and economic characteristics. In particular, developing countries should weigh the cues from prior innovations most heavily when evaluating a new policy. There are two reasons to expect this. First, the greater resource constraints—both human and financial—on technocratic processes in lowerincome nations make it more difficult for policy sarah m. brooks makers in those countries to arrive at independent judgments about a project’s merit. The usefulness of adopting a new, expensive, and effectively irreversible policy change thus remains more uncertain in such contexts, raising the (option) value of waiting for more information about it from the social system. Second, tighter financial constraints should make developing country governments at once more sensitive to changes in the option value of waiting and more vulnerable to the negative effects of adopting the “wrong” innovation. Information about the benefits of a new policy from other governments’ experiences thus should be highly influential in decision-making processes of governments in capital-scarce countries and less significant for governments in more affluent nations. Competitive rewards to policy innovation also should weigh more heavily in the policy process of developing countries than in the advanced nations. For one thing, gains in international status and reputation offer relatively greater prospects for political or financial reward for developing countries compared to the affluent nations. The credibility of a policy decision in the eyes of international market audiences, moreover, bears directly upon the capacity of capitalscarce nations to compete with peer nations for foreign investment (Bartolini and Drazen 1997; Rodrik 1989). To the extent that developing-country governments use policy reform as a signal to international audiences of the government’s commitment to a given principle—be it economic liberalism or democracy—then certain policy innovations salient to these concerns may become the focus of competition for governments vying for excludable goods such as investment or accession into international political or economic organizations. The Cases of NDC and FDC Pension Reform How does this cost-centric argument help to explain when diffusion matters in the adoption of NDC and FDC pension reforms? This section draws out predictions based on the argument above to explain when diffusion forces should drive the spread of these competing models of structural pension reform. Analysis of the notional and funded pension reforms offers an ideal setting in which to examine these hypotheses, for it holds constant several important variables that may shape diffusion, such as the issue area, actors involved in the reform, and the weight of global and demo- when does diffusion matter? graphic pressures on a given country, while allowing the innovations to vary in terms of their political and financial costs. Domestic political costs. NDC and FDC pension reforms differ markedly in the political toll that they impose on reforming governments. While NDC reforms may be enacted with minimal short-term political costs, FDC models tend to exact a high political price of reformers. In general, measures such as structural pension reform are considered to be potentially costly in political terms because they impose direct losses on significant portions of the electorate while promising only distant and diffuse benefits (Pierson 1994; Pierson and Weaver 1993). Scholars thus have shown that a “frontal attack” on the welfare state may be all but politically deadly for career politicians, who instead will seek to avoid blame for such losses either by obfuscating benefit cuts altogether, or by enacting them through broad multiparty legislative coalitions that spread political responsibility widely among multiple political actors (Myles and Pierson 2001; Weaver 1986). In the case of the FDC reform, however, the creation of new private pension accounts makes this reform highly visible, and thus impossible to obfuscate. Rather, privatizing governments typically face mobilized protest from beneficiaries of traditional social insurance programs. Overcoming such opposition is a politically very demanding task, for it obliges reformers to persuade a skeptical public of the reform’s merit and often to compensate allies for their support on such a contentious reform. Once adopted, FDC pension reform is very difficult to reverse since it empowers politically relevant actors such as private pension fund managers with large stakes in the reformed system while also creating new and widely distributed private property rights. Any repeal of such rights, if constitutionally feasible, would likely be viewed as confiscation, imposing additional and very high political costs on the government. The political dynamics of NDC reform are quite different from those of privatization. For one thing, a notional pension system is considerably more opaque than its funded analogue. Since pension provision remains under state auspices, most citizens may not even be aware of the reform until they enter retirement. In Sweden, for example, despite a vigorous public information campaign, surveys reveal that most citizens lacked a basic knowledge or understanding of the NDC system that had been created five years earlier (Sundén 2006). The distributional implications of NDC pension reform are also likely to be less obvious to most citizens prior to enactment of the 707 reform. Indeed, benefits depend not only on each worker’s future income stream, but also on the evolution of broader labor market conditions and demographic trends, which are difficult for most citizens to accurately predict (Brooks and Weaver 2006, 368–69). Thus it is unlikely, at least in the early phases of diffusion, that citizens would be able to identify the distributional effects of a proposed NDC pension reform and mobilize against its enactment. The