UNCHECKED POWER: THE PRESIDENCY UNDER FUJIMORI AND BEYOND PHILIP MAUCERI DEPARTMENT OF POLITICAL SCIENCE UNIVERSITY OF NORTHERN IOWA CEDAR FALLS, IA 50701 PHILIP.MAUCERI@UNI.EDU Comments Welcome This Paper is part of a larger project on Constitutional Reform and the Presidency in Colombia, Venezuela and Peru. Presented at the Panel “The Y2K Problem in Peru: Fujimori and the Bases for Liberal Democracy: Institutions and Processes” at The XXII International Congress of the Latin American Studies Association, 16-18 March, 2000 in Miami, Florida Since first being elected in 1990, President Fujimori has dominated the politics of Peru by defining the policy agenda, redesigning the country’s institutional framework and maintaining almost consistently high public approval ratings. No other institution within the state structure has appeared to check presidential power and no organizations in civil or political society have been able to challenge what has at times appeared to be an almost inevitable concentration of political power in the presidency. These trends raise important questions about the role of presidents in Peru and Latin America in general. Were the sources of Fujimori’s power and legitimacy in the 1990s the result of a particular “coyuntura” or indications of structural and/or institutional conditions likely to influence the course of Peruvian politics in the coming decades? More generally, what are effective checks on presidential power and how do they develop? Finally, what does such a dominant presidency say about the social and cultural underpinnings of power relations in a society such as Peru’s at the start of the 21st Century? This paper will argue that the Fujimori administration accelerated trends already in place during the 1980s towards ever greater presidential power. The analysis focuses on the three primary “checks” in modern liberal democracies on presidential power: mutual power checks among institutions, decentralization of decision making and party systems. The historical legacy of Peru, the political practice of the Fujimori government and the institutional framework that developed in the 1990s have undermined the possibility of developing checks on presidential power. The paper ends with some reflections on the likelihood of institutional reforms in the postFujimori era. The preponderance of academic studies of presidential systems has been highly critical (Lijphart 1991, Mainwaring 1993, Stepan & Skach 1993, Linz and Valenzuela 1994). These critics have argued that a presidential system is more likely to promote immobilism, institutional conflict and weak legitimacy as well as inexperienced and authoritarian leadership. The Latin American cases found in the second volume of the Linz and Valenzuela study (1994), offer a convincing series of country studies that attempt to demonstrate how presidentialism has contributed to unstable democracies and in some instances, outright democratic breakdowns. One of the few analyses to focus on the advantages of presidentialism is found in Shugart and Carey (1992), which focuses on 48 countries that have held at least two presidential elections during the 20th Century. The authors suggest that presidentialism provides a high level of both accountability and identifiability of alternatives, as well as mutual checks and an arbiter of social and political conflicts. Most importantly, they question whether presidentialism is any more likely to lead to democratic breakdown than parliamentarism. Despite the apparent scholarly consensus against presidentialism, the historical reality of most democracies established in recent decades, particularly in Latin America, is that presidentialism (or at least a mixed semi-presidential system), remains the favorite choice in constitutional frameworks. Of the three new constitutions adopted in the region during the 1990s–Colombia, Venezuela and Peru–not only was a changeover to parliamentarism not even debated, but in the cases of Peru and Venezuela the formal powers of the presidency were strengthened. For scholars and policy makers interested in deepening democracy in Latin America, the unlikelihood of alternative systems being adopted in the near future suggests that it is time to move beyond the presidential vs. parliamentary debate. Given that presidential systems -1- have been and are likely to continue to be a fixture of Latin American constitutions, a more fruitful line of inquiry would focus on the sources of presidential power and legitimacy. Specifically, how do we define “checks and balances” in a modern liberal democratic system and are there conditions under which such a situation is more likely to develop? Finally, what institutional mechanisms and/or social configurations can be used to prevent (or undo) a situation of unchecked presidential power? I. Defining Unchecked Presidential Power in an Electoral Democracy: Beyond `Delegative Democracy’ In a now seminal article, Guillermo O’Donnell (1994) defined “delegative democracy” as a situation in which a president becomes “the embodiment of the nation and the main custodian of the national interest”. As such he has little tolerance for institutional rules and procedures, which are viewed as possible impediments to achieving his goals. Politics is viewed in personalist and plebiscitarian terms. Although elections are generally free of significant fraud and minimal civil liberties are maintained, manipulation of the media and intimidation of the opposition are the norm. O’Donnell’s description of a “delegative democracy” paints a bleak picture of presidential power run amok and clearly from Peronist Argentina onward, the latter half of the 20th Century in Latin America offers numerous examples of what might be labeled delegative democracies. The power of presidents in these “democracies” to undertake policies with few constraints, provides a vivid example of unchecked presidential power and offer an illustration of the fear expressed by James Madison in Federalist Paper #47 that, “The accumulation of powers [in the same hands]...whether hereditary, self-appointed or elective may be justly pronounced the very definition of tyranny”. Building on the ideas of Locke and Montesquieu, Madison devised a system based on checks and balances, or what presidential scholar Richard Neustadt has termed the principle of “separated institutions sharing power” (Neustadt, 1960: 33). The purpose of “checks and balances” is to prevent any single institution from making decisions without the support or at least acquiescence of other institutions. The system forces participants to negotiate, bargain and compromise in order to achieve their objectives, inhibiting “winner-take-all” scenarios, whereby oppositions and/or minorities have no ability to shape or influence policy making. Mutual checks thus become mutual restraints on the exercise of institutional power. The Madisonian approach to dividing power was extended to the division between national and local power in a federal system. The justification is found in Federalist Paper #51, where Madison argues that “The different governments will control each other.” The framers of the US Constitution hoped that the federal and state governments would restrain each other just as the executive, legislative and judicial branches would do so at the national level. When discussing checks and balances, most of the literature builds on the Madisonian tradition by focusing on specific constitutional mechanisms designed to divide and check power. Although these remain the primary checks on presidential power in modern liberal democracies, there is at least one more institutional arrangement that evolved beyond Madison’s scheme, namely party systems, that can exercise important checks on executive powers. Beyond their function as “interest aggregators” linking the state with civil society, parties provide important