IEU Lehrstuhl für Industrie, Energie und Umwelt International Industrial Management I Location Decisions I | Introduction | Examples | Check List | | Steiner-Weber Model| Universität Wien Fakultät für Wirtschaftswissenschaften Lehrstuhl für Industrie, Energie und Umwelt Brünner Straße 72, 1210 Wien IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Overview | Location Decisions F Choice of locations F F F F Introduction A class of locational choice problems Factors for locations Methods F F F F F F F Check lists Benefit analysis (simple, additive) Location break-even analysis Transportation method Steiner-Weber Model Location-alloction Model of Cooper and extensions Hotelling Model F Choice of locations with the firm F The basic problem F CRAFT F Layouts | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 2 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Location Decisions - Objective Choose the location that maximizes the firm’s benefit There are only three important things concerning locations: 1) Location, 2) Location, 3) Location. | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 3 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Location Decisions F Importance: Location decisions do not only result in real estate and investment costs but influence in particular fixed and variable costs. F Transportation costs F rentals F Wages F Taxes, etc. F Links to the environment (universities, clusters, etc.) | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 4 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Example: Automobile Industry I Source: Dyer, J.H.,Dedicated Assets: Japan‘s Manufacturing Edge , Harvard Business Review, Nov.‐Dec., 1994, S.174ff. | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 5 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Example: Automobile Industry II Source: Dyer, J.H.,Dedicated Assets: Japan‘s Manufacturing Edge , Harvard Business Review, Nov.‐Dec., 1994, S.174ff. | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 6 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Example: Automobile Industry III Comparing locations of production and organizational units of the automobile industry in Japan and the US (Dyer, 1994) finds and argues the following: F Thesis: The huge success of the Japanese car industry is to a large extent due to the close relations with its suppliers and in particular the geographical vicinity. F There exist large differences concerning the average distance between locations of Japanese and American car manufacturers. In particular, the entire ring of Toyota and its suppliers fits between two GM locations. F Inventory as a share of turnover is much larger at US car producers which implies more bound capital. These distances in turn make it hard to implement Just-in-Time Management (see later), which further increases inventory costs. | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 7 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Example: Automobile Industry IV F Closeness implies much better contacts between relevant people and organizations (including suppliers). It is a grave misunderstanding that personal contacts become redundant once an industry can actually choose its supply in aglobally integrated world by a mouse click; remember this for the following discussion about clusters. F If GM had a similar ratio between inventory and sales it would save US$ 6 billions which amounts to annula cost saving of the order between US$ 400 – 500 Millions depending on costs of capital ranging between 6% to 8%. | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 8 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Introductory Example Assumptions: Procurement centered around Dortmund. Volume = 1.500 t and transport cost are 1 MU per t and km. Demand in Munich, Volume = 1000 t, transport cost are 1.2 MU per t and km. Table: Example of a location decision l Feasible locations Distance from procurement center Transport costs (in 1000 MU) Distance to center of demand Transport costs Sums (in 1000 MU) Aachen 150 (150*1500*1)= 225 650 (650*1000*1,2)= 780 1005= 4th rank Braunschweig 270 405 625 750 1155= 6th rank Dortmund 10 15 650 780 795= 1st rank Erfurt 420 630 380 456 1086= 5th rank Munich 650 975 10 12 987= 3rd rank Nürnberg 480 720 170 204 904= 2nd rank | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 9 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Interdependences Produktionsprogramm *: Optimierungsproblem Ertrag Produktpreise Externe Transportkosten Profitability of a firm for a given configuratio n of locations Aufwand Innentransportkosten Sonstige aufwandsgleiche Kosten + (Aufwand≠Kosten) Transportwege Transportmenge n Innerbetriebliche Standorte* Transportmengen Löhne, Steuern usw. Investitionsprogramm Kapitaleinsatz Investitionsausgaben je Projekt * Optimization problem Source: Lüder, p.31 | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 10 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Mathematical Formulation of Location Decisions I F Assumptions (given): F A set of locations: S = {s j ; j = 1, K , n } F A set of organisational units: B = {bi ; i = 1, K , m } F Location of the organisational units: s (bi ) = s j ∈ S F Objective: F A mapping that assigns to each unit bi a location from the set S: ∑:B → S bi → s (bi ) ⊂ S | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 11 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Mathematical