NDC model is not a politically risk-free strategy, however. Once the NDC reform takes effect, workers may ultimately find that their pension is lower than anticipated, sparking a political backlash against politicians who backed the reform. Knowing that NDC pension reform is fundamentally a means to cut pension costs, albeit “by stealth” (Pierson and Weaver 1993), career politicians should be willing to support this measure only where it is enacted by a broad range of coalition partners, as in multiparty systems (Brooks and Weaver 2006). Critically, NDC reforms are relatively easy for governments to revise ex post if the policy does not live up to expectations. Since the government determines the notional interest rate on individual account balances, it can award additional contribution credits for nonremunerated activities such as child care or military service or increase the return to contributions in order to defuse public dissatisfaction with the reform. For this reason economists have criticized the NDC model for maintaining the “political risk” of unanticipated changes in the rules of the system (Kruse 2006). Financial Costs. The two policy models also diverge markedly in the financial toll that they impose on reforming governments. Because individual FDC accounts are fully funded and privately managed, privatization opens up a wide gap in government finances as workers begin to divert payroll contributions to private sector funds. This leaves the government without a principal source of revenue for ongoing pension costs, which may be enormous where a nation’s elderly population is large. Moreover, the transition cost of FDC reform cannot be easily recovered later if the policy does not meet expectations, since any effort to reclaim the funds in citizens’ individual retirement accounts would spur a financial (and political) panic. FDC pension reform thus entails very high costs that are difficult, if not impossible, to recover later. By contrast, NDC pension reform imposes significantly lower up-front costs on reforming governments. It does so by maintaining the payas-you-go financing and public management of pension funds and thus allows reforming governments to sidestep the weighty transition cost associated with 708 FDC reform. This lighter financial burden has raised the appeal of the NDC model to governments struggling with very high pension costs and which lack the financial leeway to assume the cost of transition to a private pension system (Brooks and Weaver 2006). Competitive Benefits. The varied costs of NDC and FDC pension reform also imply differences in the importance that competitive rewards are likely to play in such decisions. In the case of old age pension reforms, while the putative macroeconomic benefits of the FDC model have so far been unproven, privatization is said to raise the attractiveness of an economy both to owners of financial capital and to direct investors through its effects on the depth and sophistication of domestic financial markets and firm management strategies (Diamond and Valdés-Prieto 1994). Further, the considerable political and financial toll associated with privatization has made that reform a costly, and thus credible, signal to market actors of the government’s commitment to market-oriented reform. Establishing such credibility became particularly important for developing countries seeking access to international capital markets in the 1990s, as the history of default, inflation, and economic instability made investment in those economies more risky for international investors. The potential investment rewards for developing countries that could establish their commitment to stable, market-based policies thus were great (Bartolini and Drazen 1997). Concerns for the signal that pension privatization would send to international market audiences entered prominently in the decision-making process for many developing-country governments (Mesa-Lago and Müller 2002; Müller 1999). In Argentina, for example, President Menem took the more arduous path of legislative enactment of his 1993 pension reform—unlike the bulk of his economic reforms, which were enacted by decree—precisely because market actors insisted on this costly signal of his commitment to the new private pension system (Schulthess 1998). For their part, market actors responded to the embrace of pension privatization among developing countries by offering lavish praise for reforming governments, while international banks rushed to join the new private pension markets. High-profile economists applauded early adopters such as Chile and Argentina as a “star performer,” and “model” for peer nations, respectively (e.g., Becker 1996; Edwards 1996; The Economist 12/1995). Other privatizing governments were even rewarded by sovereign credit-rating agencies following the enactment of FDC pension reform (James 1998, 466). The FDC model thus promised important competitive advantages—both in international status and sarah m. brooks investment—for developing countries that adopted this model in the 1990s. While the NDC model appeals to some governments on account of lower up-front financial costs, it also promises fewer ancillary reputational gains to adopters. Indeed, because NDC reform entails a less significant and costly institutional change from the traditional state-run system, it may be viewed as a signal that governments are less committed to the reform. And since the NDC model can be more easily revised over time, it may be perceived as less “permanent” than FDC reform. Not surprisingly, there has been little evidence to date that NDC reforms have captured substantial attention among international political or economic audiences. Expectations. Differences in the political and financial costs of innovation and country wealth imply a set of expectations over the category of reforms and the types of countries for which diffusion effects