linkages between the branches of government as well as between national and local authorities. -2- Parties not only provide channels for demands and participation to be expressed, but they also shape preferences and as such play an important role in creating democratic legitimacy and accountability. The autonomous political and institutions interests of parties creates a level of accountability between the executive as politicians to party elites. In summary, this paper suggests that there are three institutional mechanisms that are the primary checks on presidential power in modern liberal democracies: Mutual Institutional Checks Under Separation of Powers: The system of mutual checks developed in the US political system included specific checks on presidential powers by the Congress and Courts, such as the ability to overide vetos, advise and consent on diplomatic treaties and judicial review. While the specific mechanisms will vary, the purpose of formal checks on the presidency is to provide the other branches of government legal restraints on the policy making and/or implementation powers of the executive. Nonetheless, the mere existence of formal/legal checks on presidential power does not in themselves guarantee their effectiveness, particularly where there is not the political will to enforce the authority of those checks. The unwillingness to exercise that authority might result from a variety of factors, from partisan closeness to the president to outright corruption. A good example of this dynamic is the legislative power given to presidents. In a number of systems, including Peru’s, the Congress can cede legislative authority to the executive. Under most circumstances that authority is limited to specific issues within a set time limit. Although legislative decree powers, if used sparingly would not necessarily result in excessive presidential power, the unwillingness of legislatures to set specific limits or timetables or enforce those limits, often for partisan reasons, usually contribute to concentrated presidential power. Thus it is not the formal/legal mechanism but the abdication of legislative authority that neutralizes the check on power. Decentralized Decision Making and Local Autonomy: Beyond formal/legal checks by other branches of government on the President, the Madisonian approach to checks and balances also creates multiple sources of legitimacy and authority, namely the idea of a federal system of governance in which separate local institutions and laws exist and derive their legitimacy from officials elected independently of national leaders. The impact of federalism or other forms of decentralization is to carve out a series of policy arenas and jurisdictions over which presidents have little effective power. Moreover, the alternative governing figures--from mayors and governors to local legislators and judges--limit the ability of presidents to proclaim themselves the embodiment of the national will by establishing other actors with a legitimate claim to represent the people’s will. Institutionalized Party Systems: Parties as organizations have a broad range of interestsideological, electoral, financial, membership–which they are likely to enforce when dealing political actors, including a president. The consequences of policies over the long term on party interests will inevitably be an important part of presidential decision making and is likely to act as a constraint. Since presidents in such systems are likely to come from the party machinery, there is a sense of mutual obligation between party leaders and the president to advance each others -3- interests and avoid policies that might be costly to each other. Mexico provides a superb example of this dynamic. During most of the 20th Century, Mexican presidents were highly authoritarian and paternalistic. Yet the “presidencialismo” of the Mexican system was far from a model of personal and arbitrary rule. Mexican presidents were traditionally constrained by party elites and interests both within the party organization as well as those entrenched in the state apparatus. When presidents did undertake actions that many party leaders opposed, as with the 1981 bank nationalization by President Lopez Portillo, they were often frustrated by the party’s check on their power. (Camp, 1996: 156). The mutual dependence of the dominant PRI and the president thus ensured that executive personalism would not develop.1 By contrast, in personalist systems the president focuses on personal popularity, emphasizes short-term policies and, unconstrained by the needs or interests of a party organization, appeals directly to the electorate generally disdaining institutional norms and procedures. The presence of one or more of the above checks on presidential power is likely to be the result of the social and historical context of a political system, and particularly the experience with institutions. Institutions reflect social and cultural attitudes, and executive power and its institutional limitations are not an exception to this general principle. In much of the recent analyses of presidential systems in Latin America, however, surprisingly little attention has been paid to this dimension. In one of the few efforts to address this issue, Glen Dealy suggests that although Latin American constitutions historically incorporated formal separation of powers, the idea of separation of powers has little basis in the Ibero-American understanding of the limitations of power, where “restraints were not procedural but moral” (1982: 168). Unlike the Madisonian approach which assumes a Hobbesian view of human political behavior, and thus requires specific constraints on the accumulation of power, the writers of Latin American constitutions, Dealy argues, believed the only restraint on the exercise of power that was needed was the selection of virtuous rulers. The accumulation of power was not viewed by Ibero-American philosophers as inherently evil and so there was little need to develop elaborate schemes to divide, separate and balance the exercise of governmental power. The primary task of constitution writers was to ensure the moral exercise of power, something that would occur through moral education, social conformity and the enforcement of religious authority. Although this understanding of power has not been immutable during the last two centuries, it clearly has played an important role in shaping political patterns. A history of arbitrary, personalist and authoritarian rule is an obvious impediment to producing either institutional arrangements focused on limiting the power of executives or a culture of executive accountability. But checks and balances are largely the result of political craftsmanship and with sufficient support from political elites and public opinion, might offer a creative breakthrough to deepen the process of democratic institutionalization. In order to examine both the challenges and promises such an attempt might confront we now turn to the case of Fujimori’s Peru. 1 This is not to argue that the Mexican presidency operates in ways that are consistent with democratic institutionalism. Although the presidency has traditionally had a highly authoritarian character, it has not been a tool of arbitrary personalist rule. -4- II. Sources of Presidential Power and Legitimacy in Peru The Fujimori presidency offers a good example of unchecked presidential power. While elections have generally been free of fraud and minimal civil liberties have been maintained, institutional rules and norms have been altered in ways that enhance the powers of the president over other institutions in the state and society. Largely eschewing any reliance on organizations outside direct executive control, President Fujimori’s rule has been based on an arbitrary personalism that has put into place an informal network of supporters to advance