A ppendix to Chapter 10 Producing at Least Cost This appendix describes a set of useful tools for studying a firm’s long-run production and costs. The tools are isoquants and isocost lines. I soquants F . ’ function. The figure highlights that Swanky can use three different combinations of labor and capital to produce 15 sweaters a day and two different combinations to produce 10 and 21 sweaters a day. These combinations, and many others not shown in the figure, can be illustrated by using an isoquant map. An Isoquant Map An isoquant is a curve that shows the different combinations of labor and capital required to pro- duce a given quantity of output. The word isoquant means “equal quantity”—iso meaning equal and quant meaning quantity. There is an isoquant for each output level. A series of isoquants is called an isoquant map. Figure A10.2 shows an isoquant map with three isoquants: one for 10 sweaters, one for 15 sweaters, and one for 21 sweaters. Each isoquant shown is based on the production function in Fig. A10.1. Although all goods and services can be produced by using a variety of alternative methods of production or techniques, the ease with which capital and labor can be substituted for each other varies from industry to industry. The shape of the production function reflects the ease with which inputs can be substituted for each other. Therefore the production function can be used to calculate the degree of substitutability between inputs. Such a calculation involves a new concept—the marginal rate of substitution of labor for capital. FIGURE TO C H A P T E R 1 0 P RO D U C I N G AT LEAST COST A10.1 FIGURE Capital (machines per day) Swanky’s Production Function Output (sweaters per day) 5 4 3 16 15 13 22 21 18 25 24 22 27 26 24 28 27 25 5 4 10 15 18 20 b 3 2 2 A10.2 An Isoquant Map Capital (machines per day) APPENDIX a c 21 1 1 4 10 13 15 1 2 3 15 sweaters 16 10 sweaters 0 0 21 sweaters 4 5 Labor (workers per day) The figure shows how many sweaters can be produced per day by various combinations of labor and capital inputs. For example, by using 1 worker and 2 machines, Swanky can produce 10 sweaters a day; and by using 4 workers and 2 knitting machines, Swanky can produce 20 sweaters. Marginal Rate of Substitution The marginal rate of substitution of labor for capital is the decrease in capital needed per unit increase in labor so that output remains constant. The marginal rate of substitution is the magnitude of the slope of the isoquant. Figure A10.3 illustrates this relationship. The figure shows the isoquant for 13 sweaters a day. Pick any point on this isoquant and imagine increasing labor by the smallest conceivable amount and decreasing capital by the amount necessary to keep output constant at 13 sweaters. As we increase the labor input and decrease the capital input so as to keep output constant at 13 sweaters a day, we travel down along the isoquant. The marginal rate of substitution of labor for capital at point a is the magnitude of the slope of the straight red line that is tangent to the isoquant at point a. The slope of the isoquant at point a equals the slope of the red line. To calculate that slope, let’s 1 2 3 4 5 Labor (workers per day) The figure illustrates an isoquant map, but one that shows only 3 isoquants—those for 10, 15, and 21 sweaters a day. These curves correspond to the production function shown in Fig. A10.1. If Swanky uses 2 machines and 1 worker (point a), it produces 10 sweaters. If it uses 4 machines and 1 worker (point b), it produces 15 sweaters. And if it uses 2 machines and 5 workers (point c), it produces 21 sweaters. move along the red line from 5 knitting machines and no workers to 2.5 workers and no knitting machines. Capital decreases by 5 knitting machines, and labor increases by 2.5 workers. The magnitude of the slope is 5 divided by 2.5, which equals 2. Thus when Swanky uses technique a to produce 13 sweaters a day, the marginal rate of substitution of labor for capital is 2. The marginal rate of substitution of labor for capital at point b is the magnitude of the slope of the straight red line that is tangent to the isoquant at point b. Along this red line, if capital decreases by 2.5 knitting machines, labor increases by 5 workers. The magnitude of the slope is 2.5 knitting machines divided by 5, which equals 1/2. Thus when Swanky uses technique b to produce 13 sweaters a day, the marginal rate of substitution of labor for capital is 1/2. The marginal rates of substitution we’ve just calculated obey the law of diminishing marginal rate of substitution, which states that ISOCOST LINES FIGURE A10.3 FIGURE Swanky’s Input Possibilities Capital (machines per day) Capital (machines per day) The Marginal Rate of Substitution 5 4 MRS = 2 a 3 2 A10.4 5 4 3 a Total cost = $100 b c 2 1 MRS = — 2 b 1 d 1 13 sweaters 0 1 2 3 4 5 Labor (workers per day) The marginal rate of substitution is measured by the magnitude of the slope of the isoquant. To calculate the marginal rate of substitution at point a, use the red line that is tangential to the isoquant at point a. Calculate the slope of that line to find the slope of the isoquant at point a. The magnitude of the slope at point a is 2. Thus at a point a, the marginal rate