Corporate Life Cycle and Cost of Equity Capital Abstract This paper investigates the impact of the corporate life cycle on the cost of equity capital. Using a sample of Australian firms during the years 1990–2012, we find that the proxies for the cost of equity capital vary across the life cycle of the firm. In particular, we find that the cost of equity declines as the earned/contributed capital mix (a proxy for the firm life cycle) increases, after controlling for other relevant firm characteristics and unobserved heterogeneity. Moreover, when different stages of the firm life cycle are taken into account, we find that the cost of equity is higher in the introduction and decline stages and lower in the growth and mature stages, resembling a ‘U’ shaped pattern. These findings are robust when subjected to a series of sensitivity tests. Collectively, the results are consistent with the notion that firms in the introduction (or decline) stages are more risky in the sense that their resource base, competitive advantages and capabilities are limited (concentrated), while those in the growth and mature stages are relatively less risky due to the richness and diversity of their resource base, competitive advantages and capability. Hence, the market demands a higher risk premium for the former than for the latter. JEL classifications: D21, G12, G30, L22 Keywords: Cost of equity; Firm life cycle; Earned equity; Contributed capital 1 Corporate Life Cycle and Cost of Equity Capital I. Introduction This paper investigates whether and how the firm life cycle1 affects the cost of equity capital. In particular, we test whether the cost of equity capital of the firm implied in stock prices and forecasts of analysts’ earnings corresponds to different stages in the firm life cycle. In this study, we integrate two strands of research, viz., corporate life cycle and cost of equity capital. The first stream of research, corporate life cycle theory, suggests that firms, like living organisms, pass through a series of predictable patterns of development and that the resources, capabilities, strategies, structures and functioning of the firm vary significantly with the corresponding stages of development (Miller and Friesen 1980, 1984; Quinn and Cameron 1983). Studies in the field of organisational science and strategic management have long recognised the existence and importance of the firm life cycle. Life cycle theory provides management with some parameters, guidelines and diagnostic tools to assess the transition of the firm from one stage to the next: hence, understanding the essence of the life cycle can help firms to utilise valuable resources in the optimal way to outperform their peers (Adizes 2004; Solomon et al. 2003) and to achieve and retain the prime life stage. Recent research in financial economics and accounting (e.g., DeAngelo et al. 2006, 2010; Dickinson 2011) also recognises that firm life cycle stages have important implications for understanding the financial performance of firms. The second stream of research, cost of equity capital, is of paramount importance in accounting and finance research. This is frequently used in settings such as estimation of equity risk premiums, firm valuation and capital budgeting, and investment management 1 We use the terms ‘firm life cycle’, ‘corporate life cycle’ and ‘organisational life cycle’ interchangeably throughout this paper. Anthony and Ramesh (1992), DeAngelo et al. (2006), Coulton and Ruddock (2011) and Dickinson (2011) use ‘firm life cycle’; DeAngelo et al. (2010) use ‘corporate life cycle’; and Adizes (1979) and Smith et al. (1985) use ‘organisation life cycle’ to refer to the same concept. 2 practices such as portfolio allocation, performance evaluation, active risk management and attribution analysis (Hou et al. 2012; Câmara et al. 2009). The cost of equity depends on firms’ economic fundamentals, industry dynamics and overall national economic conditions (Banz 1981; Fama and French 1989; Gebhardt et al. 2001). Previous research indicates that firm-specific determinants of the cost of equity include size, leverage, financial strength, level of disclosure and overall riskiness of the firm. Since the resource base and corresponding competitive advantages of the firm vary across the life cycle, the investors’ demand for a risk premium could potentially vary accordingly. Therefore, these two streams of research together suggest that the firm life cycle should have important implications for the ability of a firm to attract investors, which eventually increases the liquidity of shares and lowers the cost of equity capital. However, there has been little research on their interrelationship. Hence, in this study, we make an important contribution to the literature by investigating the association between the corporate life cycle and cost of equity so as to reveal whether and how the cost of equity capital of the firm varies with the corresponding change in the stage of the firm’s life cycle. This study is primarily motivated by the ‘dynamic resource-based view’ of the firm which articulates that the general patterns and paths in the evolution of organisational capabilities change over time. This resource-based view analyses firms from the resource side rather than from the product side, and posits that the existence and application of the bundle of valuable, interchangeable, immobile and imitable resources2 generate the basis of the competitive advantage of a firm and that this resource base is the basis of heterogeneity in organisational capabilities (Wernerfelt 1984; Rumelt 1984; Penrose 1959). Dynamic 2 ‘Resource’ refers to any assets or input (tangible and intangible) to the production which are tied semipermanently to the firm (Caves 1980) and which help the firm to implement strategies to improve efficiency and effectiveness. Examples of resources include brand names, in-house knowledge of technology, employment of skilled personnel, trade contacts, machinery, efficient procedures, capital, etc. (Wernerfelt 1984). 3 resource-based theory incorporates the founding, development and maturity of capabilities and thereby suggests that the competitive advantages and disadvantages in terms of resources and capabilities evolve over time in important ways (Helfat and Peteraf 2003). This dynamic resource-based theory is mainly based on The Theory of the Growth of the Firm (Penrose 1959) which proposes that the growth of the firm depends on the efficient and effective interaction of the firm’s resources and management (human beings). Thus, the evolution of the firm’s competitiveness, in terms of its resource base and capabilities, is the foundation of the firm’s life cycle. The essence of firm life cycle theory suggests that the investment and financing decision and the operating performance of the firm are greatly influenced by the change in the firm’s organisational capabilities (life cycle stages). Recent research in finance and accounting that confirms the unique role of the firm life cycle stage in the functioning of a firm also instigates the quest for our study. Management accounting literature (Rappaport 1981; Richardson and Gordon 1980) provides evidence that performance measures differ across life cycle stages. In a recent paper, DeAngelo et al. (2010) demonstrate that the corporate life cycle has a significant influence on the probability that a firm will engage in secondary equity offerings. Other studies (e.g., Fama and French 2001; DeAngelo et al. 2006; Coulton and Ruddock 2011; Bulan et al. 2007) acknowledge the role of the firm life cycle in determining the dividend payout policy. Berger and Udell (1998), in a related study, view the firm through a financial growth cycle paradigm in which different capital structures are optimal at different points in the cycle. Evidence in the accounting literature also suggests that investors’ valuation of firms is a function of the life cycle stage of the firm (Anthony and Ramesh 1992). Based on the above theoretical framework in strategic management and subsequent application of life cycle theory in accounting and finance, we also posit that the 4 life cycle has significant influences on the firm’s ability to attract investors, which eventually affects the ex-ante cost of equity capital of the firm. Using a sample of Australian listed companies, we find that the cost of equity decreases as the retained earnings as a proportion of total assets (RE/TA) and total equity (RE/TE) increase. Moreover, compared to the shake-out stage of the firm life cycle, the cost of equity is significantly higher in the introduction and decline stages of the firm life cycle, while it is lower in the growth and mature stages of the firm. Our results conform to the findings of Bender and Ward (1993) that financing strategy and structures of firms evolve over the firms’ life cycles. Furthermore, we conduct an additional test to ascertain that our results are robust to alternative measures of cost of equity and firm life cycle. Endogeneity issues may affect the sign, magnitude or statistical significance of the results. To mitigate this concern, we use instrumental-variables techniques together with fixed effects estimation that can control for unobserved heterogeneity. The instrumental-variables results are very similar to the baseline firm fixed effect results and indicate that endogeneity cannot explain away the negative relationship between cost of equity and firm life cycle. Our study contributes to the literature in several ways. First, in this paper, we extend life cycle literature to cover a key input in the firm’s financial decision making by directly examining the role of the firm life cycle in influencing the cost of equity. While prior research investigates the role of the firm life cycle in dividend and capital structure decisions, little attention has been paid to the role of the firm life cycle in determining the cost of equity capital. Even though Easley and O'Hara's (2004) model predicts that the “life cycle of a firm may also influence its cost of capital. In particular, it seems reasonable that a firm with a long operating history will be better known by investors … the greater the prior precision, the 5 lower the cost of capital”, they have not examined the validity of this prediction empirically. This paper attempts to fill that gap in the literature. Second, the cost of equity represents the return that the investors require on their investment in the firm and thus it is a key factor in firms’ long-term investment decisions. Examining the link between the firm life cycle and the cost of equity, therefore, should help managers understand the effect of the life cycle on firms’ financing costs, and hence this study has important implications for strategic planning. Indeed, the cost of equity capital could be the channel through which capital markets encourage firms to reach and maintain maturity, the prime stage, in their life cycle. Third, given the importance of the firm life cycle and the cost of equity capital in the literature, and the longstanding interest in trying to understand their determinants, an empirical study on the association between corporate life cycle and cost of equity is timely. The remainder of the paper is organised as follows: in section two, we review studies on the cost of equity and life cycle theory and develop testable hypotheses. Section three focuses on the research design, data sources and sample selection. Section four documents the results of the study, while section five concludes the paper. II. Literature Review and Hypotheses Development In this section, we review prior studies related to the firm life cycle and cost of equity separately and then show the interrelationship between them for hypotheses development. Substantial research in industrial organisation, strategic management and accounting and finance has investigated the firm life cycle and cost of equity in isolation. However, no studies have yet shed light on how these issues may relate to one another. 