A Theoretical Review of the Signaling Role of Certifications

advertisement
A Theoretical Review of the Signaling Role of
Certifications in Career and Technical Education
Kenneth R. Bartlett
Department of Organizational Leadership, Policy, and Development
College of Education and Human Development
University of Minnesota
This paper examines the theoretical and conceptual foundations of the
signaling ability of career and technical education (CTE) certifications
awarded by industry, trade associations, and other organizations.
Additionally, specific attention is directed to the way in which occupational
certifications signal expertise and readiness for employment in the context of
entry into the labor market. The theoretical frameworks used to explore the
impact of education qualifications will be briefly reviewed, starting with
human capital theory and moving to the complementary yet, somewhat
divergent theories of signaling and screening. The literature applying
signaling theory to educational outcomes will be summarized. Finally, a
conceptual model of certification and signaling in the service marketing
context will be reviewed, and an extension will be proposed that applies the
model to certification and signaling in CTE. Conclusions and suggestions for
future research are then presented.
Introduction
The appropriate assessment of career and technical education (CTE) has generated
widespread discussion in the past several years. The issue is highlighted by an increasing interest
in standards-based education, driven by the need for an educated and highly trained workforce
able to respond to the increasing pace of change. While there has been continued movement
towards improvements in creating dependable measures of student achievement, the assessment
of student learning remains “the Achilles’ heel of quality” (Knight, 2002). An associated
discussion related to appropriate measures of student achievement has focused on the role of
non-traditional educational credentials and certifications. The past decade has seen explosive
growth both in the number of certifications awarded and in the number of post-secondary CTE
providers offering training and courses leading to certification (Aragon, Woo, & Marvel, 2005;
Carter 2005; Van Noy, Jacobs, Korey, Bailey, & Hughes, 2008). In spite of this activity, little is
known about the way industry certifications and qualifications in CTE function in terms of their
signaling ability in the labor market. This paper seeks to broaden the scope of current
knowledge, synthesize existing literature, and propose a model to explain the signaling function
of certifications in the CTE context.
The work reported herein was supported under the National Research Center for Career and Technical
Education, PR/Award No. VO51A070003 administered by the Office of Vocational and Adult Education, U.S.
Department of Education. However, the contents do not necessarily represent the positions or policies of the Office
of Vocational and Adult Education or the U.S. Department of Education, and you should not assume endorsement
by the Federal Government.
The study of education outcomes increasingly considers the awarding of a credential as a signal
or indicator of meeting pre-determined levels of proficiency (Darling-Hammond, 1994; Wang &
King, 2009). This paper is primarily focused on an increasingly wide range of credentials known
as a certification (alternatively referred to as industry-based certification, occupational
certification, and professional certification). A high level of conflict and confusion surrounds the
use of terms to describe various educational qualifications, including certification. For the
purpose of this paper the following definition of certification is used: certification is a form of
credential awarded by an employer, a vendor, an association, or an independent agency (Hale,
2000) that requires “passage of an examination benchmarked to predetermined occupational or
professional standards” (Carnevale & Desrochers, 2001, p. 19). Certification may or may not
require additional prior education and experience. Hale (2000) described certifications as a form
of credential that can be awarded by an employer, a vendor, an association, or an independent
agency. Certifications can also be awarded to groups or organizations as well as individuals. For
example, the American National Standards Institute (ANSI) and the American Society for
Quality Control (ASQC) certify organizations that meet pre-determined process standards.
However, the focus of this study is on the certification of individuals by employers, vendors, and
professional and trade associations. An important distinction also needs to be made between
certification and other types of credentials including degrees, diplomas, licenses, and
accreditation, all of which lie outside the bounds of this paper.
Over recent years the increase in prominence, number of programs, and qualifications
related to the external certification of workplace skills has become a widely accepted as a key
trend in both CTE and education (Acemogle & Pischke, 1999; Carter, 2005; Castellano, Stone, &
Stringfield, 2005; Miller, Kellie, & Acutt, 2001). The unique vocational and occupational focus
of CTE has in some ways resulted in the qualification issue being more pronounced than in
general academic education. Prior studies in CTE have shown that industry-based certifications
do function as signals (Bartlett, 2002; 2004; Bartlett, Horwitz, Ipe, & Liu, 2005; Colardyn,
2009). However, previous research has focused on entry-level certifications with little known on
the theoretical mechanisms for how certification operates for workforce entry for occupations
typically associated with CTE. This paper seeks to broaden the scope of current knowledge,
synthesize existing literature, and propose a model to explain the signaling function of
certifications in the CTE context.