of substitution of labor for capital is 2. The marginal rate of substitution at point b is found from the slope of the red line tangential to the isoquant at that point. That slope is 1/2. Thus the marginal rate of substitution of labor for capital at point b is 1/2. The marginal rate of substitution of labor for capital diminishes as the amount of labor increases and the amount of capital decreases. You can now see that the law of diminishing marginal rate of substitution determines the shape of the isoquant. When the capital input is large and the labor input is small, the isoquant is steep and the marginal rate of substitution of labor for capital is large. As the capital input decreases and the labor input increases, the isoquant becomes flatter and the marginal rate of substitution of labor for capital diminishes. Only curves that are bowed toward the origin have this feature; hence isoquants are always bowed toward the origin. Isoquants are very nice, but what do we do with them? The answer is that we use them to work out a Isocost line e 0 1 2 3 4 5 Labor (workers per day) For a given total cost, Swanky’s input possibilities depend on input prices. If labor and capital cost $25 a day each, for a total cost of $100 Swanky can employ the combinations of capital and labor shown by the points a through e. The line passing through these points is an isocost line. It shows all possible combinations of capital and labor that Swanky can hire for a total cost of $100 when capital and labor cost $25 a day each. firm’s least-cost technique of production. But to do so, we need to illustrate the firm’s costs in the same sort of figure that contains the isoquants. I socost Lines A ’ lines. An isocost line shows all the combinations of capital and labor that can be bought for a given total cost. For example, suppose Swanky is going to spend $100 a day producing sweaters. Knitting-machine operators can be hired for $25 a day, and knitting machines can be rented for $25 a day. The points a, b, c, d, and e in Fig. A10.4 show five possible combinations of labor and capital that Swanky can employ for $100. For example, point b shows that Swanky can use 3 machines (costing $75) and 1 worker (costing TO C H A P T E R 1 0 P RO D U C I N G AT LEAST COST $25). If Swanky can employ workers and machines for fractions of a day, then any combination along the line ae will cost Swanky $100 a day. This line is Swanky’s isocost line for a total cost of $100. The Isocost Equation The isocost line can be described by an equation. We’ll work out the isocost equation by using symbols that apply to any firm and with numbers that describe Swanky’s situation. The variables that affect the firm’s total cost (TC ) are the prices of the inputs—the price of labor (PL) and the price of capital (PK)—and the quantities of the inputs employed—the quantity of labor (L) and the quantity of capital (K ). In Swanky’s case, we’re going to look at the amount of labor and capital that can be employed when each input costs $25 a day and the total cost is $100. The cost of the labor employed (PLL) plus the cost of the capital employed (PK K ) is the firm’s total cost (TC ). That is, PL L + PK K = TC and in Swanky’s case, 25 L + 25 K = 100. To calculate the isocost equation, divide the firm’s total cost by the price of capital and then subtract (PL/PK)L from both sides of the resulting equation. The isocost equation is K = TC /PK − ( PL /PK ) L It tells us how the firm can vary its capital input as it varies its labor input, holding total cost constant. Swanky’s isocost equation is K = 4 − L. This equation corresponds to the isocost line in Fig. A10.4. The Effect of Input Prices Along the isocost line that we have just calculated, capital and labor cost $25 a day each. Therefore, to decrease its capital input by 1 unit and keep its total cost at $100 a day, the firm must increase the labor input by 1 unit. The magnitude of the slope of the isocost line shown in Fig. A10.4 is 1. The slope tells us that 1 unit of labor costs 1 unit of capital. If factor prices change, the slope of the isocost line changes. If the wage rate rises to $50 a day and the rental rate of a machine remains at $25 a day, then 1 worker costs 2 machines and the isocost line becomes steeper—line B in Fig. A10.5. If the wage rate remains at $25 a day and the rental rate of a machine rises to $50 a day, then 1 machine costs 2 workers and the isocost line becomes less steep—line C in Fig. A10.5. The higher the relative price of labor, the steeper is the isocost line. The magnitude of the slope of the isocost line measures the relative price of labor in terms of capital—that is, the price of labor divided by the price of capital. As the price of either capital or labor changes, so too does the relative price of labor and the slope of the isocost line. FIGURE A10.5 Input Prices and the Isocost Line Capital (machines per day) APPENDIX 4 Labor $50 Capital $25 3 Labor $25 Capital $25 2 Labor $25 Capital $50 B 1 0 1 C 2 A 3 4 Labor (workers per day) The slope of the isocost line depends on the relative input prices. Three cases are shown (each for a total cost of $100). If the prices of labor and capital are $25 a day each, the isocost line is line A. If the