Paper to be presented at the DRUID Summer Conference on "Industrial Dynamics of the New and Old Economy - who is embracing whom?" Copenhagen/Elsinore 6-8 June 2002 Theme A Technical Change, Corporate Dynamics and Innovation INDUSTRY DYNAMICS AND TYPES OF MARKET CONVERGENCE THE EVOLUTION OF THE HANDHELD COMPUTERS MARKET IN THE 1990s AND BEYOND First Draft Nils Stieglitz Philipps University Marburg Universitaetsstr. 24 35032 Marburg (Germany) tel +49 (0)6421 282-6592 fax + 49 (0)6421 282-6595 stieglitz@wiwi.uni-marburg.de May 9, 2002 Abstract: One recurrent theme in the discussion about the features of the ‘new economy’ is the claim that due to an increased rate of technological change and widespread deregulation, markets like telecommunications, computers, and entertainment are converging. After clarifying what is meant by market convergence, four different broad patterns of market convergence and their impact on industry dynamics are analyzed. The developed framework is then used to discuss market evolution and firm behaviour in the market for handheld computers. Keywords: Technological convergence, corporate strategy, handheld computer industry JEL codes: L1, L63 1. Introduction One recurrent theme in the discussion about the salient features of the ‘new economy’ is the claim that due to an increased rate of technological change and widespread deregulation, markets like telecommunications, computing, and entertainment are converging and will one day evolve into a huge multimedia industry (e.g. Collis/Bane/Bradley, Economist 2000). What is surprising is that the notion of convergence is often used in this context, but seldom clearly defined, making its meaning quite vague (Katz 1996). For example, Choi/Valikangas (2001, 426, their emphasis) recently defined convergence indiscriminately as the blurring of “boundaries between industries by converging value propositions, technologies, and markets.” As a result, market convergence often means different things to different authors. The idea that markets converge goes back to Rosenberg (1976) and his study of the emergence and evolution of the US machine tool industry. In the early 1800s, machines were constructed in-house to the specific production needs of their end users. The degree of vertical integration was therefore very high. A separate, specialized machine tool industry only began to emerge in the mid-1800s. According to Rosenberg (1976), the main reason for this process of vertical disintegration was the application of similar mechanical skills like drilling, grinding, polishing, etc. to diverse final products. Rosenberg (1976) termed this process technological convergence, since different industries increasingly relied on the same set of mechanical skills. Industries which were apparently unrelated from the point of view of nature and uses of the final product were very closely related on a technological basis. Examples for these technologically convergent industries in 1800s are firearms, sewing machines, and bicycles. In evolutionary economics, Sahal (1985) and Dosi (1988) have developed similar conceptions of technological convergence. They argue that certain technological paradigms spread their effects over a range of industries and induce innovative activities in once stagnant markets. An example is digital electronics and its impact on both the computer and telecommunications industries (Hagedoorn/Duysters 1998, Rao 1999). From this perspective, an important consequence of technological convergence is the broadening of the technological base of large established firms (e.g. Cantwell/Fai 1999, Fai/Tunzelmann 2001). In order to be able to adapt to technological change, large firms have to digest technological knowledge increasingly developed in other industries but which has an impact on their businesses. Furthermore, firms could use their broader technological base as a springboard for entering new technologically convergent markets (Teece/Rumelt/Dosi/Winter 1994). Since 2 technological competencies can be utilized in more than one industry, diversified firms possibly have competitive advantages over their more focused competitors. Not surprisingly, this idea figures prominently in the management literature on corporate strategy and market convergence. Important early authors are Porter (1985) and Hamel/Prahalad (1994), who argued independently that technological innovations and political deregulation of product markets “blur” the boundaries of traditional industries. Technologies (Porter 1985) and core competencies (Hamel/Prahalad 1994) can be exploited in formerly different industries. At the same time, different existing products are becoming close substitutes, since their functions are increasingly unified and bundled in innovative products (Katz 1996, Yoffie 1997, Collis/Bane/Bradley 1997). Thus, from this point of view, industry convergence not only implies the convergence of technologies but of products at the same time. Furthermore, industry convergence can also lead to a convergence in complements. In this case, previously unrelated products became complementary and tend to be used together (Greenstein/Khanna 1997). The strategic response to this “new competitive landscape” (Bettis/Hitt 1995) is an increased reliance on corporate networks and strategic alliances (Gomes-Casseres 1996), and the migration and diversification of firms into new markets (Reve 1990, Wirtz 2001). Despite this common interest in the convergence of industries and technology, there has been very little cross-fertilization between evolutionary economics and the strategic management literature. The diversity of definitions and meanings of what market convergence really means certainly does not help. Recently, Malerba (2002, 259) concluded his discussion of sectoral systems of innovation by pointing out that “even more work is necessary when the transformation of sectors involves not just traditionally defined sectors […], but the emergence of new clusters that span over several sectors, such as Internet-software-telecom, biotechnologypharmaceutical and new materials. Here, the analysis of sectoral systems has to consider the integration and fusion of previously separated knowledge and technologies and the new relations and overall dynamics among different types of users and consumers, firms with different specialization and competencies, and non-firms organizations and institutions and institutions grounded in previously separated sectors” The present paper contributes to these questions, in particular to the question of how market convergence affects firm behaviour, innovative activity, and industry evolution. If market convergence is to be more than a popular buzzword, the concept of market 3 convergence needs more analytical clarity. Consequently, in the first section, four generic types of market convergence are defined and related to the existing body of literature. Building on evolutionary economics and industry life cycle theories, these four types of convergence and their impact on market structure and firm behavior are discussed in the second section of the paper. Specifically, it is asked what kind of effect these types have on a) market entry, b) corporate strategy, and c) corporate alliances. In the third section, the developed theoretical framework is applied to the analysis of the market for Personal Digital Assistants (PDAs) and handheld computers in the 1990s and beyond. Three stages of industry evolution are identified. In the formative stages in the early 1990s, industry evolution was driven by complementary technological convergence. Following this convergence, the industry entered a growth stage (mid-1990s to the end of the 1990s), which was characterised by incremental innovative activities and rapid growth. Since the early 2000s, changes in the competitive landscape of the industry are increasingly shaped by a convergence of different products. Consequently, to fully appreciate the evolution of this particular industry, it is necessary to take account of these different kinds of convergence. A fourth section concludes. 2. Convergence Defined If one is interested in a definition of market convergence, it is useful to reflect about what is actually meant when talking about industries and, especially, markets. From an economic viewpoint, a market is a locus of exchange. In order to understand the formation of prices in a particular market, the relevant suppliers and demanders have to be identified (Stigler/Sherwin 1985). This delineation of market boundaries is an important topic in industrial economics, antitrust policy, and strategic management (Geroski 1998, Pleatsikas/Teece 2001). Traditionally, markets are defined by the substitutability of the traded products (Robinson 1969). In an influential book, Abbott (1955) argued that products should be treated as substitutes if they satisfy the same want. In this vain, the demand theory developed by Lancaster (1966) perceives a product as a bundle of multiple product characteristics. Consumers do not derive their utility from the product as such but from the embodied mixture of product characteristics. Substitutes are products that share common characteristics, even if the exact mixture or specification of the characteristics varies. Consequently, the boundary or width of a market (Lancaster 1979) is determined by grouping products with similar characteristics. Moreover, to derive or increase the utility of certain products it is required to jointly use other products, e.g. video recorder and video cassette. 