Formulation of Location Decisions II F Further assumptions: F O is the set of given locations that are connected to locations bi e.g. customers: O = {o p , p = 1, K , r } F The sets O, S and B are independent (in practice however there are many interdependencies and feedbacks). F Further constraints such as those on capacity. F Objective: Z = f [s (b1 ), s (b2 ), K , s (bm )] F Maximize/Minimize F e.g. the locations of the organizational units are chosen in order to minimize the transport costs. F e.g. the (incremental) benefit from the choice of a particular location or locations should be maximized. | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 12 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Examples of Constraints Organizational units that must be close to the market F Public F Police, ambulance, fire brigade F post F Retail and Services F Fast food, gas stations, super markets F Pharmacies, shopping malls. F Services F M.D., lawyers, barbers F Banks (?), mechanics, hotels | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 13 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Evaluation of Locations F Methods F Check lists F (Cost-) Benefit analysis F Location Break-Even Analysis F Transportation Method F Steiner-Weber Model F Location-Alloction Model von Cooper F Hotelling | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 14 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Factors Crucial for Locations Arthur Anderson Deloitte Touche F Market size F Availability of qualified labor F Expected profits F Reserach institutes F Openess of markets F Quality of life F Stability F Venture-Capital F Costs F bureaucracy F Labour (quality and work ethics) F Infrastructure F Technological know how F Labor costs F Technology F IT-Infrastructure F Bureaucracy F Suppliers & partners F Subsidies F Resources, primary inputs | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 15 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Match Product & Country 1. Braun Household Appliances 2. Firestone Tires 3. Godiva Chocolate 4. Haagen-Dazs Ice Cream 5. Jaguar Autos 6. MGM Movies 7. Lamborghini Autos 8. Alpo Petfoods | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. Great Britain Germany Japan United States Switzerland India Italy Denmark Page 16 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Match Product & Country 1. Braun Household Appliances 2. Firestone Tires 3. Godiva Chocolate 4. Haagen-Dazs Ice Cream 5. Jaguar Autos 6. MGM Movies 7. Lamborghini Autos 8. Alpo Petfoods 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. Great Britain Germany Japan United States Switzerland India | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 17 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | A Few International Comparisons FProductivity FGrowth FCountries FCities FEconomic liberty FCorruption | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 18 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Growth Competitiveness Index: 2006-2007 | Top 20 Source: World Economic Forum | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 19 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Growth Competitiveness Index: 2006-2007 | Rank > 100 Growth Competitiveness Index – 2006-2007, Rank >100 Source: World Economic Forum | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 20 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Business Competitiveness Index: 2006-2007 | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 21 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Business Competitiveness | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 22 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Productivity by Sectors Martin Neil Baily und Robert M. Solow, International Productivity Comparisons Built from the Firm Level, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15/3, 151-172, 2001. | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 23 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Labor Productivity and Wages | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 24 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | International Labor Costs in Automobile Industry (in €/h) n A pa Ja ia S. U. l st r ga Au rtu en ai n Po Sp ed UK Sw Th e Ne th e r la n B e ds l gi um ly Ita ce an Fr Ge rm an y € 50.00 42.29 36.61 35.52 31.46 31.66 30.71 34.51 € 40.00 28.94 24.68 23.95 21.99 € 30.00 12.06 € 20.00 € 10.00 € 0.00 | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 25 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Corruption F 5 Best: F F F F F Finland USA Canada Singapur Australia F Corruption index: FFinland FDenmark / New Zealand FCanada FUK FUSA FGermany / Israel FJapan FItaly FChina FEgypt FIndia / Russia FNigeria FBangladesh F 5 Worst: 9,7 9,5 9,0 8,7 7,7 7,3 7,1 5,2 3,5 3,4 2,7 1,6 1,2 FBangladesh FParaguay FNicaragua FNigeria FZimbabwe 10 = No corruption | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 26 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Economic Freedom I | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 27 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Economic Freedom II | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 28 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Economic Freedom - Graphical HONG KONG keeps its top position in the Economic Freedom Index compiled by the Fraser Institute, a Canadian