the political interests of the president. The most direct challenge to democratic institutionalism during Fujimori’s administration came in April 1992, when the president used the armed forces to forcibly shut-down the Congress and Judiciary. Largely as a result of international pressure, the administration was forced to hold constituent assembly elections and ultimately a new constitution was approved by voters in a 1993 plebiscite. Under the 1993 Constitution, both the congress and judiciary saw their formal powers reduced. Since the adoption of the new constitution, neither the congress nor the judiciary, which are dominated by Fujimori appointees and loyalists, have impeded the adoption or implementation of a major policy initiative of the president. Where the threat of such an event occurred, as in the Constitutional Tribunal’s decision regarding presidential reelection, institutional rules and personnel were arbitrarily changed. An evaluation of possible checks on presidential power nonetheless requires an examination of the traditional sources of checks on presidential power and influence, a task to which we now turn. A. Personalism and The Use of Informal Networks over Political Parties Viewed from a historical perspective, Fujimori’s highly personalist style of governance is certainly not unprecedented in either Peru or the region. Latin America has a long experience with caudillo (strongman) rule, both civilian and military. As mentioned earlier, the historical and cultural context in which the idea of executive power developed is key to understanding this experience. Nonetheless that does not mean that the ways in which this power is either understood or operationalized is deterministically fixed. New power relations, technologies and social structures are likely to impact on how presidential personalism is viewed and/or exercised. President Fujimori has been quite adept at incorporating many of these new elements into this traditional pattern, most notably his use of television as a way to shape political opinions. Carefully orchestrated media events, in which the president appears dressed in traditional costumes, dancing, drinking or bantering with local peasants or workers have been a staple of the administration. Such events are the results of a sympathetic national media willing to provide a forum for a popular president, but also of the network of media consultants, focus groups and polling data that can artfully craft an image for politicians everywhere. Fujimori has been very successful in appealing to the different social classes and groups that make-up modern Peru, by creating a discourse that links his own person with the needs, interests and even culture of these disparate groups. Like the populists of the past, Fujimori has demonstrated enormous political skill, mixed with demagoguery, in convincing people with such divergent interests that loyalty to him personally is the best way to achieve their goals within the political system. Fujimori’s ability to maintain such personal loyalty even while implementing policies that create high economic costs for these constituencies, has been one of the most -5- surprising aspects of his administration and also the source of much academic attention.2 A key aspect of this dynamic has been the extraordinary focus, both in policy terms and the discourse offered the public, that the administration has had on “practical” solutions to everyday problems. A Japanese engineer-president focused on pragmatic problem solving had special appeal in the context of the hyper-ideologized political society, spiraling political violence and near economic collapse of Peru in the early 1990s. What is perhaps most astonishing is that continued support has come despite the complete disinterest in political organization and mobilization. Unlike classic populist politicians such as former president Alan García, the Fujimori administration has been uninterested in mobilizing support from lower class groups and has avoided using class-oriented appeals or redistributive policies to gain support. While cultivating approval in opinion polls and elections, there have been no significant pro-government organizations designed to channel support for administration policies. Since the start of the administration, Fujimori has consistently attacked the concept of parties as well as the existing parties in Peru. Indeed, Fujimori was elected in 1990 in part as an “outsider” to the party elites. Peru since the 1960s had a multiparty system with the major parties mixing ideology and strong class identity with the charisma of a founding leader. By contrast, the two “parties” developed by Fujimori and his supporters, Cambio 90 and Nueva Mayoria, are little more than electoral vehicles. Neither has a national organizational structure, independent leaderships or programmatic agendas, and both are viewed as mere electoral labels for proFujimori candidates. In order to accomplish many of the tasks that a formal party structure might provide, President Fujimori has been astute in creating a web of personalist networks throughout the administration made up of people loyal to his person and occupying formal and informal roles in the government. These networks provide the president with the staff of loyal followers within the state bureaucracy that is often recruited from a political party. They also help the president manage and ultimately aggregate the demands coming from different sectors of society. Unlike party officials however, they do not have an independent power base of their own, and are thus unable to provide a check on presidential activities. Their dependence on the president means that their positions are tied to their ability to loyally serve the interests and needs of the president. If they are perceived as threatening, they can be easily removed and in contrast to party officials who might have organizational interests of their own, there are likely to be few if any repercussions for the president. There are two primary networks that Fujimori developed from the start of his administration: social/familial and technocratic. Lacking a formal political party, it was almost inevitable that once elected, Fujimori would turn to friends and family to staff his administration. Although many in the developing family/social network were highly trained and competent, others had little more than their ties to Fujimori as qualifications. Santiago Fujimori, the new president’s brother became a de-facto chief of staff, overseeing appointments and promotions within the 2 See in particular Ken Roberts, “Neoliberalism and the Transformation of Populism in Latin America: The Peruvian Case”, World Politics 48(4), October 1995, pp. 82-116; Susan Stokes, “Economic Reform and Public Opinion in Peru, 1990-1995" Comparative Political Studies 29(5), October 1996. Pp. 544-565. -6- executive branch and until their separation, Fujimori’s wife Susana Higuchi also played a role as informal advisor. Victor Joy Way, a successful Chinese-Peruvian businessman from the Andean department of Huanuco and friend of the president has at various points been Prime Minister and President of the Congress. The administration recruited heavily among the Japanese-Peruvian community, which had traditionally not been politically active or mobilized. During the 1990s, several prominent ministers and vice-ministers came from this community, including Daniel Hokama, former Minister of Energy and Mines, Alejandro Afuso Higa, director of the social program FONCODES and Victor Kobashigawa, Vice-Minister of Education. The most prominent figure from this community and one of the most influential officials of the first Fujimori administration was Jaime Yoshiyama, who first as Minister of Energy and Mines and later as director of the Ministry of the Presidency oversaw much of the economic and governmental restructuring