4 Products can not only be substitutes, but complements as well. Market definition has to take this into account. Besides this demand side approach to market definition, there is also a small but growing stream of literature which tries to tackle the problem from the supply side. An early attempt is Narver (1967). Building on Penrose (1959), he defined a market as a “supply space” spanning firms with the similar resources and technologies. Integrating supply and demand factors, Abell (1980) included the production technology in his conceptualisation of market delineation. From a resource based view of the firm, Bettis (1998) claims that firms compete against other firms that have similar resources, not just against firms producing current product substitutes. Consequently, markets or industries should be defined by groups of firms with similar resource bases. It is therefore possible to define a market from the supply and from the demand side. Dictionaries define convergence as the movement towards the same point or the meeting of two elements. Applied to our discussion, this means that at least two existing markets have to be effected by market convergence. Since markets can be defined by demand or by supply factors, we can distinguish supply sided technological convergence from product convergence on the demand side. Technological convergent markets produce different goods and services with similar sets of technological capabilities. Convergent markets on the product level, on the other hand, offer substantial substitute or complementary product characteristics, but employ different technologies. Thus, markets can also converge either as substitutes or as complements. Technologies can be substitutes and complements, too. In the former case, an existing technology is replaced with another, while in the later case two formerly unrelated technologies are used together. To sum up, we can distinguish four generic types of market convergence (Figure 1). 5 Figure 1: Four generic types of market convergence.1 Note that market convergence, whether technological or product convergence, is an inherently dynamic process with three distinct stages. In the first stage, two existing markets are unrelated from the supply and demand side. The process of convergence is then triggered by an outside event, for example the invention of new technologies or political deregulation. In the second stage, markets converge, implying on-going changes in market structures and firm behaviour. Finally, in the third stage, the markets are related from a technological or product market perspective, and market structures stabilize. To characterize each generic type of market convergence in more detail, we employ a framework advanced by Saviotti/Metcalfe (1984) and Saviotti (1996). They have developed an approach which integrates the supply and demand characteristics of products and markets in a common conceptual framework.2 A particular product can be represented by its technology and product characteristics respectively (Figure 2). 1 For a similar representation, see Pennings/Puranam (2001). However, their treatment differs from our discussion on a conceptual level. In contrast to our approach, Pennings/Puranam (2001) treat consumer preferences as endogenous, and interpret complementary product offerings solely as the bundling of products. Likewise, in their framework technological innovations only have an impact on the supply side, while deregulation and societal changes lead demand side convergence. 2 See also Gallouj/Weinstein (1997) for an extension of the concept to service industries. 6 Figure 2: Technology and product characteristics (Source: adapted from Saviotti 1996) On a basic level, the technological capabilities X1, X2,…, XN contain the knowledge required to transform inputs and labour into a final product. This product exhibits a mixture of certain characteristics C1, C2,…, CN which are used by the buyers to satisfy basic wants. As a result, the product characteristics offered by a firm depends crucially on its technological capabilities. From this starting point, it is now possible to define different types of convergence, since the interrelationship between technology and product characteristics can be made explicit. 2.1 Technological Convergence In the case of technological convergence, unrelated product markets become related from a technological point of view, because they begin to share the same technological capabilities. As already mentioned, two principal causes for technological convergence can be distinguished: technological substitutes and technological complements. 2.1.1 Type I: Technological substitutes In this case, two markets exist which use different technological capabilities to produce different products A and B. These products do not share any product characteristics (Figure 3a). A process of technological convergence is now triggered by the invention of a technology XZ. This technology can be applied both in the production of product A and B, and it is thus a technological substitute for older technologies in these markets. Consequently, this process of technological convergence is characterized by the development and diffusion of the new production technology and the parallel learning processes of the technological users. Eventually, the older technologies XM and XM+1 will be replaced, and the former unrelated markets become related from a technological point of view. In a pure case, as 7 depicted in Figure 3a, XZ is a process innovation only. The main effect is to lower the production costs of the two products. The product characteristics are not affected. Empirically more relevant is the case in which process innovations induce changes in quality of products. In many cases, process innovations not only make the production of existing goods cheaper, but transform the trade offs associated in the bundling of product characteristics, too (Rosenberg 1982). Process and product innovations are then interdependent. Additionally, the new technology may also lead to changes in other technologies. Thus, the initial invention, development, and diffusion of XZ leads to a complex innovation process, in which the technological capabilities and products in the two markets are constantly modified and improved. In this case, the technological convergence is characterised by changes in the established market structures, since the process is now also driven by product innovations. Figure 3: Types of technological convergence This generic type of market convergence is identical to Rosenberg’s (1976) classic treatment of technological convergence. As described above, industries like firearms (“A”) and sewing machines (“B”) became technologically convergent, since broad mechanical capabilities like precision grinding (“XZ”) replaced older, more specialized technologies (“XM”, “XM+1”) in those markets. This kind of technological convergence also lies at the heart of the discussion surrounding the “new economy”. The productivity gains of the US economy in 1990s are often tied to the diffusion of digital technologies in different industries, like consumer electronics, financial services, telecommunications, and many more (Jorgensen/Stiroh 2000). Accordingly, these technologies have been termed “general purpose technologies” (Bresnahan/Traitenberg 1995, Helpman 1998, David/Wright 1999). Other historical examples of general purpose technologies include the steam engine, rail transport, 8 and electric power. General purpose technologies share the following characteristics (Lipsey/Bekar/Carlaw 1998). They are (1) applicable across a broad range of uses, (2) offer a potential for use in a wide variety of product and processes, (3) offer a wide scope for improvement and elaboration, (4) and exhibit strong complementarities with existing and potential new technologies. The former points highlight the technological convergence of markets, as defined above, while the later two underscore the importance of subsequent innovations in products and other existing technologies which can be induced by the new general purpose technology. 2.1.2 Type II: Technological complements A different type of technological convergence, on the other hand, involves existing technologies that are combined to develop entirely new products (Figure 3b). In other words, existing technologies are fused together to create new technologies and products (Kodama 1992). In this case, two markets exist which produce two separate products A and B with different technological capabilities. A process of technological convergence is triggered by the creation of new technology XZ that opens up the possibility to combine the existing technologies XM and XM+1 to produce the new product C. Alternatively, the combination could also be induced by regulatory changes. In this case, it has been technically possible to combine the technologies, but it was not attempted due to government regulations. This type of technological convergence is influenced by two learning processes. First, since the product C is an entirely new product, an entrepreneurial process of trial and error drives the technological convergence, since firms and buyers have to find out which basic product characteristics constitute the product and how value is derived from it (Utterback 1993, Adner/Levinthal 2000). Second, the existing technological capabilities have to be amended and developed in order to be able to modify and enhance the quality of the new product. This process of technological learning is a significant force if technological convergence is triggered by an entirely new technology XZ. Furthermore, there can be important spill-over effects into the existing markets as well (Markides/Williamson 1995, Fai 2001). An example of this complementary technological convergence is the emergence of the market for handheld computers in the early 1990s. Partly triggered by new advances in handwriting recognition technology (“XZ”), companies from different industries like 9 telecommunications, computers, and consumer electronics combined different technologies (“XM”, “XM+1”) to offer the first handheld computers (“C”).3 2.2 Product convergence In the case of product convergence, established markets become related from a demand point of view. They begin to share similar or complementary product characteristics, leading to a convergence in substitutes or complements. 