+(,121/,1( Citation: 29 Antitrust 54 2014-2015 Content downloaded/printed from HeinOnline (http://heinonline.org) Fri Nov 27 15:45:27 2015 -- Your use of this HeinOnline PDF indicates your acceptance of HeinOnline's Terms and Conditions of the license agreement available at http://heinonline.org/HOL/License -- The search text of this PDF is generated from uncorrected OCR text. -- To obtain permission to use this article beyond the scope of your HeinOnline license, please use: https://www.copyright.com/ccc/basicSearch.do? &operation=go&searchType=0 &lastSearch=simple&all=on&titleOrStdNo=0162-7996 C O V E R S T O R I E S Qihoo versus Tencent: Roadmap or Anomaly? B Y N AT E B U S H , L I N I N G S H A N , A N D N I N G Q I AO M EDIA COVERAGE OF CHINESE enforcement of the Antimonopoly Law (AML) often spotlights administrative investigations involving multinational companies or Chinese state-owned enterprises (SOEs).1 The National Development and Reform Commission (NDRC) recently fined Qualcomm RMB6.088 billion (approximately US$975 million)—the largest penalty imposed to date under the AML—for abuse of dominance, while the NDRC and the State Administration of Industry and Commerce (SAIC) have also trumpeted probes targeting state-owned telecommunications companies and utilities. But when China’s Supreme People’s Court (SPC) issued its first decision under the AML on October 8, 2014, it faced a showdown between two homegrown private-sector Internet giants: Tencent and Qihoo.2 The SPC upheld the March 2013 decision by the Guangdong Higher People’s Court rejecting Qihoo’s claims that Tencent had violated the AML rules against abuse of dominance by rendering its “QQ” instant messaging (IM) service incompatible with Qihoo’s security software and by bundling new application manager software with IM software upgrades. The SPC articulated a flexible approach to abuse of dominance claims, focusing on actual market dynamics rather than market shares in gauging dominance and on the actual competitive effects rather than the form of the challenged conduct in defining abuse. But while this outcome may be welcomed by multinationals fearing future abuse of dominance claims in China, it remains to be seen how far the SPC’s effects-based approach will extend to future investigations and litigation. China’s Fast and Fractious Internet Sector China’s Internet sector offers a unique laboratory for observing the application of the AMLs’ rules against abuse of dominance in disputes between large private-sector Chinese companies. China’s online ecosystem evolved as entrepreNate Bush is a partner in the Singapore and Beijing offices of O’Melveny & Myers LLP. Lining Shan and Ning Qiao are senior legal consultants with the firm. 5 4 · A N T I T R U S T neurs adapted foreign business models and devised innovative services catering to China’s 632 million Internet users. While state-owned enterprises (SOEs) and multinationals tower over many other industries in China, privately owned domestic companies prevail in the Internet space. This is no accident. Beyond the inherent linguistic and cultural barriers facing non-Chinese Internet firms, the “Great Firewall” of governmental surveillance, censorship, and access restrictions impairs foreign companies’ efforts to court Chinese users from offshore, while restrictions on direct foreign ownership in numerous online and brick-and-mortar services restrain many foreign firms from operating directly onshore. But while China’s government tightly regulates Internet activity for consumer protection and “public security” reasons, online services are neither a focal point for industrial policy (such as solar cells, semiconductors, smartphones, and steel) nor a bastion of SOE’s (such as telecommunications or energy). In the absence of state-backed national champions or foreign giants, niche start-ups could mature into colossal private companies. Many of China’s Internet titans now offer diverse services from platforms built around core products, such as Baidu’s search engine, Alibaba’s online retailing site, and Sina’s Weibo microblogging site. Tencent’s flagship product is “QQ,” its instant messaging (IM) service, but it offers a palette of social media, gaming, entertainment, search, and other services alongside QQ. Qihoo is best known for offering a range of security software applications under its “360” brand, but it also offers various other applications. Like many other Internet companies, Tencent and Qihoo offer basic services for free, while earning revenue from premium services and advertising. Qihoo’s Annual Report summarizes competition at both the “application” and “platform’ level: “We compete in the Internet security market with other companies providing anti-virus software. . . . We also compete with PRC-based Internet companies that, like us, build Internet platforms to offer value-added services and online advertising services.” Qihoo labels Tencent its “primary competitor in this market.” 3 China’s Internet titans increasingly clash, vying for user attention and advertiser funds by upgrading existing services, developing and acquiring new products, and raising their profiles through marketing stunts and public feuds. The Ministry of Industry and Information Technology (MIIT) and other authorities oversee their commercial practices, as illustrated by the SAIC’s probe of Alibaba’s alleged sale of counterfeit goods in violation of the Anti-Unfair Competition Law (AUCL).4 Brawls between Internet companies also reach the courts. In June 2014, the Beijing First Intermediate People’s Court announced that 33 of its 110 AUCL cases since 2010 involved disputes between Internet companies, warning that victims often became offenders through retaliation.5 This announcement followed rulings that Baidu violated the AUCL by disseminating rumors that Qihoo had leaked customer passwords, while Qihoo also violated the AUCL by releasing security software that interfered with Baidu’s search engine. The “3Q War” The first AML case to reach the SPC stemmed from similar frictions between Qihoo and Tencent, which finally