price of labor rises to $50 but the price of capital remains $25, the isocost line becomes steeper and is line B. If the price of capital rises to $50 and the price of labor remains constant at $25, the isocost line becomes flatter and is line C. ISOCOST LINES The Isocost Map An isocost map shows a series of isocost lines, each for a different total cost when the price of each input is constant. With a larger total cost, larger quantities of all the inputs can be employed. Figure A10.6 illustrates an isocost map. In that figure, the middle isocost line is the one in Fig. A10.4. It is the isocost line for a total cost of $100 when capital and labor cost $25 a day each. The other two isocost lines in Fig. A10.6 are for a total cost of $125 and $75, when the input prices are constant at $25 each. The answer can be seen in Fig. A10.7. The isoquant for 15 sweaters is shown, and the three points on that isoquant (marked a, b, and c) illustrate the three techniques of producing 15 sweaters that are shown in Fig. A10.1. The figure also contains two isocost lines—each drawn for a price of capital and a price of labor of $25. One isocost line is for a total cost of $125, and the other is for a total cost of $100. First, consider point a. Swanky can produce 15 sweaters at point a by using 1 worker and 4 machines. The total cost when Swanky uses this technique of production is $125. Point c, which uses 4 workers and 1 machine, is another technique by T h e L e a s t - C o s t Te c h n i q u e FIGURE A10.6 An Isocost Map 5 A10.7 The Least-Cost Technique of Production 5 a 4 Least-cost technique 3 TC b 2 = 25 $1 4 $1 0 5 $1 2 $1 = 00 = TC 00 TC 2 15 sweaters = 3 c TC 1 TC Capital (machines per day) FIGURE Capital (machines per day) The least-cost technique is the combination of inputs that minimizes total cost of producing a given output. Let’s suppose that Swanky wants to produce 15 sweaters a day. What is the least-cost way of doing this? 1 2 3 4 5 Labor (workers per day) = 5 $7 1 0 1 2 3 5 4 Labor (workers per day) This isocost map shows three isocost lines, one for a total cost of $75, one for $100, and one for $125. For each isocost line, the prices of capital and labor are $25 a day each. The slope of each isocost line is equal to the price of labor divided by the price of capital—a constant. The larger the total cost, the farther is the isocost line from the origin. The least-cost technique of producing 15 sweaters is 2 machines and 2 workers (point b) and the total cost is $100. An output of 15 sweaters can be produced by using 4 machines and 1 worker (point a) or 1 machine and 4 workers (point c). But with either of these techniques, the total cost is greater, at $125. At b, the isoquant for 15 sweaters is tangential to the isocost line for $100. The isocost line and the isoquant have the same slope. If the isoquant intersects the isocost line—for example, at a and c—the least-cost technique has not been found. With the least-cost technique, the marginal rate of substitution (slope of isoquant) equals the relative price of the inputs (slope of isocost line). APPENDIX TO C H A P T E R 1 0 P RO D U C I N G AT LEAST COST which the firm can produce 15 sweaters for a cost of $125. Next look at point b. At this point, Swanky uses 2 machines and 2 workers to produce 15 sweaters at a total cost of $100. Point b is the least-cost technique or the economically efficient technique for producing 15 sweaters when knitting machines and workers cost $25 a day each. Notice that although there is only one way in which Swanky can produce 15 sweaters for $100, there are several ways of producing 15 sweaters for more than $100. Techniques shown by points a and c are two examples. All the points between a and b and all the points between b and c are also ways of producing 15 sweaters for a cost that exceeds $100 but is less than $125. That is, there are isocost lines between those shown, for total costs between $100 and $125. Those isocost lines cut the isoquant for 15 sweaters at the points between a and b and between b and c. Swanky can also produce 15 sweaters for a cost that exceeds $125. That is, the firm can change its technique of production by moving along the isoquant to a point above point a or to a point to the right of point c. All of these ways of producing 15 sweaters are economically inefficient. You can see that Swanky cannot produce 15 sweaters for less than $100 by imagining the isocost line for $99. That isocost line will not touch the isoquant for 15 sweaters. That is, the firm cannot produce 15 sweaters for $99. At $25 for a unit of each input, $99 will not buy the inputs required to produce 15 sweaters. Marginal Rate of Substitution E q u a l s R e l a t i ve I n p u t P r i c e At the least-cost technique point b, the slope of the isoquant is equal to the slope of the isocost line. Equivalently, when a firm is using the least-cost technique of production, the marginal rate of substitution between the inputs equals their relative price. Recall that the marginal rate of substitution is the magnitude of the slope of an isoquant. Relative input prices are measured by the magnitude of the slope of the isocost line. We’ve just seen that producing at least cost means producing at