6 2.1 Corporate Life Cycle: Theory Corporate life cycle theory derives its roots from organisational science literature. The corporate life cycle model suggests that firms, like the organic body, tend to progress in a linear fashion through predictable stages of development sequentially from birth to decline and that their strategies, structures and activities correspond to their stages of development (Gray and Ariss 1985; Miller and Friesen 1984, 1980; Quinn and Cameron 1983). Strategy and management researchers have adopted the firm life cycle model from the biological sciences (Van De Ven and Poole 1995) and have incorporated it into business research since the 1960s. Penrose (1959) provides a general theory of growth of the firm and argues that firm growth depends on the firm’s resources and productive opportunities. She identifies managerial limitations as the main source of constraint to a firm’s growth rate. Chandler (1962), one of the pioneers in life cycle theory, argues that organisational structure follows the growth strategy of the firm to avail itself of external opportunities. Subsequent studies in organisational science reveal the grounds behind the existence of the firm life cycle. For example, the resource-based theory of Wernerfelt (1984) suggests that resources are the ultimate source of establishing and maintaining competitive advantage. He argues that firms possess resources, a subset of which allows them to achieve competitive advantage over others, and a subset of those helps them to attain superior long-term performance and thus to earn above average profits (Grant 1991). In a more recent study, Helfat and Peteraf (2003) argue that the resource-based view must incorporate the emergence, development and progression of organisational resources and capabilities over time and hence they introduce a more comprehensive and vibrant view: ‘the dynamic resource-based theory’. This view suggests that the resource base that forms the foundation of competitive advantage and disadvantage comes about over a period of time and also may shift over time. They document 7 that firms’ portfolios of resources and capacities and their characteristics change over time, and this variation results in different stages in the firm life cycle. There are several multi-stage life cycle models which differ in terms of the number of stages involved and the features that correspond to each stage. For example, Greiner (1972) proposes that firms move through five stages of life cycle in their movement from growth through creativity: direction, delegation, coordination, monitoring and collaboration. Adizes (1979) proposes that firms evolve through ten stages in their life cycle ranging from courtship (where the firm exists only as an idea) to death. Kazanjian and Drazin (1990) propose four stages in the firm life cycle which are conception and development, commercialisation, growth and stability. Gort and Klepper (1982) suggest five stages in the firm life cycle, viz., introduction, growth, maturity, shake-out and decline. Summarising the prior literature on life cycle models, Miller and Friesen (1984) propose a similar classification that separates the firm life cycle into five common phases: birth, growth, maturity, revival and decline. Based on this, Dickinson (2011) provides empirical methodology to classify firms into different life cycles. The firm life cycle has important implications in management and business strategy. Each stage in the firm life cycle enforces unique characteristics and demands which entail organisational structures, personnel, leadership styles and decision-making processes appropriate to meet the requirements (Kazanjian 1988). The stages in the life cycle are a key determinant of organisational competitiveness. Koberg et al. (1996) document that organisational and environmental attributes’ impact on innovation is moderated by the firm’s life cycle stage. However, much of the work in the field of management, entrepreneurship and strategy is conceptual rather than empirical. 8 There are some recent empirical studies in accounting and finance that investigate the impact of the firm life cycle on corporate financial decisions.Bender and Ward (1993) report that the financial structure of firms changes over the firms’ life cycles. Berger and Udell (1998) argue that small and young firms generally resort to private equity and debt markets, whereas larger and mature firms mainly rely on public markets. Richardson (2006) suggests that a firm is more likely to undertake relatively larger, growth-oriented investments in the initial stage while, in the mature stage, its investments are more likely to be geared towards maintenance of assets-in place. Fama and French (2001), Grullon et al. (2002) and DeAngelo et al. (2006) find that the life cycle of the firm can influence payout policies. More recently, in an Australian study, Coulton and Ruddock (2011) document that mature and profitable firms are more likely to pay dividends and young firms with higher growth options are less likely to do so. These archival studies suggest that the firm life cycle should have important implications for corporate financing decisions, especially in the area of the cost of equity capital. 2.2 Cost of Equity: Theory Cost of equity is the return that shareholders require on their investment in the firm.. Cost of equity is extensively used in the valuation of investment projects and estimation of equity risk premiums (Câmara et al. 2009). This is also important in optimum capital structure determination, portfolio formation and performance evaluation, risk management and attribution analysis (Hou et al. 2012). Therefore, estimating and validating the cost of equity has become a considerable research interest in the literature. Firm-specific factors such as firm size, age, riskiness, liquidity of stock, financial leverage and quality of disclosure determine the cost of equity. Moreover, non-firm-specific 9 factors such as the industry and the economy also influence the cost of equity. Transparency and availability of information about management and potential earnings of large firms reduce uncertainty level. Hence, investors of larger firms require less return on their investment, which effectively reduces the cost of equity (Witmer and Zorn 2007; Banz 1981; Berk 1995). Firm age or maturity affects equity price and thereby the cost of equity (Pástor et al. 2008). Transaction cost (e.g., commission, fees and other charges incurred in buying or selling a security) is higher for less liquid stock and hence investors require more return for these securities. Shareholders are the residual claimers and hence an increase in the financial leverage also increases the risk to the shareholders. This effectively increases the cost of equity (Witmer and Zorn 2007). Firms in different industries have different costs of equity depending on the nature of their business. For example, Gebhardt et al. (2001) find that the implied risk premium is higher for firms in recreational products, tobacco products, banks, computers and automotive industries, while this is consistently lower for firms in real estate, agriculture, trading (financial) and medical equipment industries. Moreover, the cost of equity is higher under weak economic conditions, while it is lower under strong economic conditions (Fama and French 1989). 2.3 Association between Corporate Life Cycle and Cost of Equity Capital Firms in different life cycle stages differ in their ability to raise funds from the market (Berger and Udell 1998). Firms at the earlier stage of the life cycle are relatively small and unknown, and are less closely followed by analysts and investors. Hence, these firms suffer from substantial information asymmetry. This information asymmetry may cause equity mispricing (Myers and Majluf 1984) which has a positive relation with riskiness and consequently increases the cost of capital (Armstrong et al. 2011). On the other hand, mature firms have a long existence in the market and they are more closely followed by analysts and 10 investors. Hence, these firms suffer from less information asymmetry. Therefore, these firms are less risky. Easley and O'Hara (2004) also note that firms with a long operating history are better known by investors, which improves the precision of information about the firm and lowers the cost of capital. Investors generally prefer securities with low estimation risk, low transaction costs and/or less information asymmetry (Botosan 2006). Greater demand for securities with these characteristics enhances the liquidity of the stocks (Diamond and Verrecchia 1991) which influences the cost of equity (O'Hara 2003). Prior studies (e.g., Gebhardt et al. 2001) overwhelmingly show that firm maturity is associated with a decline in systematic risk. In addition, resource-based theory assumes that firms differ in terms of their bundle of resources (e.g., financial, physical, human capital, technological, reputation and organisational resources) and capabilities (Barney 1991; Dierickx and Cool 1989; Grant 1991), and that these firm-specific resources and capabilities are crucial in explaining the firm’s growth and performance (Penrose 1959). According to this view, the resource base and capabilities of mature firms are large, diverse and rich, while those of young and declining firms are small, concentrated and limited. This resource base and its accompanying superior competitive advantages and capacities help mature firms to benefit from cheaper and easier sources of finance. More specifically, since the life cycle affects the perceived riskiness of the firm, firms in the mature stage of their life cycle should be in a better position to raise adequate capital at a lower cost. Therefore, we hypothesise that: H1: Compared to the shake-out stage of the firm life cycle3, the cost of equity is negatively associated with the mature stage of the firm life cycle. 3 As Dickinson (2011) remarks, the literature clearly spells out the role of different stages of the firm life cycle except for the shake-out stage. As a result, the expected signs of this stage are unclear. Thus, in developing hypothesis H1, we use the shake-out stage as a basis of comparison with other stages of the firm life cycle. 11 Although firms in the growth stage of the life cycle have an insufficient resource base, these firms are promising and have good potential. Growth firms invest more in research and development and seek innovation and rapid development. Organisational theory suggests that growth firms maintain greater information asymmetry to benefit from product development and market movement (Aboody and Lev 2000; Barth et al. 2001; Smith and Watts 1992). However, prior studies also suggest that characteristics of growth firms attract greater analyst coverage to attain potential benefits from private information acquisition (Barth et al. 2001; Lehavy et al. 2011). Greater analyst coverage in turn reduces mispricing and information asymmetry (Barth et al. 2001; Brennan and Subrahmanyam 1995). Furthermore, growth firms are more likely to receive coverage in the business press (Bentley et al. 2012). Firms with greater press coverage are associated with lower levels of information asymmetry (Bushee et al. 2010). Moreover, growth firms have greater strategic incentives to reduce information asymmetry via voluntary disclosure to attract potential providers of capital. ‘Growth investors4’ are willing to invest in these firms to realise benefit from the above-average earnings. Moreover, ‘strategic investors5’ are attracted to invest in growth firms to gain benefits from the future success of the business enterprise. In summary, greater analyst following, press coverage and voluntary disclosures reduce the information asymmetry of growth firms eventually reducing the cost of capital. Hence, we hypothesise that: H2: Compared to the shake-out stage of the firm life cycle, the cost of equity is negatively associated with the growth stage of the firm life cycle. 4 Growth investors invest in companies that exhibit signs of above average growth potential. They bet on more structural changes in the firm and expect a run-up in price (Bourguignon and de Jong 2003). 5 Strategic investors invest in young companies that have the potential to bring something of value to investors or to create synergy with the existing business of the investor. An independent venture capitalist only cares about financial gain, while the strategic investor also cares about the new venture’s strategic impact (Hellmann 2002). 