ignited in an incident known as the “3Q War” or “Choose One from Two.” In September 2010, Qihoo announced that its new “360 Privacy Protector” application had discovered that “certain instant messaging software” accessed users’ personal data without permission. The culprit went unnamed, but a screenshot of Tencent’s QQ logo accompanied the report. Tencent denied the allegations, and joined four other Internet companies in a public declaration denouncing Qihoo for unfair commercial conduct, requesting regulators to investigate Qihoo and adopt new rules for Internet competition, and exhorting other companies to refuse to cooperate with Qihoo.6 On October 29, 2010, Qihoo released “Koukou Guard,” a new security application marketed as protecting QQ users’ personal data from unauthorized access by Tencent.7 Tencent responded that Koukou Guard disrupted many features of QQ, and threatened legal action against Qihoo.8 Then Tencent resorted to self-help. On November 3, 2010, Tencent announced that its QQ IM service would no longer operate on computers in which Qihoo “Koukou Guard” had been installed.9 Tencent modified its online IM application so QQ users were unable to utilize QQ accounts without first removing Qihoo applications from their devices. This deliberate non-interoperability lasted just one day. The MIIT and other agencies jointly ordered Tencent to restore interoperability and Qihoo to withdraw Koukou Guard (which they promptly did). On November 21, 2010, MIIT publicly censured both Tencent and Qihoo for their conduct, and ordered both companies to apologize to the public (which they promptly did).10 This episode spurred the MIIT to issue new rules against unfair commercial practices in the Internet sector with the stated objectives of “regulating the order of the Internet information service market” and “protecting the interests of service providers and users.” 11 These measures prohibited various alleged tactics of Tencent and Qihoo, including “fabricating or disseminating false facts” or “disparaging the services” of other Internet companies, “maliciously causing incompatibility” with other Internet companies’ products, “deceiving, misleading or forcing users to use or not to use” other Internet companies’ products, and “maliciously modifying or deceiving, misleading or forcing users into modifying” other Internet companies’ products.12 The “3Q War” also spawned three lawsuits between Tencent and Qihoo. Tencent prevailed in two separate actions against Qihoo for spreading false information damaging Tencent’s commercial reputation in violation of the AUCL in connection with the “360 Privacy Protector” and “Koukou Guard” programs, with the SPC eventually confirming a damages award of RMB5 million against Qihoo in February 2014.13 Qihoo pursued Tencent under the AML. In November 2011, Qihoo filed a lawsuit against Tencent before the Higher People’s Court of Guangdong Province, seeking RMB 150 million (approximately US$24 million) in damages alleging that Tencent had abused its dominance of the IM market in violation of the AML by (1) rendering its IM services incompatible with Qihoo’s security software and (2) bundling IM service upgrades with Tencent’s own security software. The court of first instance (the trial court) dismissed Qihoo’s claims in March 2013 on grounds that Qihoo failed to define the relevant market properly and to submit evidence “sufficient to prove that [Tencent] has a monopoly position in the relevant product market.” Qihoo appealed to the SPC. The SPC’s published opinion identified five key questions to be resolved: (1) how to define the relevant market; (2) whether Tencent possessed a dominant market position; (3) whether Tencent’s conduct constituted abuse; (4) whether the trial court committed procedural errors; and (5) whether Tencent was liable for any resulting damages. Market Definition A Tool, Not a Necessity. The SPC framed market definition as an analytical tool rather than a necessary step in assessing abuse of dominance under the AML. Qihoo complained that the trial court failed to define the relevant product market explicitly, but the SPC explained that “even without a clear definition of relevant market, it is possible to assess the market position of the [defendant] and the possible impact of the alleged monopolistic practices upon the market by using direct evidence of the elimination or restriction of competition.” This approach dovetails with U.S. precedents where direct evidence of anticompetitive effects avoided the need for elaborate market definition under the Sherman Act.14 At any rate, the SPC viewed the trial court’s factual findings as effectively defining the relevant product market. In the same vein, the SPC recalibrated a basic tool of market definition to measure competition among free online services. The trial court had ostensibly defined the relevant product market as encompassing the smallest possible set of discrete goods and services such that a hypothetical monopS P R I N G 2 0 1 5 · 5 5 C O V E R olist could profitably implement a “small but significant and non-transitory increase in price” (SSNIP). The SPC found this conventional SSNIP test inappropriate in markets for free IM and security software services since any price would represent an infinite increase. The SPC suggested that other hypothetical monopolist methodologies focused on quality and consumer experience (such as a “small but significant and non-transitory decrease in quality” test) would be more appropriate, even though they entailed greater reliance on qualitative rather than quantitative analyses. The SPC’s reformulation of the hypothetical monopolist test to address the nuances of free online services by focusing on functionality and quality rather than price resonates with the European Commission’s approach to market definition in Microsoft/ Skype and the U.S. antitrust agencies’ 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines.15 Product Market Definition: Apps or Platforms? The bulk of the SPC’s analysis was devoted to defining the relevant product market for Tencent’s IM