2.2.1 Type III: Product convergence in substitutes A product convergence in substitutes leads to a greater substitutability of formerly unrelated products as they increasingly share the same characteristics. As sketched out in Figure 4a, a product “B” is changed to also include the new feature CM, making it a (partial) substitute of product A. Once again, this generic type of market convergence is often sparked by a new technological capability (“XZ”) which enables the changes in product characteristics. Another possible cause is the deregulation of these markets, making it possible to integrate a wider range of characteristics into the final product. Independent of what causes the process, the speed and the pattern of market convergence critically depends on the substitutability of the products. Products are closer substitutes the more product characteristics they share. Since the potential array of product characteristics depends on the underlying technological capabilities, the convergence in products could also lead to changes in technological bases of the involved firms. Similar product characteristics are frequently based on similar technologies, and we hypothesise that a product convergence of substitutes is often followed and paralleled by technological convergence. In this case, increasing competition between the two markets forces firms to expand the product characteristics by incorporating features of the other market’s product. Correspondingly, besides having to assimilate the new technology XZ, firms of both markets also have to adopt existing technological capabilities of the other market. In an extreme case, both markets merge into one larger market with very similar technologies and product characteristics. 3 On a more aggregate level, Andersen (1998) finds in her analysis of the long term evolution of technological trajectories from 1890 to 1990 that recent technological progress has been shaped by the combination of diverse technologies into more integrated technological systems. Thus, it appears that the long term trend is fundamentally shaped by this type of technological convergence. 10 Figure 4: Types of Product Convergence Examples for this type of market convergence are manifold. For years, the discussion about a multimedia industry has centered around digital broadband TV, and it has been predicted that PCs and TVs will one day evolve into close substitutes (Baldwin/McVoy/Steinfield 1996). Broadband TV allows to access a wide range of services, like Video/Music-on-Demand, games, electronic shopping, etc. In the past, most of these services could only be accessed via PCs, and there was no substitutability between TVs and PCs. According to industry commentators, this might change with the advent of broadband technology. Thus, the new broadband (“XZ”) technology has the potential to integrate certain product features into a TV set like Internet access, electronic shopping, and Music-onDemand, which were formerly only accessible via a PC (“CM”). 2.2.2 Type IV: Product convergence in complements Finally, in the case of a convergence in product complements, existing unrelated products become complementary to one another. In the past, both products have been used independently, and there was no connection between them from a demand perspective. Once again, this process of market convergence is caused by a new technology which opens up the potential to jointly use the two existing products (Figure 4b). In other words, the products are now complementary to each other, delivering a higher value if consumed together. Unlike the case of product convergence in substitutes, convergence in complements does not lead to technological convergence. While a prerequisite for their joint use, the new technology XZ is not needed to produce the existing products A or B individually. Its task is to provide the “glue” for the two existing products. What is needed, however, is some kind of standard that warrants the complementary use of the products. Consequently, product 11 convergence in complements is also being shaped how and what kind of standards are being set and modified. An example of this type of product convergence is the development of the computer language HTML and the introduction of graphical browser programs. These new technologies (“XZ”) allowed private households to easily access Internet services via their PCs (“A”) and existing telephone lines (“B”). Formerly, phones and PCs were two distinct products which served different needs, e.g. “data processing” and “communications”. It was only after the advent of the Internet that computers and telephone lines were perceived as complementary products by private consumers. The defined four cases of market convergence are fairly generic, and they represent abstract “ideal types” in the sense of Max Weber (1988). Empirically, processes of market convergence are paralleled by other innovation activities which have nothing to do with convergence. In addition, different types of market convergence may be present at the same time. For instance, as already discussed, product convergence in substitutes often brings about a process of technological convergence. But the four generic types nevertheless allow the identification and disentanglement of different drivers of change in convergent markets. Furthermore, they provide a basic framework to structure and to explain broad patterns of market convergence. The next section discusses these patterns in greater detail. 3. Industry Dynamics and Types of Convergence 3.1 Systems of Innovation and Firm Behaviour - A Conceptual Framework In recent years, several authors have developed the related concepts of technological regimes and of sectoral systems of innovation to organize different determinants of industrial dynamics (e.g. Nelson/Winter 1982, Dosi/Malerba/Orsenigo 1994, Dosi 1997, Marsili 2001). Malerba (2002, 250) defines a sectoral system of innovation and production as „a set of new and established products for specific uses and the set of agents carrying out market and non-market interactions for the creation, production and sale of those products.” A sectoral system is shaped by four main factors, namely (1) technological opportunities, (2) cumulativeness of knowledge, (3) sources and accessibility of knowledge, 12 and (4) appropriability of innovative rents, and we discuss each in turn (Malerba/Orsenigo 2000, Marsili 2001, Malerba 2002): (1) Technological opportunities shape the incentive to invest into R&D. High technological opportunities are present if new technological knowledge is applicable to a wide variety of products or leads to large increases in the performance or quality of a product. Sectors with high technological opportunities are characterized by higher investments into R&D and a higher rate of innovations. (2) The condition of cumulativeness of knowledge captures an important property of evolutionary theories of economic change and its underlying theory of the firm (Nelson 1995). The knowledge base of a firm is the outcome of firm-specific and path-dependent learning processes (Rosenberg 1976). Therefore, the knowledge base constrains the strategic behaviour of firms, and it is an important source for first mover advantages and performance differences between firms (Teece/Pisano/Shuen 1997). Because of differences in their knowledge bases, firms differ in their ability to exploit the technological opportunities (Nelson 1991). The cumulativeness of knowledge is high, and learning is more rapid, if new knowledge builds incrementally on the existing body of a firm’s knowledge. Cumulativeness is low, on the other hand, if firms have to learn entirely new pieces of knowledge. To add analytical clarity, the knowledge base of the firm can be separated into two broad domains (Teece/Rumelt/Dosi/Winter 1994, Granstrand 1998). The first domain includes the knowledge about the underlying technologies. These represent the technological capabilities of the firm. A different knowledge domain consists of the specific knowledge about the market and its products, its users, competitors, and applications. These are the marketing capabilities of the firm. Teece (1986) considers these capabilities as complementary to the technological capabilities since they enhance the value of an innovation. (3) Besides cumulativeness, the sources and accessibility of knowledge are a second important determinant of how easy it is to gain access to technological opportunities. Sources of knowledge can be, for example, external sources like universities (Rosenberg 1982), internal sources like users, suppliers, competitors, but also external firms active in other sectors (Hippel 1988). The accessibility of knowledge depends on the codification of knowledge, and the associated spill over effects. Important mechanisms for gaining access to tacit knowledge are strategic alliances and other inter-organizational arrangements. Furthermore, existing technological capabilities can also be accessed if they are embodied in off-the shelf products (Demsetz 1991). 