12 On the other hand, firms in the introduction (and decline) stages have limited (downgraded) resources and resource combination. Dickinson (2011) provides empirical evidence that both introduction and decline stages of the firm life cycle are associated with negative earnings per share, return on net operating assets and profit margin. Since investments in these firms are relatively less attractive, analysts are reluctant to cover firms in these stages. Therefore, these firms cannot raise capital unless investors are properly compensated (Nickel and Rodriguez 2002), which effectively increases the cost of equity for these firms. Based on this argument, we hypothesise that: H3: Compared to the shake-out stage of the firm life cycle, the cost of equity is positively associated with the introduction (decline) stages of the firm life cycle. III. Research Method 3.1 Sample and Data We draw the sample from the population of companies listed on the Australian Securities Exchange (ASX) and covered by the I/B/E/S International database for the period 1990– 2012. This yields an initial sample of 8020 firm-year observations. Data for the control variables, except beta, are extracted from the Aspect Financial Analysis databases and Connect 4. Data for beta (systematic risk) and fiscal year end stock price are collected from DataStream and DatAnalysis Morningstar, respectively. Moreover, the risk-free rate (10-year Treasury note rates) required to calculate the cost of equity has been collected from statistics available on the Reserve Bank of Australia website.6 To avoid the undesirable influence of outliers we winsorize continuous variables at the 1st and 99th percentiles. We exclude the 6 http://www.rba.gov.au/statistics/tables/index.html 13 financial sector7 from our sample for two reasons. First, the risk and complexity characteristics of financial institutions are substantially different from those of other firms. Second, financial sector firms differ significantly from other sectors in terms of accounting practice. We also exclude observations with missing values in the computation of cost of equity and control variables and lose 545, 189 and 196 firm years for price/earnings to growth ratio (PEG), modified PEG ratio (MPEG) and Ohlson and Juettner-Nauroth (2005) (OJ) models, respectively. This produces a final sample size of 3888, 3563 and 3482 firmyear observations for the PEG (Easton 2004) model, MPEG (Easton 2004) model and (Ohlson and Juettner-Nauroth 2005) OJ model, respectively. Table 1 presents sample distribution by cost of equity models (Panel A), yearly distribution of observations during the sample period from 1990–2012 (Panel B) and sample distribution by industry sector (Panel C). Insert Table 1 about Here Table 1 shows that sample size increases over the sample period (with the largest sample of 292 and 289 in the years 2008 and 2011, respectively) and the sample is unevenly distributed across industries (with the largest sample being in industrial (24.72%) and consumer discretionary (21.04%) sectors). This study suffers from a relatively limited sample size for two reasons: (i) the implied approach to estimating the cost of equity capital requires expected future cash flows, which can be derived from analyst forecasts. As analysts generally cover larger and established firms, the sample size is thus reduced. The second reason is that: (ii) sample restrictions also occur with the implied valuation models which require positive earnings and positive growth in earnings to generate meaningful cost of 7 Exclusion of the financial sector and delisted firms reduces the sample size by 1337, 1311 and 1297 for the PEG (Easton 2004) model, MPEG (Easton 2004) model and OJ (Ohlson and Juettner-Nauroth 2005) model. 14 equity estimates. A smaller sample size may make it difficult to draw inferences using the implied method. Moreover, the limited sample size may introduce a possible sample selection bias. However, we control for these effects in our regression analysis by including several control variables, such as firm size and leverage. Moreover, we also examine the robustness of our analysis using alternative estimates of the cost of equity and corporate life cycle to deal with the potential bias that may be induced by these data constraints. 3.2 Empirical Model We test the relation between the ex-ante cost of equity and the firm life cycle by four measures of cost of equity and three measures of firm life cycle proxies. To control for individual firm heterogeneity, we employ the following fixed effect model: (1) Where, R = ex-ante cost of equity; CLC = a vector of dummy variables that capture firms’ different stages in the life cycle; SIZE = firm size measured by the natural logarithm of total assets of the firm at the end of the fiscal year; BM = book-to-market ratio at the end of the fiscal year; BETA = stock beta (systematic risk); LOSSt-1 = dummy variable equal to 1 if earnings before extraordinary income in year t1 is negative, otherwise 0; 15 LEV = leverage measured by the ratio of total debt to total equity at the end of the fiscal year; ZSCORE = probability of bankruptcy estimated using Altman’s equation (1968); = year dummy variable, which is used to control for year fixed effects; = firm-specific unobserved fixed effects. Our main variable of interest is CLC. Based on the dynamic resource-based view and the life cycle theory, we predict to be negative for H1 and H2 but positive for H3. 3.2 Measurement of Variables 3.2.1 Estimation of Corporate Life Cycle Assessing the life cycle stage at the firm level is difficult because the individual firm is composed of many overlapping, but distinct, product life cycle stages. Moreover, firms can compete in multiple industries and their product offerings are fairly diverse (Dickinson 2011). To overcome this estimation problem, we follow the methodologies of DeAngelo et al. (2006) and Dickinson (2011) to develop proxies for the firms’ stage in the life cycle.8 Following DeAngelo et al. (2006), we use retained earnings as a proportion of total assets (RE/TA) and total equity (RE/TE) as the proxy for corporate life cycle. These proxies measure the extent to which a firm is self-financing or reliant on external capital. A high RE/TA and RE/TE imply that the firm is more mature or old with declining investment, while the firm with a low RE/TA and RE/TE tends to be young and growing (DeAngelo et al. 2006). 8 Anthony and Ramesh (1992) provide one of the first empirical procedures for classifying firms in different life cycle stages. However, we do not use their method for several reasons. These include (1) this classification scheme requires at least six years of data availability for each firm, which reduces our sample size significantly; (2) the life cycle proxy in this procedure is ‘ad hoc’ and relies on portfolio sorts to classify the firm in different life cycle stages; and (3) Dickinson (2011) has shown that life cycle classification based on Anthony and Ramesh’s (1992) procedure leads to an erronous classification of the stage of firms in the life cycle. 16 An alternative parsimonious measure offered by Dickinson (2011) deploys data from the firm’s cash flow statement. She argues that cash flows capture differences in a firm’s profitability, growth and risk and, hence, that one may use the cash flow from operating (CFO), investing (CFI) and financing (CFF) to group firms in life cycle stages such as: ‘introduction’, ‘growth’, ‘mature’, ‘shake-out’ and ‘decline’.9 The methodology is: introduction: if CFO ≤ 0, CFI ≤ 0 and CFF ˃ 0; growth: if CFO ˃ 0, CFI ≤ 0 and CFF ˃ 0; mature: if CFO ˃ 0, CFI ≤ 0 and CFF ≤ 0; decline: if CFO ≤ 0, CFI ˃ 0 and CFF ≤ or ≥ 0; and the remaining firm years will be classified under the shake-out stage. Identification of life cycle stages based on Dickinson (2011) combines the implications from diverse research areas such as production behaviour, learning/experience, investment, market share and entry/exit patterns. As a result, this process can capture the performance and allocation of resources of the firm. 3.2.2 Estimation of Cost of Equity Cost of equity can be measured using both the implied approach and the realised approach. Estimation of implied cost of equity involves calculating the internal rate of return that equates the stock prices to the present value of forecasted cash flows (Hou et al. 2012). On the other hand, the realised approach uses ex-post stock returns to estimate the cost of equity. However, estimates based on ex-post realised stock returns suffer from measurement errors such as imprecise estimates of factor risk premium and risk loading (Fama and French 1997). Furthermore, Elton (2002) argues that information surprises cause realised returns to be a biased and noisy measure of expected returns. Pástor et al. (2008) document that estimation of the cost of equity that uses forward estimates of earnings outperforms measures based on realised returns. Hence, researchers are increasingly relying on the implied cost of equity 9 For detailed justification used to classify firms into different life cycle stages based on cash flow statement data, please refer to Dickinson (2011). 17 capital.10 In line with previous studies, we use implied approach to estimate the cost of equity. Particularly we use Easton (2004)11 and Ohlson and Juettner-Nauroth (2005) as modified by Gode and Mohanram (2003) models to estimate the cost of equity. We choose these measures because Botosan and Plumlee (2005) document that t Easton’s (2004) PEG ratio model and the target price (or dividend discount) method, introduced by Botosan and Plumlee (2002), are preferable measures of the cost of equity as both dominate the other alternatives in the sense that they are consistently and predictably related to various risk measures.12 In addition, we use the Ohlson and Juettner-Nauroth (2005) (OJ) model modified by Gode and Mohanram (2003) because this model is theoretically rigorous yet parsimonious, and provides a simple closed form solution for the implied cost of capital (Gode and Mohanram 2008). Furthermore, prior studies document that while the Ohlson and Juettner-Nauroth (2005) model provides cost of capital estimates that are highly correlated with ex-ante risk factors (Gode and Mohanram 2003), they are weakly correlated with realised returns (Easton and Monahan 2005). Consistent with prior studies (e.g., Hail and Leuz 2006; Chen et al. 2009; Hou et al. 2012), we use a simple average of three models due to the lack of consensus on precision of the estimation of implied e cost of capital . 3.3 Control Variables Prior research has revealed several risk factors and firm characteristics that affect the cost of equity. Accordingly, we control for these risk factors and firm characteristics. . 10 Most Australian studies on the cost of equity adopt the realised approach to estimate the cost of equity. For example, Gray et al. (2009) use industry-adjusted earnings-to-price ratio and Monkhouse (1993) uses the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) to estimate the cost of equity. However, Azizkhani et al. (2010) use the PEG approach to estimate the cost of equity. Moreover, some cross-country studies (e.g., Gray et al. 2009; Hail and Leuz 2006; Khurana and Raman 2004) use the implied approach to estimate the cost of equity with a limited sample size. 11 We use both PEG and MPEG approaches. 