services. (Neither the trial court nor the SPC engaged in any detailed discussion of the security software market in which Qihoo allegedly suffered injuries.) The record included written reports and testimony from economists engaged by each party, statistics and industry analyses published by third parties, and documentation of the functionality of various online services. Upon reviewing the trial record and additional evidence submitted by the parties on appeal, the SPC defined the relevant market to include all instant messaging services (including any combination of text, video, and voice messaging). The SPC found the trial court erred by including all social networking site and microblogging services (as opposed to their discrete instant messaging functions). The SPC rebuffed Qihoo’s efforts to narrow the relevant market to include only integrated instant messaging services combining text, voice, and video functions, and likewise rebuffed Tencent’s efforts to broaden the relevant market to include all email and SMS services. The SPC also rejected Tencent’s proposal to define the relevant market expansively to reflect the competition among “Internet platforms” to attract users and advertisers. Tencent suggested that defining markets based on discrete applications (such as search, IM, or security) masked the important competitive constraints from rival Internet platforms vying for the same users’ attention and the same advertising funds by offering different suites of services. Even though Qihoo’s own SEC filings highlight competition among Internet platforms, Qihoo dismissed the notion of an “application platform” as a “broad commercial concept that cannot constitute a relevant market under the AML.” The trial court recognized that the competition between Internet companies for users and advertisers was the actual “underlying reason” for the “3Q War,” but emphasized demand-side substitutability in defining relevant product markets. The SPC similarly acknowledged “competition in Internet sector to some extent presents features of the com5 6 · A N T I T R U S T S T O R I E S petition among platforms,” and that “Internet operators compete with each other by attracting users’ attention and soliciting advertisers in an effort to obtain profit from advertising business and value-added services.” However, the SPC considered the key question to be whether the competitive constraint from rival Internet platforms across diverse applications exceeds the pressure from competing suppliers of the same type of application. The SPC reasoned that consumers primarily select applications rather than platforms, and platforms offering different types of applications (such as IM versus search) are not substitutable. The SPC also noted that Qihoo’s core contention was that Tencent sought to leverage its dominance in IM services into the security software market, so defining a relevant market for “Internet platforms” would understate Tencent’s own market power. The SPC suggested that platform competition would be considered “in a more proper way” when evaluating the market position and market power of the parties rather than in defining the relevant product market. In its later discussion of dominance, the SPC observed that platform competition “constrained” Tencent’s ability to “control quality,” as IM service providers must “keep improving service quality and developing new services” in order to attract users for free services and profit from advertising and premium services. The SPC also pointed to the integration of IM with other applications such as search, dating, online shopping, gaming, micro-blogging, or music as evidence of innovation by competitors within the IM product market, and repeatedly suggested that IM search providers face competitive constraints from products “outside the relevant market.” The SPC effectively treated the competition among Internet platforms as increasing the competitive constraints from threat of new entry into discrete application markets by established platforms seeking to diversify their offerings. Even though platform rivalry animated the animosity between Tencent and Qihoo, the SPC assessed Qihoo’s claims in terms of separate IM and security software markets. Geographic Market: Within the Great Firewall. The SPC faulted the trial court’s finding of a global market, siding with Qihoo in defining the geographic market as China. The SPC explained that the geographic market should be defined by determining whether competitors outside a proposed market would “pose effective competition constraint to the hypothetical monopolist in the target territory if there is any change in such competition factor as price and quality.” Applying these principles, the SPC emphasized evidence that the “vast majority” of Chinese IM users choose domestic services for linguistic, commercial, and social reasons, with domestic IM services accounting for over 97 percent of all Chinese users’ IM activity. The trial court had erred by mistaking the possibilities that some Chinese customers might use foreign IM services or that some foreign customers might use Chinese IM services as demonstrating a competitive constraint from foreign IM service providers. It also erred in overlooking numerous regulatory barriers to entry for foreign investors, includ- ing measures limiting foreign investment to minority stakes in joint ventures. Qihoo had observed that the “quite different political and social environment” in China as well as the “very complex” legal framework presented barriers to entry for foreign suppliers, but the SPC did not discuss potential social or political barriers. (Unsurprisingly, neither the parties nor the court discussed the effect of censorship protocols on the speed and reliability of access to foreign IM services by consumers within China.) Dominance The finding that Qihoo had failed to prove that Tencent possessed a dominant market position in the Chinese IM market was among the most controversial elements of the trial court’s original decision. Critics pointed to frequent reports of astronomical market shares