are likely to be significant. First, all else being equal, diffusion forces should weigh more heavily in the adoption of the more politically and financially costly FDC pension reform, such that the likelihood of adopting this measure in one country should increase systematically as the innovation is enacted by a greater share of the country’s peer nations. Conversely, diffusion should be a less significant influence in the adoption of the NDC pension reform design. Lastly, all else being equal, diffusion should be a stronger predictor of innovation adoption among lower-income nations than among the more affluent countries. Research Design: Data and Empirical Model I test these hypotheses in data from 71 nations with mandatory national social insurance pension systems between 1980 and 2002. These countries encompass the broad risk group over which structural pension reform models may diffuse. A list of the countries used in the analysis along with a list of definitions and sources for each variable are included in the online appendix at www.journalofpolitics.org/articles.html. Dependent Variable. The two dependent variables in the analysis are binary recordings of whether a government adopts an NDC or an FDC structural pension reform in a given year (coded 1 for each reform variable). If a structural pension reform is adopted, the country drops out of the analysis the following year. A diminishing risk group is justified by the long time horizon over which structural pension reforms are implemented—typically three to four when does diffusion matter? decades. Given this long transition, governments that have adopted one pension reform model face little if any “risk” of adopting the alternative model during the 23 years under observation here. Indeed, such a switch has not been observed in the last quarter century of structural pension reform. Independent Variables. Diffusion is widely defined as the observation of systematic ties between the likelihood of adopting an innovation in one location and the number or proportion of relevant prior adopters in a social system (Gray 1973; Jordana and Levi-Faur 2005; Mintrom 1997). The principal independent variable of this analysis thus is the percent of “peer” nations that have enacted each policy innovation by each year (Peer Adoption). As previous research has shown, peer status rests upon a firm sociocultural foundation, which may coincide with geographic proximity or shared regional status. For developing countries, peer status is defined geographically by international institutions such as the World Bank and International Monetary Fund, which organize research and operations around regional units. Other peer groups may be delimited by economic standing, such as the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), for which a central part of its mission is to promote the sharing of policy information among member nations. Peer nations thus may share common geopolitical and sociocultural status and are likely to be compared either by their own governments or by external audiences. Accordingly, the peer adoption variable is calculated for each reform over three distinct reference groups: (1) Latin America, which includes the Spanish and Portuguesespeaking nations of the Western hemisphere, (2) PostCommunist nations of Eastern Europe and Central Asia, and (3) the member nations of the OECD that are not included in the two previous categories. This variable is lagged one year. The domestic politics of pension reform are said to be governed by a logic of “blame avoidance,” wherein politicians seek political cover for imposing losses through large coalitions (Weaver 1986). The possibility for blame avoidance is captured through the fragmentation of legislative authority, measured as the effective number of political parties (Parties) competing in the legislature. This is the inverse of the sum of the squared seat shares of each legislative party (Laakso and Taagepera 1979). While this variable is not monotonic in fragmentation, it captures, albeit roughly, the dispersion of power among hypothetical equal-size parties in a given country and year. Where such authority is widely shared, no party is likely to hold a majority, and multiparty coalitions must there- 709 fore be built in order to sanction a policy change. As fragmentation increases, political institutions thus tend to provide greater opportunities for blame avoidance. Control Variables. I include variables to control for two alternative explanations for the observed patterns of structural pension reform. The first, population aging, is a major source of pressure on old-age pension systems. Rising life expectancy and falling birthrates mean that higher pension costs must be financed by ever-smaller working generations, raising the specter of massive financial shortfalls in state social insurance programs. Demographic change thus has been central to what some observers call a looming “crisis” of the welfare state (Huber and Stephens 2001; World Bank 1994). Other research points to the forces of globalization as the greatest challenge to welfare state sustainability (e.g., Tanzi 2002). In this view, the integration of markets for goods and capital constrain governments’ ability to finance rising pension costs through payroll taxes or budget deficits, while weakening the bargaining power of immobile labor forces to defend or improve social benefits. To control for these pressures, I include the share of the population over age 65 in each country (Age 65), as well as two proxies for global economic pressures: trade exposure, measured as imports plus exports as a share of GDP (Trade) and gross private capital flows to each nation (Capital Flows). Similar policy models also may be transferred across nations from a common source, such as by international financial institutions (IFIs). International institutions have long been shown to lower