12 The necessary forecasted data for the target price (or dividend discount) method are not available for Australian companies. Using forecasted eps4 and eps5 for Australian companies to calculate the cost of equity would significantly reduce our sample size. 18 Firm Size (SIZE) Firm size affects the cost of equity capital because a large firm has a lower probability of default (Berger and Udell 1995). Fama and French (1992) also find that stock returns are negatively correlated with firm size. Moreover, large firms are more followed by analysts and these firms have more liquidity in the capital market which effectively reduce the cost of equity to firms (Witmer and Zorn 2007). Consistent with Francis et al. (2005) and Owen and Yawson (2010), we use the natural log of total assets to measure firm size. Beta (BETA) The capital asset pricing model (CAPM) suggests that systematic risk (beta) is positively associated with the cost of equity capital (Sharpe 1964; Lintner 1965; Mossin 1966; Harris and Marston 1992; Botosan and Plumlee 2005). Hence, we control for systematic risk using the firm’s market beta. We collect beta from Datastream which is calculated over a five-year period by regressing the share price against the respective Datastream total market index using log changes of the closing price on the first day of each month. Book-to-Market Ratio (BM) Book-to-market ratio, a measure of growth opportunity, increases the uncertainty and risk and, therefore, is expected to be positively associated with the cost of equity capital. Prior studies (Chan et al. 1991; Fama and French 1992; Davis 1994; Boone et al. 2008; Khurana and Raman 2004) also consistently document a positive relation between book-to-market ratio and cost of equity capital. Loss (LOSSt-1) A continuous negative earnings stream for a firm could influence investors to consider a higher probability that the firm will abandon its resources (Collins et al. 1999). This is how 19 negative earnings relate to business risk. Therefore, we include a negative earnings indicator variable (LOSSt-1) equal to 1 if the firm has loss in the previous year, 0 otherwise. We expect the coefficient on the variable LOSSt-1 to be positive to the degree that it proxies for a firm’s business risk. Leverage (LEV) Leverage is related to the riskiness of the firm. The higher the level of leverage, the greater the perceived risk associated with the firm and, consequently, the higher the cost of equity capital (Modigliani and Miller 1958; Fama and French 1992; Petersen and Rajan 1994; Gebhardt et al. 2001). We measure financial leverage as (short-term debt + long-term debt)/shareholders’ equity. Probability of Bankruptcy (ZSCORE) In order to control for the bankruptcy risk, we use Altman’s (1968) Z score to develop a proxy for the inverse likelihood of bankruptcy (i.e., a higher score indicates better financial health and the lower possibility of financial distress).13 Altman’s Z score is an unsystematic risk factor and Dichev (1998) suggests that it is separate from the size and book-to-market factors. However, we acknowledge the inherent limitation of Altman’s model that uses historical information to predict current bankruptcy. IV. Empirical Results and Discussion 4.1 Descriptive Statistics Table 2 reports the summary statistics for the key variables included in the regression model. Panel A contains the descriptive statistics for the pooled model (average of the three cost of 13 Altman’s Z score = 1.2(Working Capital/Total Assets) + 1.4(Retained Earnings/Total Assets) + 3.3(Earnings Before Interest & Tax/Total Assets) + 0.6(Market Value of Equity/Total Liabilities) + 0.999(Sales/Total Assets). 20 equity estimates). The mean (median) cost of equity (simple average of the three cost of equity estimates) for the sample is 17.79% (13.96%) with a standard deviation of 12.92%. Owing to limited study on Australian listed firms using the same models for calculating the cost of equity capital, a reliable comparison to this estimate is difficult. The closest possible comparison is with Khurana and Raman (2004) and Azizkhani et al. (2010). Using a sample of 508 Australian firms audited by the Big Auditors (71 firms audited by non-Big Auditors) from 1990–1999, Khurana and Raman (2004) find that the mean cost of equity, estimated by the PEG (Easton 2004) model, is 10.3% (and 10.7%) and that the median cost is 9.1% (and 9.7%). Furthermore, using a sample of 1925 Australian firms audited by Big Auditors and 245 firms audited by non-Big Auditors during the period 1995–2005, Azizkhani et al. (2010) find that the mean cost of equity, estimated by the same model, is 10.8% and 14.3% for the firms audited by Big and non-Big Auditors, respectively.14 The reported mean (median) cost of equity for this paper estimated by the PEG (Easton 2004) model with a sample of 3888 firm years from 1990–2012 is 15.63% (11.81%).15 Botosan (1997) uses a US sample to estimate the cost of equity based on Ohlson (1995) and shows that the cost of equity is 20.1%. Therefore, an average cost of equity of 17.61% for this study is consistent with prior studies. Table 2 shows that there is a large dispersion among the sample firms in terms of control variables, and this dispersion indicates a considerable diversity in the sample. Insert Table 2 about here 14 Moreover, using median analyst forecasts as inputs, Truong and Partington (2007) estimate the cost of equity for Australian firms and find that the average estimates produced by different valuation models are in the range of from 10% to 17%. 15 Our results differ from those of Azizkhani et al. (2010) for several reasons. (a) Our sample size and sample period differ from that of their study. More specifically, our sample covers the global financial crisis period which is associated with increased risk and cost of equity. (b) We winsorize the cost of equity estimates at the 1% level (both sides), while they exclude the extreme values. (c) Azizkhani et al. (2010) use the square root of the numerator only, while we use the square root of both numerator and denominator, which is consistent with Easton’s (2004) original model. 21 Panel A of Table 2 presents descriptive statistics for the dependent, independent and control variables. The mean (median) RE/TA and RE/TE are .0383 (.0887) and .0662 (.1894), respectively. The mean values of SIZE (19.9026), ZSCORE (3.8928) and Losst-1 (.1052) suggest the presence of large and financially sound firms in the sample. Moreover, the mean (.8047) and median (.5657) of the book-to-market ratio suggest that the sample firms have valuable growth opportunities. The mean BETA (.9538) is slightly lower than that of Azizkhani et al. (2010) (1.02) and higher than that of Chen et al. (2004) (.75). The mean LEV (.5439) is similar to that of Cassar and Holmes (2003) (.57). Panel B of Table 2 exhibits the life cycle-wise (Dickinson 2011) cost of equity under different models. All the models show that the cost of equity is lowest in the mature stage, while it is comparatively higher in the introduction and decline stages. The lowest cost of equity for mature stage firms indicates that mature firms are, on average, the least risky among firms in other stages. Panel C of Table 3 shows the graphical expression of the cost of equity under different models and different life cycle stages. The cost of equity under all models shows a “U” shaped pattern across the life cycle. Panel D of Table 2 reports life cycle-wise descriptive statistics for the sample firms. Firms in the mature stage are characterised by stability, while firms in the decline stage are in a transition phase (Dickinson 2011). Consistent with the findings of Dickinson (2011), we find that highest (lowest) observations belong to the mature (decline) stage with 47.07% (1.52%) of observations. The overall results of Panel D of Table 2 show that mature firms, consistent with their lower riskiness, have the lowest BETA, lowest rate of LOSSt-1, and highest ZSCORE. Moreover, the descriptive statistics show that firms in the introduction and decline stages are relatively more risky (with BETA of 1.15 and 1.42 as opposed to .97 and .89 in the growth and mature stages) and hence investors demand a relatively higher risk 22 premium (average cost of equity of .29 and .36) for firms in these stages (compared to .17 and .15 in growth and mature stages). Further analysis reveals that SIZE, RE/TA and RE/TE progressively increase as firms move from introduction to mature stage and that these estimates then decline as firms move from mature to decline stage: the opposite pattern is observed for the average cost of equity, BETA and LOSSt-1. The estimates in Panel D of Table 2 are also consistent with life cycle theory and the pattern of the statistics across the life cycle is in line with Dickinson (2011), signifying the reliability of the estimates. 4.2 Correlation Analysis Table 3 reports the Pearson pairwise correlations among different estimates of the cost of equity, life cycle proxies and control variables. As expected, the cost of equity, estimated by all the models, is positively correlated (significant at 0.000 level) with introduction, shake-out and decline stages of the firm and significantly negatively correlated (significant at 0.000 level) with the mature stage of the firm. Interestingly, all the cost of equity estimates are negatively correlated (although insignificant) with the growth stage of the firm. This is possibly because growth firms can attract strategic investors who, in turn, allow these firms to use the capital with less cost. Moreover, consistent with expectations, the cost of equity estimates are also significantly negatively correlated (significant at 0.000 level) with RE/TA and RE/TE. Finally, the correlations among cost of equity estimates and BM, BETA and LOSSt-1 are positive and significant (at p = 0.000), while the correlation of cost of equity with SIZE and ZSCORE is negative and significant (at p = 0.000). Overall, the correlations among cost of equity estimates, life cycle proxies and the control variables are all in the expected direction. Insert Table 3 about Here 23 4.3 Univariate t-Test Table 4 reports the mean cost of equity capital for different stages of the firm life cycle. Panel A shows that the mean ex-ante cost of equity capital for each stage significantly differs from that of other stages. For all models of cost of equity estimates, the average cost of equity significantly decreases (significant at < 0.01 level) from introduction to growth stage, from growth to mature stage, from introduction to mature stage and from introduction to shake-out stage of the firm life cycle. However, the mean cost of equity increases significantly (significant at 0.000 level) from mature to shake-out stage, from shake-out to decline stage, from introduction to decline stage, from growth to shake-out stage and finally from growth to decline stage. Insert Table 4 about Here 4.4 Association between Cost of Equity and Firm Life Cycle 4.4.1 Firm Fixed Effect Estimation In examining the association between the firm life cycle and the cost of equity, we statistically test which empirical model – pooling, random effect or fixed effect regression – is most suitable for estimating the relationship. Specifically, following Aivazian et al. (2005), we conduct two statistical tests: the first is the Lagrangian Multiplier (LM) test of the random effect model (Breusch and Pagan 1980). The null hypothesis is that the individual effect, , is 0 for all i. The chi-square statistics for the four models of cost of equity in Panel A of Table 5 are 543.90, 564.46, 566.05, and 589.57 respectively. Thus, the null hypothesis is rejected at the 1% significance level, which suggests that the cohort effect is not zero and that the pooling regression is not suitable in this case. For the second test, we perform the Hausman specification test (Hausman 1978) to compare between fixed effect and random 24 effect models. The null hypothesis is that unique errors are not correlated with the regressors. If the model specification is correct and if individual effects are uncorrelated with the independent variables, the fixed effect and random effect estimators should not be statistically different. For all models in Panel A of Table 5, null hypotheses are rejected at the 1% significance level. The results suggest that the fixed effect model is most appropriate in estimating the impact of the firm life cycle on the cost of equity. We repeat these tests for all the estimates in Panel B and Panel C of Table 5 and find that the fixed effect model is best for investigating the intended relationship. Hence, we report only fixed effect estimates results in our study. Table 5 reports the fixed effect estimates of the relationship between the cost of equity and the corporate life cycle. As firm fixed effects and year dummies are