from third-party sources and from Tencent itself. The SPC nevertheless affirmed, outlining a flexible approach to gauging dominance based on direct evidence of the actual competitive dynamics of the relevant market. Article 17 of the AML defines a “dominant market position” as the position of business operators that are “able to control price or quantity of products or other transaction terms in the relevant market or to block or affect the entry of other business operators.” Dominance may be established through a multi-factor analysis of market structures and competitive dynamics under Article 18 of the AML. Article 19 establishes rebuttable presumptions of dominance based solely on market share; firms with market shares exceeding 50 percent may be presumed dominant. The plaintiff bears the burden of proving that the defendant possesses a dominant position in the relevant market.16 Critically, the SPC eschewed reliance on high market shares as evidence of dominance. The SPC stressed that the market-share based presumptions of dominance are rebuttable. “In general, the higher the market share and the longer the period of time during which it is held, the more likely it is to be a preliminary indication of dominance; however market share is simply one rough and potentially misleading index in determining dominant market position.” The SPC cautioned that high market shares could be particularly misleading in the Internet sector given the fluid boundaries of discrete product markets and dynamic pace of innovation. Curiously, the SPC also warned against inferring dominance from high market shares resulting from a firm’s “greater market efficiency or provision of superior products” (even though such strengths are commonly the foundation of market power) or in circumstances where “products outside the relevant market create relatively strong competitive constraints” (even though such observations may raise questions of market definition or the treatment of likely entrants as market participants). The SPC then separately addressed each indicia of dominance listed in Article 18 of the AML, starting with “market shares” and “conditions of competition” under Article 18(1). The finding that Qihoo had failed to prove that Tencent possessed a dominant mar ket position in the Chinese IM mar ket was among the most controver sial elements of the trial cour t’s original decision. The SPC noted evidence that Tencent’s market share exceeded 80 percent in both desktop and mobile IM. Nevertheless, the SPC found that competition in the Chinese IM market was “vigorous” and “innovative,” emphasizing the availability of numerous competing IM services and the frequency of product upgrades and introduction of new features. With respect to the “ability to control” price, quality, or other conditions in the IM market under Article 18(2), the SPC found that the prevalence of business models offering free core services eliminated the possibility of controlling “price,” while the numerous competitors maintained pressure to improve the quality and features of these free services. The SPC stressed evidence that Chinese consumers frequently switch IM services and concurrently utilize multiple services. With respect to “financial and technical capabilities” under Article 18(3), the SPC found that Tencent faced formidable competitors with comparable financial and technological resources, including Alibaba, Baidu, Microsoft, and China Mobile. In discussing the “extent of reliance” by consumers on Tencent under Article 18(4), the SPC found that Tencent’s product is not indispensable for any consumers, as numerous alternatives are available and switching IM services is easy. Qihoo maintained that Tencent derives substantial market power from its enormous established user base through network effects, as the opportunity to communicate with multitudes of current QQ users enhanced the value of the QQ service to individual users and deterred switching to rivals with smaller networks. The SPC rejected the factual premises of this argument, observing that “it is completely possible that only a few or a handful of contacts” would be involved in the migration to another IM service, and dismissed the possibility that a user would consider all of its contacts to be important as “highly doubtful.” Instead, the SPC again emphasized evidence that over 90 percent of Chinese IM users concurrently use more than two types of instant messaging services, so that “users may gradually create highly overlapped social networks based on different instant messaging services,” so that “the influence caused by network effects and customer retention are greatly mitigated.” The SPC also viewed the history of MSN’s plunge from its initial position as global IM market leader to single-digit market shares as demonstrating the weakness of network effects in the IM sector. With respect to “barriers to entry” under Article 18(5), the SPC cited the history of entry by new IM services as demonS P R I N G 2 0 1 5 · 5 7 C O V E R strating the absence of technical and regulatory barriers, dismissing concerns that the low market shares of recent entrants reflected entry barriers. “Low market share does not necessarily mean weak market competition constraint. As long as it is possible to enter the market quickly and expand market share effectively, it is sufficient create an effective competitive constraint on the existing competitors.” Finally, the SPC considered Qihoo’s claim that Tencent’s dominance had been demonstrated by the absence of any material effect on the market shares of Tencent and its competitors in the IM market as a result of the 3Q War. The SPC rejected the factual premises of this argument, citing evidence that competing IM services saw substantial increases in users (although starting from relatively small market shares) in the period following the dispute. Based on these factual findings, the SPC concluded that Tencent lacked dominance in the Chinese IM market. The complete record of all written submissions and testimony is not public, which makes scrutinizing the court’s factual