the cost of acquiring knowledge about policy practice abroad and to provide direct financial support for reform (Collier and Messick 1975; Dolowitz and Marsh 1996, 345; 2000, 7; Finnemore 1993). In the area of old-age pensions, the World Bank has been at the forefront of active dissemination of the NDC and FDC reform models (Holzmann and Hinz 2005) and thus is a likely source for the transfer of both innovations. For some scholars, the principal instrument of policy transfer is through the implicit or explicit conditionality attached to development loans and assistance (e.g., Huber and Stephens 2000). In this view, as the value of World Bank development loans to a given country increases, the likelihood of adopting one or the other policy model should also increase. I therefore include a measure of the level of World Bank loans and credits as a share of GDP provided to each country in a given year (World Bank). Lastly, I include controls for the strength of democratic freedoms using the Freedom House index 710 (Democracy) and for the broader structure of political authority, particularly whether the country is a presidential (direct or indirect) or parliamentary system (Political System). Country wealth is measured as per capita gross domestic product (GDP per capita). Empirical Model. The data in this analysis are equivalent to grouped duration data, where observations of the dependent and independent variables are made over the interval of a year. In such cases, maximum-likelihood methods may be used to estimate the competing risks model (Beck, Katz, and Tucker 1998). Although a common method of estimating multiple events is the multinomial logit model, that estimator suffers the potentially important limitation of assuming independence among the risks under analysis. This assumption is equivalent to Arrow’s independence of irrelevant alternatives property, which requires that the ratio of the probabilities of choosing any two alternatives be independent of the attributes of any other alternative (Hausman and McFadden 1984, 1219). Where such an assumption is not justified, statistical estimates may be inconsistent and standard errors may be artificially small (Gordon 2002, 201). When is such dependence likely? Dependence among risks may be induced by unobserved characteristics of a decision process. As Gordon (2002) has shown, learning under uncertainty constitutes a potentially important source of stochastic dependence. Given that learning is an important but unobservable feature of diffusion processes, the possibility of dependence between the risks of adopting the NDC and FDC models is high. Accordingly, I employ a bivariate probit model, which allows unobserved features related to the two reform likelihoods to be correlated while estimating the nature and significance of that dependence (Box-Steffensmeier and Jones 2004, 180). Where the two likelihoods are jointly determined, the coefficient on the term that captures this correlation, rho (r), will be statistically significant and either positive or negative. If rho is zero, then the log likelihood for the bivariate probit is equal to the sum of the log likelihoods for the two independent probits (Greene 1990, 663). By contrast to selection settings, the bivariate probit that I employ is a recursive model, wherein one decision is not a precondition for the other (Maddala 1983, 124). To account for duration dependence, I include the natural log of time in each specification (Beck, Katz, and Tucker 1998; BoxSteffensmeier and Jones 2004) and employ robust (Huber-White) variance estimation with clustering by country to account for any possible heteroskedasticity and temporal dependence in the data. sarah m. brooks Results and Discussion Table 1 reports the results of the statistical analysis, while summary statistics are provided in the online appendix at http://journalofpolitics.org/articles.html. The analysis provides broad support for the hypotheses that diffusion effects are circumscribed both by features of the policy innovation itself and by characteristics of the potential adopter. Specifically, peer diffusion is a significant predictor of the adoption of the more costly FDC reform model, but cannot account for the spread of the less politically and financially costly NDC design. Moreover, while peer decisions promote the adoption of FDC reform among lowerincome nations, they do not do so among advanced industrial nations. Lastly, the analysis reveals systematic variations in the domestic political economy of NDC and FDC pension reform that are consistent with differences in the political and financial costs of innovation. The coefficient on the correlation term between the disturbances of the two equations, rho, is statistically different from zero and negative across the three specifications. This means that unmeasured factors associated with the adoption of one model make enactment of the other model less likely. There may be several explanations for this, including the effect of learning. To the extent that potential adopters of the FDC model begin to observe certain drawbacks associated with it, interest in the NDC alternative may increase. The observation of stochastic dependence between these risks, moreover, confirms the appropriateness of the bivariate probit as the estimator for this model. The empirical results discussed below for the NDC and FDC pension reform models take into account this link between the two estimated likelihoods. The three model specifications in Table 1 differ principally in their treatment of the main diffusion variable, peer adoption. The first specification does not control for potential sources of heterogeneity in diffusion effects across nations, or groups of nations, while the second and third probe these hypotheses. Comparing the three specifications, the analysis reveals a powerful effect of country characteristics in mediating the