specified in the regressions, their estimates are constant at firm level and year level respectively. All other control variables (such as SIZE, B/M, BETA, LOSSt-1, LEV, and ZSCORE) are measured at firm-year level. The regression coefficients on these control variables remain constant in the sample. Panel A shows the results for different measures of the cost of equity and RE/TA, a life cycle proxy proposed by DeAngelo et al. (2006). The coefficient on RE/TA is negative and statistically significant for all of the cost of equity measures, suggesting that investors’ demand for the cost of equity decreases as RE/TA increases. The results also reveal that investors demand less risk premium for large and financially sound firms (the coefficients on SIZE and ZSCORE are both negative and statistically significant). On the other hand, demand for risk premium is higher for growth and risky firms (with positive and statistically significant coefficients on BM, BETA, LOSSt–1 and LEV). Insert Table 5 about Here 25 Panel B of Table 5 presents the association between cost of equity and RE/TE, another measure of corporate life cycle proxy proposed by DeAngelo et al. (2006). Obviously, a firm cannot have a high RE/TE ratio without substantial prior earnings (DeAngelo et al. 2006): hence, it is justified to use RE/TE as a proxy for the firm life cycle. All these specifications show a highly significant negative relation between RE/TE and the cost of equity estimates. The coefficients on the control variables, for example, SIZE, BM, BETA, LOSSt–1, LEV and ZSCORE have the predicted signs and significance. These findings are consistent with the resource-based view and corporate life cycle theory. The results for Dickinson’s (2011) life cycle measures are shown in Panel C of Table 5. The life cycles of firms are categorised by Dickinson (2011) into five stages: introduction, growth, maturity, shake-out and decline. Five dummy variables are thus created for each of the five stages. However, to avoid the multicollinearity problem in the regression model, one of the stages should be dropped. Since the shake-out stage of the life cycle is ambiguous in theory (Dickinson 2011), we drop this stage in the regression model. The regression results suggest that, compared to the shake-out stage, the introduction and decline stages of the firm life cycle are significantly positively associated with the cost of equity, while the growth and mature stages of the life cycle are negatively associated with all estimates of the cost of equity (at p < .01 level). Finally, the coefficients on all of the control variables have the predicted signs and are statistically significant, suggesting that the model specification is reasonable. Overall, our evidence is consistent with the resource-based theory and life cycle explanation for the cost of equity of the firm. Controlling for known determinants of the cost of equity (SIZE, BM, BETA, LOSSt–1, LEV, and ZSCORE) and individual firm 26 heterogeneity, we find that the cost of equity is significantly negatively associated with both life cycle proxies – RE/TA and RE/TE. Moreover, when the stages in the firm life cycle are taken into account, compared to the shake-out stage, the cost of equity is negative and significant in the growth and mature stages, while it is positive and significant in the introduction and decline stages. These results support the notion that, in the early stages of the life cycle, firms have a limited resources base. These firms do not have a long-term relationship with the financial market and consequently do not enjoy the opportunity to raise capital at the same cost as firms in the growth and mature stages. Growth firms have good potential, disclose more information to reduce information asymmetry and hence can attract growth and strategic investors and thereby can raise capital at a lower cost. Moreover, mature firms have positive goodwill and good credit history: thus, these firms have access to less expensive money. The cost of equity is higher in the decline stage because potential investors do not want to invest money into a crisis firm unless they are properly compensated for their risk. The important bottom line of the analysis is that all the life cycle proxies and cost of equity estimates uniformly and strongly support the view that firms’ cost of equity varies significantly with the stages in the firms’ life cycle. 4.5 Two Stage Least Squares (2SLS) Regression Even though fixed effect estimation suggests a negative association between firm maturity and cost of equity that is both statistically and economically significant, the sign, magnitude or statistical significance of these estimates may be biased due to endogeneity, that is, that the life cycle proxy and the error term in Equation (1) are correlated. Three factors may potentially contribute to this effect: reverse causality, omitted unobserved characteristics and measurement error (Aivazian et al. 2005). To formally address the concern that the proxy for the corporate life cycle is endogenous, we adopt a two-stage instrumental variable approach 27 to re-examine the fixed effect panel’s data-based findings reported in Table 5. The first stage of this procedure involves regressing endogenous variables (proxies for the firm life cycle) on selected instruments and the exogenous variables from the main analyses in Table 5. In the second stage, we estimate analyses in Table 5 by replacing the endogenous variables (proxies for the firm life cycle) with fitted values from the first-stage regressions. Contemporary studies in finance and accounting extensively adopt the two-stage instrumental variable approach to address endogeneity concerns.16 However, this approach is appropriate only if the instrumental variables are correlated with the endogenous regressor but uncorrelated with the error term of the second-stage regression. In this context, good instruments are exogenous variables that are economically related to the life cycle proxy but are uncorrelated with the error term of the second-stage regression relating the cost of equity to the life cycle. Hence, we use the average cost of equity (simple average of all non-missing observations), industry average earnings per share (EPS), industry average ZSCORE and firm-level operating performance (proxied by dummy variable for firm loss) as instruments for firm life cycle proxies (RE/TA and RE/TE). We use average cost of equity because it is expected to exhibit lower measurement error than any of the individual measures. Use of industry average EPS and Z score as instruments can be justified on the basis that industrylevel operating performance and financial strength of the firms reflect the growth and maturity of the industry to which a particular firm belongs and, therefore, it should be highly correlated with the life cycle of the firm. Lumpkin and Dess (2001) suggest that the industry life cycle affects firms’ strategy on proactiveness or competitive aggressiveness. When demand grows in an industry, firms can realise initial success without the intense competitive threat that firms face in mature industries. Therefore, it is expected that industry-level growth, 16 Please refer to Larcker and Rusticus (2010) for discussion on the use of instrumental variables in contemporary accounting research. 28 performance and financial solvency of the firm have direct impact on the overall performance of the firm, which eventually shapes the stages of the life cycle of the firm. Firm-level operating performance is one of the key indicators of the firm’s stage in the life cycle (Dickinson 2011). Firms in the introduction and decline stages generally have negative operating performance, while firms in the growth and mature stages have strong operating performance. Hence, we use a dummy variable for loss of the firm which reflects different stages of the firm life cycle. Panel A of Table 6 reports the first-stage regression results in which the endogenous variables, RE/TA and RE/TE, are regressed on the selected instruments and the exogenous variables from our analyses in Table 5. Consistent with expectations, coefficients on the instrumental variables are significant (at the 1% level), suggesting that firm maturity (RE/TA and RE/TE) is positively associated with profitability (EPS) and negatively related to loss. Panel B of Table 6 shows the results from the instrumental variable approach and suggests that the negative relationship between life cycle proxies (RE/TA and RE/TE) and the cost of equity remain robust after accounting for the endogenous relationship between the life cycle proxy and the implied cost of equity capital. The estimated coefficients of RE/TA and RE/TE are -.519 and -.276, respectively (both are significant at < .001) in the fixed effect two stage least squares (2SLS) regression, suggesting that endogeneity cannot explain away the negative relationship between the life cycle and the cost of equity capital.17 Insert Table 6 about Here In support of the instruments, we also conduct underidentification, weak identification, Hansen’s overidentifying restrictions and Hausman’s endogeneity tests. In 17 We perform Hausman’s specification test (Hausman 1978) to test whether the fixed effect and random effect instrumental variable approaches are suitable. Test results suggest that the data support the fixed effect model in estimating the relationship. 29 Table 6, underidentification test results (LM statistic) reveal that the excluded instruments are "relevant". The weak instrument test is performed to test whether the excluded instruments are sufficiently correlated with the included endogenous regressors—the goodness-of-fit of the “first stage”. Test results show that the excluded instruments are correlated with the endogenous regressors because the Cragg-Donald Wald F statistic is greater than Stock and Yogo’s (2002) critical value.18 Results from Hansen’s overidentifying restrictions test do not reject the null hypothesis (p-value > .10), suggesting that instruments are uncorrelated with the error term and are correctly excluded from the second-stage regression, which reflects the validity of the instruments used for the 2SLS regression. Finally, we perform Hausman’s (1978) test to ascertain whether the endogeneity problem is really a concern for the estimates. For our analysis, Hausman’s test strongly rejects (p-value = 0.000) the exogeneity of the firm life cycle (RE/TA and RE/TE) which justifies the use of the 2SLS regression estimates. We also employ a two-stage instrumental variable approach to address the endogeneity concern with Dickinson’s (2011) life cycle measure. The untabulated19 results of the weak instrument test, overidentification test, underidentification test and Hausman’s test indicate the validity of the instruments used and confirm that the 2SLS regression estimate is preferable for estimating the association between the cost of equity and the firm life cycle. Moreover, the second-stage results continue to provide strong evidence of a statistically significant and positive relationship between the cost of equity and the introduction and decline stages, while a statistically significant negative relationship exists between the cost of equity and the growth and decline stages of the firm life cycle. 18 When the instrument is only weakly correlated with the regressor, IV methods provide highly biased estimates (Larcker and Rusticus 2010). We also test whether 2SLS regression estimates suffer from the heteroskedasticity problem and the results reveal that our estimates do not suffer from this problem. Hence, we report the Cragg-Donald Wald F statistic for the weak identification test in Panel B of Table 6. 19 For brevity, results are not tabulated: they may be requested from the authors. 30 4.6 Additional Analysis and Robustness Check In this section, we examine the robustness of the results to alternative measurements and specifications. 