findings difficult.17 The court’s willingness to discount network effects based on a brief discussion of the “possibility” of small-group migrations to alternate IM services and concurrent use of overlapping networks seems an unsatisfactory response to one of the plaintiff’s core arguments. Regardless of any infirmities in the court’s factual findings in this specific case, the decision demonstrates that the presumptions of dominance based on market shares are not insurmountable. An Effects-Based Test for Abuse Although finding that a defendant lacks a dominant market position generally obviates further inquiry into abusive conduct, the SPC nevertheless proceeded to consider whether Tencent’s conduct constituted abuse. The SPC’s explanation of the general framework for assessing abuse of dominance claims under the AML may be one of the most significant contributions of the opinion to Chinese competition law. Article 6 of the AML broadly prohibits dominant firms from “abusing” their dominant market positions “to eliminate or restrict competition.” Article 17 then prohibits “abuse of dominant market position” by engaging in specified commercial practices “without justification” or through “unfair” pricing, as well as any other practices deemed to constitute abuse by the enforcement authorities. Neither the AML nor any implementing regulations define the term “abuse.” Although enforcement authorities’ implementing rules describe specific “justifications” for some specific abuses, neither the AML nor any published implementing measures set forth the general principles or methodologies for gauging the elimination or restriction of competition or determining whether an allegedly abusive practice is “without justification.” Significantly, the SPC prescribed an effects-based test for determining whether challenged conduct constitutes abuse: Even if the business operator sued has a dominant market position, negative effects and potential positive effects of 5 8 · A N T I T R U S T S T O R I E S such acts on consumers and competition should still be assessed comprehensively to determine whether or not it constitutes an abuse of dominant market position, so as to decide whether or not such act is legitimate. The SPC’s approach resembles the effects-based approach of U.S. courts under Section 2 of the Sherman Act and the European Commission’s 2009 guidance on abuse of dominance claims more than the form-based approach of recent European court decisions. This represents the most authoritative statement to date of the general test for defining abusive conduct under the AML. Exclusive Dealing or Monopoly Leveraging? Qihoo alleged that Tencent abused its dominance in the IM market by deliberately terminating the interoperability of Tencent’s IM services with Qihoo’s security software, compelling QQ users to discontinue use of Qihoo products (presumably switching to the security features of Tencent’s applications). It is unclear, however, whether the courts assessed this conduct as exclusive dealing under Article 17 (4) of the AML or as another exclusionary abuse under the catch-all of Article 17(7). The trial court reasoned that the “choose one from two” strategy was designed “to force users to transact with [Tencent] exclusively instead of with 360” and concluded that “such act is, by its nature, a restriction of transactions.” This conclusion was widely viewed as finding that such conduct by a dominant firm would constitute exclusive dealing. The SPC similarly framed the issue as whether or not Tencent’s conduct qualified as “a restriction on dealing which is prohibited by the AML.” The SPC explained that “according to Article 17 of the AML, if business operators with dominant market position restrict their counter-parties to transact with them exclusively or to transact with other parties designated by them exclusively without justifiable reasons, such acts constitute an abuse of a dominant market position.” This parrots the language of Article 17(4), which bars dominant firms from “restricting, without any justification, their counter-parties to transact with such business operators exclusively or to transact with other parties designated by such undertakings exclusively.” Article 17(4) targets archetypical exclusive dealing practices that compel customers to purchase solely from a dominant firm or its designees. Tencent’s conduct, however, did not actually compel users to select security software from Tencent or from any other specific vendors; it only foreclosed Tencent QQ users from concurrently using security software from Qihoo. A liberal reading of Article 17(4) reaching Tencent’s tactics might sweep in almost any exclusionary practice. The challenged conduct might be better characterized as a form of monopoly leveraging, on the theory that Tencent leveraged market power in one market (IM), into a second marker (security software), through anticompetitive actions. The catch-all prohibition of other abuses under Article 17(7) of the AML could capture such monopoly leveraging offenses. Neither the SPC nor the trial court explicitly referred to either Article 17(4) or 17(7) in evaluating this claim. In assessing Qihoo’s tying claim, in contrast, the SPC expressly invoked Article 17(5) and explained the elements of a tying offense in detail. Both Qihoo and the courts may have had incentives to sidestep this issue. Read literally, Article 17(7) applies to “other abuses” as defined by the administrative enforcement agencies such as the NDRC and SAIC— not the courts. Some Chinese practitioners and jurists have suggested that this limitation might require novel theories of abuse under Article 17(7) to be recognized in prior administrative enforcement actions before plaintiffs can seek damages before the courts.18 While empowering the enforcement agencies to set the boundaries of Article 17(7) might screen out frivolous or unsound theories of abuse, it might also lock out worthy claims that clash with the agencies’ overall policy agendas. Neither the enforcement authorities nor the courts have clearly addressed the handling of