importance of diffusion effects. Indeed, the coefficient on peer adoption in the first model specification indicates that on average peer dynamics are not a significant predictor of FDC adoption. However, once country wealth is taken into account in specification 2, peer effects emerge as a powerful catalyst of FDC pension reform only among lower-income nations. This is evident in the interaction between when does diffusion matter? TABLE 1 711 Predicting the Likelihood of Adopting Notional or Funded-DC Pension Reform 1 Seemingly Unrelated Bivariate Probit NDC Peer Adoption FDC Peer Adoption NDC Peer Adoption* GDP per capita FDC Peer Adoption* GDP per capita NDC Peer Adoption* Post-Communist FDC Peer Adoption* Post-Communist FDC Peer Adoption* Latin America Parties Age 65 Trade Capital Flows World Bank Ln(Time) GDP per capita Political System Latin America Post-Communist Democracy Constant rho Number of Obs. Log pseudolikelihood Wald chi2 2 NDC FDC -.455* (.176) — — NDC -.505* (.174) — 3 FDC — — — — — .134 (.200) — — — — .200* (.075) .276* (.138) -.022* (.008) .008 (.009) -.324* (.147) 12.126* (3.120) -.039 (.044) .054 (.340) 1.887 (1.486) 2.019 (1.228) -.823 (.426) -37.891* (1.033) -.050 (.052) .119* (.039) -.0004 (.004) .003 (.003) -.046 (.036) .418 (.428) .064* (.029) -.173 (.130) 1.519* (.547) .703 (.573) .041 (.130) -5.199* (1.277) -.935* (.088) 942 -99.796 237.16 .204* (.084) .297* (.136) -.022* (.009) .008 (.010) -.335* (.141) 12.701* (3.809) -.023 (.028) .066 (.356) 1.943 (1.328) 1.873 (1.054) -.742 (.481) -39.978* (11.322) — — .003 (.007) — — — — -.004* (.001) — — — — — — *= p < .05 Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. — — — -.033 (.050) .107* (.037) .001 (.003) -.0004 (.003) -.042 (.034) .195 (.294) .009 (.020) -.196 (.130) 1.307* (.505) .499 (.524) -.009 (.118) -4.069* (.873) -.934* (.079) 942 -104.024 72.78 -.524* (.262) — FDC -.053 (.035) — .007 (.016) — .195* (.078) .281* (.130) -.021* (.008) .008 (.009) -.328* (.148) 11.896* (3.206) -.024 (.028) .054 (.339) 2.085 (1.305) 2.148* (1.067) -.773 (.507) -37.614* (1.010) NDC .025 (.015) — .117* (.047) .061* (.030) -.047 (.054) .112* (.0377) -.001 (.004) .003 (.003) -.050 (.040) .453 (.422) .016 (.022) -.163 (.136) .703 (.525) -.451 (.743) .042 (.129) -4.169* (1.008) -.934* (.078) 942 -99.826 111.26 712 peer adoption and GDP per capita, which suggests that for a Latin American country whose per capita income is one-half a standard deviation below the mean, an increase from one to three peer adoptions raises the likelihood of adopting an FDC pension reform by 52%.1 For a similar nation at the average per capita income, however, an equivalent rise in peer adoptions reduces the likelihood of enacting FDC pension reform by 17%. More affluent countries that are inclined to adopt the FDC model thus may do so without waiting to gather information from peers, while those wealthy nations that are more resistant to pension privatization will be unmoved either by new information from peers or by the prospective competitive payoffs of reform. While diffusion effects are positive among the less affluent nations, it is not the poorest countries that are most likely to privatize. For instance, where no peers have privatized, a Latin American country with the average per capita income is more than two times more likely to adopt the FDC model than a country with a per capita income that is one-half a standard deviation below the mean, all else being equal. This result is understandable considering the significant financial and regulatory infrastructure that funded pension systems require in order to function. Moreover, it is the middle-income nations, rather than the poorest, that compete most fiercely to attract foreign investment through policy signals, while the lowestincome nations may be more likely to attend first to their more basic infrastructure needs. The interaction between peer adoption and the group dummy variables in the third specification probes whether diffusion effects vary across different peer groups. The interactions show that diffusion effects lend powerful impulse to the adoption of the FDC model among postcommunist and Latin American nations, with the former revealing strongest diffusion effects. Among postcommunist countries, the interaction in specification 3 implies that the likelihood of adopting the FDC model if three peer countries have already done so is three times greater than if only one peer has enacted this reform, all else being equal. In Latin America, by contrast, diffusion plays a less powerful role in this trend, as an increase from one to three peer adoptions in the region raises the likelihood of enacting the FDC model by 31%, all else being equal. Turning to the advanced industrial 1 Predicted probabilities are estimated using the bivariate normal cumulative density function. I am grateful to Luke Keel for providing the R code for the predicted probabilities. sarah m. brooks nations, while broad evidence of policy transfer has been found among affluent nations in previous research (e.g., Dolowitz and Marsh 2000; Mintrom and Vergari 1998) the statistical analysis reveals that among OECD member nations, pension reform decisions are not swayed significantly by the proportion of peer countries that have enacted the innovation. Rather, it is likely that other kinds of information, such as indicators of the innovation’s performance, are used in those learning processes. In the case of the less-costly NDC model, diffusion cannot explain the rapid spread of this innovation in the last decade. Rather, the coefficient on peer adoption is negative and significant across the three model specifications. There are several possible interpretations of this result. One is that government actors may receive discouraging information about the NDC model from their peers and thus eschew this reform. This is less likely, however, given the novelty of the NDC