4.6.1 Alternative Measure of Firm Life Cycle To mitigate the concerns as to whether the main results are sensitive to how the life cycle is measured, we use firm age as an alternative measure.20 Firm age is a simple and natural choice for measuring the life cycle stage of a firm because life cycle stages are naturally linked to firm age. We define AGE as the difference between the current year and the year of incorporation of the firm.21 Panel A of Table 7 reports the results of the sensitivity tests where the dependent variable is cost of equity (for the four models used in the main analysis) and the key independent variable is AGE. In Panel A, Models 1 to 4 show that the association between all the estimates of the cost of equity and AGE are negative and statistically significant. However, considering that firm age can be a proxy for various time-varying arguments, we also use a dummy variable to distinguish between firms in old and young groups. We use AGE equals 1 if the firm age is greater than the median in any given year, 0 otherwise. The untabulated results remain qualitatively the same. Overall, the results using AGE as an alternative measure of the firm life cycle are similar to those obtained in our main analysis and this helps to justify that the results are not sensitive to the choice of the life cycle proxy. 4.6.2 Alternative Measure of Cost of Equity To mitigate the concerns that our results are driven by the choice of dependent variable (estimation of the cost of equity), we use an alternative approach to measure the cost of 20 Pástor and Pietro (2003) also use firm age as a “natural proxy” for investors’ uncertainty about the profitability of the firm. 21 We have collected data on the firm’s year of incorporation from company history and listing details of DatAnalysis Morningstar. 31 equity. For this purpose, we follow Easton and Monahan (2005) and use the following model to calculate the ex-ante cost of equity: ( ( ) ) Panel B of Table 7 reports the results of the sensitivity analysis with RPE as the dependent variable and four alternative measures of firm life cycle proxies (RE/TA, RE/TE, Dickinson’s (2011) measure and AGE) as the key independent variables along with control variables. As reported in the table, our inferences on the role of the firm life cycle on the cost of equity remain unaltered when the new empirical proxy for the cost of equity is used as the dependent variable. For example, in Panel B of Table 7, Model 1 and Model 2 show that the cost of equity is significantly negatively associated with RE/TA and RE/TE. In Model 3, in considering Dickinson’s (2011) life cycle stages, the cost of equity is positively associated with the decline stages, and negatively associated with the growth and mature stages. Moreover, Model 4 shows that the relationship between the cost of equity and AGE (the life cycle proxy) is negative and significant. In conclusion, regression results using the alternative measures of life cycle and cost of equity suggest that our results are not sensitive to the choice of estimation of the life cycle and the cost of equity. 4.6.3 Estimates Excluding Regulated Industries We repeat estimations in the main analysis by excluding utilities, telecommunications and energy industries from the sample. The rationale for excluding these industries is that the investment behaviour of these firms is more likely to be affected by regulations and by the nature of their activities (Aivazian et al. 2005). In untabulated results, estimates of this 32 restricted sample are very similar to the estimates with the main analysis. None of the significant coefficients changes its sign. V. Concluding Remarks Our study provides evidence on the cost of equity for Australian listed firms and tests whether the dynamic resource-based view and life cycle theory can explain the variation in the cost of equity across different phases of the firm life cycle. In this study, we posit that firms in different life cycle stages have different levels of resource base, competitive advantages, information asymmetry and riskiness and, hence, the cost of equity of the firm should vary systematically across the firm’s life cycle. Using a sample of Australian listed firms from 1990–2012, our results show that the cost of equity of the firm significantly differs across the life cycle stages. In particular, the study reveals that the cost of equity is higher in the introduction and decline stages of the firm, while it is lower in the mature stage. Moreover, the mean difference test also suggests that there is a large difference in the cost of equity for various stages of the firm life cycle. Specifically, the results are unaffected by different estimations of the cost of equity and the firm life cycle. Overall, our empirical evidence contributes to the growing body of literature that focuses on the financial implications of the firm life cycle. Our primary contribution is in extending this body of research to document the role of the life cycle as a key determinant of the cost of equity capital. Our findings strongly support the resource-based view of competitive advantage and firm life cycle theory. The resource-based view (RBV) suggests that a firm’s resources are the ultimate determinants of competitive advantage and performance. According to the 33 resource-based view, the financial capital, physical resources, human resources, intangible know-how, and skills and capabilities of large and mature firms are rich, diverse and strong, while those of small and young firms are small, concentrated and limited. These resource bases and expertise help mature firms to achieve competitive advantage, to reduce the risk and information asymmetry problem, and to gain easy access to finance which contribute to a reduction in the cost of equity capital. The findings are also consistent with the life cycle theory of the firm in that different stages of the life cycle exhibit different levels of disclosure, analyst and investors’ following, liquidity of stock, existence, credibility and reputation in the market. Hence, as a consequence of transition from one stage to another, the cost of equity changes accordingly. Finally, from a practitioner’s perspective, our results have direct implications for the financial management and strategic direction of the firm. Our results provide evidence suggesting that firms should reach and maintain maturity, the prime stage of the firm life cycle, to benefit from the lower cost of equity. 34 Appendix A: Variable Definition and Measurement Variables = Definition and Measurement Dependent Variable RPEG Implied cost of equity, estimated by the PEG model of Easton (2004) RMPEG Implied cost of equity, estimated by the MPEG model of Easton (2004) ROJ Implied cost of equity, estimated by the modified Ohlson and Juettner-Nauroth (2005) model (modified by Gode and Mohanram (2003)) RAverage Implied cost of equity, estimated as the average of the above three models Firm Life Cycle Proxies RE/TA Retained earnings as a proportion of total assets. Measured as: retained earnings/total assets RE/TE Retained earnings as a proportion of total equity. Measured as: retained earnings/total equity CLC A vector of dummy variables that capture firms’ different stages in the life cycle AGE The difference between the current year and the year of incorporation of the firm Control Variables SIZE Natural log of total assets of the firm at the end of the fiscal year BM Ratio of book value of equity to market value of equity at the end of the fiscal year BETA A measure of systematic risk, extracted from Datastream. Datastream uses a five-year period and regresses the share price against the respective Datastream total market index using log changes of the closing price on the first day of each month LOSSt-1 An indicator variable that equals 1 if net income before abnormal is negative in the previous years, 0 otherwise LEV (Short term debt + long term debt)/Shareholders’ equity ZSCORE A model, developed by Edward I. Altman in 1968, used to predict publicly traded manufacturing companies’ likelihood of bankruptcy. Altman’s Z score = 1.2(Working Capital/Total Assets) + 1.4(Retained Earnings/Total Assets) + 3.3(Earnings Before Interest & Tax/Total Assets) + 0.6(Market Value of Equity/Total Liabilities) + 0.999(Sales/Total Assets) Year Dummy variables to control for fiscal year Firm-specific unobserved fixed effects 35 Table 1: Sample Selection and Distribution of the Sample Panel A: Sample Selection by Models Description I/B/E/S forecasted EPS (fiscal year 1990-2012) Less: Firm years dropped due to: Model’s specific requirement22 Absence of forecasted DPS1 Financial sector and delisted firms Missing values on control valuables Final Sample Pooled Easton PEG (2004) Easton MPEG (2004) 8020 8020 8020 Ohlson and JuettnerNauroth (2005) 8020 2250 N/A 1337 545 3888 2250 N/A 1337 545 3888 2250 707 1311 189 3563 2342 703 1297 196 3482 Panel B: Distribution by Year (Pooled) Year 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 N Year 35 1998 46 1999 46 2000 43 2001 46 2002 87 2003 120 2004 118 2005 N Year 127 2006 145 2007 162 2008 230 2009 223 2010 188 2011 191 2012 231 Total N 252 275 292 216 262 289 264 3888 Panel C: Distribution by Sectors and Cost of Equity Models Name of the Sector Consumer Discretionary Consumer Staples Energy Health Care Industrials Information Technology Materials Telecommunication Services Utilities Total 22 Pooled Easton PEG (2004) Easton MPEG (2004) Ohlson and JuettnerNauroth (2005) 818 362 283 266 961 273 776 79 70 3888 818 362 283 266 961 273 776 79 70 3888 770 322 246 250 918 263 656 69 69 3563 765 320 231 243 912 258 621 65 67 3482 For estimating the cost of equity, we exclude cases where eps2 > eps1 > 0 are not met. 36 Table 2: Descriptive Statistics This table presents descriptive statistics for the major variables used in the study. All the variables are defined in Appendix A. Panel A: Pooled Descriptive Statistics Variables N RAverage RE/TA RE/TE SIZE BM BETA LOSSt-1 LEV ZSCORE 3888 3888 3888 3888 3888 3888 3888 3888 3888 Mean .1779 .0383 .0662 19.9026 .8047 .9538 .1052 .5439 3.8928 Standard Deviation .1292 .3380 .7375 1.6795 .9047 .7791 .3068 .5881 4.0709 25% .1048 .0084 .0206 18.706 .3114 .4735 0.0000 .1500 1.8991 Panel B: Life Cycle-wise Cost of Equity Using Different Models Statistics Pooled Introducti Growth Maturity Model on RPEG Mean .1563 .2670 .1536 .1317 (Easton Median .1181 .2041 .1194 .1075 2004) Std. Dev. .1226 .1980 .1099 .0911 RMPEG (Easton 2004) R(Ohlson and JuettnerNauroth Median .1396 .0887 .1894 19.7753 .5657 .8570 0.0000 .4200 2.8350 75% .2018 .1844 .3771 21.0821 .9419 1.3045 0.0000 .7200 4.4014 Shakeout .1779 .1329 .1364 Decline .3385 .2679 .2218 Mean Median Std. Dev. . 1846 . 1465 .1330 .3099 .2289 .2295 .1785 .1444 .1204 .1615 .1365 .0954 .2042 .1606 .1421 .3693 .2774 .2564 Mean Median Std. Dev. .1873 .1535 .1193 .2951 .2271 .1997 .1852 .1537 .1129 .1670 .1442 .0893 .2037 .1636 .1244 .3594 .2589 .2286 Mean Median Std. Dev. .1779 .1396 .1293 .2908 .2165 .2113 .1741 .1396 .1174 .1535 .1286 .0951 .1990 .1542 .1429 .3677 .2931 .2355 2005) RAverage Panel C: Life Cycle-wise Mean Cost of Equity Using Different Models 0.4 0.35 0.3 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 PEG (Easton 2004) MPEG (Easton 2004) Ohlson and JuettnerNauroth (2005) Average Introduction Growth Maturity Shake-out 37 Decline Panel D: Life Cycle-wise Descriptive Statistics Variables RE/TA RE/TE SIZE BM BETA LOSSt -1 LEV ZSCORE Statistics Mean Median Standard Deviation Mean Median Standard Deviation Mean Median Standard Deviation Mean Median Standard Deviation Mean Median Standard Deviation Mean Median Standard Deviation Mean Median Standard Deviation Mean Median Standard Deviation N Introduction Growth -.2798 .0485 -.0716 .0769 .5514 .2363 -.5702 .0921 -.1079 .1654 1.3414 .5527 18.8836 20.0333 18.8311 19.9263 1.4782 1.5733 .7749 .7799 .5705 .5600 .9309 .8495 1.1538 .9782 1.0630 .8875 1.0116 .7665 .4096 .0973 0.0000 0.0000 .4927 .2965 .6897 .6355 .4700 .5200 .7965 .5816 3.4767 3.3226 1.9590 2.5789 5.6652 3.2954 271 1356 38 Maturity .1031 . 