13 (4) The appropriability conditions influence how difficult it is for an innovator to capture the innovation’s profit. Appropriability is influenced, among other things, by the level of competition and the accessibility of knowledge. Low appropriability conditions are present if new knowledge is easily accessible by competitors, or the level of competition is high. If the potential appropriability is high, technological opportunities are rapidly exploited, leading to an upsurge in innovative activity. These factors describe the important determinants of innovations and industry structure. The industry life cycle theories offer a dynamic conceptualisation of these four conditions, highlighting their evolution over time (Klepper 1997). These theories are therefore an important backdrop for our discussion. But to capture how firm behaviour is influenced by market convergence, additional dimensions are needed. A first question concerns the corporate strategy of the established firms that are involved in the process of market convergence. Broadly, they either have the option to focus their business activities or to diversify into new markets. Taking up the above distinction between domains of technological and marketing capabilities, it is possible to distinguish between technological and product market diversification (e.g. Gambardella/Torrisi 1998, Granstrand 1998, Piscitello 1998). Consequently, we can discern four different strategic options on the corporate level (Figure 5). Besides the behaviour of incumbent firms, it is also possible to discuss the role of new entrants. These are firms that have previously not been active in the converging industries. The threat of entry is especially high if, due to a low cumulativeness of technological knowledge and easy accessibility of complementary capabilities, the technological and market barriers to entry are low. In this case, new entrants are formidable competitors and an important source of innovations. Figure 5: Options of corporate strategy 14 Finally, a key aspect of firm behaviour associated with market convergence is the formation of interorganizational arrangements. It is often claimed that market convergence leads to an upsurge in the number of strategic alliances and corporate networks (Harianto/Pennings 1996, Duysters/Hagedoorn 1998, Santangelo 2000, Dittrich 2001). To broadly describe the rationale for the formation of an alliance, we distinguish the direction and the motivation of an alliance. Firms can form alliances vertically with suppliers and users, or horizontally with competitors or firms in other markets. The motivation for an alliance is either the creation of new capabilities or the joint use of existing capabilities (March 1991, Mowery/Oxley/Silverman 1996, 1998). 3.2 Technological Convergence 3.2.1 Type I: Technological substitutes If market convergence is characterized by a convergence in technological substitutes, then technological opportunities are usually high. The reasons for this are two-fold. First, the new technology can be exploited in many industries. Consequently, the basic innovation leads to a variety of process innovations in different markets. The second reason is the effect on the rate of product innovations in the established markets. Often, new processes will not only bring about reductions in production costs but increase the likelihood for product improvements as well. This critical link between process and product innovation is stressed in the current debate about general purpose technologies, and it was already discussed in Rosenberg’s (1976) classical study of the machine tool industry. A consequence for the established market is an upsurge in competition, since the new technology raises the likelihood of cost cuts and product innovations. Technological convergence is often triggered by new technologies that solve older problems; the cumulativeness of technological knowledge is as a result usually low. Like the term “substitutes” suggests, older technological capabilities in the existing markets are superseded by the new technology. In terms of Tushmann/Anderson (1986), technological substitutes are competence-destroying. As a reaction, incumbent firms in the existing markets have to update their technological knowledge base. Furthermore, the cumulativeness of marketing knowledge associated with the new technology is low, because potential users of the technology are the established firms in the existing markets. On the other hand, changes in the knowledge about consumers, applications, and competitors in the existing markets are cumulative. The complementary downstream capabilities of the firm are thus largely unaffected by this type of market convergence. 15 High technological opportunities and a low cumulativeness of technological knowledge imply a high rate of entry upstream of the existing markets. The entry into upstream markets is fostered by the low cumulativeness of marketing knowledge. The high rate of entry into upstream activities eventually leads to a creation of a specialized supplier industry that serves the existing markets. This process of market entry and of vertical disintegration is, for example, described by Rao (1999), Fransman (2000), and Gaffard/Krafft (2000) for the telecommunication industry. However, entry into the existing product markets is made more costly and more risky by the downstream capabilities of the incumbent firms. The process of market convergence also has an effect on the corporate strategy of the existing and the new firms. For existing firms, a major challenge is to adapt their knowledge bases to the new technology. They are thus forced to diversify their technological knowledge base to keep up with the process of technological substitution. Many established firms consequently react by pursuing a multitechnology strategy. While broadening their technological capabilities, they focus their product market activities on established markets (Gambardella/Torrisi 1998, Fai/Tunzelmann 2001). In contrast, a diversification strategy is much more risky, even if new technological capabilities can be exploited in many markets. The firms must not only learn and develop the new technology, but they also have to build up the complementary marketing capabilities. Corporate strategies of new firms, on the other hand, differ. Entrants are likely to pursue a focus strategy, concentrating on the development of a specific application of the new technology for a distinct group of users. They are thus specialized suppliers (Pavitt 1984). Successful suppliers are able to pursue a multimarket strategy, exploiting their technological capabilities in a range of existing downstream markets. An important mechanism to gain access to and to develop the new technology is the formation of strategic alliances. They are especially vital if innovations in the new technology persist, and the new knowledge is not readily accessible through off-the-shelf products. In this case, established firms and suppliers form vertical alliances to create new technological knowledge. An important outcome is the broadening of the established firm’s technological knowledge base, and vertical alliances are for that reason an essential stepping stone of a multitechnology strategy. 3.2.2 Type II: Technological Complements In contrast to the case of convergence in technological substitutes, the technological opportunities of technological complements are more limited. The driving force is the fusion of existing technologies into novel products, and technological changes are usually confined 16 to the new emerging market. Only if significant new technologies are developed for the new markets, and these spill over into the existing markets, technological opportunities are higher. This process of market convergence builds on existing technological capabilities, and the cumulativeness of technological knowledge is high. The same does not apply to demand and marketing capabilities. The new market implies new consumers, new applications, and new competitors (Adner/Levinthal 2000). In other words, firms have to explore by trial and error how potential consumers derive value from the product characteristics and which mixture and interactions of characteristics constitute a dominant design (Christensen/Suárez/Utterback 1998). Because of this fundamental learning process, the cumulativeness of marketing knowledge is low. Since established firms already have parts of the technological capabilities needed to enter the emerging markets, they pursue a diversification strategy. The main entrants into the emerging markets are consequently the established firms from existing markets. In contrast, the entry of entirely new firms