model and the long time horizon that is required for this pension reform to take effect. Alternatively, this result may derive from the broad geographic dispersion of NDC adoptions—from Northern Europe and the Baltics to Latin America. Most adoptions of this reform to date thus have not followed closely upon similar decisions by peer nations, but rather are likely to have drawn upon the policy models and cues from more distant countries. Also, since international competition is likely to be a less salient component of this decision, given the reform’s opacity, government actors may have less incentive to emulate their economic peers in this instance. Instead, highly technical policy models such as the NDC pension reform may travel across regions through global transnational policy networks. This was the case in Brazil, where an an NDC-style pension reform was adopted in 1999. As the first (and so far, only) Latin American country to have adopted this innovation, Brazilian technocrats learned about the NDC design directly from Swedish technocrats participating in a World Bank-sponsored pension reform conference at Harvard University (Pinheiro 2004). In the case of Brazil, then, direct contact among technocrats from distant and disparate nations supplanted peer dynamics as a mechanism of policy transfer. Further analysis of how these technocratic networks and “policy entrepreneurs” (Mintrom 1997) disseminate more opaque and technical innovations thus may be warranted for the case of NDC pension reform. Turning to the domestic political variables, the analysis reveals stark contrasts in the institutional correlates of NDC and FDC pension reform. First, the blame avoidance hypothesis is supported in the case of when does diffusion matter? the NDC pension reform, as this innovation is more likely to be adopted where greater legislative fragmentation muddies the lines of political accountability. This is not the case for FDC pension reform, however, where the political parties variable is negative but insignificant across model specifications. Contrary to the conventional view, therefore, the political correlates pension privatization may not be structurally given as they appear to be in the NDC case. Future research may productively focus on delineating the more contingent features of the political process that allow reformers to diminish the costs of building public support for this high-profile, but loss-imposing reform. For both the NDC and FDC pension reforms, controls for democratic freedom and the structure of the political system are not significant predictors of the likelihood of adoption. Demographic pressures, however, do reveal clear and consistent effects across model specifications. As the population over age 65 rises, the likelihood of adopting both structural pension reform models increases. This effect is stronger in the case of the notional-DC pension reform, both in substantive and statistical terms. This result makes sense considering the significant financial cost associated with the transition to a funded-DC pension system, which may be prohibitive in countries with large elderly populations. For governments struggling with very high pension costs, the less financially onerous NDC model thus may be most attractive as an option for decreasing long-term government pension liabilities. The empirical analysis does not reveal a significant role for financial coercion by the World Bank. Nor are exposure to trade and capital flows significant predictors of the likelihood of FDC pension reform. Contrary to conventional theories, the NDC model is more likely to be adopted by governments that are less exposed to global trade flows, while adoption of this model declines as World Bank loans increase as a share of GDP. For this innovation, as the case of Brazil suggested above, the World Bank may have still performed a significant role in the diffusion process, although through the use of nonfinancial means. Conclusion Diffusion research has made important gains in identifying mechanisms such as information provision and competition, through which policy choices made in disparate locations may be causally linked. Yet, this literature has devoted less attention to identifying when and where such dynamics actually matter in the 713 domestic process of policy innovation. This study has addressed these questions by arguing first that characteristics of an innovation itself, namely the “sunk” or irrecoverable political and financial costs of adoption, mediate the importance of diffusion forces in policy choice, and second, that country characteristics associated with the level of economic development further shape the importance of these mechanisms in domestic politics. On the basis of this argument I posited two hypotheses to explain the adoption of the competing notional and funded models of structural pension reform. First, adoption of the funded definedcontribution (FDC) pension reform, which is costly to adopt and difficult to reverse, should be swayed more powerfully by similar reform decisions in peer countries; the adoption of the more easily enacted and reversible NDC model, by contrast, should not be governed systematically by peer effects. Second, I hypothesized that diffusion effects in general should be more powerful in developing countries than among the advanced industrial nations. These expectations were largely borne out in the analysis, as the likelihood of adopting the FDC pension reform model revealed powerful peer diffusion effects among middle-income countries, and particularly among postcommunist nations, but there was no systematic effect of peer adoption among the more affluent OECD member nations. For the notional defined-contribution (NDC) pension reform model, which is both less costly to enact and more easily reversed, peer decisions cannot explain the rapid early diffusion of this innovation. Where the NDC reform