Theoretical Foundations for Assessing CTE Credentials and Certification
The continued high visibility of occupational certification programs in CTE (Castellano
et al., 2005), along with their increasing presence in secondary and postsecondary educational
institutions and private sector training providers (Carnevale & Desrochers, 2001; Carter, 2005)
raises many questions about the value of these credentials for those seeking entry into the
workforce. Of particular interest is the message or signal that an occupational certification sends
to employers, as compared to the more traditional qualifications in the same field usually
represented by a two-year community/technical college degree or four-year college/university
degree. The study of the impact of certification in the CTE context draws on literature, theory,
and empirical research from a number of different perspectives in the social sciences. Related
disciplines to drawn on include education, economics, management, human resource
management, sociology, and industrial organizational psychology. Existing theory provides a
strong conceptual framework for examining the role of credentials as an assessment outcome in
CTE, especially when focused on the role that qualifications play in explaining how individuals
gain entry into the workforce and the variability in their subsequent earnings.
To be valuable a credential should indicate that the holder has acquired the essential
knowledge and skills identified by an industry or occupation as critical for success (Tyler, 2003;
Walters, 2003). The exact level of knowledge and skill the certificate holder possesses is usually
unknown. The certificate, therefore, serves to signal a measure of competence and consequently
provides value for both the organization and the certificate holder. A number of theoretical
perspectives provide a potential lens through which to understand the impact of educational
qualifications on workforce entry, earnings, and advancement. Among the multiple theories
researchers have proposed for understanding questions related to certification the most
commonly supported include human capital, signaling, control, principal-agent, and cultural
capital. Although no single theory is universally applicable or accepted, each has some value in
certain labor market settings (Bills, 1992; Levy & Murname, 2001). When limiting the focus of
attention to labor market entry (i.e., hiring) and explanations for labor market returns to
education (i.e., wages), two broad bodies of theories have emerged as the most robust and
commonly applied (Frazis, 2002). Initially focusing on economics and later applied to the
economic aspects of education, these two theoretical views are known as human capital theories
and signaling theories. Both theories form part of neoclassical economics, described by Kaufman
(1985) as the dominate paradigm in labor economics and derived from and extending classical
economic theory. The neoclassical approach examines the allocation of scarce resource among
alternative ends and accounts for human behavior with the assumptions that individuals exercise
rational choice and seek to maximize their well-being. As Kroch and Sjoblom (1994) described,
the neoclassical approach is captured in both human capital and signaling theories. Both theories
are based on the assumption that individuals acquire education or training up to the point where
the marginal benefit (wage earning) just equals the marginal costs of acquiring education. The
two theories differ, however, in the reasons that employers pay a premium for education. In the
following section each theoretical perspective is briefly reviewed.
Human Capital Theory
Over the past fifty years the basic premise of human capital theory has been advanced, applied,
and empirically supported in a wide range of education, training, and learning contexts. While
this paper will not attempt to provide a thorough review, it is worth briefly summarizing key
aspects and seminal studies since human capital has been the dominant theory used in research
seeking to understanding the value of education and training. The basic tenet of human capital
theory is that expenditures on education and training are investments that produce capital in
human beings in terms of knowledge and skills (Benjamin, Gunderson, & Riddell, 1998). As
noted by Nerdrum (1999) “generally, human capital accumulation is confined to knowledge
reproducing activities” (p. 5), although other investments in human capital have also been
considered including migration, health care, and engagement in job search activities (Schultz,
1963; Wang & Holton, 2005). These collective investments are expected to improve individuals’
productivity and, therefore, their earnings. As such, “education augments natural abilities that are
subsequently sold in labor markets” (Bedard, 2001, p. 749).
The key feature of human capital theory stresses that education and training should be
viewed as an individual investment toward future returns. An individual makes decisions to
acquire learning as an investment while delaying current income or benefits in expectation of
future increased earning potential (Becker, 1993). Costs associated with education or training
include tuition and other fees along with loss of earnings foregone while new knowledge and
skills are acquired. A related aspect of this theory is the assumption that because individuals wish
to maximize the value of their lifetime earnings, they continue to accumulate education or
training (i.e., human capital) up to the point where the marginal benefits – the expected increased
income from the investment – equals the marginal cost of acquiring it (Wang & Holton, 2005).
