Congressional Intervention in State Taxation: A Normative Analysis of Three Proposals by Charles E. McLure, Jr. Hoover Institution, Stanford University Walter Hellerstein University of Georgia Law School1 Congress currently is considering or is about to consider three significant pieces of proposed legislation affecting state taxation: a proposal to extend (and perhaps expand) the Internet Tax Freedom Act (ITFA); a proposal to allow states to require collection of taxes on remote sales if they simplify their tax system in accord with the Streamlined Sales Tax Project (the Streamlined Sales and Use Tax Act (SSUTA)); and a proposal to expand nexus restrictions on business activity taxes (BATs). In this paper, we consider the merits of congressional intervention to limit and expand state taxing authority from a tax policy perspective informed by a normative analysis of the appropriate role of the federal government vis-à-vis state taxing authority. Part I provides an overview of congressional intervention in state tax matters against the background of the historical, political, and constitutional understanding of state tax sovereignty. Part II provides an overview of the normative principles of tax policy that should inform congressional intervention in state tax matters in light of the background described in Part I. Part III describes the three congressional proposals at issue, elaborates upon the key normative considerations that bear on them, and applies those norms in evaluating the proposals. I. Historical, Political, and Constitutional Overview Insofar as state taxation affects interstate commerce, Congress has virtually unlimited authority to restrict or expand the inherent taxing authority that the states possessed when they joined the Union insofar as state taxation affects interstate commerce.2 The U.S. Supreme Court has made it clear, for example, that the authority the Constitution confers upon Congress "to regulate commerce … among the several States"3 gives Congress plenary power over the channels of interstate commerce. Accordingly, "Congress may keep the way open, confine it broadly or closely, or close it entirely,"4 subject only to the restraints that the Constitution imposes on Congress's own power -- restraints that do not materially limit Congress's power to legislate with respect to state taxes. Indeed, the Court has explicitly indicated that Congress possesses power to legislate uniform state tax rules for commerce among the states. It has observed that "[i]t is clear that the legislative power granted to Congress by the Commerce Clause of the Constitution would amply justify the enactment of legislation requiring all States to adhere 5 to uniform rules for the division of income." Moreover, it is equally clear that Congress may consent to state legislation as part of a rational solution to the problem of taxing interstate commerce, even if such legislation would be unconstitutional under the "dormant" 6 Commerce Clause in the absence of such consent. As the Court observed in Quill Corp. v. 1 North Dakota,7 which reaffirmed the dormant Commerce Clause principle that the physical presence of an out-of state vendor is an essential prerequisite of a state’s power to require the vendor to collect the state's use tax, "Congress is . . . free to decide whether, when, and to what extent the States may burden mail-order concerns with a duty to collect use taxes."8 Despite the broad power that Congress possesses to legislate regarding state taxation of interstate commerce, historically Congress has rarely exercised this power, at least by comparison to the vast body of congressional legislation restricting state regulation of interstate commerce. Public Law 86-272, which limits the states' power to tax income that an out-of-state vendor derives from sales into a state when the vendor’s only activities in the state are the solicitation of orders for tangible personal property, is the most significant piece of federal legislation restricting state taxing power.9 Apart from this statute, Congress has restricted state power (other than state power to tax the federal government or its instrumentalities) only in narrowly defined circumstances. For example, in adopting the Railroad Revitalization and Regulatory Reform Act of 1975,10 Congress prohibited the states from taxing railroad property more heavily than other commercial and industrial property. Congress subsequently extended similar protection to motor carriers,11 and to air carriers.12 In amending the federal securities acts in 1975, Congress imposed limitations on the power of states to levy stock transfer taxes.13 Federal legislation also prohibits the states from imposing user charges in connection with the carriage of persons in air commerce;14 it "supersede[s] any and all State taxes insofar as they now or hereafter relate to any employee benefit plan" instituted pursuant to the Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA);15 it prohibits the states from imposing electrical energy taxes discriminating against out-of-state purchasers;16 it prohibits localities from taxing providers of direct-to-home satellite services;17 it prohibits states from taxing interstate passenger transportation by motor carriers18; and it authorizes, under specified conditions, state taxation of charges for mobile telecommunications services.19 The question naturally arises as to why Congress has so rarely intervened in matters of state taxation and generally has done so only in the most targeted manner when it has restricted or expanded state taxing authority. We believe that the answer lies in the strong tradition of state tax sovereignty, which is reflected in long-standing political and constitutional understandings. The states' sovereign power of taxation has always been regarded as essential to their independent existence and thus to the federal scheme that the Framers created. Writing in The Federalist in 1788, Alexander Hamilton declared: [T]he individual States should possess an independent and uncontrollable authority to raise their own revenues for the support of their own wants …. I affirm that (with the sole exception of duties on imports and exports) they would retain that authority in the most absolute and unqualified sense; and that any attempt on the part of the national government to abridge them in the exercise of it would be a violent assumption of power unwarranted by any article or clause of the Constitution.20 2 Throughout our constitutional history the U.S. Supreme Court has made similar statements reflecting its view that the states' taxing powers are critical to their separate existence and are an essential element of state sovereignty. Thus Chief Justice Marshall observed in 1824 that the states' "power of taxation is indispensable to their existence."21 Fifty years later, the Court echoed these sentiments when it declared: That the taxing power of a State is one of its attributes of sovereignty; that it exists independently of the Constitution of the United States, and underived from that instrument; and that it may be exercised to an unlimited extent upon all property, trades, business, and avocations existing or carried on within its territorial boundaries of the State, except so far as it has been surrendered to the Federal government, either expressly or by necessary implication, are propositions that have often been asserted by this court. And in thus acknowledging the extent of the power to tax belonging to the States, we have declared that it is indispensable to their continued existence.22 The Court has reiterated these beliefs in its modern opinions: "When dealing with their proper domestic concerns, and not trenching upon the prerogatives of the National Government or violating the guaranties of the Federal Constitution, the States have the attribute of sovereign powers in devising their fiscal systems to ensure revenue and foster their local interests."23 We should not be surprised by the deeply entrenched belief that state tax sovereignty is fundamental to the states' political independence. To be sure, as a matter of theory, taxing powers might be lodged exclusively at the national level and tax revenues distributed to the states without any limitation on how such revenues might be spent, thereby giving the states "spending" sovereignty without "tax" sovereignty. There are at least three problems with such an arrangement. First, we know from experience that he who pays the piper calls the tune. Consequently, tax revenues raised at the national level are unlikely to be distributed to subnational levels of government without material restraints on how such revenues may be spent, thus compromising spending sovereignty. Moreover, without independent taxing authority, a state's ability to determine the size, as well as the shape, of the public sector is likely to be substantially limited. Finally, experience in other countries shows that when subnational governments spend money provided by higher levels of government public spending tends to be bloated and wasteful.24 The understanding that states' tax sovereignty is essential to their independent political status in the federal system has never been regarded as inconsistent with the view that the federal government likewise possesses sovereign tax powers. To draw once more on the words of Chief Justice Marshall: The power of taxation … is a power which, in its own nature, is capable of residing in, and being exercised by, different authorities at the same time. We are accustomed to seeing it placed for different purposes, in different hands…. Congress is authorized to lay and collect taxes …. This does not interfere with the 3 power of the States to tax for the support of their own governments; nor is the exercise of that power by the States an exercise of any portion of the power that is granted to the United States.25 More recently, the Court made a similar point in observing that "[c]oncurrent federal and state taxation of income … is a well-established norm."26 The preceding discussion should not be taken to suggest that a state taxing statute may never be incompatible with either the express or implied restraints that the Constitution imposes on the states or with the exercise of congressional power to preempt state taxation. State tax sovereignty should not be confused with state tax supremacy. Nevertheless, despite the existence of some overriding restraints on state tax sovereignty, the widely shared understanding that the states' independent powers of taxation are central to their political identity in the federal system, and compatible with the existence of like powers in the national government, necessarily informs the analysis of the proper balance of federal and state power in matters of state taxation, and, in particular, when congressional intervention in state matters is appropriate. One further observation may be in order regarding what may be considered as a "disconnect" between the existence of broad congressional power to control state taxation of interstate commerce and the almost total absence of significant congressional legislation exercising such power. For many years, state taxation of interstate commerce simply was not a problem worthy of congressional attention. For much of the nineteenth century, economic activity was predominantly local, and states, as well as local governments, relied largely on the property tax as a source of revenue.27 The first modern state corporate income tax was not enacted until 1911 and states did not adopt broadbased sales taxes until the 1930s. As the national economy became increasingly integrated, the U.S. Supreme Court found that diverse and complex state tax laws can impose an unacceptable burden on interstate commerce, and it explicitly invited Congress to forge more comprehensive measures to alleviate such burdens than those it was capable of providing through case-by-case adjudication.28 Although the case for congressional intervention in state taxation therefore may be more compelling today than it was in the past, the dangers associated with such intervention are also more acute, because the power Congress possesses to do good is matched by its power to do harm. Indeed, these dangers are evident in both existing and proposed legislation that we discuss below – legislation that in some respects is more reflective of the exercise of raw political power than of the dictates of sound tax policy. II. A Normative Perspective A. Types of Congressional Intervention Congress can intervene in state tax matters in any one of three ways. It can prohibit or limit states' exercise of their existing powers of taxation; it can consent