that took place between 1990 and 1995. Yoshiyama was often mentioned as a possible successor of Fujimori and became the administration’s candidate for Mayor of Lima in November 1995, but narrowly lost. Yoshiyama’s growing prominence, ambitions and semi-public efforts to build an independent political base were important factors behind his summary dismissal as governmental minister at the end of 1996. The penetration of the state bureaucracy by this social network although providing a loyal staff for the president has often led to charges of corruption (as with Santiago Fujimori) and/ or the erosion of professionalism. Nowhere is the latter more clear than in the security forces. By far the most powerful of the informal advisors to the president has been Vladimiro Montesinos, a former army captain and shadowy figure who had been Fujimori’s attorney during the 1990 presidential campaign, Montesinos was instrumental in using his contacts in the security forces to help purge the armed forces and establish the new presidents control over them. Although he occupies no formal position within the governmental structure, he has effective control over both the armed forces and the intelligence agency, SIN. Promotions, retirements and assignments have been heavily influenced by Montesinos, and his power and influence has been the source of resentment within the security apparatus.3 Allegations of corruption and ties to drugtraffickers have had no impact on his influence and efforts by opposition congresspersons to investigate his role have been quashed. As social networks have extended their influence throughout the state, professional criteria in personnel decisions have suffered. Again, the armed forces provide a stunning example of this dynamic. Before 1990, professional criteria strictly governed promotions within the military. These criteria, developed in the 1950s, linked promotions to the upper echelons of the military with academic rankings at the Escuela Superior de Guerra and previous assignment experience. Moreover, a strict calendar of rotation was built into most appointments, including that of the commander generals of the individual service branches. All of these criteria were swept aside by presidential decrees in 1991 and 1992, paving the way for appointments based on personal and political criteria. High ranking officers today may serve indefinite terms at the pleasure of the president, who officially makes the final determination. These changes allowed Fujimori to replace “institutionalist” officers with those who were personally loyal to his administration. As happened 3 See for example Enrique Obando “Fujimori and the Military: A Marriage of Convenience” NACLA: Report on the Americas , 30(1) July/August 1996. pp. 31-36. -7- with civilians, officers whose loyalty came into question or appeared to be building an independent power base were dismissed. Such was the fate of General Nicolas de Bari Hermoza, who from 1991 until 1998 was both Commander General of the Army and President of the Joint Command, and thus Peru’s most powerful military officer. Nonetheless after highly publicized disputes with Vladimiro Montesinos and efforts to rally other officers to his side in growing conflicts with the administration, particularly over the Ecuador-Peru border conflict, General Hermoza was abruptly retired. A second type of personalist network that has been used extensively during the 1990s was the technocratic. Technocrats are highly trained and specialized functionaries. Most have advanced degrees from foreign universities, particularly in the United States, with a focus on economics or finance. Throughout Latin America in the 1990s, technocrats have developed extraordinary influence in state policy making and Peru has not been an exception. Technocrats have played a central role in reorganizing the state structure and implementing economic reforms. Their ability to forge links between government politicians, international economic actors (both financial organizations and multinational corporations), and the domestic business sector have played a critical part in the successful implementation of the administrations structural reform package. Where party systems exist, the party organization can provide the core of trained personnel beyond that which exists in the civil service. Such a cadre of party technocrats is likely to have constituencies and support within the party apparatus, as well as interests that likely transcend those of the sitting president. The recruitment of technical personnel outside of a party structure accentuates the already strong links that exist between technocracy and the executive branch since technocrats are generally found in the executive branch bureaucracy. The potential for a virtual monopoly by the executive on technical expertise is a very real danger that puts other governmental branches as well as political society at a disadvantage. Unable to acquire the expertise needed to evaluate presidential policies, they must either rely on the executive to provide this information or acquiesce in the presidential monopoly on technical information. In Peru, as in most of Latin America, the legislative and judicial branches have few resources and have traditionally not developed an independent technical staff that could serve their institutions in the way the executive is served by its bureaucracy. An “information gap” between these institutions than contributes to an increase in presidential power and influence. The Fujimori administration has relied heavily on technocrats for both developing and implementing its economic reform project. Technocrats have been found at all levels of the executive, from ministers to agency staff, and have been especially important in restructuring agencies which were seen as having a strategic role in the liberalization of the economy. Not surprisingly two agencies stand out: SUNAT, the tax collecting agency whose priority was to increase tax collections and thus strengthen governmental revenue and COPRI, the agency charged with overseeing the privatization of state enterprises. Staff and managers at both agencies were notable for being highly trained professionals, predominately lawyers, accountants and economists, many with foreign degrees. In addition to providing valuable technical advice, they played a key role in forging links between the executive, international financial institutions, including multinational corporations, and the domestic business sector. This was especially true in the first (and for economic reforms, the most critical) Fujimori administrations, with figures such -8- as former Minister of Economy Carlos Boloña and informal advisor Hernando de Soto providing important international contacts and also attracting a cadre of technocratic advisors to work in the administration. The reliance by the president on technocratic networks that are directly responsible to the executive, to design and implement economic restructuring has effectively marginalized other institutions in the policy making process and in fact contributes to the perception that legal or legislative deliberation is merely an obstacle to overcome rather than an integral part of the process. The acceleration of privatization efforts in the immediate aftermath of the autogolpe highlights the virtual disdain that some technocrats had towards the process of democratic deliberation.4 B. Separation of Powers or the Arrogation of Decision Making to the Executive? Peru’s presidential system has historically been closest to the model of separate rather than connected powers. The key difference between these two models is whether or not the terms of the executive is subject to legislative powers, specifically a vote of confidence. The 1860, 1920 and 1933 Constitutions gave the Peruvian Congress the right to censure cabinet ministers, thus creating a