Applying this theory to labor market outcomes suggests that any difference in the ability to be
hired and the level of subsequent earnings are reflective of the difference in the amount of human
capital that an individual possesses.
Because of the unique and diverse setting of CTE learning leading to certification, the
benefits to individuals are not easily analyzed with a human capital approach. Further, as
described by Livingstone (1997), much human capital is acquired after formal schooling and
human capital models in general fail to account for lifelong learning. A second limitation of the
human capital theory approach to studying the impact of CTE-related certification in the context
of the labor market is associated with employers’ unpredictable attitudes towards these
qualifications. This point was stressed in the work of Strober (1990) who noted that “while
human capital theory provides some central insights about the supply side of the labor market,
the challenges of this theory suggest that the demand side of the market, i.e., the actions of
human resource managers, also play a key role in determining earnings and employment” (p.
214). Firms may seek certified employees for a wide variety of reasons, including simplifying
recruitment, enhancing marketing, and protecting against legal issues. The specific value that
employers assign to certifications, in terms of preference for hiring and the resulting wage
offered, cannot be fully explained by human capital theories. This non-uniform valuation of
certification results from several causes but all limit to some degree the application of human
capital to the study of certification in CTE.
Signaling Theory
In simplistic descriptive terms, a signal is any observable indicator of something with
unobservable quality. However, for the observable indicator to be considered a signal it must
meet two criteria: (1) the indicator must be able to be manipulated, at least partly, by an
individual, and (2) the marginal cost of difficulty of obtaining the indicator must be inversely
correlated with the individual’s ability level (Spence 1973, 1974). A frequently used example of
a signal is the college degree, which highlights both the prerequisite criteria. A college degree is
a signal of future workplace productivity because acquisition of such a credential is at least
partly within an individual’s control and because it is more difficult for those individuals who
lack the organizational skills, commitment, motivation, and focus (or other similar such
attributes that constitute productivity) to obtain a college degree.
During the recruitment and selection process an organization attempts to identify signals
of applicants that are correlated with future performance on the job. As Kaufman (1985)
described, the importance of indices and signals for the screening process depends on their
usefulness as predictors of each applicant’s actual productivity on the job. The value of a signal
is somewhat unique to the criteria of the job and hiring organization, although certain signals,
such as education credentials and especially a college degree, often are valued independent of
job and organizational context.
The majority of studies applying signaling theory to examine the wage effects of
education focus on participation and qualifications earned in secondary schooling or four-year
colleges and universities. An important stream in the literature was a series of studies examining
the signaling value and returns to education from the sub-baccalaureate labor market. This is
usually defined as jobs requiring education beyond high school but less than a four-year degree.
A series of studies by Grubb (1992; 1993a; 1993b) examined the employment consequences of
enrollment in and acquisition of credentials from two-year community and technical colleges. A
study by Kane and Rouse (1995) re-analyzed Grubb’s data and found several errors. Their
interpretation and conclusions provided needed focus on the role of qualifications for many
entry-level occupations. Grubb (1995) contributed further with a rebuttal with corrected data.
When taken with a companion study of Kane and Rouse (1995) these provide an insightful view
and application of signaling theory to that segment of the labor market most often associated
with CTE occupations.
A newer development in the service marketing literature is studies exploring the role of
certification as a signaling device. Certification in the service marketing context often refers to
promoting and displaying endorsement of service quality by an independent reputable agency
(Corbett, Montes-Sancho, & Kirsch, 2005; Mishra, 2006; Terlaak & King, 2006; Walker &
Johnson, 2009). An example would be an automotive service firm displaying signs indicating
that its staff is Automotive Service Excellence (ASE) certified. Mishra described how displaying
certification in marketing efforts (both advertising as well as prominently displaying ASE seal
and actual employee certifications where customers can see) “creates as incentive for firms to
deliver of quality promises by using proper techniques to control delivery agents like repair
mechanics” (p. 82). A separate but related line of research considers the quality management
related certifications offered by the International Standards Organization (Corbett, MontesSancho, & Kirsch, 2005; Terlaak & King, 2006). Potentially, the theoretical application of this
work to CTE is valuable in furthering the understanding of the role of education qualifications,
especially industry-sponsored credentials, as a certification of learning.