1198 .2918 .1954 .2477 .5649 19.9791 19.8747 1.7123 .7816 .5383 .9053 .8954 .8080 .7103 .0459 0.0000 .2093 .4798 .3500 .5310 4.3926 3.2308 4.0190 1830 ShakeDecline out -.0032 -.4824 .0811 -.2996 .3597 .7275 -.0069 -1.1516 .1605 -.5401 .6898 1.9636 19.9356 18.9995 19.8323 19.0704 1.7220 1.8281 1.0026 .9791 .7250 .7037 .9897 1.2384 .9315 1.4249 .8250 1.2550 .8608 1.0039 .1559 .4068 0.0000 0.0000 .3633 .4954 .4717 .5589 .3400 .2300 .5748 .8663 3.8353 3.7729 2.6565 1.6107 4.4890 7.2754 372 59 Table 3: Correlation Matrix Correlation among the Different Estimates of Cost of Equity, Life Cycle Proxies and Control Variables Models Introduction RPEG RMPEG ROJ RAverage 0.247*** 0.258*** 0.232*** 0.239*** Growth -0.016 -0.034** -0.013 -0.021 Mature -0.189*** -0.165*** -0.164*** -0.178*** Shake-out 0.057*** 0.045*** 0.042** 0.053*** Decline 0.184*** 0.171*** 0.174*** 0.182*** RE/TA -0.436*** -0.416*** -0.389*** -0.416*** RE/TE -0.393*** -0.383*** -0.366*** -0.382*** SIZE -0.325*** -0.315*** -0.306*** -0.319*** BM 0.254*** 0.286*** 0.292*** 0.271*** BETA 0.204*** 0.230*** 0.218*** 0.196*** LOSSt-1 0.367*** 0.285*** 0.285*** 0.328*** LEV -0.023 0.012 0.028 0.005 ZSCORE -0.130*** -0.163*** -0.163*** -0.145*** This table presents the correlation among different estimates of the cost of equity, life cycle proxies and control variables. The values in the matrix are Pearson correlation coefficients and ***, **, and * denote significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels respectively (two-tailed tests). All the variables are as defined in Appendix A. 39 Table 4: Mean Difference Test of Cost of Equity (assuming unequal variance) Mean Difference Test of Cost of Equity Using Dickinson (2011) Cost of Equity Cost of Equity t statistics for Estimates p-values (Stage 1) (Stage 2) differences Introduction Growth RPEG .267 .154 -9.153 0.000 RMPEG .309 .178 -8.783 0.000 ROJ .295 .185 -7.855 0.000 RAverage .291 .174 -8.822 0.000 Growth Maturity RPEG .154 .132 -5.969 0.000 RMPEG .178 .162 -4.137 0.000 ROJ .185 .167 -4.694 0.000 RAverage .174 .154 -5.309 0.000 Maturity Shake-out RPEG .132 .178 6.253 0.000 RMPEG .162 .204 5.033 0.000 ROJ .167 .204 4.847 0.000 RAverage .154 .199 5.884 0.000 Shake-out Decline RPEG .178 .338 5.404 0.000 RMPEG .204 .369 4.567 0.000 ROJ .204 .359 4.698 0.000 RAverage .199 .368 5.347 0.000 Introduction Maturity RPEG .267 .132 -11.078 0.000 RMPEG .309 .162 -10.057 0.000 ROJ .295 .167 -9.284 0.000 RAverage .291 .154 -10.540 0.000 Introduction Shake-out RPEG .267 .178 -6.387 0.000 RMPEG .309 .204 -6.326 0.000 ROJ .295 .204 -5.919 0.000 RAverage .291 .199 -6.194 0.000 Introduction Decline RPEG .267 .338 2.286 0.025 RMPEG .309 .369 1.559 0.123 ROJ .295 .359 1.833 0.071 RAverage .291 .368 2.312 0.023 Growth Shake-out RPEG .154 .178 3.165 0.001 RMPEG .178 .204 2.911 0.004 ROJ .185 .204 2.341 0.019 RAverage .174 .199 3.085 0.002 Growth Decline RPEG .154 .334 6.371 0.000 RMPEG .178 .358 5.394 0.000 ROJ .185 .350 5.363 0.000 RAverage .174 .361 6.279 0.000 40 Table 5: Association between Cost of Equity and Firm Life Cycle Panel A: Association between Cost of Equity and RE/TA (Life Cycle Proxy of DeAngelo (2006)) Model 1 Easton 2004 RPEG Model 2 Easton 2004 RMPEG Model 3 OJ 2005 ROJ Model 4 ? 0.415*** (5.47) 0.364*** (4.95) 0.377*** (5.50) 0.392*** (5.09) RE/TA - -0.058*** (-4.14) -0.051*** (-3.10) -0.034** (-2.41) -0.056*** (-3.81) SIZE - -0.012*** (-3.31) -0.011*** (-2.88) -0.011*** (-3.09) -0.011*** (-2.94) BM + 0.032*** (6.86) 0.041*** (7.52) 0.040*** (7.88) 0.037*** (7.19) BETA + 0.004 (1.23) 0.010*** (2.61) 0.010*** (2.68) 0.005 (1.43) LOSSt-1 + 0.027*** (3.14) 0.011 (1.29) 0.011 (1.35) 0.020** (2.34) LEV + 0.013*** (2.84) 0.017*** (2.87) 0.015*** (3.29) 0.017*** (3.24) ZSCORE - -0.003*** (-4.85) -0.004*** (-4.75) -0.003*** (-4.68) -0.004*** (-5.23) Year Dummy Yes Yes Yes Yes Firm Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Adj. R-squared 0.759 0.781 0.767 0.755 Observations (N) 3,888 3,563 3,482 3,888 Number of Firms 704 679 656 704 Variables Pred. Sign Intercept Robust t-statistics in brackets *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.10 41 RAverage Panel B: Association between Cost of Equity and RE/TE (Life Cycle Proxy of (DeAngelo 2006)) Model 1 Easton 2004 RPEG Model 2 Easton 2004 RMPEG Model 3 OJ 2005 ROJ Model 4 Variables Pred. Sign Intercept ? 0.452*** (5.75) 0.379*** (4.92) 0.374*** (5.23) 0.422*** (5.25) RE/TE - -0.017*** (-3.15) -0.019*** (-3.43) -0.015*** (-2.97) -0.017*** (-3.16) SIZE - -0.014*** (-3.69) -0.012*** (-2.90) -0.011*** (-2.87) -0.012*** (-3.19) BM + 0.033*** (7.23) 0.042*** (7.71) 0.040*** (7.95) 0.038*** (7.46) BETA + 0.005 (1.38) 0.010*** (2.59) 0.010*** (2.62) 0.006 (1.54) LOSSt-1 + 0.031*** (3.67) 0.014 (1.64) 0.012 (1.45) 0.024*** (2.79) LEV + 0.010** (2.13) 0.013** (1.99) 0.011** (2.30) 0.014** (2.45) ZSCORE - -0.004*** (-5.62) -0.004*** (-5.26) -0.004*** (-5.05) -0.004*** (-5.89) Year Dummy Yes Yes Yes Yes Firm Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Adj. R-squared 0.757 0.780 0.767 0.754 Observations (N) 3,888 3,563 3,482 3,888 Number of Firms 704 679 656 704 Robust t-statistics in brackets *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.10 42 RAverage Panel C: Association between Cost of Equity and Life Cycle Proxies of Dickinson (2011) Model 1 Easton 2004 RPEG Model 2 Easton 2004 RMPEG Model 3 OJ 2005 ROJ Model 4 ? 0.503*** (6.72) 0.458*** (5.75) 0.438*** (5.86) 0.475*** (6.11) Introduction + 0.017 (1.57) 0.032*** (2.65) 0.024** (2.32) 0.019* (1.68) Growth - -0.015*** (-2.84) -0.014*** (-2.89) -0.012*** (-2.68) -0.017*** (-3.08) Maturity - -0.015*** (-3.13) -0.014*** (-2.89) -0.014*** (-3.00) -0.016*** (-3.28) Decline + 0.076*** (2.96) 0.061** (2.12) 0.055** (1.99) 0.069*** (2.62) SIZE - -0.017*** (-4.76) -0.016*** (-3.78) -0.014*** (-3.57) -0.015*** (-4.13) BM + 0.033*** (7.46) 0.042*** (7.89) 0.040*** (8.14) 0.038*** (7.63) BETA + 0.006* (1.75) 0.012*** (3.06) 0.011*** (3.04) 0.007* (1.93) LOSSt-1 + 0.031*** (3.44) 0.014* (1.66) 0.012 (1.46) 0.025*** (2.77) LEV + 0.016*** (3.36) 0.019*** (3.16) 0.016*** (3.47) 0.020*** (3.70) ZSCORE - -0.004*** (-6.25) -0.004*** (-5.76) -0.004*** (-5.40) -0.005*** (-6.40) Year Dummy Yes Yes Yes Yes Firm Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Adj. R-squared 0.761 0.783 0.770 0.757 Observations (N) 3,888 3,564 3,483 3,888 Number of Firms 704 679 656 704 Variables Pred. Sign Intercept Robust t-statistics in brackets *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.10 43 RAverage Table 6: Two Stage Least Squares (2SLS) Regression Panel A: First-Stage Regressions of Life Cycle Proxy (RE/TA and RE/TE) and Validity of Instruments Explanatory Variable Model 1 Model 2 (RE/TA) (RE/TE) Instruments Industry Mean EPS 0.005*** .011*** (4.72) (4.41) Industry Mean Z score -0.019* -.032 (-1.75) (-1.23) Loss -0.143*** -0.251*** (-6.96) (-5.13) Unreported Control Variables Included in Regression All Predetermined Variables in Main Specification Year Fixed Effects Firm Fixed Effect Observation (N) Adjusted R2 Yes Yes Yes 3735 0.607 Yes Yes Yes 3735 0.281 Underidentification Test Kleibergen-Paap rk LM statistic p-value 64.987 0.000 46.181 0.000 Weak Identification Test Cragg-Donald Wald F statistic (Stock and Yogo 2002)10% maximal IV size (Critical Value) 53.252 22.30 28.407 22.30 Test of Overidentifying Restrictions Hansen’s J-statistic p-value 0.468 0.791 1.748 0.417 Panel B: Second-Stage Regressions of Cost of Equity on Life Cycle Proxy Explanatory Variable Model 1 (RE/TA) Potentially Endogenous Instrumented Variable Life Cycle Proxy -0.519*** (-6.17) Unreported Control Variables Included in Regression All Predetermined Variables in Main Specification Yes Year Fixed Effects Yes Firm Fixed Effect Yes Observation (N) 3735 Model 2 (RE/TE) -0.276*** (-5.33) Yes Yes Yes 3735 Hausman Test for the Effect of Life Cycle (Coefficient 2SLS = Coefficient OLS) Cluster-robust F-statistic p-value 54.842 0.000 44 53.454 0.000 Table 7: Sensitivity Analysis Panel A: Age as an Alternative Life Cycle Proxy Model 1 Easton 2004 RPEG Model 2 Easton 2004 RMPEG Model 3 OJ 2005 ROJ Model 4 ? 0.582*** (7.43) 0.543*** (7.03) 0.514*** (7.11) 0.561*** (6.98) AGE - -0.003*** (-3.22) -0.004*** (-3.48) -0.004*** (-3.48) -0.004*** (3.25) SIZE - -0.018*** (-4.84) -0.016*** (-3.93) -0.014*** (-3.64) -0.016*** (-4.28) BM + 0.034*** (7.50) 0.043*** (7.92) 0.040*** (8.14) 0.039*** (7.70) BETA + 0.006* (1.70) 0.012*** (2.97) 0.011*** (2.93) 0.007* (1.87) LOSSt–1 + 0.037*** (4.14) 0.020** (2.26) 0.016* (1.96) 0.030*** (3.34) LEV + 0.017*** (3.51) 0.020*** (3.33) 0.017*** (3.75) 0.021*** (3.78) ZSCORE - -0.004*** (-6.17) -0.005*** (-5.73) -0.004*** (-5.42) -0.005*** (-6.39) Year Dummy Yes Yes Yes Yes Firm Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Adj. R-squared 0.754 0.778 0.765 0.751 Observations (N) 3,867 3,544 3,467 3,867 Number of Firms 681 658 639 681 Variables Pred. Sign Intercept Robust t-statistics in brackets *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.10 45 RAverage Table 7: Sensitivity Analysis Panel B: Alternative Estimation of Cost of Equity Variables Pred. Sign Intercept ? RE/TA - RE/TE - Introduction + Growth - Maturity - Decline + AGE - SIZE - BM + BETA + LOSSt – 1 + LEV + ZSCORE - Year Dummy Firm Fixed Effect Adj. R-squared Observations (N) Number of Firms Model 1 RPE Model 2 RPE Model 3 RPE Model 4 RPE 0.010 (0.05) -0.114** (-1.97) 0.027 (-0.12) 0.223 (0.87) 0.406* (1.65) -0.047** (-2.05) 0.017 (0.54) -0.026** (-2.18) -0.024** (-2.23) 0.219*** (3.01) 0.003 (0.28) 0.100*** (5.42) 0.011 (0.89) -0.030* (-1.51) 0.045** (2.05) -0.000 (-.77) Yes 0.006 (0.48) 0.105*** (5.56) 0.009 (0.76) -0.026 (-1.33) 0.022 (1.02) -0.000 (-1.09) Yes -0.008 (-0.55) 0.100*** (5.79) 0.016 (1.32) -0.019 (-0.97) 0.053** (2.41) -0.000* (-1.68) Yes -0.007* (-1.74) -0.011 (-0.78) 0.105*** (5.83) 0.017 (1.34) -0.008 (-0.42) 0.053** (2.46) -0.000* (-1.53) Yes Yes 0.848 4,498 798 Yes 0.849 4,498 798 Yes 0.849 4,498 798 Yes 0.845 4,470 790 Robust t-statistics in brackets *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.10 46 References Aboody, D., and B. Lev. 2000. Information asymmetry, R&D, and insider gains. The Journal of Finance 55 (6):2747-2766. Adizes, I. 1979. Organizational passages–diagnosing and treating lifecycle problems of organizations. Organizational Dynamics 8 (1):3-25. ———. 2004. Managing Corporate Lifecycles: The Adizes Institute Publishing. Aivazian, V. A., Y. Ge, and J. Qiu. 2005. The impact of leverage on firm investment: Canadian evidence. Journal of Corporate Finance 11 (1):277-291. Altman, E. I. 1968. Financial ratios, discriminant analysis and the prediction of corporate bankruptcy. Journal of Finance 23 (4):589-609. Anthony, J. H., and K. Ramesh. 1992. Association between accounting performance measures and stock prices. Journal of Accounting & Economics 15 (2/3):203-227. Armstrong, C. S., J. E. Core, D. J. Taylor, and R. E. Verrecchia. 2011. When does information asymmetry affect the cost of capital? Journal of Accounting Research 49 (1):1-40. Azizkhani, M., G. S. Monroe, and G. Shailer. 2010. The value of Big 4 audits in Australia. Accounting & Finance 50 (4):743-766. Banz, R. W. 1981. The relationship between return and market value of common stocks. Journal of Financial Economics 9 (1):3-18. Barney, J. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management 17 (1):99-120. Barth, M. E., R. Kasznik, and M. F. McNichols. 2001. Analyst Coverage and Intangible Assets. Journal of Accounting Research 39 (1):1-34. Bender, R., and K. Ward. 1993. Corporate Financial Strategy. Oxford: Butterworth-Heinemann. Bentley, K., T. Omer, and B. Twedt. 2012. Does Business Strategy Impact a Firm's Information Environment? Working Paper, Available at SSRN 2162240. Berger, A. N., and G. F. Udell. 1995. Relationship lending and lines of credit in small firm finance. Journal of Business 68 (3):351-381. ———. 1998. The economics of small business finance: The roles of private equity and debt markets in the financial growth cycle. Journal of Banking & Finance 22 (6-8):613-673. Berk, J. B. 1995. A critique of size-related anomalies. The Review of Financial Studies 8 (2):275-286. Boone, J. P., I. K. Khurana, and K. K. Raman. 2008. Audit firm tenure and the equity risk premium. Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance 23 (1):115-140. Botosan, C. A. 1997. Disclosure level and the cost of equity capital. The Accounting Review 72 (3):323-349. ———. 2006. Disclosure and the cost of capital: what do we know? Accounting & Business Research 36 (sup1):31-40. Botosan, C. A., and M. A. Plumlee. 