think-tank. The index ranks the policies of 141 countries according to how much they encourage free trade, both internally and with other territories. Countries with fewer taxes, strong property rights, low regulation and sound money score best. Britain and America tie with Canada for fifth place in the list. Germany is ranked 18th—on a par with El Salvador but above Japan. Most of the lowranking countries are African, except Myanmar and Venezuela, which are both in the bottom ten. | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 29 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Ranking of Cities Citiy 2006 2005 1990 Index2006 London 1 1 1 0,91 París 2 2 2 0,59 Frankfurt 3 3 3 0,36 Barcelona 4 5 11 0,27 Brussels 5 4 4 0,24 Amsterdam 6 6 5 0,23 Madrid 7 7 17 0,20 Berlín 8 8 15 0,18 Munich 9 9 12 0,18 Zurich 10 10 7 0,16 Source: European Cities Monitor 2006: | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 30 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Another Ranking of Cities London and Paris maintain their position as Europe's two top cities to locate a business Warsaw can expect the biggest influx of international companies over the next five years. Barcelona is also the city perceived as doing the most in Europe to improve itself as a business location, followed by Prague and Madrid | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 31 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Hardship Rating | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 32 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Austria (WIFO) Advantages Disadvantages Part of the common market Bureaucracy Active in Eastern Europe Duration until receiving operating permits Availability of high quality labor Costs of telecomm (not any more!) Availability of highly qualified labor High costs for unskilled labor Consensus seeking society Environmental regulations Rule of law Lack of venture capital Environmental quality Little competition in energy markets Cultural and leisure activities Lack of reforms (and willingness to reform) Public safety Public administration Political stability (?) Energy costs | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 33 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Austria (US-Investor Confidence Study) Advatantages Disadvatantages Knowledge of foreign languages Tax deductions of investments Access to Eastern European markets Real estate prices Sales in Austria Cost of living Qualifications and effort (of labor) Operating permit (length) Transport Labor permits for Non-EU residents Culture and leisure activities Opening hours Political stability Income taxes Social peace Labor laws Costs of electricity Wages, payroll taxes and other ancillary labor costs | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 34 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Topical (Economist, 2008): Eastern Europe vs Asia • As in the previous five years, economies in eastern Europe and Central Asia have consistently seen the fastest pace of positive reform. • On average, it takes 21 days to register a business in eastern Europe, which is 27 days faster than in East Asia. Setting up a company in Indonesia costs 77.9% of the average annual income per person; in Georgia it costs 4%—though there is the small matter of political risk to factor in. Firing a worker costs an average of 53 weeks’ salary in East Asia, compared with 27 in eastern Europe. All this cutting of red tape has brought results: Poland now has as many registered businesses relative to its population as Hong Kong does. • Eastern Europe’s rapid progress due to the accession requirements imposed by the European Union (EU), e.g., the EU requires new members to create a “one-stop shop”. Before Macedonia became a candidate for EU membership in 2005, it took 48 days to start a business there. After three years of reforms, it now takes nine days. • East Asian countries still have the edge in some respects: it is easier to move goods across their borders, for example. Businesses in East Asia also face lower taxes. Taxes on profits in eastern Europe are among the lowest in the world, typically around 10%, but labour taxes and compulsory pension contributions increase the overall tax burden on business. • Of course, a few East Asian economies are still miles ahead of eastern Europe. Singapore 1st, Hong Kong 4th but Georgia, Estonia, Lithuania and Latvia in the top 30, Russia = 120th and Azerbaijan was the top reformer. | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 35 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | (Cost-) Benefit Analysis - Additive Four steps: 1. Scaling: Evaluation via scale (say 1 – 10) the benefits of location with respect to a particular factor which allows to rank and evaluate also qualitative factors. 2. Weighting: Assign weights {gi} to each individual factor entering the analysis and to differentiate between important and less important ones. 3. Aggregate: Multiply points the scale in (1) with the weights in (2) and add up which gives the measure of benefit associated with a particular location: N(sj) = n1j*g1 + n2j*g2 + ..... 