semi-presidential system. As McClintock notes, these provisions were part of a long standing struggle between these branches, a struggle that effectively ended when the 1979 Constitution sharply limited cabinet censures (McClintock, 1994: 289-292). Despite the vulnerability of specific cabinet ministers and under certain circumstances of even the entire cabinet to censure, the President’s term is not affected. In general, the 1979 Constitution ushered in a period of growing presidential power and influence. In part this resulted from the substantial majorities Presidents Fernando Belaúnde (1980-85) and Alan García (1985-90) enjoyed in the Congress. Both presidents extensively used their legislative decree powers, duly granted to them by the Congress. Over 50 percent of the laws passed during the Belaúnde administration and 60 percent of the laws passed during the García administration were legislative decrees issued by the executive(Planas, 1999: 120). In addition, no ministers were censured and few were called by the Congress for interrogation. Important policies were usually initiated by the executive, without prior communication or coordination with party officials or congressional allies. The most egregious example of this dynamic was the 1987 bank nationalization by President García, a plan that was developed by a small circle of advisors and launched with little outside input, that dominated the political agenda of the country for two years. Both presidents were known for their highly personalist style of governance. While Belaunde focused on personally overseeing and inaugurating public works projects throughout the country, Garcia was most noted for his “balconazos”, fiery speeches delivered from the balcony of the presidential palace to crowds of loyal APRA followers. Garcia’s government was often referred to as simply “Alanista” emphasizing the personal character of the administration. The trend of the 1980s towards greater presidential power accelerated dramatically in the 1990s under President Fujimori and the 1993 Constitution. The power of the presidency increased both within the executive branch itself as well as over the Congress and Courts. The key event in 4 This was made clearest to me in an interview with a COPRI official on July 26, 1996 who gleefully recounted how easier and much more “efficient” his work was after the autogolpe. -9- reshaping these relations was the 1992 “autogolpe” or self-coup. While most analyses note the important role disputes between President Fujimori and Congress played in bringing about the coup, few suggest this was the primary cause.5 Although Fujimori, unlike his two predecessors lacked a majority in Congress, he was nonetheless able to get most of his major policy initiatives approved as well as winning legislative decree power on a number of issues. Under international pressure, including the threat of possible sanctions from the United States, a Constituent Assembly was quickly elected and set about the task of writing a new constitution. Seizing the advantage of high public approval ratings, a disorganized political opposition and the overwhelming dominance of pro-Fujimori representatives in the Assembly, the administration pushed through a constitutional blueprint that was heavily tilted in favor of presidential power. This tilt is especially notable in executive-legislative relations. Under the 1993 Constitution, Congress is smaller, has even fewer clear checks on Presidential power than in the 1979 Constitution and is more vulnerable to the threat of dissolution. The 1993 Constitution created a unicameral legislature of 120 members compared to the 240 member bicameral legislature under the 1979 Constitution. Moreover, all members are elected on national lists, which applied only to Senate members in the 1979 Constitution. The practical impact of these changes are obvious. As Fernando Tuesta has pointed out, the Peruvian Congress is one of the smallest in the world and only comparable to those of much smaller countries (Tuesta, 1996: 137). The smaller Congress is also less representative of national opinion, insofar as not all parties or departments are guaranteed representation. The result is a high level of “disproportionality”, whereby the actual percentages of votes by parties or region are not reflected in the apportionment of representatives. Moreover, the lack of a geographically fixed constituency, significantly weakens representative legitimacy by making legislators more vulnerable to national public opinion and tying their electoral fate to that of the president. The smaller size and thus reduced representativeness of Congress was accompanied by new limitations in checks on the president. Among the most important policy checks on executives in a presidential system are legislative approval for international treaties and high-level diplomatic and military promotions. Although the wide majorities enjoyed by the García and Belaúnde governments meant that no significant treaties or promotions were rejected, the process allowed Congress to question candidates and provided opposition parties the opportunity to expound their alternatives. The 1993 Constitution eliminates this requirement, freeing the president to make and ratify treaties in a series of policy arenas (Article 56) and to designate ambassadorial and military appointments without congressional approval. The presidential veto and congressional ability to overide it, is a classic type of mutual check in presidential systems. Article 108 of the 1993 Constitution maintains the right of presidents to observar congressional laws, a veto mechanism that existed in the 1979 Constitution. If the president does not promulgate a law with 15 days of congressional passage, 5 The most notable analysis of presidential-legislative dispute as the source of the autogolpe is found in Charles Kenney, “Por que el autogolpe? Fujimori y el Congreso, 1990-92" in Fernando Tuesta Soldevilla ed. Los Enigmas del Poder: Fujimori 1990-1996. Lima: Fundacion Friedrich Ebert, 1997. Most analyses stress factors such as the socioeconomic context, military politics or the authoritarian disposition of Fujimori and his supporters. -10- the law expires. Congress may than promulgate it with the votes of 51% of its members. The only difference in this regard between the 1979 and 1993 Constitutions is that the current Constitution allows the President to partially promulgate a law, in what amounts to a rough equivalent of a “line-item veto” in the US system (Chirinos Soto, 1995: 187-191). As legal observers in the US have noted, such partial vetos enhance the power of executives, allowing him to pick and choose which aspects of the law he finds palatable. In the Peruvian context, the majorities favorable to the President and the fact that most laws originated in presidential decrees, made the use of presidential observaciones exceedingly rare. Nonetheless a new line-item veto is yet another concession to presidential power. In the area of economic policy making, the new constitution retains the limited role of the Congress in developing and administering the nations finances and budget. Article 211 of the 1979 Constitution clearly gave this authority to the President. The Congress may discuss, debate and finally vote on the budget, but it cannot substantially alter spending proposals, the initiation of which remains an executive prerogative. The 1993 Constitution continues this tradition. If anything the restriction is reenforced in Article 79 by requiring the prior approval of all tax laws by the Ministry of Economics and Finance. A persistent problem facing the Congress in this area has been the lack of independent economic or budgetary information. Congress does not have its own budgetary research staff and as a result, members receive their information from the executive branch, the media or private research