to the exercise of state tax powers that would have been barred in the absence of such consent; and it can combine the first two types of intervention, permitting the states to exercise 4 powers of taxation they might not otherwise possess but only if they do so in a manner prescribed by Congress (which may curtail power the states otherwise possess). Most congressional intervention in state tax matters has been of the first type.29 Nevertheless, Congress has on occasion explicitly consented to the exercise of state taxing authority that would have been barred in the absence of such consent. For example, when the U.S. Supreme Court overruled long-standing precedent that multistate insurance companies were not engaged in "commerce" in holding that "insurance" constituted "commerce" for purposes of the antitrust laws,30 Congress quickly restored the status quo ante by enacting the McCarran-Ferguson Act,31 which, among other things, left the states free of Commerce Clause restraints in taxing the insurance industry. The act declared that "the silence on the part of Congress shall not be construed to impose any barrier to the regulation or taxation of [the business of insurance] by the several states."32 Similarly, Congress has on occasion enacted legislation combining interventions of the first and second types, as illustrated by the recently enacted Mobile Telecommunications Sourcing Act (MTSA).33 Under jurisdictional standards that the U.S. Supreme Court articulated in Goldberg v. Sweet34 under the Commerce Clause, the “only” states with “a nexus substantial enough to tax a consumer's purchase of an interstate telephone call” are (1) “a State … which taxes the origination or termination of an interstate telephone call charged to a service address within that State” and (2) “a State which taxes the origination or termination of an interstate telephone call billed or paid within that State.”35 The implications of these standards for taxation of the wireless telecommunications industry are troublesome to say the least. Consider a business traveler who lives in State A, where she receives her monthly phone bill, and, while in State B on business, makes a call to State C. Under Goldberg, none of these States can tax the charges for the call, because none of them can claim that the call either originates or terminates in the state and is charged to a service address in the state or is billed or paid within the state.36 The difficulties involved in taxing mobile telecommunications under the regime the Court established in Goldberg led Congress, with the joint support of the telecommunications industry and the states, to enact the MTSA, which permits the states to tax all mobile telecommunications charges (for services provided by the customer's "home service provider") at the customer's "place of primary use."37 The key operative language of the MTSA, which both expands and contracts state power to tax charges for mobile telecommunications, provides: All charges for mobile telecommunications services that are deemed to be provided by the customer's home service provider … are authorized to be subjected to tax, charge, or fee by the taxing jurisdictions whose territorial limits encompass the customer's place of primary use, regardless of where the mobile telecommunications services originate, terminate, or pass through, and no other jurisdiction may impose taxes, charges, or fees on charges for such mobile telecommunications services.38 5 The expansion of state power is provided by the grant of authority to the state of the customer's home service provider to tax the charge for wireless services regardless of whether that state possesses power to tax the call under the preexisting standards of Goldberg v. Sweet. The contraction of state power is contained in the final clause that prevents any state other than the state of the customer's home service provider from taxing such charges, even if that state possessed power under Goldberg v. Sweet to tax the charge. B. Normative Criteria Bearing on Federal Limitation of State Taxing Power: Overview The case for state tax sovereignty delineated in Part I is not categorical; there are important reasons why state tax sovereignty should not be unlimited. Judicial or legislative limits on state action may thus be appropriate, especially when it is the lack of coordination of state policies that causes problems. But inappropriate federal limitations on state taxing sovereignty can also be problematical. Inappropriate state policies and inappropriate federal limitations on state action can create three types problems: adverse economic effects (including economic distortions and inequities), excessive compliance costs, and revenue loss, the last of which may result from increased opportunities for tax planning. Remedies should be designed carefully to address existing problems and avoid the creation of new ones. The proper remedy depends on the nature and source of the problem. Where the policies of a single state entail unacceptable economic effects, such policies should be prohibited or otherwise curtailed. Where lack of interstate coordination of state tax policies causes needless complexity and excessive compliance costs, coordination and simplification should be required. Where federal limitations on state actions, which may be either judicial or legislative, create adverse economic effects or revenue loss, they should be modified; this, in turn, may require as a prerequisite the modification of the state policies that initially led to the limitations. Legislative remedies can be more nuanced than judicial remedies. The judiciary can determine whether something is or is not allowed under the U.S. Constitution or federal statutes, but it cannot and should not undertake the essentially legislative task of enumerating in detail what is permitted or prohibited or prescribing the precise conditions under which a state action would or would not be acceptable. Indeed, the U.S. Supreme Court has steadfastly refused to undertake such legislative tasks and has frequently recognized that the function of prescribing fine-tuned and detailed rules governing state taxation of interstate commerce is properly within Congress’s -- not the Court’s -domain.39 Quill itself clearly illustrates the point. In Quill, the Court reaffirmed a simple, “bright-line” prohibition on a state’s ability to require a vendor without physical presence in the state to collect the state’s use tax, because of the burden that such a requirement would impose on such a vendor in light of the complexity created by lack of coordination among the states in their sales tax regimes. The Court pointedly did not establish a 6 threshold level of sales or indicate the contours of interstate coordination that would be required for a state constitutionally to impose a collection obligation on a remote vendor. To the contrary, the Court indicated that Congress could revise whatever “bright-line” prohibition the Court may have articulated under the dormant Commerce Clause in any manner that Congress sees fit, and, in particular, “is . . . free to decide whether, when, and to what extent the States may burden mail-order concerns with a duty to collect use taxes."40 We are dealing here with three cases that have the following characteristics: Internet Tax Freedom Act (ITFA). Proponents of this legislation claim that the states must not be allowed to tax Internet access, in order to prevent adverse economic consequences, namely hindrance of the growth of the Internet and electronic commerce and aggravation of the digital divide between the more affluent, who generally have ready access to the Internet, and the less fortunate, who are less “wired.” Opponents object that even if these economic benefits are real, they are not significant enough to justify the substantial revenue cost to the states of exempting Internet access, especially once one considers the legislation’s broad definition of “Internet access.” Streamlined Sales and Use Tax Act (SSUTA). State sales and use taxes41 are so complex that requiring vendors who lack a physical presence in the taxing state to collect use taxes would have the adverse economic effect of imposing an undue burden on interstate commerce – a fact the U.S. Supreme Court recognized when it established the physical presence test of nexus in National Bellas Hess, Inc. v. Department of Revenue42 and when it reaffirmed that test in Quill. Yet that test also creates the undesirable economic effect of placing Main Street merchants at a competitive disadvantage, relative to remote vendors, and undermines both revenues and the equity of the sales tax system. SSUTA represents an attempt to remedy all these defects. It would prescribe simplification of the sales and use tax system as a condition for the elimination of the physical presence test, and generally authorize states that participate in the simplification effort to require remote vendors to collect use tax for those states. Business Activity Tax (BAT) Legislation. Public Law 86-272 prohibits imposition of income taxes on those who, with only minimum contact with the taxing state, sell tangible personal property to customers located there. This statute reduces complexity for remote vendors, who otherwise might be required to pay tax to any state where they make sales.43 But it also undermines equity and the revenue of state governments. The proposed legislation would expand the nexus protection afforded by Public Law 86-272, by extending it to all “business activities taxes,” making it applicable to all sales (not only sales of tangible property), establishing a physical presence test similar to that of Quill, and providing explicit safe harbor rules. Thus it would further reduce complexity, but at the cost of aggravating revenue losses and inequity. 7 III. Application of Norms to Recent Congressional Initiatives In the final part of this paper, we describe the three congressional proposals at issue, elaborate upon the key normative considerations that bear on them, and apply those norms in evaluating the proposals. In some instances our analysis suggests that the tax base should be broadened and in some that it should be narrowed. We do not conclude from this, however, that taxes should be correspondingly higher or lower. Rather, we assume a revenue-neutral process in which changes in tax bases occurring in a particular state would be compensated by changes in tax rates, in order to leave revenues in that state unchanged. A. The Internet Tax Freedom Act Extension 1. The Internet Tax Freedom Act In 1998, Congress enacted the Internet Tax Freedom Act (ITFA).44 The Act imposed a three-year moratorium (subsequently extended for another two years)45 on three types of taxes: (1) taxes on Internet access; (2) discriminatory taxes on electronic commerce; and (3) multiple taxes on electronic commerce. ITFA expired in October 2003 and, as of this writing, it has not been reenacted. a. Taxes on Internet access The prohibition against taxes on Internet access forbade states from taxing charges for "a service that enables users to access content, information, electronic mail or other services over the Internet."46 In short, it forbade the states from taxing the monthly fee that America Online and other Internet access providers charge to their customers for connecting to the Internet. The Act, however, did not apply to any tax that "was generally imposed and actually enforced prior to October 1, 1998."47 b. Discriminatory taxes The Act's prohibition against discriminatory taxes on electronic commerce would have had little impact had it been limited to that concept as it is generally understood, since there are no taxes of which we are aware that single out transactions in electronic commerce for invidious treatment. However, because Congress defined "discriminatory taxes" to include certain taxes in which a remote seller has only minimal nexus with the state, the ITFA may have had some impact with respect to use tax collection obligations. Specifically, Congress classified as "discriminatory" any tax (other than a grandfathered tax on Internet access), if the "sole ability to access a site on a remote seller's out-of-State computer server is considered a factor in determining a remote seller's tax collection obligation."48 In substance, it forbade states from imposing taxes on Internet sales by "remote" (i.e., non-physically present) sellers, if the state relied on the purchaser's "sole ability" to access the seller's out-of-state computer server as a factor in determining whether the remote seller has nexus with the state and, consequently, an obligation to collect a tax on the