is low, because they lack the technological capabilities. Only if these are accessible easily, for example through off-the-shelves products, then there is a higher rate of entry. In this case, the low cumulativeness of marketing knowledge and the learning process associated with the emergence of a dominant design opens a window of opportunity for entrants. In this case, the technological capabilities of incumbent firms are not an important first mover advantage anymore. Even more so, the incumbent’s early designs are often framed by past experiences in the established markets, and this can hamper the trial and error process. In other words, the local search processes in the new markets are still constrained by the marketing capabilities that applied to the old market. In the new market, these capabilities can be more a liability than an asset. A crucial problem for established firms and entrants is that they only command parts of the necessary technological capabilities, because the new product is the outcome of the fusion of existing technologies previously employed in different markets. Firms have to access the complementary technologies if they want to enter the market. A main mechanism for gaining access to these complementary technological capabilities is through horizontal alliances with established firms from other markets. Since alliances are formed to access existing technologies, their impetus is the joint use of existing knowledge. Alternatively, firms can also merge or acquire firms to integrate the complementary technologies. 17 3.3 Product Convergence 3.3.1 Type III: Convergence in Substitutes The technological opportunities in the convergence of product substitutes are low, since the effects of a new technology are closely confined to the existing markets. New technologies enable innovative changes in the characteristics of existing products. While competitive pressures mount for the reason that these products evolve into substitutes, the knowledge bases of the existing firms nonetheless allow the absorption of new technological knowledge. The cumulativeness of technological knowledge is usually high, and the same is true for the marketing capabilities of the established firms in the two existing markets, because the existing products, applications, and dominant designs are the starting points for product innovations. High uncertainty, however, exists about the new competitors and new groups of customers, since the boundaries of the markets are “blurring” in the wake of new product features (Greenstein/Khanna 1997). The rate of entry by new entrants is low, because the incumbent firms can apply their existing knowledge bases to cope with market convergence. They have all the capabilities to successfully deal with the threat of entry, and the process of convergence is thus more driven by their competitive actions than by the entry of innovative entrants. The incumbent’s strategies are either focus or diversification. In the former case, firms concentrate on serving a niche market. The creation of new knowledge is closely restricted to their existing technological and marketing knowledge, and they passively adapt to the convergence process. A more active role is played by the diversifiers. These firms’ competitive strategies are the fundamental driver of this type of market convergence. They are vigorously seeking to expand product characteristics and to extend their market reach beyond their traditional industry boundaries. In view of the fact that product convergence in substitutes often requires the adoption of the other market’s technological capabilities, horizontal strategic alliances are an important method to access these capabilities and jointly use the existing knowledge. Also, the magnitude of mergers and acquisitions is increased, since diversifiers can rapidly expand their technological base and market reach by acquiring other established firms in the “other” market. 18 3.3.2 Type IV: Convergence in Complements The technological opportunities of a convergence in complements are generally high. Like in the case of technological substitutes, the reasons are, first, the innovation avenues opened by the new technology itself, and second, the potential changes in the product characteristics in the existing markets. An illustrative example is the convergence in complements of telecommunications and personal computers through Internet technologies. Here, the complementarity of PCs and telecommunications was not only made possible by new hard- and software, but tempted alterations in the characteristics of PCs (their hardware and especially software) and of telecommunication services (Baldwin/McVoy/Steinfield 1996, Collis/Bane/Bradley 1997). Since entirely new technologies often initiate the process of convergence in complements, the cumulativeness of technological knowledge is low. In contrast, the cumulativeness of marketing knowledge is often high, since customers and new applications are tied to the existing products. Still, incumbent firms are often slow to respond to the new technological opportunities. This opens up the possibility of entry for new entrants. As a result, the rate of entry by new firms is high. Entrants pursuit a focus strategy, concentrating on the development of the new technology and new complementary services. Once again, this can be illustrated by the advent of the Internet, and the subsequent emergence of an “Internet industry”. The same is true for incumbent firms, since the gains from diversification are limited. They can not exploit their technological base in the emerging new industry or in the other established industry. More common than outright diversification are horizontal alliances between incumbent firms and new entrants. These are often knowledge using, because the new entrants can profit from the marketing capabilities of the established firms, while incumbent gain access to the new technologies developed by the entrants. Incumbent and new firms have a mutual interest in an expanded market due to the new complementarity of products. A very important motive for the formation of knowledge using alliances in this type of market convergence is the setting of standards that govern the interfaces between the complements (Katz 1996,Yoffie 1997). 19 3.4 Patterns of Market Convergence The following table sums up the discussed broad patterns of market convergence. This theoretical framework is applied in the next section to the evolution of the Personal Digital Assistant and handheld computer market in the 1990s. Type of Market Technological Convergence substitutes Technological Product substitutes complements Product complements Pattern of…* Process Innovation Product Innovation Product Innovation Product Innovation High Low Low High - technology - Low - High - High - Low - demand - Low - Low - High - High Threat of New High Low Low High - Multitechnology - Diversification - Focus - Focus Dominant Type of Innovation Technological opportunities Cumulativeness Entrants Corporate Strategy (incumbent) (incumbent) - Diversification - Focus (entrants) - Focus (entrants) - direction - vertical - horizontal - horizontal - horizontal - motivation - knowledge creating - knowledge using - knowledge using - knowledge using Example Machine Tool industry Personal Digital PCs versus TVs Internet (PC, Online Alliances Assistants Services) Table 1 Patterns of Market Convergence *Accessibility and appropriability conditions are very important building blocks of sectoral systems of innovation, and they have a major impact on the process of market convergence. Nevertheless, these conditions are idiosyncratic, and a stable relationship between the generic types of convergence and these conditions does not exist. 20 4. Market Convergence and the Evolution of the Handheld Computer Industry A handheld computer or Personal Digital Assistant (PDA) is a compact, palm sized computing device. One of it’s defining product characteristics is the user’s ability to hold the device in one hand while entering data at the same time. Today, input devices are either small keyboards or stylus-based touch-screens with handwriting recognition. Other key product characteristics are mobility, an expandable set of programs and applications, and the ability to communicate with other devices like personal computers, fax machines, and cellular phones. A PDA’s hardware consists of a microprocessor, solid-state memory, a liquid crystal display (LCD), an input device, batteries, and various input/output ports and extension slots. The software consists of an operating system and applications which are often stored permanently in the Read-Only memory (ROM) or are available on cartridges and extension cards. In the following case study4, it is shown how the evolution of the handheld computer market was affected over time by three different types of market convergence. Actual market processes roughly correspond to the broad patterns identified in the theoretical section of the paper. 4.1 Technological complements and the search for a dominant design: 1984 to 1996 The early years of the handheld computer market were shaped by the fusion of complementary technologies which had their roots in different industries. For example, LCD displays and power management technologies emanated from the consumer electronics industry, operating systems, memory chips, and handwriting recognition technologies from computers, fax and paging technologies from telecommunications, and semiconductors from computers and consumer electronics (Figure 6). Early market dynamics was thus driven by a convergence in technological complements. 