institutes. The Congress does not have any specific investigatory powers and it’s ability to remove officials is similarly limited. Ministers can be interrogated by Congress on policy and as mentioned earlier, cabinet censure is a prerogative of Congress. In some ways censure appears to be a legislative “check” on presidential power. However, the censure of a minister or even an entire cabinet does not affect the President, whose extensive policy making and implementing powers remain unaffected. Moreover, censure carries inherent dangers for the Congress. Under the 1979 Constitution three cabinet censures by the Congress allowed the President to close the Congress for new elections. Under the new Constitution, the President can dissolve the Congress after only two cabinet censures. Moreover, unlike the older censure mechanism which restricted the President to proceeding with only one congressional dissolution per term, the 1993 Constitution allows the President to dissolve Congress an unlimited number of times and provides that the President can govern through “decrees of urgency” until a new Congress is elected, leading some analysts to suggest that this provides an incentive for a President to provoke crises with an uncooperative Congress (Bernales, 1995:102-3). Despite limited investigatory powers and few resources, Peru’s Congress in the 1980s did appoint a number of multiparty investigative commissions, primarily in the area of human rights violations, that resulted from public pressure and were critical of executive actions. These included investigations of paramilitary activities and the 1986 prison massacre. The 1990s witnessed no such investigations, despite calls from the media and opposition legislators to appoint such commissions to examine accusations of corruption, drugtrafficking and human rights violations carried out by executive branch officials. In dealing with abuses of power or accusations of malfeasance, Peru’s Constitution does not have an “impeachment” clause. The closest mechanism is the “antejuicio” in which officials from all three branches can be stripped of their immunity from office if they are found to have committed malfeasance in office. Unlike -11- impeachment in the United States, an antejuicio does not cover violations of the constitution or abuse of power, but is restricted to specific criminal conduct (Paniagua: 1995: 127-129). A final area where legislative authority has been limited further is in the area of legislative decree power. The 1979 gave the Congress the power to cede law-making authority on specific issues for a set time period to the President, a power that Belaúnde and García used extensively. Article 104 of the 1993 Constitution continues this tradition and only requires that the President inform the Congress of such decrees when they are issued. The new constitution also creates a new category of decrees that are considered “urgent” and can thus be put into place without prior congressional authorization (Fernandez Segado, 1994: 38-40). The judiciary in Peru has historically been the branch most susceptible to political manipulation and domination by the president and as a result offering few effective checks on presidential power.6 After dismissing most of the country’s judges, including members of the Supreme Court during the 1992 autogolpe, President Fujimori promised wide ranging reforms to deal with a judiciary that was largely viewed as corrupt and inefficient. Many of these reforms, such as elected justices of the peace and a new ombudsman office (defensoria del pueblo) have been promising, however they have not fundamentally altered the reality of a system that remains highly vulnerable to executive manipulation. Two important bodies within the judicial system that have the potential to check presidential power are the National Council of Magistrates, which directs the selection of judges, and the Tribunal of Constitutional Guarantees, which reviews the constitutionality of laws. Both institutions have been subject to political pressures by the executive, seriously compromising the idea of judicial independence. Up to four of the seven members of the National Council can be from outside the judicial system and even the field of law, opening the way for purely political appointments, which has been the practice of the administration (Fernandez Segado, 1994: 53). Moreover, the appointment of an executive “reorganization” commission in 1996, headed by former Admiral Jose Dellepiane, effectively took control of the National Council’s functions, by purging and appointing a new series of justices throughout the system. Executive intervention in the Tribunal of Constitutional Guarantees was even more egregious. Members of the Tribunal are elected by Congress and can also be removed by Congress. In 1997 three members of the Tribunal were removed, at the behest of pro-Fujimori legislators, by Congress for having voted against the possibility of a presidential reelection. With the appointment of more clear-cut Fujimori loyalists, the Tribunal has issued rulings that are consistently on the side of the executive (Planas, 1999: 215). Executive efforts to influence judicial decision making and thus undermine judicial independence have occurred largely where either administration officials have been accused of corruption or where investigations of human rights abuses have threatened to undermine the administration’s counter-insurgency campaign. Judges and prosecutors have been pressured to end investigations and the outright dismissal of investigators has been a common occurrence. When serious allegations of corruption involving drug-trafficking against presidential advisor 6 The most comprehensive examination of the judicial system and reform efforts in English is Lynn Hammergren, The Politics of Justice and Justice Reform in Latin America: The Peruvian Case in Comparative Perspective. (Boulder: Westview Press, 1998). -12- Vladimiro Montesinos surfaced during the trial of one of Peru’s most notorious drug kingpins, prosecutors suppressed possible evidence and refused to allow further questioning.7 The most notorious interventions in judicial processes have involved human rights abuses. As evidence mounted in 1995 that security forces were involved in the killings of students and professors at La Cantuta University, the Congress at the behest of the President passed a blanket amnesty law for all military officers involved in human rights abuses. In a further limit on judicial independence, trials for terrorist suspects are carried out by special military tribunals, over which no civilian court has jurisdiction. During these trials, cross examinations were not allowed, evidence was not shared with defense attorneys and sentences could only be appealed once to a higher military court. Most trials lasted only a few minutes, the minimum guilty sentence was thirty years and the conviction rate of those accused was an astounding 97 percent.8 Needless to say, these procedures are a fundamental violation of due process. Although most of the laws allowing these trials have been suspended, their past use demonstrate the vulnerability of judicial independence to arbitrary executive authority. A final element in highlighting the lack of checks and balances within the governmental structure of Peru in the 1990s is the growing power and authority of the executive itself. As noted earlier, the presidency has traditionally dominated the policy process, particularly through the use of legislative decrees. During the Fujimori administration, this dominance has been enhanced by an expansion in the size and scope of the executive bureaucracy. In 1992 the administration created the Ministry of the Presidency, which concentrates previously scattered executive offices under one cabinet-level ministry. From it’s creation until 1995, it’s budget expanded nine-fold.9 The Ministry concentrates control over all spending on infrastructure projects, from road building to school construction, as well as most social programs. A significant part of the Ministry’s budget goes to the latter, particularly a series of new social programs designed and implemented during Fujimori’s first term in office. These included the National Development and Social Compensation Fund (FONCODES), the National Housing Fund (FONAVI) and the National Nutritional Assistance Program (PRONAA). In addition, the Ministry took control of previously existing programs, most notably the Glass of Milk program which was created and run by municipalities until 1996. Funding for these programs initially came from profits derived from privatizations and had the support of international aid agencies. Nonetheless, the implementation of these programs have usually been carried out in ways that advance the president’s political interests. Not surprisingly, billboards announcing the benefits of these programs are painted in bright orange, the same color used by Fujimori’s electoral vehicle, Cambio 90. 