transaction.49 ITFA also prevented the states from claiming that they 8 have nexus with a remote seller for purposes of requiring the remote seller to collect a use tax on its Internet sales into the state by characterizing an Internet access provider (e.g., America Online) as the remote seller's agent "solely as a result of (I) the display of a remote seller's information or content on the out-of-State computer server" of the Internet access provider or "(II) the processing of orders through the out-of-State computer server" of the Internet access provider.50 c. Multiple Taxation ITFA's prohibition of multiple taxation of electronic commerce was not a model of clarity. A multiple tax was defined as any tax that is imposed by one State …on the same or essentially the same electronic commerce that is also subject to another tax imposed by another State … (whether or not at the same or rate or on the same basis), without a credit (for example, a resale exemption certificate) for taxes paid in other jurisdictions.51 Congress excluded from this definition of a "multiple tax" sales or use taxes imposed concurrently by a state and its political subdivisions on the same electronic commerce and "a tax on persons engaged in electronic commerce which may also have been subject to a sales or use tax thereon."52 Although one can discern Congress' objective in enacting this provision -- to prevent the same electronic commerce from being subject to tax by more than one state -- the language that Congress chose to accomplish that goal was opaque at best. While the policy objective of preventing more than one state from taxing "the same electronic commerce" might leave some room for debate, the prevention of states from taxing "essentially the same electronic commerce" was almost an invitation for controversy. Indeed, it read more like cocktail party conversation than a carefully thought out restraint on state taxing power. Moreover, Congress apparently believed that two states can tax "the same" or "essentially the same" electronic commerce, even if the two levies are not imposed "on the same basis." In any event, it is fair to say -- especially in light of the "grandfather clause" -- that there was less than met the eye when ITFA's taxation moratorium was originally enacted (and then renewed for two years). It was in substance a narrowly based prohibition on Internet access charges with few other practical implications for state taxing authority. However, during debates over the extension of ITFA -- a debate that is continuing -- the stakes became much higher. Although there was never agreement about the language of any bill proposing to extend or expand ITFA, or, indeed, precisely what the proposed language meant, it is clear that some of the proposals would have (1) made the legislation permanent, (2) eliminated the grandfather provision, and (3) extended the prohibition to certain telecommunications utilized to provide "Internet access," which arguably included a broad range of Internet services (including Internet telephony).53 Our ensuing evaluation does not enter into the controversy over precisely what the various proposals for extension or expansion mean. Rather we focus on what types of congressional action, if any, would make sense from a normative perspective. 9 2. Principal Normative Considerations Bearing on a Tax Exemption for Internet Access In considering the normative case for exempting Internet access, it is useful to begin with the unrealistic situation in which the taxation of goods and services is economically neutral and then consider the actual situation, in which there are important deviations from economic neutrality. Since “Internet access” has been interpreted in several ways, we consider first a narrow interpretation that allows an exemption only for Internet access in the limited sense of connecting to the Internet, and then the much more sweeping interpretations that include exemption of telecommunications and/or digital content sold over the Internet. a. Economically neutral sales taxation An economically neutral tax system would not interfere with market choices – choices of what to consume and produce and how to organize and finance production and distribution. A neutral system of sales taxation54 would follow these four tenets: a) all sales to consumers would be taxed uniformly, b) all sales to business would be exempt, c) these rules would apply whether sales were made by in-state vendors or by out-of-state vendors, and d) the system would be simple – or at least as simple as possible, consistent with other objectives.55 Principled deviations from such a regime can be justified in three situations. First, it may not be cost-effective to require all vendors to collect the tax. (For example, it would not be administratively feasible to require teenagers to collect sales tax on lawn-mowing services.) We do not discuss this issue further. Second, if consumption of particular products takes a disproportionate fraction of the income of the poor, exemption of such products may further distributional objectives. However, an exemption is likely to involve relatively little “bang for the buck,” because the non-poor consume more of most products than do the poor, and there are generally much more efficient ways to achieve distributional objectives, such as refundable income tax credits. Third, consumption of certain products creates social benefits that are not reflected in product prices (what economists call external benefits).56 It may thus be thought appropriate to subsidize such consumption by exempting it from generally applicable taxation, as is done with most education and health care.57 Proponents of exempting Internet access have often failed to articulate clearly the economic principles underlying their position. There are, however, two principled arguments that might support exemption of Internet access, narrowly defined, in a system that is otherwise economically neutral. First, one might argue that the expansion of Internet access creates external benefits and that such access should thus be subsidized by relieving it of the tax burden imposed on other goods and services or taxing it at a lower rate. Second, it may be considered important to subsidize Internet access in order to bridge the digital divide between relatively poor non-users and more affluent users. (Whether this is seen as involving the (current and future) distribution of income or as involving external benefits, such as reducing crime and welfare dependency, is of little consequence for the present discussion; the conclusions are roughly the same in either 10 event.) Cursory examination of these arguments reveals either that they are invalid or that, even if valid, they would not justify the loss of revenue inherent in exemption of Internet access. “Network effects” are one example of potential external benefits. Network effects occur when the benefits a user of a network receives depend on the size of the network58 Thus, for example, there is no benefit to having a telephone if no one else has one, and not much benefit if only one other person has one. A third member of the network will double the potential benefits enjoyed by each of the first two members, because they can talk to two other parties, instead of only one. External benefits occur in this setting because someone considering joining the network does not consider the benefits created for existing users. It might be thought that there are enough unexploited network effects to justify subsidizing Internet access in order to encourage greater use of the Internet. One way to subsidize Internet access by households would be to exempt it from otherwise applicable taxation.59 This argument for exempting Internet access is no longer valid, if ever it was. The strongest case for such a subsidy would be to “jump-start” the growth of the Internet, so that it could achieve critical mass.60 With estimates of more than 2 billion Internet users, about 150 million of whom reside in the United States,61 such an “infant industry” argument is ludicrous. Moreover, the case for a subsidy depends on the size of network effects, relative to the private benefits realized by users, and (because of the revenue consequences of exempting Internet access of existing users) on the size of the pool of potential new users, relative to the pool of existing users.62 It is difficult to quantify network effects, but it defies belief to suggest that the external benefits of adding more users to the Internet are significant at this stage of the cyber-revolution or that they could justify the revenue loss of exempting Internet access of all existing household users. 63 In theory, it would be possible to adjust the tax system to encourage network effects, while avoiding significant revenue loss, by limiting the exemption of Internet access to new users, but, as a practical matter, this does not seem to be administratively feasible.64 Exempting only basic access would be preferable to exempting all Internet access, since the revenue costs, although far from inconsequential, would be lower, but that raises difficult definitional problems – problems that could best be addressed by simply exempting a given dollar amount of monthly charges.65 An argument can also be made that access to broadband should be subsidized, the point being that access to broadband reduces “hourglass (waiting) time” and thus encourages more use of the Internet, which in turn creates network effects and spurs the development and availability of digital content. It seems, however, that private benefits of broadband access are sufficiently large, relative to any conceivable external effects, that a subsidy to broadband access by households is not justified. (Recall that business use of broadband, which almost certainly far outweighs potential household use, would be exempt under an economically neutral tax system. We discuss exemption of digital content further below.) The development of Internet telephony (transmission of telephone messages over the Internet) provides another powerful reason to avoid exemption of 11 Internet access. Since Internet access automatically entails the possibility of Internet telephony, exemption of all telecommunications would be required to avoid giving Internet telephony a competitive advantage over other forms of telephony.66 Total exemption of telecommunications would, of course, entail an enormous loss of state and local tax revenues.67 This also provides ample reason not to adopt the proposal to exempt basic Internet access; parity would demand that such an exemption should be matched by exemption of basic charges for other forms of telecommunications. Some definitions of Internet access are so broad that the ITFA would exempt digital content. There is, however, no principled justification for exempting digital content that is transmitted over the Internet. Such an exemption would create a competitive advantage for downloaded digitized products that can also be (and traditionally have been) delivered in tangible form. This would be a significant blow to Main Street merchants, who sell the latter type of products, and would discriminate against those who buy them, typically the less educated and the poor. If bridging the digital divide is seen to be a question of external benefits, the conclusion is similar to that for network effects. Inducing poor non-users of the Internet to become users may have social benefits, but exempting all Internet access (or even basic service) is an extremely costly way to achieve them. If, on the other hand, the issue is seen to be one of income distribution, exempting Internet access also cannot be justified. Since the lion’s share of Internet access is consumed by the non-poor, a general exemption, even if limited to basic service, would not have the posited distributional effects, and limiting the exemption to the poor would not be administratively feasible.68 A final non-technical point deserves attention. One can identify many instances in which textbook analysis of external economies, distributional effects, and other forms of “market failure” might seem to justify corrective governmental intervention. Yet, for the most part, the United States sensibly does not follow this approach, preferring the sometimes imperfect results of market forces to the very real risks inherent in intervention. (The risk is not just that economic results will be worse; perhaps as important, once one starts down the road to intervention, by providing preferential treatment of selected sectors, it is politically difficult to withstand the entreaties for special treatment of others.) We should