4 The data for the case study has been collected from public sources like press releases, business magazines, and industry publications. In addition, it builds and extends on earlier case studies of the PDA market (Bayus/Jain/Rao 1997, Yoffie et al. 1997, Gomes-Casseres/Leonard-Barton 1997, Wegberg 1998). A fully referenced version is available from the author upon request. 21 4.1.1 Early Experiments: 1984-1992 The first handheld computing device sharing some of the characteristics of a PDA was introduced by UK software company Psion in 1984 (Potter 1998).5 The Organiser was build around a 8-bit Hitachi microprocessor, a 16 character LCD display, a tiny keyboard, and an operating system developed by Psion. It featured a clock, simple calendar, math functions, and a database with a search function. With the optional Science Pack, the Organiser was capable of being programmed in its own simple computer language. The product was a modest success and until the early 1990s, Psion sold over 500,000 units of the Organiser and its successor, the Organiser 2. Figure 6 Convergence in complementary technologies in the handheld computer market The Organiser was basically a programmable calculator with a database and a simple calendar. Early imitators were suppliers which had been active before in the market for handheld calculators. In 1988, the Japanese consumer electronics companies Sharp and Casio entered the market with Organiser clones that later evolved into the Wizard and Boss electronic organizer series respectively. Both companies had commercialized early prototypes of handheld computers in the beginning of the 1980s. Sharp had pioneered the development of LCD displays in 1970s, and was the largest supplier of LCDs in the late 1980s. The Wizard electronic organizers were based on LCD displays and semiconductors originally developed for Sharp’s long-standing product line of calculators. The company could thus draw on its existing technological capabilities to develop the Wizard. Casio, as a diversified electronics company, was able to draw on its experiences in calculators, watches, and handheld LCD television receivers. Early imitators were also other Japanese and US consumer electronics companies like Seiko, Selectronics, Radio Shack, Rolodex, Royal, and Zenith. Despite the 5 A summary of major entries (and exits) into the handheld computer industry can be found in the appendix. 22 number of market entries, Sharp and Casio quickly gained nearly 90 percent of the market share for electronic organizers worldwide (1991), largely confining Psion’s customer base to Europe. Early electronic organizer models were stand-alone, non-programmable devices, with rudimentary organizing functions like agenda, contacts, alarm, and note taking. A 1991 product survey by Consumer Reports (1991) described them as a cross between a pocket calculator and a laptop computer. But the electronic organizers were not true computers, since they were not able to run any other programs and applications, and their build-in features were inspired by pen and paper organizers like Filofax. In 1989, two products were launched that promoted the concept of a “palmtop computer”. These palmtop computers were supposed to be more compact and mobile substitutes for laptop computers. The Portfolio was commercialized by hardware computer supplier Atari and introduced to the European market in 1988. The Portfolio had been designed and licensed to Atari by UK company Distributed Information Processing (DIP), a Psion spin-off. In 1988, the US company Poqet Computer Corporation was founded in the US by former Fairchild, Texas Instrument, and DIP employees. In 1989, Poqet introduced the powerful, but high-priced Poqet PC. The Portfolio and Poqet PC both were full-fledged MS-DOS compatible handheld computers built around an Intel-licensed 80C88 microprocessor using off-the-shelf products in a highly innovative way. Despite much praise from industry journals, especially for the Poqet, both products were only very modest commercial successes. An important introduction into the handheld computer market was the HP 95 LX that Hewlett-Packard shipped in 1991. In just 16 months, HP had developed a handheld computer which heavily built on its existing technological capabilities, especially in computing and the design of scientific calculators. Hewlett-Packard had pioneered the scientific handheld calculator in 1973 and had developed an early prototype of a handheld computer, the HP 75C, in 1982. The HP 95 LX was based on Intel’s 8086 microprocessor and ran the MS-DOS operating system. Besides rudimentary organizing functions, key features were a version of Lotus’ spreadsheet software and an optional connectivity pack designed by Traveling Software that linked the 95 LX to a desktop computer. The HP 95 LX was a modest commercial success, and in the next three years, over 390,000 units were sold. In Europe, Psion launched the Psion Series 3, a major revision of the Organiser, featuring organizing functions, computing capabilities, and Psion’s own proprietary OS. The Series 3 was designed with the help of, among others, microprocessor supplier NEC. In next year, Sharp introduced the PC 3000. It was the result of an alliance with DIP. Like DIP’s Portfolio design, the PC 23 3000 was based on a 80C88 microprocessor, and it ran DIP’s proprietary operating system and applications. Thus, in the early 1990s, two distinct segments in handheld computer industry existed. The larger sub-market for electronic organizers was dominated by consumer electronics companies Casio and Sharp, while in the smaller sub-market for palmtop computers HewlettPackard, Psion, and Poqet were the leading suppliers. The large technologically diversified companies Casio, Sharp, and Hewlett-Packard were able to draw on their technological inhouse capabilities to develop their handheld products, while entrants like Psion, DIP, and Poqet relied on off-the-shelf products and, increasingly, on knowledge-using alliances. Furthermore, while established firms choose to diversify, entrants focused their activities on the emerging market. Widespread adoption of handheld computers, however, failed to materialize. All these early models relied on tiny keyboards that made entering data a slow and cumbersome process. Industry observers argued that the user interface was the key problem of handheld computers, and a major obstacle to mass market acceptance. The technological problems surrounding the user interface were to act as a focusing device for further innovations in the market. Incidentally, pen-based computing with handwriting recognition was predicted to be a major new breakthrough technology for PC computers, and GriD, a Tandy division, had introduced one of the first pen-based computer, the GRiD Pad in 1988. In 1991, Canon, IBM, NCR, and Toshiba had announced plans to bring pen computers to market, and venture capitalists financed start-ups developing pen-based computing technologies like GO and Momenta. And following the path paved by Apple’s MacOS, software companies like Microsoft, GeoWorks and General Magic were developing graphical user interfaces (GUIs) that simplified user interaction. Thus, in the early 1990s, new technological opportunities were opened by these innovations. At the same time, new communication hardware like pagers and cellular phones were introduced, while older technologies like fax machines evolved into mass market products. New communication services like electronic messaging, and proprietary information networks like for example CompuServe and AOL were brought to market. Demand for these innovative communication products was steadily increasing. Additionally, the technological advances in consumer electronics and computing continued rapidly, allowing for the development and introduction of new technologies like CD-ROM and and DVD and the miniaturization of existing technologies and products. 24 Therefore, the stage was set for a range of product innovations in handheld computing, fueled by the advances in technologies as diverse as telecommunications, computers, and consumer electronics. In 1992, Apple, AT&T, and Tandy announced their entry into the handheld computer market. In his product announcement speech, Apple CEO John Sculley coined the name “Personal Digital Assistant” in early 1992. In next two years, established companies from different markets like Amstrad (consumer electronics), IBM (computer hardware), BellSouth (telecommunications services), Sony (consumer electronics), and Motorola (computers, telecommunications hardware and services) brought to market different PDA models. But by 1998, all these entrants had left the handheld computer market. 