The Development of a Conceptual Model of Certification and Signaling in CTE
Mishra (2006) proposed a conceptual model that explains how firms use certification to
signal marketing messages to customers. Building on earlier work in service marketing
(Zeithaml, Berry, Parasuraman, 1988) Mishra’s model brings together multiple theoretical
perspectives related to the role of certification signals in service relationships. Mishra (2006)
then tested his model on the role of signaling and screening to overcome information gaps. The
empirical setting for testing was the automotive service industry. The automotive service
industry is well suited for exploring the role of certification given that greater information
asymmetries and high consumer information search costs are found for products and services
with large numbers of choices (Beatty & Smith, 1987). As described by the model, significant
information asymmetry exists for customers who are seeking automotive repairs. Customers are
often highly uncertain about which of the many available car repair firms is likely to deliver
high-quality service. Mishra found considerable empirical support for his model in this setting.
In addition, Bartlett (2004) also examined certification in the automotive service industry and
found that Automotive Service Excellence (ASE) certification is used as a signal in a variety of
ways. “Technicians earning certification are awarded sleeve badges to wear on their work
uniforms and certificates that are usually framed and predominantly displayed in public areas of
the workplace. In addition, technicians’ employers will often display large blue signs on the
business frontage stating that ASE-certified technicians are employed. ASE directs this
marketing effort in the hope that customers will seek out firms with ASE-certified technicians
when repairs are needed to their vehicles” (p. 10). Although the context of Mishra’s (2006)
conceptual model is customer service marketing, potential connections exist to explore the role
of educational certification in CTE. This is explored further in the following section.
An Extension of a Conceptual Model of Certification and Signaling in CTE
The model of the role of certification in service marketing developed by Mishra (2006) is
potentially useful for considering the impact of education certifications in hiring for CTE
occupations. Consequently, an extension of the Misha model in the CTE context is proposed.
Figure 1 is an extension of the Mishra (2006) model adapted to fit the context of
certification in hiring for jobs typically associated with CTE. The rapid expansion of industry
certification has not been uniform in all occupations. This model attempts to explain why
industry certification is more visible in certain CTE occupations. The model examines the role of
certification and screening in bringing about the desired outcome of a successful hire. The model
captures both the employer and applicant in examining the signaling role of certification.
Certification is a worthwhile investment for an applicant who knows that potential employers
will have information asymmetries in relation to their knowledge, skills, and abilities. For
employers, certification is a worthwhile screening device to overcome these same information
gaps. A successful hire results from both an applicant signaling and organizational screening to
identify an applicant’s suitability for the job.
Using this model to explore the signaling role of qualification related to CTE, it becomes
apparent that the need for certification would likely be greatest in jobs and occupations with
large information asymmetries. Consequently, there is greater need for signaling and screening
which can be accomplished with educational credentials. Such information asymmetries are
likely to occur when employers do not know the specific knowledge, skills, and abilities for jobs.
This situation could be found in CTE related jobs in highly dynamic industries where the
requirements for job performance change frequently due to technology, new legal requirements,
or other significant factors emanating from the organization’s external environment. The
existing data of occupations and industries with the greatest numbers and expansion of
certification programs would lend some support to this conclusion (Adelman, 2000; Carter,
2005).
CERTIFICATION
COST
CERTIFICATION
INFORMATION
ASYMMETRY
RELATIONAL
INTELLIGENCE
GENERATION
SUCCESSFUL
HIRE
SCREENING
SCREENING
COST
Denotes moderating effects
Denotes feedback loop
Figure 1. An extension of Mishra (2006): The development of a conceptual model of
certification and signaling in CTE
A range of additional drivers for certification in CTE can be explained by the model and
existing literature on signaling theory. The model presented in Figure 1captures the idea that
high information asymmetries lead to the need for relational intelligence generation (Mishra,
2006). This situation is likely to be found in jobs and occupations where customer relationships
are important. Many CTE programs focus on occupations with heavy customer service
interactions. The model proposed that these occupations are more likely to benefit from the use
of certification as a signaling device for entry into the labor market. Examples would include the
already discussed automotive service industry along with certain jobs in the health care
professions, tourism and hospitality, and IT. Health care is especially noted given the importance
of quality customer (patient) interaction which is considered vital for effective and efficient
delivery of health care services. Education and training for the highest levels of professionals in
this field (doctors, nurses, etc) has long been associated with licenses and certification. Yet today
certification is increasingly a requirement in many allied health professions (Althauser & Appel,
1996). The IT field also provides an example to test the model in Figure 1. As organizations
increasingly rely on information technologies to function, so too do they rely on IT staff able to
meet the computer and network needs of all employees in an organization. The complexity of the
technology and the rate of change and innovation often create information asymmetries between
what employers want in IT employees and their ability to determine if applicants possess the
needed skills and knowledge. Consequently, the IT field has emerged as perhaps the leader in
certification (Adelman, 2000; Brookshire, 2001; Carter, 2005).