2002. A re‐examination of disclosure level and the expected cost of equity capital. Journal of Accounting Research 40 (1):21-40. ———. 2005. Assessing alternative proxies for the expected risk premium. The Accounting Review 80 (1):21-53. Bourguignon, F., and M. de Jong. 2003. Value versus growth. Journal of Portfolio Management 29 (4):71-79. Brennan, M. J., and A. Subrahmanyam. 1995. Investment analysis and price formation in securities markets. Journal of Financial Economics 38 (3):361-381. Breusch, T. S., and A. R. Pagan. 1980. The Lagrange multiplier test and its applications to model specification in econometrics. The Review of Economic Studies 47 (1):239-253. Bulan, L., N. Subramanian, and L. Tanlu. 2007. On the timing of dividend initiations. Financial Management (Blackwell Publishing Limited) 36 (4):31-65. Bushee, B. J., J. E. Core, W. Guay, and S. J. Hamm. 2010. The role of the business press as an information intermediary. Journal of Accounting Research 48 (1):1-19. Câmara, A., C. San-Lin, and W. Yaw-Huei. 2009. Option implied cost of equity and its properties. Journal of Futures Markets 29 (7):599-629. Cassar, G., and S. Holmes. 2003. Capital structure and financing of SMEs: Australian evidence. Accounting & Finance 43 (2):123-147. 47 Caves, R. E. 1980. Industrial Organization, Corporate Strategy and Structure. Journal of Economic Literature 18 (1):64-92. Chan, L. K. C., Y. Hamao, and J. Lakonishok. 1991. Fundamentals and Stock Returns in Japan. Journal of Finance 46 (5):1739-1764. Chandler, A. D. 1962. Strategy and structure: Chapters in the history of the American enterprise. Massachusetts Institute of Technology Cambridge. Chen, F., B. N. Jorgensen, and Y. K. Yoo. 2004. Implied cost of equity capital in earnings-based valuation: International evidence. Accounting and Business Research 34 (4):323-344. Chen, K. C. W., Z. Chen, and K. C. J. Wei. 2009. Legal protection of investors, corporate governance, and the cost of equity capital. Journal of Corporate Finance 15 (3):273-289. Collins, D. W., M. Pincus, and H. Xie. 1999. Equity valuation and negative earnings: The role of book value of equity. The Accounting Review 74 (1):29-61. Coulton, J. J., and C. Ruddock. 2011. Corporate payout policy in Australia and a test of the life-cycle theory. Accounting & Finance 51 (2):381-407. Davis, J. L. 1994. The cross-section of realized stock returns: the Pre-COMPUSTAT evidence. Journal of Finance 49 (5):1579-1593. DeAngelo, H., L. DeAngelo, and R. M. Stulz. 2006. Dividend policy and the earned/contributed capital mix: a test of the life-cycle theory. Journal of Financial Economics 81 (2):227-254. ———. 2010. Seasoned equity offerings, market timing, and the corporate lifecycle. Journal of Financial Economics 95 (3):275-295. Diamond, D. W., and R. E. Verrecchia. 1991. Disclosure, liquidity, and the cost of capital. Journal of Finance 46 (4):1325-1359. Dichev, I. D. 1998. Is the risk of bankruptcy a systematic risk? The Journal of Finance 53 (3):11311147. Dickinson, V. 2011. Cash flow patterns as a proxy for firm life cycle. Accounting Review 86 (6):19641994. Dierickx, I., and K. Cool. 1989. Asset stock accumulation and sustainability of competitive advantage. Management Science 35 (12):1504-1511. Easley, D., and M. O'Hara. 2004. Information and the Cost of Capital. The Journal of Finance 59 (4):1553-1583. Easton, P. D. 2004. PE ratios, PEG ratios, and estimating the implied expected rate of return on equity capital. The Accounting Review 79 (1):73-95. Easton, P. D., and S. J. Monahan. 2005. An evaluation of accounting-based measures of expected returns. Accounting Review 80 (2):501-538. Elton, E. J. 2002. Presidential address: expected return, realized return, and asset pricing tests. The Journal of Finance 54 (4):1199-1220. Fama, E. F., and K. R. French. 1989. Business conditions and expected returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics 25 (1):23-49. ———. 1992. The cross-section of expected stock returns. Journal of Finance 47 (2):427-465. ———. 1997. Industry costs of equity. Journal of Financial Economics 43 (2):153-193. ———. 2001. Disappearing dividends: changing firm characteristics or lower propensity to pay? Journal of Financial Economics 60 (1):3-43. Francis, J., R. LaFond, P. Olsson, and K. Schipper. 2005. The market pricing of accruals quality. Journal of Accounting and Economics 39 (2):295-327. Gebhardt, W. R., C. M. C. Lee, and B. Swaminathan. 2001. Toward an implied cost of capital. Journal of Accounting Research 39 (1):135-176. Gode, D., and P. Mohanram. 2003. Inferring the cost of capital using the Ohlson–Juettner model. Review of Accounting Studies 8 (4):399-431. Gode, D., and P. Mohanram. 2008. Improving the relationship between implied cost of capital and realized returns by removing predictable analyst forecast errors. Stern School of Business and Columbia University working paper. Gort, M., and S. Klepper. 1982. Time paths in the diffusion of product innovations. Economic Journal 92 (367):630-653. Grant, R. M. 1991. The resource-based theory of competitive advantage. Strategy: Critical Perspectives on Business and Management 135 (Spring):114-135. 48 Gray, Barbara, and S. S. Ariss. 1985. Politics and strategic change across organizational life cycles. Academy of Management Review 10 (4):707-723. Gray, P., P. S. Koh, and Y. H. Tong. 2009. Accruals quality, information risk and cost of capital: Evidence from Australia. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting 36 (1‐2):51-72. Greiner, L. E. 1972. Evolution and revolution as organizations grow. Harvard Business Review 50 (4):37-46. Grullon, G., R. Michaely, and B. Swaminathan. 2002. Are dividend changes a sign of firm maturity? Journal of Business 75 (3):387-424. Guay, W. R., S. P. Kothari, and R. L. Watts. 1996. A market-based evaluation of discretionary accrual models. Journal of Accounting Research 34 (3):83-105. Hail, L., and C. Leuz. 2006. International differences in the cost of equity capital: do legal institutions and securities regulation matter? Journal of Accounting Research 44 (3):485-531. Harris, R. S., and F. C. Marston. 1992. Estimating shareholder risk premia using analysts' growth forecasts. Financial Management (Summer):63-70. Hausman, J. A. 1978. Specification tests in econometrics. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society:1251-1271. Helfat, C. E., and M. A. Peteraf. 2003. The dynamic resource-based view: capability lifecycles. Strategic Management Journal 24 (10):997-1010. Hellmann, T. 2002. A theory of strategic venture investing. Journal of Financial Economics 64 (2):285-314. Hou, K., M. A. van Dijk, and Y. Zhang. 2012. The implied cost of capital: A new approach. Journal of Accounting & Economics 53 (3):504-526. Kazanjian, R. K. 1988. Relation of dominant problems to stages growth in technology-based new ventures. Academy of Management Journal 31 (2):257-279. Kazanjian, R. K., and R. Drazin. 1990. A stage-contingent model of design and growth for technology based new ventures. Journal of Business Venturing 5 (3):137-150. Khurana, I. K., and K. Raman. 2004. Litigation risk and the financial reporting credibility of Big 4 versus non-Big 4 audits: Evidence from Anglo-American countries. The Accounting Review 79 (2):473-495. Koberg, C. S., N. Uhlenbruck, and Y. Sarason. 1996. Facilitators of organizational innovation: The role of life-cycle stage. Journal of Business Venturing 11 (2):133-149. Kothari, S. P., A. J. Leone, and C. E. Wasley. 2005. Performance matched discretionary accrual measures. Journal of Accounting and Economics 39 (1):163-197. Larcker, D. F., and T. O. Rusticus. 2010. On the use of instrumental variables in accounting research. Journal of Accounting and Economics 49 (3):186-205. Lehavy, R., F. Li, and K. Merkley. 2011. The effect of annual report readability on analyst following and the properties of their earnings forecasts. The Accounting Review 86 (3):1087-1115. Lintner, J. 1965. The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets. The Review of Economics and Statistics 47 (1):13-37. Lumpkin, G. T., and G. G. Dess. 2001. Linking two dimensions of entrepreneurial orientation to firm performance: The moderating role of environment and industry life cycle. Journal of Business Venturing 16 (5):429-451. Miller, D., and P. H. Friesen. 1980. Momentum and revolution in organizational adaptation. Academy of Management Journal 23 (4):591-614. ———. 1984. A longitudinal study of the corporate life cycle. Management Science 30 (10):11611183. Modigliani, F., and M. H. Miller. 1958. The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. The American Economic Review 48 (3):261-297. Monkhouse, P. H. 1993. The cost of equity under the Australian dividend imputation tax system. Accounting & Finance 33 (2):1-18. Mossin, J. 1966. Equilibrium in a capital asset market. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 34 (4):768-783. Myers, S. C., and N. S. Majluf. 1984. Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics 13 (2):187-221. 49 Nickel, M. N., and M. C. Rodriguez. 2002. A review of research on the negative accounting relationship between risk and return: Bowman's paradox. Omega 30 (1):1-18. O'Hara, M. 2003. Presidential address: Liquidity and price discovery. Journal of Finance 58 (4):13351354. Ohlson, J. A. 1995. Earnings, Book Values, and Dividends in Equity Valuation. Contemporary Accounting Research 11 (2):661-687. Ohlson, J. A., and B. E. Juettner-Nauroth. 2005. Expected EPS and EPS growth as determinants of value. Review of Accounting Studies 10 (2):349-365. Owen, S., and A. Yawson. 2010. Corporate life cycle and M&A activity. Journal of Banking & Finance 34 (2):427-440. Pástor, Ľ., and V. Pietro. 2003. Stock valuation and learning about profitability. The Journal of Finance 58 (5):1749-1790. Pástor, Ľ., M. Sinha, and B. Swaminathan. 2008. Estimating the intertemporal risk–return tradeoff using the implied cost of capital. The Journal of Finance 63 (6):2859-2897. Penrose, E. T. 1959. The Theory of the Growth of the Firm: Wiley, New York. Petersen, M. A., and R. G. Rajan. 1994. The effect of credit market competition on lending relationships: National Bureau of Economic Research. Quinn, R. E., and K. Cameron. 1983. Organizational life cycles and shifting criteria of effectiveness: Some preliminary evidence. Management Science 29 (1):33-51. Rappaport, A. 1981. Selecting strategies that create shareholder value. Harvard Business Review 59 (3):139-149. Richardson, P. R., and J. R. Gordon. 1980. Measuring total manufacturing performance. Sloan Management Review 21 (2):47-58. Richardson, S. 2006. Over-investment of free cash flow. Review of Accounting Studies 11 (2/3):159189. Rumelt, R. P. 1984. Towards a strategic theory of the firm. In Competitive Strategic Management, edited by B. Lamb: Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, 556-570. Sharpe, W. F. 1964. Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. The Journal of Finance 19 (3):425-442. Smith, C. W., and R. L. Watts. 1992. The investment opportunity set and corporate financing, dividend, and compensation policies. Journal of Financial Economics 32 (3):263-292. Smith, K. G., T. R. Mitchell, and C. E. Summer. 1985. Top level management priorities in different stages of the organizational life cycle. Academy of Management Journal 28 (4):799-820. Solomon, G., L. W. Fernald, and W. Dennis. 2003. Self-identified management deficiencies of entrepreneurs. Journal of Private Equity 7 (1):26-35. Stock, J. H., and M. Yogo. 2002. Testing for weak instruments in linear IV regression: National Bureau of Economic Research Cambridge, Mass., USA. Subramanyam, K. 1996. The pricing of discretionary accruals. Journal of Accounting and Economics 22 (1):249-281. Truong, G., and G. Partington. 2007. Alternative Estimates of the Cost of Equity Capital for Australian Firms. Working Paper, available at http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1009125 Van De Ven, A. H., and M. S. Poole. 1995. Explaining development and change in organizations. Academy of Management Review 20 (3):510-540. Wernerfelt, B. 1984. A resource-based view of the firm. Strategic Management Journal 5 (2):171180. Witmer, J., and L. Zorn. 2007. Estimating the cost of equity for Canadian and U.S. firms. Bank of Canada Review:27-35. 50