keep in mind the admonition of former president Ronald Reagan, even recognizing that it is the rhetoric of a politician rather than the analysis of a public finance economist, that “[t]he taxing power of government must be used to provide revenues for legitimate government purposes. It must not be used to regulate the economy or bring about social change. We've tried that, and surely we must be able to see it doesn't work.” (February 18, 1981). It is anomalous that many who fancy themselves to be supporters of free-market economics advocate exemption of Internet access, in order to encourage the growth of the Internet. b. Economically defective sales taxation Extant state and local sales taxes deviate from the principles stated earlier, in that: a) not all sales to consumers are taxed uniformly, b) not all sales to business are exempt, 12 c) sales often are not taxed when made by out-of-state vendors, and d) the system is needlessly complicated. We discuss here the first two types of deviations, reserving discussion of the last two to the part of the next section on “Principal Normative Considerations Bearing on Nexus Over Remote Sellers for Purpose of Requiring Collection of State and Local Use Taxes.” All states apply their sales taxes primarily to goods, leaving many services exempt. Given this, one might think that Internet access and digital content should also be exempt. However, achievement of economically neutral sales taxation requires the taxation of all goods and services consumed by households. Accordingly, from a normative perspective, the appropriate solution is to broaden the tax base to include household purchases of Internet access and digital content, not to exacerbate the deviation from an ideal tax base by exempting such purchases. All states exempt tangible products bought for resale and most states extend this principle to products incorporated or used “directly” in the manufacture of products for sale. On the other hand, most states tax a wide range of products that are used only “indirectly” to produce goods that are resold or to distribute them (e.g., when an automobile manufacturer or dealer acquires office equipment). Consistency might seem to demand that business purchases of telecommunications, Internet access, and digital content should be taxable, because they are not acquired for resale as such (much like the office equipment acquired by an automobile manufacturer or dealer).69 But, again, the right way to address this long-standing defect is not to expand the taxation of business purchases; rather, all telecommunications, Internet access, and digital content should be exempt when purchased by business. 3. Summary Comment Evaluating ITFA Legislation The case for exempting Internet access by households is weak, no matter how Internet access is defined (narrowly, as embracing only connection to the Internet or more broadly to include telecommunications and/or digital content). Even an exemption for only basic Internet access is an extremely inefficient way to achieve the posited objectives. On the other hand, all business purchases of Internet access, telecommunications, and digital content should be tax-exempt. We reiterate that these conclusions, and others in this paper that suggest a broader or narrower tax base, are not a recommendation for higher or lower taxes. Rather, we assume a revenue-neutral process in which changes in tax bases would be compensated by changes in tax rates, in order to leave revenues unchanged in each state. B. Streamlined Sales and Use Tax Legislation 1. The Streamlined Sales and Use Tax Act (SSUTA) Legislation has been introduced in Congress authorizing the states, under specified conditions, to require collection of sales and use taxes with respect to sales by remote sellers, notwithstanding their lack of physical presence in the state (otherwise 13 constitutionally required under the Quill decision), if the states conform to the provisions of the Streamlined Sales and Use Tax Agreement (the "Streamlined Agreement").70 The legislation “consents” to the Streamlined Agreement, thereby authorizing the states, consistent with other provisions of the legislation, to require collection of taxes on remote sales notwithstanding Quill. The Streamlined Agreement requires that 10 states comprising at least 20 percent of the total population of all states with sales taxes significantly simplify and harmonize their sales and use tax regimes by providing, among other things, a centralized, one-stop multistate registration system; uniform definitions of product and product-based exemptions; uniform sourcing rules; uniform procedures for certifying tax collection software and intermediaries; uniform rules for bad debts; uniform rules for tax returns and remittances; consistent electronic filing and remittance methods; single state-level administration for all state and local taxes; reasonable compensation for sellers who administer sales and used tax; and appropriate protections for consumer privacy. If the states satisfy the Streamlined Agreement’s requirements, Congress would authorize collection by remote sellers, but with additional conditions and limitations (beyond those required by the Streamlined Agreement). These include, among other things, an exception for “small” sellers (those with less than $5 million of nationwide remote sales) and federal court review of controversies arising under the Streamlined Agreement. 2. Principal Normative Considerations Bearing on Nexus Over Remote Sellers for Purpose of Requiring Collection of State and Local Use Taxes We believe analysis of these considerations will be advanced by subdividing the inquiry in two respects. First, we focus on collection of state use taxes before examining the problems caused by the existence of local sales and use taxes. Second, we approach both sets of issues under alternative assumptions of what is achievable from a practical standpoint. We initially address the nexus question on the somewhat utopian assumption that all – or least most – desirable changes are possible. We then revisit the question under the more realistic hypothesis that there will continue to be at least some diversity in state and local tax rules. a. Uniform state sales tax rules Under an ideal retail sales tax, sales would be taxed by the jurisdiction of destination. Moreover, as we have already observed in connection with the discussion of ITFA, only sales to households would be taxed; sales to business would be exempt. For reasons of social policy, it may be thought desirable to exempt certain categories of consumer purchases, for example, food and prescription drugs, despite the complexity and economic distortions this creates. In addition, states should provide vendor discounts to both local merchants and remote vendors to compensate them for the cost of collecting sales and use tax.71 Such compensation should reflect actual incremental costs of collecting tax and the fact that costs are relatively much higher for vendors with a small sales volume in a given state than for those with a large volume.72 14 If all sales to business were exempt in all states (or even if some such sales were taxed, but the rules for exemption were the same in all states), if definitions of products, exemptions of consumer purchases, and administrative procedures were also uniform from state to state, and if a remote vendor making only small amounts of sales in a state could register, file, and remit tax to its home state, which would forward the revenue to the state of destination, rather than completing these administrative requirements in each state where it makes sales, compliance with state sales and use taxes would be relatively simple, even for remote vendors.73 In particular, a vendor located in one state could relatively easily comply with the state use tax of another state, because of the uniformity across states. In such an environment there would be little reason for a nexus rule excusing remote vendors from collecting use tax,74 and the vendor discounts offered to remote sellers would not need to be much higher than the discounts provided local merchants. b. Diverse state sales tax rules None of the “ideal” preconditions for simple compliance listed in the previous paragraph currently exists. Definitions of products, exemptions for sales to business, exemptions of consumer purchases, and administrative procedures are not uniform, and it is not possible for a remote vendor to complete administrative procedures in its home state. Moreover, vendor discounts are generally woefully inadequate to compensate for costs of compliance, especially for small remote merchants. In such an environment it would not be appropriate to require remote vendors to incur costs of collecting use tax, especially in situations where the amount of revenue at stake does not justify the considerable cost of collection. There are two ways to deal with this situation. One would be to allow the diversity to continue unabated, but require that states pay realistic vendor discounts – that is, vendor discounts that accurately reflect the incremental cost of compliance for remote vendors of various sizes. The second would be to require greater uniformity, allow correspondingly lower vendor discounts, and impose a nexus standard that would relieve small remote vendors of the obligation to collect use tax where incurring the compliance costs to collect a modest amount of revenue cannot be justified. Such a nexus standard would, of course, be based on the volume of sales a remote vendor made to a given state. How high the threshold was set would depend on the degree of uniformity. As noted earlier, there would be little or no reason for a nexus rule if there were enough uniformity. Both these techniques would prevent the states from foisting off on remote vendors the costs of dealing with the unwarranted diversity that characterizes the current state sales and use tax system. They differ in one important respect.75 State compensation for the costs caused by the complexity of the current system would entail continuation of the deadweight cost to society that could be avoided by reducing complexity and thus costs. Thus the second alternative is preferable, because it would reduce those costs. Merchants who now bear the costs of compliance, with little or no compensation, would benefit from both the reduction in complexity and the state compensation for their 15 remaining costs. c. Uniform local sales taxes The existence of local sales and use taxes complicates the picture considerably. Suppose first that there were a uniform system of state sales and use taxes of the type described above, that at most only one level of local government levied sales and use tax in a given state, that all local governments at that level in the state imposed the tax and at the same rate, and that states collected the tax for local governments. Under these circumstances, remote sales need not cause serious problems. There would be no problem in knowing the correct local tax rate to apply, since local tax would apply to all taxable sales in the state. This means that there would be only one combined state and local rate per state. The only issue would be how to get use tax revenue to the jurisdiction of destination of sales. It might be possible for remote vendors to differentiate between sales made to buyers in various local jurisdictions and report the results to the state. It would be far simpler – and probably produce an acceptable result – for the state government to collect use tax on remote sales by adding the local rate to the state rate and divide the revenues among local governments in proportion to receipts of tax collected by local merchants.76 d. Diverse local sales taxes. Again, reality is much more complicated than the scenario just described. More than one level of local government in a given state may levy sales and use taxes, all jurisdictions at a given level may not impose the tax, state and local tax bases may not be identical, even in a single state, and some local governments administer their own sales taxes. In this environment it may be difficult merely to determine the correct tax rate to apply to a given transaction and to channel the revenue to the correct jurisdiction. The need to deal with unique local tax bases and local tax administration further complicates matters. Solving this problem by prohibiting local sales and use taxes would be impractical, both because sales taxes are an important source of local revenue in many states and because revenues have previously been pledged to service bonds issued to finance capital improvements. Nor would simply levying a use tax at “one rate per state” and sharing the local part of revenues with local governments in proportion to receipts from taxes collected by local merchants give the theoretically correct answer. All things considered, the best choice may be either to exempt remote sales from local use tax entirely or to collect tax at a single uniform rate in each state and share revenues among local jurisdictions in a manner chosen by the state. 