In the Mishra (2006) model, both certification and screening provide a mechanism for an
organization to overcome information asymmetries. Applying the adapted model in Figure 1 to
educational credentials in CTE the processes of certification and screening can be viewed as
steps towards the successful hiring of a new employee with known skills that meet the
predetermined needs for a job. A key contribution of the marketing approach embedded in the
model of Figure 1 is the focus on relational intelligence generation to meet customer needs.
Returning to the context of education certification in CTE, the consumer could firstly be
considered to be the employer seeking to purchase labor and skills. A successful hire, therefore,
is one in which the new employee is able to meet organizational needs by in turn meeting
customer needs. A second tier of consumer could be identified as the customers that the certified
employee interacts with on the job.
The Mishra (2006) model, and the extension to CTE presented in Figure 1, includes the
costs of certification and screening. If certification costs are high, which would include training,
materials, and examination fees, there may be a perception from employers of the greater value
of the qualification. Signaling theory supports this proposition, as a signal must meet the
requirement of distinguishing between high and low ability individuals. It could be that very
expensive certifications are only within the reach of current and future high income earning
employees who use the credentials to signal their greater ability. Certainly, there could be
evidence for this in the advanced IT certifications currently available today (Hentea & Dhillon,
2006; Nelson & Rice, 2001). Alternatively, in occupations and jobs with high screening costs,
certification may also play a more prominent role. The costs to screen employees could include
interviews, background checks, and a variety of job related pre-employment assessments
(Chapman & Webster, 2003; Huang & Cappelli, 2006). When a firm invests considerable time
and expense to screen, there may be a tendency to place greater reliance on certification. Lastly,
in certain occupations there are significant costs to a firm for failed hires. In situations where a
successful hire is important as a result of high staff turnover, high training costs, high job
demand, and limited labor pool, it could expected that certification may play a more prominent
role.
One possible critique of the Mishra (2006) model is that the desired outcome of
certification and screening are absent, although increased firm profit is perhaps implied. Figure 1
attempts to address this by considering the hiring of an employee with the necessary prior
education and training to perform the job as the outcome of CTE signaling. The feedback loop,
absent in the Misha (2006) model although clearly stated in the theoretical literature, is a key
aspect of signaling theory. The model of the signaling role of certification in CTE presented in
Figure 1 captures the feedback that occurs as employers gradually learn the value of certification
with evaluations of subsequent job performance and employees gradually learn the relative value
of different education certifications in the screening and hiring process. Eventually, the repeated
process of hiring gradually reduces information asymmetries leading to the state of equilibrium.
Yet, it must be stressed that the research literature of signaling theory to explain certification in
CTE is in its infancy. Much additional research in a variety of occupations and industries is
needed.
Conclusions
This paper has examined the theoretical and conceptual foundations of the signaling
ability of certifications and credentials to further the understanding of the impact of educational
qualifications in CTE. Certification continues to play an expanded role in CTE as a measure of
assessment. As students and employers increasingly rely on certification as a signal, a
corresponding move to offer education leading to certification has emerged for both secondary
and post-secondary CTE providers. This paper explored the theoretical foundation behind the
signaling role of CTE certification in the hope that a review of the key elements of the theory can
be applied to develop a greater understanding of how certification can and should operate.
While much literature on the role and returns to education is grounded in human capital
theory this paper has argued that signaling theory is a more appropriate theoretical framework to
examine the certification issue in CTE. The origins of signaling theory as a way to explain how
economic markets operate with incomplete information was briefly reviewed, with specific
emphasis on the seminal work of Spence and the development of his theory of signaling in the
labor market. As explained by signaling theory, there is uncertainty on the part of both
employers and job applicants about the best way to identify individuals with the necessary skills
and abilities to fill positions. Credentials and certifications play a signaling role by providing
potential employees a way to indicate their fit for a vacancy and for employers to quickly
identify employees who can perform on the job with minimal additional training.