private actions alleging abuses not specific under Article 17(1) through (6), and the SPC passed a chance to do so in this case. In any event, the SPC’s approach may offer greater guidance for general abuse of dominance claims under Article 17(7) rather than for conventional exclusive dealing cases under Article 17(4). The Shadow of Prior Decisions In determining whether Tencent’s non-interoperability measures constituted abuse, the SPC faced a fact pattern cluttered with prior judgments. The MIIT had intervened to stop the allegedly abusive conduct and restore interoperability after just one day, then publicly chastised both parties’ conduct and issued rules barring such tactics in the future. The SPC explicitly noted its own prior ruling that Qihoo “developed and operated Koukou Guard software to assist or abet damaging the safety and integrity of QQ software and its services and promote its own products by disparaging QQ software and its services, which constituted unfair competition in violation of the principle of good faith and customary business ethics.” These prior decisions impacted the SPC’s analysis of the actual motivations and effects of Tencent’s conduct. Although the trial court had ultimately dismissed Qihoo’s claims for failure to prove that Tencent was dominant, its brief discussion of abuse favored Qihoo. It focused on the immediate object of Tencent’s conduct, summarily concluding that it was a “restriction of competition.” The trial court also rejected Tencent’s justification defense. While acknowledging that Qihoo’s software functions and public claims actually jeopardized Tencent’s valid interests, the trial court found that Tencent’s proper remedy was to sue Qihoo. Forcing end-users to choose between Tencent or Qihoo exceeded the scope of “necessary” self-help authorized under China’s Civil Code, and was thus unjustified.19 Qihoo invoked the trial court’s finding on appeal; once Tencent was recognized as dominant, this improper conduct should be readily condemned as an “obvious abuse.” Unlike the trial court, the SPC looked beyond the immediate object of the challenged conduct to focus on the actual motivations and effects. In assessing Tencent’s “motives,” the SPC framed Tencent’s actions as a defensive reaction to Qihoo’s unlawful conduct rather than an offensive effort to exclude Qihoo. Tencent’s IM had long been compatible with Qihoo’s security software, and the incompatibility measures were only imposed after Qihoo released Koukou Guard. “It is particularly worth noting that the background of the implementation of [Tencent’s] incompatibility is that [Qihoo] developed and operated Koukou Guard to specifically target [Tencent’s] QQ software and engaged in unfair competition, and [Tencent] was forced to react.” The SPC also noted there was “no evidence sufficient to show” that the incompatibility was intended to “prevent potential competitors from entering” or otherwise “eliminate or restrict competition” in the IM market. (It is unclear whether the SPC intended to apply this finding to the security software market from which Qihoo claimed to have been excluded.) Whereas the trial court had focused on the immediate exclusionary objective of the “choose one from two” measures, the SPC focused on the subjective motivation of responding to Qihoo. The SPC did not, however, directly reach Tencent’s justification defenses. Given the MIIT’s prior public criticisms of both parties, explicitly blessing the deliberate non-interoperability as a “justified’ strategy may have been untenable. Indeed, the SPC warned that the absence of significant harm to consumers “does not mean that [Tencent] was beyond criticism for its implementation of the incompatibility.” In assessing impacts on “consumers’ interests,” the SPC found that the product incompatibility “inconvenienced” consumers but did not “significantly” impact consumer interests because ample alternatives were available for both IM and security software products. The SPC also considered the effects on “competition” by examining changes in market share in the IM and security software markets following the one-day incompatibility period. While acknowledging the limitations of the available data, the SPC concluded that competition had actually intensified in the IM market. Tencent’s market share fell 1 percent, the number of users of several rival IM services rose, and other competitors accelerated their market entry plans. The SPC further speculated that Tencent’s market share would have fallen further if the interoperability had not been restored so quickly. Turning to the security software market, the SPC acknowledged evidence of “certain negative impacts” on Qihoo. However, the SPC clarified that “the AML, however, focuses on whether or not a healthy market competition mechanism is distorted or damaged rather than the interests of individual business operators.” The SPC cited Qihoo’s experts in finding that weekly users of two specific applications fell 10% and 12% following the incident, but also S P R I N G 2 0 1 5 · 5 9 C O V E R cited Tencent’s experts as finding that Qihoo’s overall share of the safety software market dipped only 3.3%, from 74.6% to 71.3%, while Tencent’s share nudged up 0.57%, from 3.89% to 4.46%. These figures suggest that Qihoo’s share of the security software market remained well above the 50 percent threshold for the presumption of dominance under the AML, while Tencent’s minute share barely budged. The SPC characterized the effects of the one-day interruption of interoperability as “subtle,” finding no “significant” elimination or restriction of competition in the security software market. Based on these factual findings, the SPC concluded that the incompatibility implemented by [Tencent] has caused inconvenience to users, but it did not have an obvious effect of eliminating or restricting competition. This, on one hand, proves that the incompatibility implemented by [Tencent] did not constitute an abuse of dominant market position prohibited by the AML, and on the other hand, substantiates the conclusion that [Tencent] does