3. Evaluation of the Streamlined Sales and Use Tax Act (SSUTA) Based on the normative criteria outlined above, we believe that the SSUTA is fundamentally a move in the right direction – the prescription of simplification and 16 greater uniformity in conjunction with the removal of nexus rules that create undesirable economic consequences Under the prescribed conditions of simplification and uniformity, nexus rules would no longer be needed to reduce complexity and thus could no longer be justified. The requirement of “reasonable compensation for all sellers that administer, collect, and remit sales and use tax,”77 including, in particular, “compensation that covers all tax processing costs of remote sellers”78 reinforces our view that the SSUTA recognizes the importance of requiring vendor discounts to compensate for incremental costs of compliance, which would still be much higher than they need to be, because of the complexity that would remain even under the Streamlined Agreement. We also believe that the requirement that the state and local tax base within any jurisdiction be “identical” – which is explicitly embodied in the Streamlined Agreement79 and, therefore, by implication, in the SSUTA – is an essential component of the legislative proposal that we endorse as a matter of principle. Finally, we believe that the legislation strikes the proper balance between the interests of state sovereignty and those of national economic unity. It respects the states' ability to establish their own tax rates, and, indeed, even goes so far (perhaps further than we would have gone) as to allow the states freedom to define their own tax bases. At the same time, it imposes significant requirements on the states to harmonize and simplify their systems and thereby to provide the proper predicate for requiring collection by remote sellers. Having expressed our general agreement with the thrust of the SSUTA, we wish to make it clear that there are many aspects of the legislation, not to mention the untidy reality surrounding it, about which we are skeptical, uncomfortable, and, in some instances, in flat disagreement. For present purposes, we simply identify these concerns, because full exploration of them would demand more time and space than we currently have. Nevertheless, we believe that these concerns must be addressed in the public debate over the wisdom and shape of the SSUTA, and our endorsement of the SSUTA as a matter of principle is conditioned on the assumption that these concerns will be the subject of robust and open debate. First, we believe that the “minimum simplification requirements” prescribed by the SSUTA80 and embodied in the Streamlined Agreement must be more than empty promises that are ignored in fact. While no one can seriously quarrel with the desiderata embodied in the SSUTA and the Streamlined Agreement, the devil (as they always say) is in the details, and there is considerable controversy as to whether the current efforts of the states to implement the Streamlined Agreement satisfy the promise of meaningful simplification.81 It essential that Congress examine carefully the extent to which the efforts of the states to implement the Streamlined Agreement have in fact adequately simplified and harmonized the states’ sales and use tax regimes before it puts its imprimatur upon the SSUTA in any form. Second, we question whether the thresholds established by the SSUTA make any sense. The SSUTA provides that no seller shall be subject to any requirement that it collect taxes on remote sales when the seller and its affiliates have less than $5 million of gross remote sales or when an individual seller has less than $100,000 of gross remote sales (even when its affiliates exceed the $5 million threshold). We believe the thresholds 17 are misguided on two counts. First, and most importantly, thresholds (as we observed above) are justified when the costs of compliance are not commensurate with the revenue collected. This is an inquiry that depends on the volume of sales that a remote vendor makes to any particular state, not on its nationwide volume of sales. If a company makes $4,999, 999 into State A and $1 of remote sales into every other state, there is no warrant for requiring collection of the taxes on remote sales except in State A. Moreover, the vendor compensation, if properly calculated for the other states, would almost certainly far exceed the revenue at issue. In short, Congress should focus on thresholds on a stateby-state basis. Second, we see no justification for providing an exception for affiliated sellers who happen to have less than $100,000 of gross sales. Congress should make up its mind whether it wants to treat affiliated sellers as a single unit or not. The SSUTA generally treats them as a single unit (which we believe is sound), but then provides an exception for “small” affiliates. To us this is simply an invitation for tax planners to create separate affiliates who have less than $100,000 of remote sales and therefore need not collect taxes on such sales. Finally, we wish to make it clear that we are persuaded to express our support for the SSUTA, despite some misgivings, because we are at a critical juncture where Congress has a unique opportunity to act. Although in an ideal world we might urge Congress to tell the states to go back to the drawing boards and get it “right” – adopting a uniform tax base, as well as uniform definitions, providing administrative procedures that are uniform from state to state, permitting small vendors to comply with tax collection requirements in their “home” state, etc. – we recognize that the world is less ideal than we might like it to be. Accordingly, we believe that the SSUTA may be our “last best chance” (at least during our lifetimes) of achieving significant, if less than perfect, reform and improvement of the state sales and use tax system. In the end, notwithstanding our reservations about the SSUTA in its present form, we believe that the “perfect” should not be permitted to drive out the “good,” and that the second-best solution embodied in the SSUTA, modified we hope by some of the suggestions we have made above, will result in meaningful improvement of the states sales and use regimes as they exist today. C. Business Activity Tax Legislation 1. The Business Activity Tax Simplification Act Legislation has been introduced in Congress limiting the states’ power to impose business activity taxes (BATs).82 The proposed legislation prevents the states from imposing net income taxes or other “direct” taxes on business activity (e.g., gross receipts taxes), unless the taxpayer satisfies the statutorily prescribed nexus requirements. The most significant of these requirements are a physical presence requirement (exceeding 21 days of physical presence). In substance, the legislation expands the requirements of Public Law 86-272,83 which imposes limited nexus requirements with respect to net income taxes on income from the sale of tangible personal property, to any BAT on any form of business activity (including the sale of services and intangibles), and provides a number of specified “safe harbors” for physical presence (e.g., the 21-day requirement, 18 activities in connection with the possible purchase of goods or services, and participation in educational or training conferences). 2. Principal Normative Consideration Bearing on Nexus for for BAT Legislation As in the discussion of ITFA and SSUTA, we begin by asking what nexus standards would be appropriate under an ideal tax regime, in this context one in which all states used the same income attribution rules. Then we ask what nexus rules would be appropriate under the more realistic assumption that the tax regime is less than ideal, namely, that income attribution rules are not uniform.84 a. Uniform income attribution rules Corporate income should be subject to tax in the state where it is earned, at rates chosen by the state. It is, however, generally not realistic to try to employ geographic separate accounting to determine the source of income for a corporation that carries on integrated economic activities across state lines. Leaving aside the obvious fact that corporations do not keep books on a state-by-state basis, and should not be required to incur the enormous compliance costs required to do so, geographic separate accounting would fail to take account of the economic interdependencies between activities occurring in different states and would be vulnerable to manipulation of transfer prices on transactions occurring within the corporation to shift income to low-tax or no-tax states. The states have thus long used formulas to apportion “business income,” by far the majority of corporate income, between in-state and out-of-state activities. Some states “combine” the activities of affiliated corporations deemed to be engaged in a “unitary business” for two of the same reasons they use formula apportionment, economic interdependence and difficulties of transfer pricing. The choice of apportionment formulas (including the weights to put on the various apportionment “factors”) and the definition of each of the factors are, to some extent, arbitrary, as are the definition of apportionable income, the exact standard to use in determining the contours of a unitary business, and administrative procedures. But it is clearly advantageous for all states to define apportionable income in the same way, use the same apportionment formula,85 define the apportionment factors in the same way, employ unitary combination, employ the same definition of a unitary business, and utilize the same administrative procedures. Uniformity would minimize compliance costs and prevent gaps and overlaps in the tax system, with the attendant inequities and distortions. Combination, rather than separate entity accounting, is required to combat tax planning and prevent loss of revenue. With uniform income attribution rules and administrative procedures, a single spreadsheet would provide a comprehensive division of income of the relevant corporate group among the various states, including those that have no income tax, and there would be little or no need for nexus rules. Introduced into this environment, a nexus threshold like that currently embodied in Public Law 86-272 would, in the first instance, almost certainly create “nowhere income” – income attributed to states that lack jurisdiction to tax it86 – and a high nexus standard would probably lead 19 to suggestions for ways to prevent this from happening, such as excluding the taxpayer’s factors in the state where it lacks nexus from the denominator of the apportionment formula.87 Uniform income attribution rules are necessary for a satisfactory solution, but they are not sufficient. Even if income attribution rules were uniform, there might be adverse economic consequences, opportunities for tax planning, and “nowhere income;” these possibilities would depend on the particular rules chosen. For example, if the uniform rules included apportionment based solely on sales, a nexus standard based on anything but a sales threshold would have this effect. This can be illustrated by the interaction of Public Law 86-272 and uniform adoption of sales only apportionment. Under this regime a corporation would pay little or no BAT in a state either i) if it had substantial sales in the state, but could take advantage of the Public Law 86-272 safe harbor, or ii) if it had a substantial physical presence but only minimal sales. b. Diverse income attribution rules The BATs currently levied by the states often provide substantially different solutions to the problem of attributing income to its source. Definitions of apportionable and allocable income differ. Some states do not require combination, and those that do often have inconsistent definitions of the combined group. Nor do all states use the same apportionment formula or define the apportionment factors (especially sales) in the same way. Finally, administrative procedures are not uniform. The result is complexity, gaps and overlaps in taxation, adverse economic effects, opportunities for tax planning, and loss of revenue. While a nexus threshold is arguably appropriate under these circumstances to reduce complexity, a badly chosen threshold will aggravate the other problems, just as in the case of uniform income attribution rules. The only persuasive justification for nexus rules is to ameliorate complexity – to avoid payment or collection of taxes where the revenue involved is not worth the cost of compliance and administration. This implies that nexus rules for BATs should take account of the taxpayer’s apportionment factors in a state88 That is, if a taxpayer does not have at least one factor in the state that exceeds a certain threshold, stated alternatively as a minimum dollar amount or a minimum fraction of the taxpayer’s total of that factor, it should not be liable for BAT in that state. Conversely, if it exceeds the threshold for at least one factor that appears in the state’s apportionment formula, it should be deemed to have nexus for BAT in that state.89 How high nexus standards should be depends on how much diversity there is in the state BATs. If there were little or no diversity, the standard could be quite low or non-existent, as noted earlier. On the other hand, substantial diversity would call for a much higher standard. This implies that if the states want the Congress to enact a low nexus standard for BAT they should be required to reduce substantially the diversity of their taxes. 