4. Choose the location with the highest benefit = highest value of N. | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 36 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | A Simple Example Labor Sales Subsidies Locations s1 7 2 1 s2 5 1 9 s3 10 4 6 s4 Weights 5 7 8 0.3 0.5 0.2 N(s1) = 7*0,3 + 2*0,5 + 1*0,2 = 3,3 N(s2) = 5*0,3 + 1*0,5 + 9*0,2 = 3,8 N(s3) = 10*0,3 + 4*0,5 + 6*0,2 = 6,2 N(s4) = 5*0,3 + 7*0,5 + 8*0,2 = 6,6 Therefore, location 4 should be chosen. Extension: Multi-criteria optimization (or decision making) | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 37 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Check Lists F Precise evaluation of the benefits associated with each factor. F Similarly to the the above benefits analysis – hierarchical | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 38 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Benefit Analysis F Weights allow to mitigate for outliers F Ranking without weights: C–B–A-D F Ranking with weights: A–C–D–B | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 39 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Location Break-Even Analysis I F Comparison of the costs at different locations depending on the rate of utilization. F Example F F F F Production of a new Volkswagen model. 3 potential locations with their respective costs Assume a sales price Profit: Standort Poznan Pamplona Wolfsburg Fixe Kosten € 3.000.000 € 6.000.000 € 11.000.000 Variable Kosten € 7.500,00 € 4.500,00 € 2.500,00 | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Verkaufspreis € 12.000,00 Standort Poznan Pamplona Wolfsburg E(Menge) 2.000 Gesamtkosten* Gewinn* € 18.000.000 € 6.000.000 € 15.000.000 € 9.000.000 € 16.000.000 € 8.000.000 * bei einer Menge von 2.000 Stk. Page 40 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Location Break-Even Analysis II 1. Given a fixed quantity of 2000 pieces Pamplona yields the highest profits. 2. Since the assumption of 2000 pieces depends on a marketing study it is unreliable. Therefore, the management wants to know whether Pamplona remains the most profitable with less or higher production. F Location Break-Even Analysis F This procedure calculates the intersections of the cost curves associated with the different locations depending on the rate of production. F This yields capacity bounds where which location is efficient as well as the minimal costs over all locations contingent on production. | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 41 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Location Break-Even Analysis III F Depending on production, different locations turn out to be the most profitable ones: 22.000.000 Poznan Pamplona Gesamtkosten 19.000.000 16.000.000 Wolfsburg 13.000.000 10.000.000 7.000.000 4.000.000 Poznan Pamplona Wolfsburg 1.000.000 0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 Menge (Stk.) | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 42 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Sequential (Hierarchical) Location Decisions I 1) Countries 2) Regions 3) Final location | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 43 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Sequential (Hierarchical) Location Decisions II Countries 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. Political risks, regulation, incentives. Cultural and economical. Location relative to markets (sales and procurement). Labor: availability, productivity, costs, behavior. Availability of suppliers, communication, energy. Exchange rates and their risks. Regions 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. Specifics views and demands of the firm. Atractiveness of region (culture, climate, taxes, etc.) Labor: availability, productivity, costs, unions. Availability and costs of materials. Environmental regulation at federal and city level. Incentives (by regions, cities). Availability and distance to primary inputs. Costs for real estates and construction. Specific location 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. Location specific costs contingent on the size of the unit. Air, rail, road and water transport networks. Zoning, in particular restrictions. Availability and distance to suppliers and service providers. Environment and environmental constraints. | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 44 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Case Study | BMW Spartanburg, USA I Location decision of BMW F Production of BMW Z3 in the USA, mid 1990ies. F Expansion to include BMW X5 und Z4. | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 45 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Case Study | BMW Spartanburg, USA II 1) Choice of the US 2) Choice of South Carolina 3) Final decision for Spartanburg | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 46 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Case Study | BMW Spartanburg, USA III Factors decisive for choosing USA F Market: F Market size: USA is the world‘s largest market for luxury cars F Growing versus declining markets: US growing market due to baby boomers. F Labor: F Lower labor and production costs: (US: US$ 17/h, DEU: US$ 27/h) F High labor productivity (Holidays: US 11, Germany: 31) F Additionally: F Low transport costs (US$ 2.500,- less per vehicle) F New facilities improve productivity and thus lower the costs per car (around US$ 2.000-3.000.-) F Insurance (‚hedging‘) against high Dollar-Euro exchange rates. | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 47 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Case Study | BMW Spartanburg, USA IV Factor in favor of South Carolina 85 F Labor: F Low wages in South Carolina F Public subsidies: F US$ 135 Mio.in terms of tax deductions. F Free trade zone: F Duties neither on imported goods nor on car exports. 