not hold a dominant market position. On the same facts, similar monopoly leveraging claims before U.S. courts under Sherman Act Section 2 would have met the same fate following Trinko.20 Even if Tencent were found to possess monopoly power in the IM market and to have engaged in anticompetitive or exclusionary conduct, it would be difficult to prove that Tencent had a dangerous probability of success in monopolizing the security software market. Different facts may, of course, have yielded different outcomes. If the MIIT had not intervened to restore interoperability, protracted incompatibility between Tencent’s QQ and Qihoo’s security software might have led to substantial erosion of Qihoo’s share and gains in Tencent’s share in the security software market. Faced with evidence of a material reduction in competition, it is unclear how the courts would have viewed Tencent’s defense that the need to protect QQ users (and Tencent’s reputation) from the technical interference by Qihoo products “justified” the deliberate incompatibility. If Tencent had acted without the provocation of Qihoo’s prior violations of the AUCL, the SPC might not have looked far beyond the exclusionary object of the deliberate incompatibility measures to require evidence of significant anticompetitive effects. Tying Qihoo also claimed that Tencent violated the AML rules against tying by integrating a new application management program with security functions (called “QQ Guanjia,” or “QQ Housekeeper”) into free upgrades for the QQ IM software. The SPC first articulated the elements of a tying offense under Article 17(5) of the AML. The tying and tied products must be independent. The seller must possess a dominant position in the market for the tying product, and must force the purchaser to accept the tied product. The challenged 6 0 · A N T I T R U S T S T O R I E S tying practice must have a negative impact on completion, and must be “unjustified,” inconsistent with “trade practices or consumers’ habits,” or disregard “product functions.” The SPC acknowledged the risk that a dominant firm might leverage market power from the tying product to the tied product, but also stressed potential “positive effects under certain circumstances to improve product quality, reduce costs, boost sales, ensure safety and improve efficiency.” The SPC affirmed the trial court’s dismissal of this claim. First, the SPC found “no reliable evidence” that Tencent “would extend its leading position in the instant messaging market to the safety software market by the alleged tie-in sale,” again citing the evidence of minimal changes in market shares in the security software market. Second, the SPC found it “reasonable” to bundle the IM and application manager software to improve the performance of the IM service and protect account data. Third, the SPC concluded that Tencent did not, in fact, compel users to utilize the application manager software as a condition of using the IM service. Although the application manager installed automatically along with the IM upgrades, users could easily remove it without disturbing the IM functions. Consequently, the SPC upheld the trial court’s dismissal of Qihoo’s tying claim. Implications For U.S. Companies China’s recent surge in investigations targeting foreign companies for cartel activity, resale price maintenance, and abusive licensing of standard-essential patents has fueled fears of discriminatory enforcement of the AML for industrial policy, protectionist, or political ends.21 Multinational companies with strong IP portfolios and product lines remain concerned that abuse of dominance charges relying on high market shares as evidence of market power and commercial losses by competitors as evidence of anticompetitive effect may lead to exorbitant fines or disproportionate remedial commitments. The SPC’s opinion in Qihoo v. Tencent equips future defendants with the tools to advocate a flexible analysis of abuse of dominance claims focusing on actual procompetitive and anticompetitive effects of challenged practices. Although the SPC’s statutory interpretations in specific cases are not technically binding precedent for future cases under China’s civil law scheme, SPC opinions present powerful authority in judicial proceedings as well as administrative investigations (albeit to a lesser extent). But flexible tests bend both ways. The dismissal of Qihoo’s claims against Tencent explicitly rests on factual findings reflecting the actual effects of prior intervention by the MIIT, prior adjudication of Qihoo’s misconduct, and the unique dynamics of competition among providers of free online services. It may also reflect the absence of overriding policy interests in the outcome. Even under the flexible tests articulated by the SPC, the outcome of future abuse of dominance cases may depend heavily on the specific practices, parties, and policy interests at stake.䡵 1 See Antimonopoly Law of the People’s Republic of China (promulgated by the Standing Comm. Nat’l People’s Cong., Aug. 30, 2007, effective Aug. 1, 2008), available at http://www.gov.cn/flfg/2007-08/30/content_732 591.htm. 2 See Court Opinion for Appeal on Monopoly Dispute Between Qihoo Technology Limited and Tencent Technology (Sup. People’s Ct. Oct. 8, 2014), available at http://www.court.gov.cn/zgcpwsw/zgrmfy/zscq/201 410/t20141017_3425404.htm. All quotations to the opinion in this article are based on an unofficial English translation prepared by the authors. 3 See Qihoo 360 Technology Co. Ltd., Annual Report (Form 20-F) (Apr. 25, 2014), at 7, available at http://ir.360.cn/phoenix.zhtml?c=243376&p= irol-reportsannual. 4 The AUCL prohibits a broad range of commercial misconduct, such as false advertising, commercial bribery, trade libel, and several anticompetitive practices. See Anti-Unfair Competition Law of the People’s Republic of China (promulgated by the Standing Comm. of the Nat’l People’s Cong., Sept. 2, 1993, effective Dec. 1, 1993), available at http://www.gov.cn/ banshi/2005-08/31/content_68766.htm. 5 See Cases on Unfair Competition on the Internet Exploding, IPR IN C HINA (July 4, 2014), http://www.chinaipr.gov.cn/newsarticle/news/enterprise/ 201407/1827294_1.html. 6 See Five Big Internet Players Including Baidu and Tencent Joined Efforts Against 360 (Dec. 28, 2010), http://tech.sina.com.cn/i/2010-10-28/ 01194797778.shtml. 