20 3. Evaluation of Proposed BAT Legislation As noted earlier, legislation has been proposed that would expand the nexus protection provided by Public Law 86-272 by making it applicable to income from any type of sales (not merely sales of tangible products) and specifying activities that could be conducted in a state without creating nexus for BAT. In other words, it specifies that a physical presence is required to create nexus; sales are not enough. The proposed legislation is clearly inconsistent with the normative considerations delineated above. It would expand the scope for the creation of “nowhere income,” and thus aggravate the opportunities for tax planning and the revenue loss created by Public Law 86-272. This is especially true in states where sales are the only or primary factor used to apportion income – a rule that has been advocated by many of the same business interests that are seeking a physical presence nexus rule for BAT. Beyond the normative considerations that we believe should shape congressional policy regarding nexus for BAT purpose, we believe it important to identify and discuss several unsound arguments that are often heard in the present debate. The following excerpt from a policy statement by the Council for State Taxation is representative of one such view: Determinations of jurisdiction to tax should be guided by one fundamental principle: a government has the right to impose burdens—economic as well as administrative—only on businesses that receive meaningful benefits or protections from that government. In the context of business activity taxes, this guiding principle means that businesses that are not present in a jurisdiction and are therefore not receiving any benefits or protections from the jurisdiction, should not be required to pay tax to that jurisdiction.90 This line of reasoning is indefensible, whether the benefits corporations receive are defined broadly, to mean the ability to earn income, or defined more narrowly to mean specific benefits of public spending, one of which is the intangible but important ability to enforce contracts, without which commerce would be impossible. A profitable corporation clearly enjoys both types of benefits. It is true that in-state corporations may receive greater benefits than their out-of-state counterparts, for example, because they have physical assets that need fire and police protection. But this is a question of the magnitude of benefits and the tax that is appropriate to finance them – something that is properly addressed by the choice of apportionment formula and the tax rate, not the type of yes/no question that is relevant for issues of nexus.91 The answer must clearly be a resounding “Yes,” to the question, "whether the State has given anything for which it can ask return."92 A second invalid argument relies on the Revolutionary War rallying cry, “No taxation without representation.” Opponents of tighter nexus rules suggest that such rules would violate the basic American principle that there should be no taxation without 21 representation. This argument fails on several grounds. First, not all rallying cries of the Revolutionary War made their way into the Constitution. An inviolate link between the right to vote and the duty to pay tax is not among those that did. Individuals who lack the right to vote due to non-residence are nonetheless (properly) taxable. Second, virtually all of the taxes under discussion here are (or would be, under a tighter nexus standard) paid or collected by corporations, not by individuals. Since corporations do not vote, this argument is something of a red herring. Beyond that, out-of-state taxpayers, whether actual or potential and whether corporations or individuals, have the same right to be represented by lobbyists as do in-state corporate and individual taxpayers. Indeed, corporate officials can probably do their own lobbying without running afoul of existing nexus standards, let alone sensible ones.93 Thus this charge lacks substance. Third, the same argument could be made against payment of property taxes.94 Finally, and most fundamentally, the type of taxation that would occur under sensible nexus rules would not discriminate against out-of-state business (something the U.S. Supreme Court would not countenance). Rather, sensible nexus rules would prevent discrimination in favor of out-of-state business, by subjecting them to the same rules as in-state businesses, except as required to prevent excessive complexity. Even if it were true that out-of-state businesses had no representation, it is difficult to see the harm in requiring that they pay or collect the same taxes as their in-state competitors. (With uniform taxation, in-state businesses can be expected to help protect the interests of their out-of-state competitors in the political arena, since they will pay the same taxes.) 4. The Issue of Linkage It has been suggested that enactment of the SSUTA and the BAT legislation should be linked – that both are good, but neither should be enacted without the other.95 It may be appropriate under certain circumstances to link reforms. For example, it has long been recognized that it might be possible to link state action to simplify their sales and use taxes with federal action to allow an expanded duty for remote sellers to collect use taxes, thereby reducing the adverse economic effects caused by the physical presence test of nexus, as well as complexity. This linkage is entirely appropriate, as the National Bellas Hess/Quill decisions were a response to the complexity of these taxes. It would not be appropriate to allow an expanded duty to collect, in the absence of simplification, and true simplification, although desirable for its own sake, may occur only if the federal government holds out the “carrot” of an expanded duty to collect. By comparison, the proposed linkage of SSUTA and the BAT legislation is only political; it has no inherent logic. It is intended a) to create a quid-pro quo for action on the two issues and b) to allay fears that the lower nexus threshold for use taxes would seep over into a lower threshold for BATs. The second of these is more appropriately addressed by establishing the type of nexus standard based on the presence of apportionment factors described earlier. 22 IV. Conclusion Debates over the propriety of congressional intervention in state tax matters are intense and important, because they touch one of most sensitive nerves of our federal system – the tension between the states’ right to exercise their sovereign tax powers and the nation’s interest in a common market unfettered by burdensome state regulations. Understandably, but unfortunately, such debates often generate more heat than light, and the debates over the ITFA, SSUTA, and BAT legislative proposals are no exception. In this paper, we have attempted to contribute to a reasoned consideration of these legislative proposals by identifying the principal normative criteria that should guide the inquiry into their merits and by evaluating the proposals in light of those criteria. Although we are not so optimistic or naïve as to believe that our conclusions will command universal support, we do hope that our analysis will help inform and elevate the debate over these legislative proposals. 23 NOTES 1 This paper was sponsored by the National Governors Association (NGA). The views expressed in this paper are, however, entirely our own and do not necessarily reflect those of the NGA. The authors would like to thank Hal Varian and George Zodrow for their helpful comments on an earlier draft of this article. All remaining errors are our own. 2 See generally Walter Hellerstein, “Federal Constitutional Limitations on Congressional Power to Legislate Regarding State Taxation of Electronic Commerce,” National Tax Journal, Vol. 53, No. 4, Part 3 (December 2000), pp. 1307-25. 3 U.S. Const. art. I, § 8, cl. 3. 4 Prudential Insurance Co. v. Benjamin, 328 U.S. 408, 434 (1946). 5 Moorman Manufacturing Co. v. Bair, 437 U.S. 267, 280 (1978). 6 Under the so-called "dormant" or "negative" Commerce Clause, the U.S. Supreme Court has construed the affirmative grant of power to Congress to regulate interstate commerce as embodying implied restraints on state legislation, even when Congress does not act. See generally Jerome R. Hellerstein and Walter Hellerstein, State Taxation, 3rd ed (Boston: Warren, Gorham & Lamont, 1998), chapter 4. Over the course of the past two centuries, the Court has handed down hundreds of decisions delineating these negative restraints, which include, in the area of state taxation, the requirements that "the tax is applied to an activity with a substantial nexus with the taxing State, is fairly apportioned, does not discriminate against interstate commerce, and is fairly related to the services provided by the State." Complete Auto Transit, Inc. v. Brady, 430 U.S. 274, 288-89 (1977). 7 504 U.S. 298 (1992). 8 Id. at 318. 9 15 U.S.C. §§ 381-84. 10 Pub. L. 94–210, 90 Stat. 54, 49 U.S.C. § 14501. 11 49 U.S.C. § 14502. 12 49 U.S.C. § 40116. 13 15 U.S.C. § 78bb(d). 14 49 U.S.C. § 40116. 15 29 U.S.C. § 1144(a). 16 15 U.S.C. § 391. 17 47 U.S.C. § 251. 18 49 U.S.C. § 14505. 19 4 U.S.C. § 116 et seq. 20 The Federalist No. 32 (A. Hamilton), reproduced in The Federalist Papers (New York: Mentor, 1961), 24 pp. 197-201. Some of the more extravagant statements regarding the scope of the states' sovereign powers of taxation found in The Federalist, made to emphasize the importance of such powers to the states' independent political existence, are not accurate descriptions of the legal scope of such powers under current constitutional doctrine. 21 Gibbons v. Ogden, 22 U.S. (9 Wheat.) 1, 199 (1824). See also Weston v. City of Charleston, 27 U.S. (2 Pet.) 449, 466 (1829) ("The power of taxation is one of the most essential to a state, and one of the most extensive in its operation."). 22 Railroad Co. v. Penniston, 85 U.S. 5, 29 (1873). 23 Allied Stores of Ohio, Inc. v. Bowers, 358 U.S. 522, 527 (1959). 24 See Mariano Tommasi, “Federalism in Argentina and the Reforms of the 1990s,” and Alberto DiazCayeros, José Antonio González, and Fernando Rojas, “Mexico’s Decentralization at a Crossroads,” both presented at the Workshop on Federalism in a Global Environment, Stanford University, June 6-7, 2002, and forthcoming in T. N. Srinivasan and Jessica Seddon Wallack, editors, Federalism and Economic Reform in a Global Environment. 25 Gibbons v. Ogden, 22 U.S. (9 Wheat.) 1, 199 (1824). 26 Mobil Oil Corp. v. Commissioner of Taxes, 445 U.S. 425, 448 (1980). 27 See Hellerstein and Hellerstein, supra note 6, chapter 1. 28 During the 1960s, Congress undertook an extensive study of state income, capital stock, gross receipts, and sales and use taxation, and it recommended the enactment of legislation. See Special Subcomm. on State Taxation of Interstate Commerce of the House Comm. on the Judiciary, State Taxation of Interstate Commerce, H.R. Rep. No. 1480, 88th Cong., 2d Sess. (1964); H.R. Reps. Nos. 565 and 952, 89th Cong., 1st Sess. (1965). However, no legislation was ever enacted as a result of this study and its recommendations. 29 See supra notes 9-19 and accompanying text. 30 United States v. South-Eastern Underwriters Ass'n, 322 U.S. 533 (1944). 31 15 U.S.C. §§ 1011-1015. 32 Id. 33 114 Stat. 626 (July 28, 2000), codified at 4 U.S.C. § 116 et seq. 34 488 U.S. 252 (1989). 