4.3.2 The Rise and Fall of the Personal Digital Assistants: 1992-1995 During the next years, incumbents Hewlett-Packard, Sharp, Casio, and Psion continued to extend their products, adding new technologies and features. In 1993 and 1994, seven major new handheld computers were brought to market by Amstrad, Apple, AT&T, Tandy, Motorola, Sony, and IBM. The new entrants heavily relied on strategic alliances to develop and market their products. Alliances were especially important if the product was based on new technologies (Gomes-Casseres/Leonard-Barton 1997). However, knowledge using alliances dominated because companies applied their existing technological capabilities to new products.6 Apple Newton Apple started to develop their first PDA, to be called the Newton, in early 1990. At the same time, Apple began to weave a dense network of alliances for the Newton, spanning computer hardware and software suppliers, consumer electronics, telecommunications, and media companies. The first Newtons were shipped in August 1993. Within the first month, 50,000 units were sold, but subsequent sales were much lower than expected. Apple pulled the plug on the Newton in 1998, having barely sold 120,000 units overall. Despite its technological and marketing capabilities in the Personal computer market, Apple had failed to turn the Newton into a successful mass market product. To develop the Newton, Apple acquired a capital stake in the UK semiconductor company Advanced RISC Machines (ARM) which was developing the low power consumption ARM610 microprocessor chip that was later used in the Newton. An integral part of the Newton was the pen-based user interface which was able to interpret cursive hand6 See the appendix for an extensive listing of alliance partners involved in the development and marketing of major products introduced in 1993. 25 writing. Apple developed the operating system alone and the necessary handwriting recognition software together with the Russian software company ParaGraph. Sharp developed the LCD display for Newton and released a Newton under the Sharp brand, the Expert Pad. Sharp also manufactured the Newton. Motorola and Siemens both negotiated licences to develop complementary products for the Newton and to build devices based on Newton’s technologies. Other partners included telecommunication companies like BellSouth, US West, and Ameritech, but also publishing company Random House and online service provider AOL. The final product was a highly innovative product incorporating state of the art technologies. But despite the high price, the Newton offered only limited functionality. The handwriting recognition, while technologically advanced, was nevertheless error-prone and unreliable for serious day-to-day use. Despite the lack of a keyboard, the Newton was quite bulky. The much advertised communication features required the purchase of an additional device and were limited to a send-only fax and a modem. An additional device was also necessary to connect the Newton to a PC. AT&T EO During the 1980s, former telecommunication company AT&T had actively diversified into semiconductors and computing, and had acquired hardware computer supplier NCR in 1991. In 1992, AT&T unveiled the Hobbit RISC microprocessor which became the integral building block of the EO 440 “personal communicator” that was developed by the start-up company EO. AT&T had financed EO’s start-up, and, shortly before the release of the EO in the first half of 1993, acquired 51% of EO’s equity. Until it was discontinued in July 1994, less than 10,000 units of EO personal communicators were sold. With the end of the EO, all further developments of the Hobbit were stopped, ending AT&T’s engagement in semiconductors. EO Inc. was founded in 1991 as a spinoff of GO Corp. In the early 1990s, GO was one of the leading companies developing handwriting recognition software (Kaplan 1994), and the EO used the PenPoint operating system and handwriting recognition software developed by GO. The basic hardware and software design of the EO was developed together with the UK computer company Active Book Company. The manufacturer of the EO was Matsushita, while Marubeni and Olivetti were distribution and sourcing support partners. Other alliance partners included Sharp and an assortment of software start up companies that developed the applications for the EO. 26 AT&T’s long-standing involvement in communication services heavily influenced the design and product characteristics of the EO which was announced not as a PDA but as a “personal communicator”. The EO’s handwriting recognition software was only able to interpret block letters, and its computer capabilities were more limited than Newton’s. But the EO had a fax/modem built in that could also be linked to a cellular phone, and it was so able to send and receive fax and send e-mails via AT&T’s EasyLink network. Additional features included built-in microphone to voice annotate documents, and access to the Internet and proprietary networks like CompuServe. But with its steep price, large and heavy design, poor connectivity with PCs, and just 4 hours of battery working time, the EO failed on the market. Tandy/Casio Zoomer Casio had been one of the first movers in the market for handheld computers with the Boss electronic organizer, while Tandy’s GriD subsidy had introduced one of the first penbased computers. Both companies were thus in a good position to exploit the commercial opportunities of the handheld computer market. In 1992, Casio and Tandy had formed an alliance to develop and market the Zoomer PDA, and, in stark contrast to Apple, they used modifications of existing hardware and software to build the unit. Casio developed an Intelcompatible CPU, which was equivalent to the 8086. With its long-standing production skills in consumer electronics, Casio was also the main manufacturer, while Tandy distributed and marketed the product. GeoWorks modified their existing GEOS operating system for the Zoomer. Palm Computing, a GriD spinoff, provided the handwriting recognition software based on technology originally devised for the pen-computer Grid Pad. Furthermore, Palm Computing wrote most of the application and the connectivity software that was shipped with the Zoomer. At roughly the same price as the Newton, the Zoomer had very good personal organizing and finance features, and provided easy connectivity with desktop computers. And with an additional fax/modem, it was easy to send faxes, write e-mails, and access online services like America Online. With nearly 100 hours of battery life, the Zoomer was a truly mobile device. But like the Newton and the EO, the Zoomer had only poor handwriting recognition, and it was bulky, too. Moreover, because of its dated Intel microprocessor and Casio’s insistence on a very long battery life, the Zoomer was extremely slow. Launched in October 1993, sales of the device were a lot poorer than expected. In March 1994, Casio pulled out of the alliance, putting an end to the Zoomer project. 27 Other entries The UK consumer electronics company Amstrad was the first to bring to market a self-styled PDA in March 1993. Amstrad had successfully diversified into computer hardware during the 1980s by selling cheap home computers and PC clones using off-the-shelf components. Amstrad applied this approach to the emerging PDA market. Together with UK software company Eden and using its own vintage 8-bit Z80 microprocessor, Amstrad developed the PenPad. It was the cheapest and lightest of all PDAs introduced in 1993 and 1994. Lacking any communication features, the programmable PenPad had a limited set of software applications included and a very crude handwriting recognition technology. In the same year, Amstrad had acquired the Danish telecommunication hardware supplier Dancall, and announced the InfoPad for 1995, with strong communication features. With sluggish sales of PenPad, and growing difficulties for Amstrad in other markets, the InfoPad was never shipped. The Simon was a joint development by IBM and BellSouth. Introduced in August 1994, it was a cellular phone with very rudimentary organizing features and electronic ink as the main input device. The Simon was discontinued in 1995. Motorola introduced two PDAs in 1994. The Marco was based on Newton’s technologies and included a wireless modem allowing faxes and email to be sent, but it did not support voice communications. The Envoy used Motorola’s own Dragon microprocessor. The operating software and communication software had already been developed by General Magic. Like the EO, the Envoy was supposed to be a “Computing Communicator” with very strong communication features. Like the Envoy, it had a built-in wireless modem. Both PDAs gave access to Motorola’s own proprietary ARDIS network. Sony’s Magic Link was marketed as a personal communicator as well and it was also based on General Magic’s software. Motorola and Sony independently announced their withdrawal from the PDA market at the end of 1996, Motorola having sold less than 5,000 units of the Envoy and the Marco. To conclude, as a consequence of new technologies like handwriting recognition there was a wave of innovative entries into the emerging PDA market in the mid-1990s. An important area for experimenting and learning was the product itself and its key characteristics. The entrants tested different concepts and models of a Personal Digital Assistant, and these concepts were heavily influenced by the firm’s pre-entry experiences and the existing technological and marketing capabilities of the firms. 