The empirical research supports the concept that signaling theory can be used to examine
the returns to educational credentials from both the employee and employer perspective. Key
studies from both perspectives were reviewed. The growing interest in signaling theory in
marketing was highlighted for the potential application to CTE certification. More specifically,
the role of certification in service marketing was examined with a review and discussion of the
model presented by Mishra (2006). An extension of this model was then developed for suggested
use to explore issues related to certification in CTE.
The prevalence of industry-sponsored credentials and certification is likely to continue to
grow in importance in a variety of occupations, providing additional support for CTE policy
makers, administrators, and instructors to promote the need for lifelong learning within the
context of changing career patterns. The model proposed in this paper can provide a framework
for determining which industries and occupations are likely to engage in the widespread use of
credentials and certifications as signaling devices. Understanding the context in which such
signaling is likely to be of benefit to job applicants and potential employers will help CTE
professionals react appropriately to this trend.
References
Acemogle, D., & Pischke, J. (1999). Certification of training and training outcomes. Boston,
MA: Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
Adelman, C. (2000). A parallel postsecondary universe: The certification system in information
technology. Washington, DC: Office of Educational Research and Improvement, U.S.
Department of Education.
Althauser, R. P., & Appel, T. (1996). Education and credentialing systems, labor market
structure and the work of allied health occupations. In A. C. Kerckhoff, (Ed.). Generating
social stratification: Toward a new research agenda, (p. 223-255). Boulder, CO: Westview
Press.
Aragon, S. R., Woo, H. J. & Marvel, M. R. (2005). The role of national industry-based skill
standards in the development, implementation, and assessment of community college
curriculum. Journal of Career and Technology Education, 21(2), 35-50.
Bartlett, K. R. (2002). The perceived influence of industry-sponsored credentials in the
information technology industry. St. Paul, MN: National Research Center for Career and
Technical Education, University of Minnesota (National Dissemination Center for Career
and Technical Education Research Report No.RR2002).
Bartlett, K. R. (2004). The signaling power of occupational certification in the automobile
service and information technology industries. St. Paul, MN: National Research Center for
Career and Technical Education, University of Minnesota (National Dissemination Center
for Career and Technical Education Research Report No.RR4001).
Bartlett, K. R., Horwitz, S., Ipe, M., & Liu, Y. (2005). The perceived influence of industrysponsored credentials on recruitment in the information technology industry: Employer and
employee perspectives. Journal of Career and Technical Education, 21(2), 51-65.
Beatty, S. E., & Smith, S. M. (1987). External search effort: An investigation across several
product categories. Journal of Consumer Research, 14, 83-96.
Becker, G. S. (1993), Human capital: A theoretical and empirical analysis, with special
reference to education. (3rd Ed). Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Bedard, K. (2001). Human capital versus signaling models: University access and high school
dropouts. Journal of Political Economy, 109(4), 749-775.
Benjamin, D., Gunderson, M., & Riddell, W. C. (1998). Labour market economics. (4th Ed.,).
Toronto: McGraw-Hill Ryerson.
Bills, D. B. (1992). The mutability of educational credentials as hiring criteria. Work and
Occupations, 19(1), 79-95.
Brookshire, R. G. (2001). Information technology certification: Is this your mission? Information
and Technology, Learning, and Performance Journal, 18(2), 1-2.
Carnevale, A. P., & Desrochers, D. M. (2001). Help wanted…credentials required: Community
college in the knowledge economy. Princeton, NJ: Educational Testing Service.
Carter, S. D. (2005). The growth of supply and demand of occupational-based training and
certification in the united states, 1990-2003. Human Resource Development Quarterly,
16(1), 33-54.
Castellano, M., Stone, J. R., & Stringfield, S. (2005). Earning industry-recognized credentials in
high school: Exploring research and policy issues: Journal of Career and Technical
Education, 21(2), 7-34.
Chapman, D. S., & Webster, J. (2003). The use of technologies in the recruiting, screening, and
selection processes for job candidates. International Journal of Selection and
Assessment, 11(2-3), 113-120.
Colardyn, D. (2009). The certification of competencies. In R. Mackean and D. Wilson (eds.),
International handbook of education for the changing world of work, (Vol. 6), 27772792.
Corbett, C. J., Montes-Sancho, M. J., & Kirsch, D. A. (2005). The financial impact of ISO 9000
certification in the United States: An empirical analysis. Management Science, 51(7),
1046-1059.