85 F Infrastructure: F Access to freeway and via the freeway to the airport Charlotte from which Lufthansa operates direct flights to Munich. Port Charleston serves for exports and the imports of engines and gearboxes from Europe | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 26 Page 48 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Labor Productivity F Keyword: level of labor costs F Cheaper employees => higher profit? F However, cheap labor is NOT everything – countries with cheap labor are often characterized by low labor productity that can erode partially or totally the advantage in terms of labor cost. Compare: Gregory Clark, Farewell to Alms, textile production in England and colonial India. F ‚Skills‘ of workers, good infrastructure, and technology are often more important to many industries than plain labor costs. | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 49 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Case Study | Labor productivity F Quality Coils Inc., CT, USA F Coil production for electrical equipments F 2 potential locations: F Expanding a the present location in Connecticut F New factory in Juarez (one of the fastest growing cities in Mexiko along the US border due to the Maquiladoras) F Comparison based on labor costs: Labor Productivity = Labor Cost per day = cost per unit Productivity (units per day) Wage/d Output/ worker Labor cost/ piece Connecticut Plant US$ 70.- 60 units US$ 1.17/unit Juarez Plant US$ 25.- 20 units US$ 1.25/unit F Historical Example: Alfa Romeo - Alfasud | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 50 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Four International Operations Strategies Cost Reduction Considerations High Global Strategy Transnational Strategy ; Standardized product ; Economies of scale ; Cross-cultural learning ; Move material, people, ideas across national boundaries ; Economies of scale ; Cross-cultural learning Examples Texas Instruments Caterpillar Otis Elevator Examples Coca-Cola Nestlé International Strategy ; Import/export or license existing product Multidomestic Strategy ; Use existing domestic model globally ; Franchise, joint ventures, subsidiaries Examples U.S. Steel Harley Davidson Examples Heinz The Body Shop McDonald’s Hard Rock Cafe Low Low High Local Responsiveness Considerations (Quick Response and/or Differentiation) | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 51 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Steiner-Weber Model I F Geometric, continuous Model based on the works of the German geometricians and regional scientists: F Launhardt (1882), Steiner-Weber (1909) & Lösch, Christaller (1940er) F Model assumptions: { } F The set location where to delivery to, O = o p , p = 1, K r is given. F The set of potential locations (S) is the entire plane (infinitely many, actually uncountable many). F The decision involves only a single location s. F Transport costs are proportional to the Euclidean distance. F Problem – minimize transport costs: F Find the optimal location s * ∈ S determined by the coordinates x*, y* that minimizes from the chosen location the transport costs to the sinks Op with the coordinates xp, yp (p=1,…r). | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 53 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Steiner-Weber Modell II F The objective function depends on: F Volume (delivered or for delivery) from the given location p, ap, F Normalized transport cost (e.g. EUR/ton/km) kt, F Distance measures in terms of direct connection (Euclidean), dp. dp = (x − x ) + (y − y ) 2 2 p (xp, yp) p dp xp F Objective x r r p =1 p =1 (x, y) K T = ∑ K T p = ∑ kt * a p * d p y yp | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 IEU Page 54 International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Steiner-Weber Modell III (x − x ) + (y − y ) r F Objective Æ min: min K T = k t ∑ a p * x, y 2 2 p p =1 p F Differentiation with respect to x and y and equating to zero yields the first order optimality condition. r ∂K T = kt ∑ ∂x p =1 r ∂K T = kt ∑ ∂y p =1 ap (x − xp ) ! (x − x ) + (y − y ) 2 p 2 p ap(y − yp) ! (x − x ) + (y − y ) 2 p =0 2 =0 p F Result: two nonlinear equations that require numerical means (e.g. Newton‘s iteration scheme) F Fortunately, Excel does it! (via the Solver). | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 55 IEU International Industrial Management I Lehrstuhl f. Industrie, Energie und Umwelt | Mag. Florian Pützl | Steiner-Weber Modell IV | Increments F Nonlinear transport costs but distance depending, e.g., quadratic, or including set up costs for each connection: k T p = k T p (d p ) F It can make sense to link the transport costs to particular sinks p to account for differences in deliveries (e.g., scrap versus sensitive final prducts): k t = k t ( p ) A further extension is to allow for the deliveries of multiple goods from the source (i.e., the sought location) s to sinks O. Accounting for the last two recommendation leads to the following cost minimization: min K T = x, y q r ∑ ∑k p =1 q =1 T qp * a qp * d p = ∑ (x − x ) + (y − y ) ∑ k q r p =1 2 p 2 p q =1 T qp * a qp where : q = 1, K , q k T qp products transport cost of product q to sink p | Florian Pützl © 2009 | International Industrial Management I, WS 2009 Page 56