7 See 360 Launched New Product—Koukou Guard, Said It Makes QQ Safe, Fast and More User-Friendly (Oct. 28, 2010), http://tech.ifeng.com/ internet/special/360pkqq/content-1/detail_2010_10/29/2941498_0. shtml. 8 See Tencent Responded to the Launching of Koukou Guard by 360: Will Pursue 360’s Legal Liabilities (Oct. 28, 2010), http://www.caijing.com.cn/ 2010-10-29/110555294.html. 9 See Tencent Announces It Will Stop Running QQ on Computers Installed with 360 (Nov. 3, 2010), http://tech.ifeng.com/internet/special/360pkqq/ content-1/detail_2010_11/03/2991628_0.shtml. 10 See The Ministry of Industry and Information Technology Circulated a Notice Harshly Criticizing Tencent and 360 and Said They Caused a Baneful Influence (Nov. 21, 2010), http://tech.hexun.com/2010-11-21/125738894. html. 11 See Several Provisions Regulating the Internet Information Service Market Order (promulgated by the Ministry of Indus. and Info. Tech., Dec. 29, 2011, effective Mar. 15, 2012), available at http://zfs.miit.gov.cn/n11293472/ n11294912/n11296542/14414761.html. 12 See id. art 5. 13 See Tencent Technology (Shenzhen) Company Limited and Shenzhen Tencent Computer Systems Company Limited v. Beijing Qihoo Technology Limited, Qizhi Software (Beijing) Co., Ltd, Beijing Sanji Wuxian Network Technology Co., Ltd., (Beijing Changyao Dist. People’s Ct. Apr. 26, 2011; Beijing 2nd Interm. People’s Ct. Sept. 14, 2011), available at http://cyqfy. chinacourt.org/public/paperview.php?id=549582, and http://www.110. com/panli/panli_27891191.html; Tencent Technology (Shenzhen) Company Limited, Shenzhen Tencent Computer Systems Company Limited v. Beijing Qihoo Technology Limited, Qizhi Software (Beijing) Co., Ltd., (Guangdong Higher People’s Ct. Apr. 3, 2013; Sup. People’s Ct., Feb. 18, 2014) available at http://www.law-lib.com/cpws/cpws_view.asp?id=200401917814, and http://www.court.gov.cn/zgcpwsw/zgrmfy/zscq/201402/t20140225_ 387819.htm. 14 See FTC v. Ind. Fed’n of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447, 460–61 (1986) (evidence of “actual, sustained adverse effects on competition” is “legally sufficient” to support liability “even in the absence of elaborate market analysis.”); see also J. Douglas Richards, Is Market Definition Necessary in Sherman Act Cases When Anticompetitive Effects Can Be Shown with Direct Evidence?, A NTITRUST , Summer 2012, at 58 n.9 (surveying U.S. precedent and academic commentary). 15 See Case No. COMP/M.6281 (Microsoft/Skype) Regulation (EC) No. 139/ 2004 Merger Procedure (Oct. 7, 2011), at ¶¶ 10–43, available at http:// ec.europa.eu/competition/mergers/cases/decisions/m6281_20111007_ 20310_2079398_EN.pdf, confirmed by Case T-79/12, Cisco Sys. Inc. v. Comm’n (Gen. Ct. Eur. Comm’n Nov. 12, 2013) (focusing on functionality of various free online communications services); see also U.S. Dep’t of Justice & Fed Trade Comm’n, Horizontal Merger Guidelines 12 (Aug. 19, 2010), available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/2010/08/100819hmg.pdf (emphasizing the value of the hypothetical monopolist test as “a useful methodological tool for gathering and analyzing evidence pertinent to customer substitution and to market definition” even when necessary quantitative data is unavailable). 16 See Provisions of the Supreme People’s Court on Certain Issues Relating to the Application of Law in Hearing Cases Involving Civil Disputes Arising out of Monopolistic Acts (promulgated by the Sup. People’s Ct., May 3, 2012, effective June 1, 2012), art. 8, available at http://www.chinacourt. org/law/detail/2012/05/id/145752.shtml. 17 Economists retained by both parties subsequently published critiques of the SPC’s opinion. See David Evans & Vanessa Yanhua Zhang, Qihoo 360 v. Tencent: First Antitrust Decision by the Supreme Court, C OMPETITION P OL ’ Y I NT ’ L (Oct. 21, 2014); Sharon Pang, Qihoo v. Tencent: Economic Analysis of the First Chinese Supreme Court Decision Under Anti-Monopoly Law, C HARLES R IVER A SSOCS . (Feb. 2015), available at http://ecp.crai.com/ecp/assets/ Qihoo_360_v_Tencent-Economic_Analysis_of_the_First_Chinese_Supreme_ Court_Decicion_under_Anti-Monopoly_Law.pdf. 18 See Susan Ning, Kate Peng, Jia Lin & Rui Li, The Dual System of AntiMonopoly Law—The Interplay Between Administrative Enforcement and Civil Action, C HINA L AW I NSIGHT (Sept. 12, 2013), http://www.chinalawinsight. com/2013/09/articles/corporate/antitrust-competition/the-dual-systemof-anti-monopoly-law-the-interplay-between-administrative-enforcement-andcivil-action/; Summary Report of Seminar on the Coordination and Connection of AML Administrative Enforcement and Civil Litigation (June 2009), available at http://www.a-court.gov.cn/platformData/infoplat/pub/ no1court_2802/docs/200906/d_622011.html. 19 See General Principles of Civil Law of the People’s Republic of China (2009 Revision) (promulgated by the Nat’l People’s Cong., Apr. 12, 1986, effective Jan. 1, 1987, revised Aug. 27, 2009), arts.128–129, available at http:// www.npc.gov.cn/npc/lfzt/rlys/2014-10/28/content_1883354.htm; Tort Liability Law of the People’s Republic of China (promulgated by the Standing Comm. of the Nat’l People’s Cong., Dec. 26, 2009, effective July 1, 2010), arts. 30–31, available at http://www.gov.cn/flfg/2009-12/26/content_ 1497435.htm. 20 See Verizon Commc’ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 414 n.4 (2004). 21 See e.g., U.S. Chamber of Commerce, Competing Interests in China’s Competition Law Enforcement: China’s Anti-Monopoly Law Application and the Role of Industrial Policy (Sept. 9, 2014), available at https://www. uschamber.com/sites/default/files/aml_final_090814_final_locked.pdf; US-China Business Council, Competition Policy and Enforcement in China (Sept. 2014), available at https://www.uschina.org/sites/default/files/ AML%202014%20Report%20FINAL_0.pdf. S P R I N G 2 0 1 5 · 6 1