has been enacted, it is thus likely to have been swayed more powerfully by domestic considerations, such as the appeal of the policy as a means to control pension costs, rather than by cues from peer nations or the prospects of ancillary benefits such as international praise or investment. Overall, these findings point to important limits on the scope of policy decisions over which diffusion forces may be relevant. Whereas diffusion research often treats different policy innovations as being essentially equivalent in theoretical terms, this study suggests that such a view may not be warranted. Instead, diffusion research may productively consider how the features of a policy innovation mediate both the importance of information from abroad and concerns about competitive status in domestic political processes. This research should also pay close attention to the question of where internationally transmitted information and competitive concerns are likely to be decisive in the political process, and thus to the ways in which country characteristics mediate the importance of those effects in domestic politics. 714 sarah m. brooks Acknowledgments Earlier versions of this paper were presented at the 2004 annual meeting of the American Political Science Association and at the Joint Sessions of the European Consortium for Political Research Nicosia, Cyprus. I am very grateful for comments and suggestions along the way from Nancy Brune, David Darmofal, Fabrizio Gilardi, Torben Iversen, Marcus Kurtz, Covadonga Meseguer, and Anthony Mughan and for methodological advice from Janet Box-Steffensmeier and Luke Keele. Finally, I am grateful to Kent Weaver for many insights into the politics of notional definedcontribution pension reform. All errors remain my own. Manuscript submitted 9 September 2005 Manuscript accepted for publication 20 January 2007 References Abel, Andrew, Avinash Dixit, Janice Eberly, and Robert Pindyck. 1996. “Options, the Value of Capital and Investment.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 111 (3): 753–77. Arrow, Kenneth, and Anthony Fisher. 1974. “Environmental Preservation, Uncertainty, and Irreversibility.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 88 (2): 312–19. Anselin, Luc. 1988. Spatial Econometrics: Methods and Models. New York: Springer. Bartolini, Leonardo, and Allan Drazen. 1997. “Capital-Account Liberalization as a Signal.” The American Economic Review 87 (1): 138–54. Beck, Nathaniel, Jonathan N. Katz, and Richard Tucker. 1998. “Taking Time Seriously: Time-Series-Cross-Section Analysis with a Binary Dependent Variable.” American Journal of Political Science 42 (2): 1260–88. Becker, Gary S. 1996. “A Social Security Lesson from Argentina.” Business Week October: 9. Bennett, Colin J. 1997. “Understanding Ripple Effects: The CrossNational Adoption of Policy Instruments for Bureaucratic Accountability.” Governance 10 (3): 213–33. Bernanke, Ben. 1983. “Irreversibility, Uncertainty, and Cyclical Investment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 98 (1): 85–106. Berry, Frances Stokes, and William Berry. 1992. “Tax Innovation in the States: Capitalizing on Political Opportunity.” American Journal of Political Science 36 (3): 715–42. Box-Steffensmeier, Janet M., and Bradford Jones. 2004. Event History Modeling: A Guide for Social Scientists. New York: Cambridge University Press. Braun, Dietmar, and Fabrizio Gilardi. 2006. “Taking ‘Galton’s Problem’ Seriously: Towards a Theory of Policy Diffusion.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 18 (3): 298–322. Brooks, Sarah, and R. Kent Weaver. 2006. “Lashed to the Mast: The Politics of NDC Pension Reform.” In Pension Reform: Issues and Prospects for Non-Financial Defined Contribution (NDC) Schemes, ed. Robert Holzmann and Edward Palmer. Washington: The World Bank, pp. 345–85. Brune, Nancy E., and Alexandra Guisinger. 2006. “Myth or Reality? The Diffusion of Financial Liberalization in Emerging Economies.” Presented at the European Consortium of Political Research, Nicosia, Cyprus. Collier, David, and Richard Messick. 1975. “Prerequisites versus Diffusion: Testing Alternative Explanations of Social Security Adoption.” The American Political Science Review 69 (4): 1299– 315. Diamond, Peter, and Salvador Valdés-Prieto. 1994. “Social Security Reforms.” In The Chilean Economy: Policy Lessons and Challenges, ed. Barry Bosworth, Rudiger Dornbusch, and Raul Laban. Washington: Brookings Institution, pp. 257–320. Dolowitz, David. 1997. “British Employment Policy in the 1980s: Learning from the American Experience.” Governance 10 (1): 23–42. Dolowitz, David, and David Marsh. 1996. “Who Learns What from Whom? A Review of the Policy Transfer Literature.” Political Studies 44 (2): 343–57. Dolowitz, David, and David Marsh. 2000. “Learning from Abroad: The Role of Policy Transfer in Contemporary Policy-Making.” Governance 13 (1): 5–24. The Economist. 1995. “Save, Amigo, Save.” December. S15. Edwards, Sebastian. 1996. “The Chilean Pension Reform: A Pioneering Program.” NBER Working Paper No. W5811. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Fearon, James. 1997. “Signaling Foreign Policy Interests: Tying Hands versus Sinking Costs.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 41 (1): 68–90. Finnemore, Martha. 1993. “International Organizations as Teachers of Norms: The United Nations Educational, Scientific, and Cultural Organization and Science Policy.” International Organization 47 (4): 565–97. Geroski, Paul A. 2000. “Models of Technology Diffusion.” Research Policy 29 (4–5): 603–25. Gordon, Sanford. 2002. “Stochastic Dependence in Competing Risks.” American Journal of Political Science 46 (1): 200–17. Gray, Virginia. 1973. “Innovation in the States: A Diffusion Study.” American Political Science Review 67 (4): 1174–85. Greene, William H. 1990. Econometric Analysis. 2nd ed. New York: Macmillan Publishing. Hausman, Jerry, and Daniel McFadden. 