Darling-Hammond, L. (1994). Performance-based assessment and educational equity. Harvard
Educational Review, 64(1), 5-30.
Frazis, H. (2002). Human capital, signaling, and the pattern of returns to education. Oxford
Economic Papers, 54, 298-320.
Grubb, W. N. (1992). Postsecondary education and the sub-baccalaureate labor market: New
evidence on economic returns. Economics of Education Review 11, 225-248.
Grubb, W. N. (1993a). Further tests of screening on education and observed ability. Economics
of Education Review 12, 125-136.
Grubb, W. N. (1993b). The varied economic returns to postsecondary education: New evidence
from the class of 1972. Journal of Human Resources, 28, 365-382.
Grubb, W. N., (1995). The economic returns to baccalaureate degrees: Corrections. Review of
Higher Education, 18(4) 483–490.
Hale, J. (2000). Performance-based certification: How to design a valid, defensible, costeffective program. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
Hentea, M., & Dhillon, H. S. (2006). Towards changes in information security education,
Journal of Information Technology Education 5, 221–223.
Huang, F., & Peter Cappelli. P. (2006). Employee screening: Theory and evidence. Cambridge,
MA: National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 12071.
Kane, T. J., & Rouse, C. E. (1995). Labor market returns to two- and four-year colleges.
American Economic Review 85(3), 600–614.
Kaufman, B. E. (1985). The economics of labor markets and labor relations. Chicago: The
Dryden Press
Knight, P. T. (2002). The Achilles' heel of quality: The assessment of student learning. Quality
in Higher Education, 8(1), 107-115
Kroch, E. A., & Sjoblom, K. (1994). Schooling as human capital or a signal: Some evidence. The
Journal of Human Resources, 29(1), 156-180.
Levy, F. & Murnane, R. J. (2001). Key competencies critical to economic success. In D. S.
Rychen & L. H. Salganik (Eds.). Defining and selecting key competencies. Kirkland,
WA: Hogrefe & Huber Publishers.
Miller, L., Kellie, D., & Acutt, B. (2001). Factors influencing the choice of initial qualifications
and continuing development in Australia and Britain. International Journal of Training and
Development, 5(3), 196-222.
Mishra, D.P. (2006). The role of certification in service relationships: theory and empirical
evidence. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services, 13, 81-96.
Nelson, M. L., & Rice, D. (2001). Integrating third party-certification with traditional computer
education. The Journal of Computing in Small Colleges, 17(2), 280-287.
Nerdrum, L. (1999). The economics of human capital: A theoretical analysis illustrated
empirically by Norwegian data. Oslo: Scandinavian University Press.
Spence, A. M. (1973). Job market signaling. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87(3), 355-374.
Spence, A. M. (1974). Market signaling: Information transfer in hiring and related screening
processes. Boston: Harvard University Press.
Strober, M. H. (1990). Human capital theory: Implications for HR Managers. Industrial
Relations, 29(2), 214-239.
Terlaak, A., & King, A. A. (2006). The effect of certification with the ISO 9000 Quality
Management Standard: A signaling approach. Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization, 60(4), 579-602.
Tyler, J. H. (2003). Economic benefits of the GED: Lessons from recent research. Review of
Educational Research, 73, 369-403.
Van Noy, M., Jacobs, J., Korey, S., Bailey, T., & Hughes, K. L. (2008). The landscape of
noncredit workforce education: State policies and community college practices. New York:
Community College Research Center Teachers College, Columbia University.
Walker, R. H., & Johnson, L. W. (2009). Signaling intrinsic service quality and value via
accreditation and certification. Managing Service Quality, 19(1), 85-105.
Walters, D. (2003). “Recycling”: The economic implications of obtaining additional postsecondary credentials at lower or equivalent levels. The Canadian Review of Sociology and
Anthropology, 40(4), p. 463-480.
Wang, G. G., & Holton, E. F. (2005). Neoclassical and institutional economics as foundations
for human resource development theory. Human Resource Development Review, 4 (1),
86-108.
Wang, V. C. X., & King, K. P. (2009). Building workforce competencies in career and technical
education. Charlotte, NC: Information Age Publishing.
Zeithaml, V. A., Berry, L. L., & Parasuraman, A. (1988). Communication and control processes
in the delivery of service quality. Journal of Marketing, 52, 35-48.
Download