35 Id. at 263. 36 The issues become even more complex if the customer is billed not on a transaction-by-transaction basis, but instead pays, say, $50 per month for 500 minutes of calls regardless of where the calls originate or terminate. Indeed, if the customer were billed at a flat rate, the Goldberg-mandated inquiry would be virtually impossible, since there would be no breakdown of the charges for the calls on a transaction-bytransaction basis. A typical wireless phone bill simply shows the calls made and the minutes consumed with no itemized price allocation if one does not exceed the number of flat rate minutes. Indeed, the “charge” shown for such individual calls is “$00.00.” 37 4 U.S.C. § 116 et seq. 25 38 Id § 117(a). 39 See, e.g., Moorman Mfg. Co. v. Bair, 437 U.S. 267, 278-80 (1978). 40 Quill Corp v. North Dakota, 504 U.S. 298, 318 (1992). 41 Sales taxes are imposed on the sale of goods or services within the state. States lack the constitutional authority to impose a sales tax on goods or services sold outside the state to resident purchasers. To deal with the potential loss of business and revenue that would result if the states' residents made out-of-state purchases to avoid the state's sales tax, states enacted use taxes imposed on the use of goods or services purchased outside the state but used within the state. Use taxes are functionally equivalent to sales taxes, and every state that imposes a sales tax also imposes a use tax in an effort to impose a uniform tax on taxable goods or services sold or used within the state. See generally Hellerstein and Hellerstein, supra note 6, at ¶ 16.01[2]. Because the distinction between sales and use taxes has no bearing on the normative issues that are the concern of this paper, the discussion in the paper generally does not distinguish between sales and use taxes, and it refers to such taxes interchangeably when discussing use taxes. 42 386 U.S. 753 (1967). 43 Whether this is true would depend on whether the physical-presence test of nexus applies to income taxes, an open question; state statutory requirements for filing income tax returns (e.g., whether an enterprise is deemed to be “doing business” in a state); and the formula the state uses to apportion the income of multistate enterprises, in particular, how sales are “sourced”. All states include sales in their apportionment formulas, but some source sales of intangible property and services in such a way that there would be no liability, even in the absence of Public Law 86-272. 44 Pub. L. No. 105-277, §§ 1101-04, 112 Stat. 2681-719 to 2681-726 (1998). For a general discussion of ITFA, see Walter Hellerstein, “Internet Tax Freedom Act Limits States' Power to Tax Internet Access and Electronic Commerce,” Journal of Taxation, Vol. 90, No. 1 (January 1999), pp. 5-10. 45 In November 2001, Congress retroactively extended ITFA for two years through October 2003. "Internet Tax Nondiscrimination Act," H.R. 1522, 107th Cong., 1st Sess. (2001). 46 ITFA § 1104(5). 47 ITFA § 1101(a)(1). 48 ITFA § 1104(2)(B). 49 This provision contains a fundamental ambiguity: whether the critical phrase "a remote seller's out-ofState computer server" -- which a state is barred from considering in determining the out-of-state seller's nexus with the state -- should be read from the vantage point of the taxing state or from the vantage point of the seller. If read from the perspective of the taxing state, which is the more natural reading, the provision is redundant with existing constitutional jurisprudence and is thus virtually meaningless. It would prevent a state from asserting nexus over an out-of-state Internet seller if the state relied solely on the seller's computer server in some other state as a factor in considering whether the taxpayer had nexus in the taxing state. But existing constitutional law would preclude an assertion of jurisdiction in these circumstances. Hence the provision would have added nothing to existing constitutional protections. If the phrase "a remote seller's out-of-State computer server" is read from the standpoint of the seller, so that a state would be forbidden from imposing a use tax collection obligation on a remote Internet seller based exclusively on the presence of the seller's server in the taxing state, then the provision would have had some theoretical significance, but not much practical impact. Most states have indicated that they would not assert jurisdiction over an out-of-state seller based solely on the presence of the out-of-state seller's server in the state. 26 50 ITFA § 1104(2)(B)(ii). This provision contained an ambiguity similar to that contained in the provision described above, see supra note 49: whether the "out-of-State computer server"---which a state is barred from considering in determining whether the Internet access provider is the agent of the remote seller--should be read from the vantage point of the taxing state or from the vantage point of the seller. For reasons set forth above, the provision would have had meaning only if read from the standpoint of the seller. Thus read, it would prevent a state from asserting nexus over an out-of-state Internet seller if the state relied solely on the Internet access provider's computer server in the taxing state as a factor in considering whether the Internet access provider was the remote seller's nexus-creating agent in the taxing state. Construed from this perspective, the provision essentially forbade the states from invoking an "attributional nexus" theory based solely on the remote seller's use of the Internet access providers in-state server. 51 ITFA § 1104(6)(A). 52 ITFA § 1104(6)(B). 53 For varying perspectives on this debate, see Robert Cline, “Critique of Multistate Tax Commission's State and Local Revenue Impact Estimates of H.R. 49,” State Tax Notes, Vol. 30, No. 4 (Oct. 27, 2003), pp. 317-19; Harley Duncan, “States' Approach to ITFA Problems,” State Tax Notes, Vol. 30, No. 4 (Oct. 27, 2003), pp. 311-15; Harley Duncan and Matt Tomalis, “On the ITFA: Telecom’s Trojan Horse,” State Tax Notes, Vol. 31, No. 2 (Jan. 12, 2004), pp. 129-32; Michael Mazerov, “Making the Internet Tax Act Permanent in Currently Proposed Form Would Hurt States,” State Tax Notes, Vol. 30, No. 4 (Oct. 27, 2003), p. 321-37. 54 As noted earlier, see supra note 41, we draw no distinction between sales and use taxes. Such a distinction has no place in a sensible sales tax system. 55 Among the many places where this is explained are Charles E. McLure, Jr., “Achieving Neutrality Between Electronic and Nonelectronic Commerce,” State Tax Notes, Vol. 17, No. 3 (July 19, 1999), pp. 193-97, and Hellerstein and Hellerstein, supra note 6, at ¶¶ 12.05, 12.06. That these tenets were included in a popular undergraduate textbook almost 50 years ago indicates clearly that they have long been an important part of the conventional wisdom among tax experts; see Walter Hellerstein and Charles E. McLure, Jr., “Sales Taxation of Electronic Commerce: What John Due Knew All Along,” State Tax Notes, Vol. 20, No. 4 (January 1, 2001), pp. 41-46; also in the proceedings of the 93rd annual conference on taxation of the National Tax Association, Santa Fe, November 11, 2000, pp. 216-22. The first three principles underlie the value added taxes levied in the European Union and perhaps 90 other countries around the world. (Simplicity is less common.) See Charles E. McLure, Jr., “EU and US Sales Taxes in the Digital Age: A Comparative Analysis,” Bulletin for International Fiscal Documentation, Vol. 56, No. 4 (April 2002), pp. 135-145. 56 Readers might have expected us to list a fourth situation where deviation from the tenets is appropriate, namely, where requiring out-of-state vendors to collect tax may impose an unacceptable burden on interstate commerce, because of the lack of uniformity of sales taxes from state-to-state. If, however, all states followed the first two tenets (tax all sales to households and exempt all sales to business), there would be substantially more uniformity – and much less complexity –than in the current system. In that case, lack of uniformity would seem to derive primarily from inconsistent exemptions of household consumption (including inconsistent definitions of exempt products) and inconsistent administrative requirements. See Charles E. McLure, Jr., “How — and Why — the States Should Tax Electronic Commerce: Explanation of My ACEC Proposal for Radical Simplification,” State Tax Notes, Vol. 18, No. 2 (January 10, 2000), pp. 129-40, Appendix A, or Charles E. McLure, Jr., “The Taxation of Electronic Commerce: Background and Proposal,” in Nicholas Imparato, Public Policy and the Internet: Privacy, Taxes, and Contracts (Stanford, Calif., Hoover Institution Press, 2000), pp. 49-113. We do not discuss this case further here, but do so in Section III(B) below ( “Principal Normative Considerations Bearing on Nexus Over Remote Sellers for Purpose of Requiring Collection of State and Local Use Taxes”). 27 57 Similarly, consumption of some products may entail public spending or be associated with external costs, either of which could justify higher taxation than is imposed on other products. For example, consumption of motor fuels is directly related to motor vehicle operation, which requires the construction and maintenance of roads and highways and may cause congestion and pollution. 58 See generally George R. Zodrow, “Network Externalities and Indirect Tax Preferences for Electronic Commerce,” International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 10, No. 1 (January 2003), pp. 79-97; also in State Tax Notes, Vol. 28, No. 11 ( June 16, 2003), pp. 969-79. 59 Under the assumption that taxation is economically neutral, business purchases of Internet access would be exempt, just like all other business purchases of goods and services. Thus the argument for a subsidy to all users of the Internet would imply not merely an exemption for business purchases of Internet access, but that business should benefit from an actual subsidy. We do not examine this issue further, because the basic argument for subsidizing Internet access is weak. 60 See Zodrow, International Tax and Public Finance, supra note 58, at pp. 82-83; Zodrow, State Tax Notes, supra note 58, at pp. 970-72. 61 "Internet Statistics," available at www.nielsen-netratings.com (visited 2/6/04). 62 Thus it is one thing to exempt 1 million existing users (as well as new users) in order to induce 100 million potential users to join the network, and quite another matter to exempt 100 million existing users in order to induce 1 million potential users to join. While the exemption would eventually benefit 101 million users in both cases, the revenue cost of inducing new use would be very different in the two situations: the tax on only 1 million existing users in the first, but the tax on 100 million existing users in the second. 63 Thus, after a careful evaluation of network externalities, Zodrow writes: At current levels of computer usage, it seems likely that the marginal external benefits from increases in the number of computers connected to the Internet are fairly small -certainly relative to the size of the Internet or the number of transactions conducted over the Internet, and probably in an absolute sense. …That is, the marginal external benefit of adding another user to the network may indeed be large at low and intermediate levels of network usage. Nevertheless, such benefits will eventually become small at a large enough network size because the marginal joiners will be increasingly low demanders, who place a relatively small value on the benefits of joining the network and also generate small external benefits because they participate less in network activities. Although it would be difficult to prove that the marginal external benefits of adding another user to the Internet are currently small, the size of the existing network suggests this is likely to be the case. Citing 1999 figures on Internet access and usage, Zodrow concludes: “Figures of this magnitude (especially if updated to reflect growth over the intervening two years) suggest that the period of explosive Internet growth is rapidly coming to a close…” and “marginal network externalities are likely to be relatively small.” Zodrow, International Tax and Public Finance, supra note 58, at pp. 85-86; Zodrow, State Tax Notes, supra note 58, at pp. 973-74. Two more years of growth have occurred since those words were written in 2001. 