7 “Acusacion: La denunuca de Vaticano” Caretas. August 22, 1996. pp. 16-19. 8 A good summary of the rules behind these procedures is found in Rodolfo Gamarra, Terrorismo: tratamiento juridico. (Lima: Innstituto de Defensa Legal, 1995). 9 Bruce Kay, “Fujipopulism and the Liberal State in Peru, 1990-1995" Journal of InterAmerican Studies and World Affairs 38(4), Winter 1996. p. 83; Also see Marcial Rubio, “Ministerio del Presidencialismo” Cuestion de Estado, 1(2), 1993. P. 23. -13- C. Reversing Decentralization: The End of Local Autonomy and Governance. Peru has traditionally had a highly centralized political system, a legacy of Spanish colonialism during which Lima was a viceroyal capital. Unlike many of it’s neighbors, the issue of federalism has never been salient in Peruvian politics. Centralization was a key feature of the political system throughout the 19th and 20th centuries, although local caciques had considerable autonomy and used their economic and social dominance to not only perpetuate themselves in power, but on occasion to resist efforts by national actors to impose their authority.10 Without a system of local governments, Peru historically lacked an important check on executive power: a legitimate set of regional institutions that could initiate and implement policies independent of the national executive. One of the most promising features of the 1979 Constitution was the promise of regionalization. For the first time in Peru’s history, the Constitution mandated a federal-like system of regional governments with control of local development issues, extending the first steps toward local autonomy taken in the 1960s with the election of mayors. Although the Belaúnde administration did not actively develop plans to implement this mandate, the García administration put into place a scheme that divided the country into twelve regions, each with a regional assembly that would have substantial powers to legislate and control local finances (McClintock, 1994: 293). The movement towards decentralization was to prove short-lived, as the Fujimori administration moved quickly to end regionalization. As a result of the 1992 autogolpe, the regional assemblies were closed down. In their place, President Fujimori established Transitional Councils of Regional Administration (CTAR) whose members are designated by the President and which are dependent on the Ministry of the Presidency. The CTAR’s were meant to be transitional bodies leading to the creation of permanent and locally elected councils. The promise of such councils was held out in Articles 188-190 of the 1993 Constitution, but as of 1999 they had yet to be created. Instead, the CTAR’s and presidentially designated “regional presidents” remain the only form of local governance. The limits to any future development of regional autonomy are made clear in Article 199 of the Constitution which explicitly states that both regions and municipalities “must report their budgets to the Controlaria General de la Republica. They are regulated by law” (my translation). The effect of this article is to make all local governments responsible to the central government, and specifically the executive branch. With regional governments reduced to mere implementors of presidential policies, it’s not surprising that municipal powers have also been severely reduced. During much of the 1980s, municipalities developed considerable policy autonomy. Some municipalities, particularly those controlled by the Left in and around Lima, developed innovative programs to deal with housing, nutrition and education needs. Among these initiatives was the Glass of Milk Program, started by Mayor Alfonso Barrantes in Lima in 1984. The purpose of the program was to guarantee one glass of milk to needy children in the city. The program’s success led to it’s being copied around the country and it quickly became a showcase for the Left’s political agenda. Not surprisingly, the 10 A good example of these historic complexities is found in the analysis of the south and central Andes offered by Nelson Manrique, Yawar Mayu: Sociedades terratenientes serranas: 1879-1910. Lima: DESCO, 1988. -14- ability to develop policy initiatives made mayoral positions an important springboard to national politics, as well as a political and policy competitor to the executive branch. Municipal initiative, which allowed the opposition an important organizational as well as policy forum, became a major target of the Fujimori administration’s effort to define and dominate the country’s political agenda. During the first six years of the administration, 49 decrees were issued by the presidency intended to eliminate or curtail municipal powers, from tax powers to regulation of bus routes.11 Decree Law 776 issued in 1993, eliminates the ability of municipalities to raise revenue by taxation and provides that all municipal revenue comes from a Municipal Compensation Fund (FCM) whose criteria regarding the distribution of funds is determined by executive decree laws and the Ministry of Economy and Finance, in effect making municipalities fiscally dependent on the executive branch (Planas, 1999: 311). Continuing with the trend of reducing municipal prerogatives, an executive decree was issued in 1996 transferring authority over the Glass of Milk program from municipalities to the Ministry of the Presidency and thus effectively eliminating the possibility of municipalities to initiate social welfare policies. As many countries in Latin America during the 1990s were moving towards greater decentralization (Colombia, Mexico, El Salvador) as part of broadening democratization, Peru was moving decisively in the opposite direction. III. The Presidency Under Fujimori and Beyond In this paper, three institutional checks on presidential power under modern liberal democracy have been outlined: mutual checks under separation of powers, a decentralized governmental structure and a political party system. A review of the operation of these institutional checks on presidential power in Peru in the 1990s suggests that they are either not part of the institutional structure of Peru’s political system or have been rendered inoperable by the political practices of President Fujimori and his followers. Although President Fujimori has played a significant part in limiting such institutional checks, it is also clear that political elites in Peru also bear some responsibility. As I argued elsewhere (Mauceri, 1997), the 1980 “transition to democracy” put into place a weak institutional foundation for democracy. The Left and popular movement of the 1970s opted to pursue radical change through social actions (strikes, protests, demonstrations) rather than institution building. This was partly a result of exclusion, but also a political choice, given