1984. “Specification Tests for the Multinomial Logit Model.” Econometrica 52 (5): 1219– 40. Heclo, Hugh. 1974. Modern Social Politics in Britain and Sweden: From Relief to Income Maintenance. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Holzmann, Robert, and Richard Hinz. 2005. Old Age Income Support in the 21st Century. Washington: The World Bank. Huber, Evelyne, and John Stephens. 2000. “The Political Economy of Pension Reform: Latin America in Comparative Perspective.” United Nations Research Institute for Social Development Occasional Paper 7. Geneva: United Nations. Huber, Evelyne, and John Stephens. 2001. Development and Crisis of the Welfare State: Parties and Policies in Global Markets. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. James, Estelle. 1998. “The Political Economy of Social Security Reform: A Cross-Country Review.” Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics 69 (4): 451–82. Jordana, Jacint, and David Levi-Faur. 2005. “The Diffusion of Regulatory Capitalism in Latin America: Sectoral and National Channels in the Making of a New Order.” The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 598 (1): 102–24. when does diffusion matter? Keohane, Robert O., and Joseph Nye. 2000. “Globalization: What’s New? What’s Not? (And So What?)” Foreign Policy 118 (1): 104–19. Kruse, Agneta. 2006. “Discussion of ‘Lashed to the Mast? The Politics of NDC Pension Reform’ ” In Pension Reform: Issues and Prospects for Non-Financial Defined Contribution (NDC) Schemes, ed. Robert Holzmann and Edward Palmer. Washington: The World Bank, pp. 389–93. Laakso, Markku, and Rein Taagepera. 1979. “Effective Number of Parties: A Measure with Application to West Europe.” Comparative Political Studies 12(1): 3–27. Maddala, G. S. 1983. Limited Dependent and Qualitative Variables in Econometrics. Econometric Society Monographs, 3. New York: Cambridge University Press. Martin, Lisa L. 1993. “Credibility, Costs, and Institutions: Cooperation on Economic Sanctions.” World Politics 45 (3): 406–32. Mesa-Lago, Carmelo, and Katharina Müller. 2002. “The Politics of Pension Reform in Latin America.” Journal of Latin American Studies 34 (3): 687–715. Meseguer, Covadonga. 2004. “What Role for Learning? The Diffusion of Privatisation in OECD and Latin American Countries.” Journal of Public Policy 24 (3): 299–325. Mintrom, Michael. 1997. “Policy Entrepreneurs and the Diffusion of Innovation.” American Journal of Political Science 41 (3): 738–71. Mintrom, Michael, and Sandra Vergari. 1998. “Policy Networks and Innovation Diffusion: The Case of State Education Reforms.” Journal of Politics 60 (1): 126–48. Müller, Katharina. 1999. The Political Economy of Pension Reform in Central-Eastern Europe. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. Myles, John, and Paul Pierson. 2001. “The Comparative Political Economy of Pension Reform.” In The New Politics of the Welfare State, ed. Paul Pierson. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 305–33. Palmer, Edward. 2002. “Is Swedish Pension Reform the Right Medicine for Aging Europe?” Journal of Aging and Social Policy 14 (1): 35–52. Pierson, Paul. 1994. Dismantling the Welfare State: Reagan, Thatcher and the Politics of Retrenchment. New York: Cambridge University Press. Pierson, Paul. 2001. “Coping with Permanent Austerity.” In The New Politics of the Welfare State, ed. Paul Pierson. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 410–56. Pierson, Paul, and R. Kent Weaver. 1993. “Imposing Losses in Pension Policy.” In Do Institutions Matter? Government Capabilities in the United States and Abroad, ed. R. Kent Weaver and Bert A. Rockman. Washington: The Brookings Institution, pp. 110–50. 715 Pindyck, Robert. 1991. “Irreversibility, Uncertainty, and Investment.” Journal of Economic Literature 29 (3): 1110–48. Pinheiro, Vinícius. 2004. “The Politics of Social Security Reform in Brazil.” In Learning from Foreign Models in Latin American Policy Reform, ed. Kurt Weyland. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, pp. 110–38. Rodrik, Dani. 1989. “Promises, Promises: Credible Policy Reform via Signaling.” Economic Journal 9 (397): 756–72. Rogers, Everett. 1995. Diffusion of Innovations. 4th ed. New York: Free Press. Rose-Ackerman, Susan. 1980. “Risk Taking and Reelection: Does Federalism Promote Innovation?” Journal of Legal Studies 9 (3): 593–616. Schelling, Thomas C. 1966. Arms and Influence. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Schulthess, Walter. 1998. Author interview with former Secretary of Social Security in Argentina. Buenos Aires, Argentina. Simmons, Beth, and Zachary Elkins. 2004. “The Globalization of Liberalization: Policy Diffusion in the International Political Economy.” American Political Science Review 98 (1): 171–89. Simon, Herbert. 1976. Administrative Behavior: A Study of Decision-making Processes in Administrative Organizations. New York: Free Press. Sundén, Annika. 2006. “How Much Do People Need to Know about Their Pensions and What Do They Know?” In Pension Reform: Issues and Prospects for Non-Financial Defined Contribution (NDC) Schemes, ed. Robert Holzmann and Edward Palmer. Washington: The World Bank, pp. 325–44. Tanzi, Vito. 2002. “Globalization and the Future of Social Protection.” Scottish Journal of Political Economy 49 (1): 116–27. Walker, Jack L. 1969. “The Diffusion of Innovations Among the American States.” American Political Science Review 63 (3): 880–99. Weaver, R. Kent. 1986. “The Politics of Blame Avoidance.” Journal of Public Policy 6 (4): 371–98. Weyland, Kurt. 2005. “Theories of Policy Diffusion: Lessons from Latin American Pension Reform.” World Politics 57 (2): 262–95. World Bank. 1994. Averting the Old Age Crisis: Policies to Protect the Old and Promote Growth. Washington: The World Bank. Sarah M. Brooks is assistant professor of political science, The Ohio State University, Columbus, OH 43210-1373.