64 Internet access providers (IAPs) commonly provide special startup packages, with low initial rates for 3 to 6 months, followed by a bump up to the standard rate. Although the primary purpose of such special rates is presumably to attract customers from other IAPs, they may help create network effects. It would be possible to allow IAPs to package a sales tax reduction as part of the deal, but there seems to be no way to prevent the benefit being made available repeatedly to those who switch IAPs. 28 65 If this approach were adopted for political reasons, the exemption should not be indexed for inflation, so that its real value would decline over time. 66 See Martin Sullivan, “Will VOIP Telephone Service Be Subject to Telephone Taxes,” Tax Notes, Vol. 102, No. 4, (January 26, 2004), pp. 458-66, or State Tax Notes, Vol. 31, No. 5 (February 2, 2004), pp. 385-92. 67 Of course, the revenue loss would not be nearly as large if business purchases of telecommunications were already exempt, as they would be under the economically neutral system. It should also be noted that the telecommunications industry is currently subjected to far higher taxes than other industries; see Council on State Taxation (COST) Telecommunications Tax Task Force, “2001 State Study and Report on Telecommunications Taxation,” reproduced as a Special Report in Tax Management (Bureau of National Affairs), Multistate Tax Report, Vol. 9, No. 2 (February 22, 2002). Since such deviations from uniform taxation cannot be justified, this excessive taxation should be eliminated, in order to avoid placing telecommunications at a competitive disadvantage, which would occur even if Internet access and thus Internet telephony were taxed like other products. 68 It would, in theory, be possible to use a refundable federal income tax credit to make the subsidy available only to the poor. Such an approach would at least put the cost in terms of lost revenue on the federal government, where it belongs, but this approach is fraught with difficulties. We do not discuss it further. 69 This raises an interesting question of interpretation, namely, whether telecommunications services and digital content purchased by Internet service providers should be exempt, since they can be seen as purchases for resale. Under existing statutes and case law, the answer to that question would turn on such inquiries as whether the telecommunications services or content are being resold as such or rather are being “consumed” in the course of delivering a different service or product and whether the ultimate service or product that is sold is subject to tax, since the sale-for-resale exemption is designed to avoid pyramiding of the tax. The conceptually correct solution – exemption of all sales to business -- avoids the need to make these often difficult determinations. 70 The description of this legislation is based on the Streamlined Sales and Use Tax Act, S. 1736, 108th Cong., 1st Sess. (2003). Similar legislation will almost certainly be (if it has not already been) introduced into Congress during the Second Session of the 108th Congress. 71 It seems to be more common to argue that vendors should be compensated for collecting sales taxes than to argue for compensation for collection of withholding taxes, although both cases involve private firms acting as collection agents for taxes owed by third parties. A strong case can be made on policy grounds, but rarely is, that those who pay income and other direct taxes should be compensated for at least part of their costs of compliance and litigation (but not costs of tax planning), in order to reduce the inclination to enact complex statutes. Since the federal government is the source of most complexity in the income tax, it should be responsible for this aspect of taxpayer compensation. 72 Vendor costs should cover only the additional costs vendors incur in order to comply with tax collection obligations. Thus, for example, they should not cover any of the costs of processing credit card purchases, except to the extent that such costs result from calculation and collection of tax. 73 This is not intended to be a complete list of the ways in which state sales and use taxes could and should be made uniform. It is intended to paint the “big picture.” 74 We say this fully appreciating that in a world of truly independent sovereign states, there may be no jurisdictional authority to require a remote vendor to comply with another state’s consumption tax rules, even on the utopian assumption that all such states had identical consumption tax rules. As we have noted above, however, in the U.S. federal system, there is ample authority for Congress to authorize such collection, subject only to the loose restraints that the Due Process Clause imposes on the exercise of state 29 taxing authority. 75 They would differ in other respects as well (e.g., in the extent to which they treat customers of remote vendors and local merchants the same), none of which seems worth discussing in detail. 76 Whether merchants currently paying local sales and use taxes under so-called “direct pay” authority – whereby certain taxpayers are permitted to self-assess sales and use taxes rather than paying them to their vendors – would continue to pay under this regime or would be integrated into the regime described in the text is a question that would need to be addressed. We leave this question, and many other detailed questions that could be raised about such a regime, to another day. 77 SSUTA § 6(12). 78 Id. § 4(c). 79 Streamlined Agreement § 302. The effective date of this provision is January 1, 2006. 80 SSUTA § 6. 81 See generally George S. Isaacson, “A Promise Unfulfilled: How the Streamlined Sales Tax Project Failed to Meet Its Own Goals for Simplification of the State Sales and Use Taxes,” State Tax Notes, Vol. 30, No. 4 (Oct. 27, 2003), pp. 339-52. We recognize, of course, that the cited reference is the partisan testimony of a skilled advocate on behalf a client (the Direct Marketing Association), whose constituency benefits roundly from the existing regime under which many of its members have no constitutional obligation to collect use taxes on remote sales. Nevertheless, a number of the points raised in the testimony cannot be dismissed as mere rhetoric, and plainly warrant further consideration by Congress and its staff. 82 The description of this legislation is based on the Business Activity Tax Simplification Act of 2003, H.R. 3220, 108th Cong., 1st Sess. (2003). Similar legislation will almost certainly be (if it has not already been) introduced into Congress during the Second Session of the 108th Congress. 83 See supra note 9 and accompanying text. 84 We ignore the question of separate nexus with localities because it does not appear to have generated any controversy in the BAT debate and is not an issue under Public Law 86-272 (or the proposed BAT legislation extending Public Law 86-272). Although Public Law 86-272 (and the proposed BAT legislation) cover state and local income taxes and BATs, the basic nexus restraint is imposed at the state level only. In other words, if there is nexus within a state, a locality within that state may impose a BAT, even if there is no “independent” nexus within the locality under the nexus standards applied at the state level. The same analysis applies under judicially articulated constitutional doctrine. See Aldens v. Tully, 49 N.Y.2d 525, 404 N.E.2d 703 (1980) (existence of nexus with a state provides sufficient nexus for a state to require a vendor to collect a use tax imposed by a locality within the state, even if the vendor has no “independent” nexus with the locality). 85 On the importance of a uniform apportionment formula, see National Tax Association, “Report of Committee on the Apportionment between States of Taxes on Mercantile and Manufacturing Business,” Proceedings of the National Tax Association, 1922, p. 202. (“All methods of apportionment ... are arbitrary -- the cutting of the Gordian knot. ... [T]here probably are a number of different rules, all of which may work substantial justice... [T]he only right rule ... is a rule on which the several states can and will get together as a matter of comity.”) 86 Only if the states adopted a uniform apportionment formula without a sales factor would a nexus threshold based on sales be unlikely to create “nowhere income.” 87 Some states employ a “throwback” rule that attributes sales otherwise attributable to a state that lacks jurisdiction to tax to the state of origin of such sales. It would seem more logical simply to eliminate sales 30 to the no-nexus state from the denominator of the sales factor. Whereas this rule would eliminate the possibility of “nowhere income,” reliance on “throwback” would do so only if adopted by the state of origin. 88 Nexus rules intended to mitigate complexity for multistate corporations could be designed also to take account of the taxpayer’s total apportionable income, since there will be little tax liability if there is little apportionable income, even if the taxpayer has a large amount or a large fraction of its apportionment factors in the taxing state. But lack of enough taxable income to justify costs of compliance is not an acceptable basis for a solely in-state corporation not to file a tax return. 89 See also Charles E. McLure, Jr. "Implementing State Corporate Income Taxes in the Digital Age,” National Tax Journal, Vol. 53, No. 4, Part 3 (December 2000), pp. 1287-1305. In principle, the nexus rule should be tailored to the apportionment formula employed by the state. Suppose, for example, that state A used a three-factor formula, but state B used only sales to apportion income. In state A there would be three alternative thresholds, one for each factor in the formula, exceeding any of which could trigger nexus. In state B there would be only a sales threshold. The Multistate Tax Commission has proposed a rule that considers the presence of all three factors, regardless of the particular formula the state uses. As a practical matter, the two rules are likely to have quite similar effects, as the sales threshold is the one that is most likely to be effective in most cases where nexus is at issue. 90 Council on State Taxation, “Jurisdiction to Impose Business Activity Tax,” a policy position, available at: http://www.statetax.org/Content/NavigationMenu/Legislative/Policy_Statements/Default271.htm (emphasis supplied). 91 For earlier expressions of this view, see Walter Hellerstein, "Jurisdiction to Tax Income and Consumption in the New Economy: A Theoretical and Comparative Perspective," Georgia Law Review, Vol. 38, No. 1 (Fall 2003), pp. 1-70, and Charles E. McLure, Jr., "Source-Base Taxation and Alternatives to the Concept of Permanent Establishment, in Report of the Proceedings of the World Tax Conference: Taxes without Borders (Toronto: Canadian Tax Foundation: 2000), pp. 6:1-15. 92 Wisconsin v. J.C. Penney Co., 311 U.S. 435, 444 (1940). It is worth noting that the failure to receive quantifiable benefits from the state is not, at least in constitutional terms, a defense to the imposition of a tax. As the U.S. Supreme Court observed in Commonwealth Edison Co. v. Montana, 453 U.S. 609 (1981), in rejecting a taxpayer's argument that the severance tax imposed on its coal far exceeded the benefits it received from the state and that the tax therefore violated the Commerce Clause: "[a] tax is not an assessment of benefits. It is, as we have said, a means of distributing the burden of the cost of government. The only benefit to which the taxpayer is constitutionally entitled is that derived from his enjoyment of the privileges of living in an organized society, established and safeguarded by the devotion of taxes to public purposes." Id. at 623 (quoting Carmichael v. Southern Coal & Coke Co., 301 U.S. 495, 521-22 (1937)). 93 This raises interesting and perhaps complicated questions that cannot be addressed here. To meet this objection there could be a safe harbor for coming to a state for the purpose of “[m]eeting government officials for purposes other than selling goods and services,” as in the BAT legislation. 94 The fact that property taxes are “in rem” and may be satisfied by sale of the property in question (rather than a direct action against the taxpayer) does not, as a practical matter, undermine our essential point that the taxation (and involuntary deprivation of property associated with taxation) may not be resisted on the ground that the person (individual or corporate) who bears the burden of the deprivation has no voting rights in the taxing state. 95 Council on State Taxation, “Federal Standard for Imposition and Collection of State and Local Taxes,” a 31 policy position, available at: http://www.statetax.org/Content/NavigationMenu/Legislative/Policy_Statements/Default271.htm. 32