it’s general disdain and undervaluation of institutions. Conservative elements which dominated the transition and the first Belaúnde administration continued to rely on clientelistic practices and did little to change the strong centralized and authoritarian character of Peru’s political order. If we add to this mixture a rigid party elite structure, unable to introduce internal mechanisms of democratization that could produce leadership circulation, we have a reasonable understanding of why the political order created out of the 1979 Constitution would not produce an institutional structure that would provide incentives for democratic behaviors among key political actors. Both the institutional structure created by the 1979 Constitution and the behavior of political actors, reduced the possibilities of maintaining let alone expanding democracy under 11 “En suma muchas restas” Caretas January 16, 1997, p. 10. -15- this framework. When President Fujimori attacked the inefficiency and unrepresentative character of Peru’s institutions, he was merely tapping into the general perception of most Peruvians. In short, the “political decay” of Peru’s democratic institutions in the 1980s paved the way for the authoritarian presidency of the 1990s. Democratization cannot take place without an institutional structure that provides incentives for political actors to engage in democratic behaviors. However, institutional structures are themselves the result of complex historical and cultural legacies, not all of which may be compatible with democratic norms. In the case of Peru, such legacies includes racism, economic inequality, political and economic centralization, authoritarian and clientelistic behaviors by elites, the lack of a culture of accountability and the belief in concentrated political power as the ultimate agent of social change. The dilemma for those interested in deepening democratization is in not only recognizing the importance of institutional structures in shaping behavior, but in developing creative institutional arrangements that can overcome, or at least minimize, past choices and legacies that have impeded democratization thus far. This is clearly not an easily accomplished task. It is highly improbable that the institutional environment created during the Fujimori presidency can be significantly altered while President Fujimori remains in office. The dynamic outlined in this paper suggests a combination of severe institutional limits on change and a determined political willingness on the part of the President and his supporters to maintain the status quo. Such change is therefore likely to come only with the end of the Fujimori administration. It would be mere speculation on how such an end might occur–death, violence (coup, rebellions etc...) or electoral defeat. If democratic reforms are a part of the post-Fujimori political scene, than limiting the scope and reach of presidential powers, as they have evolved in the 1980s and 1990s should be an integral part of this effort. Given that the 1992 Constitution has become so closely identified with the Fujimori administration, there is a strong likelihood of it being significantly altered if not simply scrapped in the post-Fujimori era. However such reforms emerge, they obviously need to focus on strengthening the checks on the presidency outlined in this paper and might include the following: Increased Mutual Institutional Checks: -Restoring congressional ratification powers on treaties. -Restoring congressional approval of senior diplomatic and military appointments. -Creating an independent technical research organization responsible to the congress. -Providing Congress with more detailed powers over the budgetary process. -Expanding the formal investigatory powers of Congress. -Severely limiting presidential decree powers and eliminating “decrees of urgency”. -Expanding the size of the Congress and electoral reforms to ensure each region representation. -Increased technical and financial support for the judiciary. -Increasing the professionalization of the National Council of Magistrates. -Significantly reducing the ability of Congress to remove members of the Constitutional Tribunal or of the Executive to “intervene” the judiciary. -Restrictions on the use of military tribunals. -16- Implementation of Decentralization: -Restoration of elected Regional Assemblies and Presidents. -Independent and autonomous sources of revenue for regional and municipal governments. -Clearly established policy arenas for local governments. -Specific restrictions on national governments ability to intervene in regional or municipal affairs. Creating a Reformed Political Party System: -Internal democratic reforms of party structures, allowing for elite circulation and responsiveness to voters, including primary-like elections. -Oversight of party finances. -Regulation of party access to media, particularly television. -Incentives for the creation of nationally organized party structures. While this is far from an exhaustive listing of the reforms needed to strengthen institutional mechanisms that check presidential power, it points towards the type of reforms needed. Although the likelihood of these reforms being adopted in the near future are minimal, progress towards a more democratic institutional structure cannot take place without creative craftmanship. -17- BIBLIOGRAPHY Camp, Roderic. Politics in Mexico. 2nd Edition. New York: Oxford University Press, 1996. Chirinos Soto, Constitución de 1993: Lectura y Comentario. 2nd Edition. Lima: Nerman S.A. 1995. Dealy, Glen. “Prolegomena on the Spanish American Political Tradition” in Howard Wiarda, Politics and Social Change in Latin America: The Distinct Tradition. 2nd Edition. Cambridge: University of Massachusetts Press, 1982. Pp. 163-176. Fernández Segado, Francisco. “El nuevo ordenamiento constitucional del Perú: Aproximación a la Constitución de 1993" in Comisión Andina de Juristas, La Constitución de 1993: analisis y comentarios I. Lima: CAJ, 1994. pp. 11-65. Lijphart, Arend. “Constitutional Choices for New Democracies” Journal of Democracy. Winter 1991. Linz, Juan & Arturo Valenzuela, The Failure of Presidential Democracy: Comparative Perspectives. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University. 1994. Mainwaring, Scott. “Presidentialism, Multipartism and Democracy: The Difficult Combination” Comparative Political Studies. 26(2), 1993. Pp. 198-228. Mauceri, Philip. “The Transition to ‘Democracy’ and the Failures of Institution Building” in Maxwell Cameron & Philip Mauceri eds. The Peruvian Labyrinth: Polity, Society, Economy. University Park: Penn State Uniuversity Press, 1997. Pp. 13-36. McClintock, Cynthia. “Presidents Messiahs, and Constitutional Breakdowns in Peru” in Juan Linz & Arturo Valenzuela eds. The Failure of Presidential Democracy: The Case of Latin America. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1994. pp. 286-321. Neustadt, Richard. Presidential Power. New York: Wiley, 1960. Paniagua, Valentín. “Acusación Constitucional, antejuicio o juicio político?” in Comisión Andina de Juristas, La Constitución de 1993: analisis y comentarios II . Lima: CAJ, 1995.pp. 125138. Planas, Pedro. El Fujimorato: Estudio Politico Constitucional. Lima: NP, 1999. O”Donnell, Guillermo. “Delegative Democracy” Journal of Democracy, 5(1). January 1994. Shugart Matthew & John Carey. Presidents and Assemblies: Constitutional Design and Electoral Dynamics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992. Stepan, Alfred & Cindy Skach, “Constitutional Frameworks and Democratic Consolidation: Parlamentarism versus Presidentialism” World Politics. October 1993, pp. 1-22. Tuesta Soldevilla, Fernando. “El sistema electoral peruano: sus efectos en el sistema politico” in Fernado Tuesta Soldevilla ed. Simposio Sobre Reforma Electoral: Memoria. Lima: IFES, 1996. pp. 125-162. -18-