a point where the isocost line is tangential to the isoquant. Because the two curves are tangential, their slopes are equal. Hence the marginal rate of substitution (the magnitude of the slope of isoquant) equals the relative input price (the magnitude of the slope of isocost line). M a r g i n a l P ro d u c t a n d Marginal Cost in the Long Run W - , ginal cost of increasing output by using one more unit of capital is equal to the marginal cost of increasing output by using one more unit of labor. To see why, we’re first going to learn about the relationship between the marginal rate of substitution and marginal product. Marginal Rate of Substitution and M a r g i n a l P ro d u c t s The marginal rate of substitution and the marginal products are linked together in a formula: The marginal rate of substitution of labor for capital equals the marginal product of labor divided by the marginal product of capital. The change in output resulting from a change in inputs is determined by the marginal products of the inputs. That is, Change in output = ( MPL × ∆L ) + ( MPK × ∆K ). That is, the change in output equals the marginal product of labor, MPL multiplied by the change in labor, ∆L, plus the marginal product of capital, MPK, multiplied by the change in the capital, ∆K. Suppose that Swanky wants to change its inputs but remain on an isoquant—that is, it wants to change its inputs of labor and capital but produce the same number of sweaters. To remain on an isoquant, the change in output must be zero. We can make the change of output zero in the above equation; doing so yields the equation MPL × ∆L = − MPK × ∆K . Divide both sides of this equation by the increase in labor (∆L) and also divide both sides by the marginal product of capital (MPK) to give MPL /MPK = − ∆K /∆L This equation tells us that, when Swanky remains on an isoquant, the decrease in its capital input (∆K) divided by the increase in its labor input (∆L) is equal to the marginal product of labor (MPL) M A R G I N A L P RO D U C T divided by the marginal product of capital (MPK). The decrease in capital divided by the increase in labor when we remain on a given isoquant is the marginal rate of substitution of labor for capital. What we have discovered, then, is that the marginal rate of substitution of labor for capital equals the ratio of the marginal product of labor to the marginal product of capital. Marginal Cost When the least-cost technique is employed, the slope of the isoquant and the isocost line are the same. That is, MPL /MPK = PL /PK Rearrange the above equation in the following way. First, multiply both sides by the marginal product of capital and then divide both sides by the price of labor. We then get MPL /PL = MPK /PK This equation says that the marginal product of labor per dollar spent on labor is equal to the marginal product of capital per dollar spent on capital. In other words, the extra output from the last dollar spent on labor equals the extra output from the last dollar spent on capital. This makes sense. If the extra output from the last dollar spent on labor exceeds the extra output from the last dollar spent on capital, it will pay the firm to use less capital and use more labor. By doing so, it can produce the same output at a lower total cost. Conversely, if the extra output from the last dollar spent on capital exceeds the extra output from the last dollar spent on labor, the firm can lower its cost of producing a given output by AND MARGINAL COST IN THE LONG RUN using less labor and more capital. A firm achieves the least-cost technique of production only when the extra output from the last dollar spent on all the inputs is the same. Marginal cost with fixed capital and variable labor equals marginal cost with fixed labor and variable capital. To see this proposition, simply flip the last equation over and write it as PL /MPL = PK /MPK . Expressed in words, this equation says that the price of labor divided by its marginal product must equal the price of capital divided by its marginal product. But what is the price of an input divided by its marginal product? The price of labor divided by the marginal product of labor is marginal cost when the capital input is held constant. To see why this is so, first recall the definition of marginal cost: Marginal cost is the change in total cost resulting from a unit increase in output. If output increases because one more unit of labor is employed, total cost increases by the cost of the extra labor, and output increases by the marginal product of the labor. So marginal cost is the price of labor divided by the marginal product of labor. For example, if labor costs $25 a day and the marginal product of labor is 2 sweaters, then the marginal cost of a sweater is $12.50 ($25 divided by 2). The price of capital divided by the marginal product of capital has a similar interpretation. The price of capital divided by the marginal product of capital is marginal cost when the labor input is constant. As you can see from the above equation, with the least-cost technique of production, marginal cost is the same regardless of whether the capital input is constant and more labor is used or the labor input is constant and more capital is used.