28 With the Newton, Apple developed a highly innovative product which was, in essence, a mobile information processor. Its design and features were inspired by the personal computer. According to Steve Sakoman, the head of the Newton development division, “the idea was to see if the personal computer could be rethought without carrying around a lot baggage.” Furthermore, Apple planed to generate most of its profit from selling application software for the Newton. Accordingly, like may firms in the computer industry, Apple freely licensed their technology (McGahan et al. 1997). In contrast, AT&T’s participation in the development of the EO, and Motorola’s and BellSouth’s background in telecommunications lead to the creation of personal communicators with very strong communication features. Profits were supposed to come from accessed communication services, less from the sale of hardware. Amstrad’s experience in consumer electronics and the home computer market lead to a cheap electronic gadget with limited functionality. But all these products failed more or less spectacularly in the market. The segment that continued to grow steadily during these years was the market for electronic organizers. Sharp, Hewlett-Packard, Casio, and Psion continued to develop incrementally their products, adding new features with each new product model. The market grew steadily: In 1993, 685,000 handheld computers were sold worldwide. Two years later, in 1995, the market had nearly doubled to 1,200,000 units, a lot less than industry observers had expected. But in the next two years, the market was to more than double, this time unexpectedly. In 1997, PDA sales grew by more than 65 percent (Figure 7). This rapid market growth can be attributed largely to the introduction of the Pilot PDA in April 1996. Figure 7 PDA Sales worldwide 1993 to 2002 (*expected) 29 4.3.3 The Pilot: A modest innovation The software company Palm Computing7 had already been engaged in the development of the Zoomer. After the demise of the Zoomer, Palm had initially focused on writing software for handwriting recognition and connectivity packs for the Hewlett-Packard line of handheld computers. But, due to the small market for handheld computers, the potential for revenue was limited. Building on their experience in the handheld computer market, Palm embarked on a mission to develop its own PDA, the Pilot. In their design, they relied on off-the-shelf products. The Pilot was built around Motorola’s Dragonball processor and an outdated Toshiba memory chip. For hardware design, Palm relied on Palo Alto Design Group, and its manufacturing company was Singapore-based Flexotronics, a manufacturer with a long-standing experience in consumer electronics. In addition, Palm could build on their own technology for handwriting recognition, Graffiti. Unlike other approaches to handwriting recognition, Graffiti did not try to interpret the handwriting of the user, but forced the user to adopt a simple to learn, stylized alphabet. Thereby, Graffiti was much more reliable and faster than other, more ambitious handwriting recognition technologies. Palm also developed its own operating system, PalmOS. From the beginning, Palm made its operating system available to independent software developers. The shirt-pocket sized Pilot was designed expressly to complement a personal computer. Accordingly, it only had limited, but tightly integrated features. Its standard applications – calendar, address manager, to-do list, and memo pad – were launched instantly by pressing a button. The synchronization between the desktop PC and the Pilot, often a tedious task with other PDAs, was made easy by a specially designed docking cradle and Palm’s own connectivity software. With a very low price, the Pilot became an instant hit. Despite the lack of any communication features, and without sophisticated software packs, the Pilot was successful, because in the words of one reviewer (Himowitz 1996, 224), it is a “gadget that does a few things very well”. The Pilot was built according to quality standards developed in telecommunications, as Yoffie/Kwak (2001, 59) remark “the Pilot adhered to the telecommunications-industry standard of ‘five nines’, working 99.999% of the time, whereas PC programs often crashed several times a day.” The Pilot reached a market share of more than 70 percent of the US handheld computer market at the end of 1996. In one year, the Pilot sold more than 500,000 units. After 7 Before the launch of the Pilot, Palm Computing was acquired by US Robotics in September 1995. It became a part of 3COM when 3COM acquired US Robotics in June 1997. In March 2000, after a successful IPO, Palm was an independent company once again. See Butter/Pogue (2002) for a history of Palm Computing. 30 three and half years, Palm had sold more than 5 million units of different Pilot models. With the Pilot, Palm established the dominant design for handheld computers for years to come. The PDA was, above all, a mobile complement to a desktop or laptop computer. For that reason, effortless synchronization with a desktop computer became an essential feature of a PDA. Compactness, reliability, and ease of use became other defining product characteristics of a PDA, while Palm’s Graffiti quickly evolved into the de facto industry standard for handwriting recognition. In the next years, rivals tried to emulate the product characteristics of the Pilot, and its basic design became the starting point for further product improvements for all firms in the handheld computer industry. As a startup company in the handheld computer industry, Palm was nevertheless able to successfully enter the market for handheld computers because the technological knowledge required to build a handheld was largely accessible through off-the-shelf products and alliances. The critical new technologies like handwriting recognition and connectivity software were developed in-house. Furthermore, Palm’s product design was not constrained by existing marketing capabilities, while Palm’s involvement in the Zoomer project was an important learning experience. Thus, Palm was able to exploit the window of opportunity opened by the technological convergence in complements. 4.2 The handheld computer industry in the 2000s: Towards Product Convergence After the success of the Pilot, the market for handheld computers grew rapidly. Despite a number of market entries of established firms with a strong background in computers and consumer electronics like, among others, Philips, Compaq, and Toshiba that brought to market handheld computers based on a Microsoft operating system, Palm remained the dominant firm in the next few years. Newly founded Handspring, a Palm spin-off, evolved into its main competitor. In 2000, the two firms had a combined market share of nearly 80 percent worldwide. Innovative activities was incremental: Building on the dominant design of the Pilot, the competitors added new features like color LCD display, voice recording and music playing, while the existing features were improved. At the same time, the wireless telecommunication markets is changing fundamentally. With falling prices and increasing adoption, cellular phones evolved into genuine mass market products. Due to advances in miniaturization technologies, cell phones got smaller and more functional at the same time. Based on the WAP (wireless application protocol) standard, 31 mobile phone producers like Nokia, Ericsson, and Motorola added rudimentary data communication features to their devices. While adoption was slow, the WAP standard nevertheless foreshadowed future development in wireless data communications. The SMS (short message service) standard for simple text messaging, on the other hand, was an instant hit. More demanding data communication is expected to be available via wideband networks which provide higher bandwidth. Emerging technologies are GPRS (General Packet Radio Standard) and especially the 3G/UMTS standard which is launched in 2002. Other emerging, personal and local area network technologies are Bluetooth and 802.11b. All these emerging wireless telecommunications technologies offer a higher bandwidth than the current GSM (Global System for Mobile Telecommunications) standard. They finally make possible the complementary use of cellular phones and multimedia online services. Consequently, cellular phones and online services are converging as complementary products. However, the same is true for PDAs. While many PDA models had data communication features like fax, e-mail, and rudimentary Internet access, they were not the key features as the success of the Pilot showed. The main task of a PDA still is data processing. The emerging wireless telecommunications technologies thus open the possibility to make data communication a key feature of a PDA, not an expensive add-on. In this context, the ability to be always “online” appears to be a crucial feature. Using technologies developed for paging devices, the Canadian company Research in Motion (RIM) introduced the Blackberry wireless e-mail pager in early 1999 and it is a huge success with corporate clients. Relying on a dated pager network, the Blackberry’s allows to instantly receive e-mails without the need to actively go “online”. Thus, like a cell phone, the PDA is rapidly becoming a complementary product to online services. As in mobile telecommunications, a convergence in complementary products of PDAs and online services is at hand. In addition, the miniaturization achieved in the production of cell phones makes the integration of voice communication features in a PDA and vice versa technically viable. Early attempts were the Simon, but also the Nokia Communicator introduced in 1996 and a PalmOS-based cellphone by Qualcomm. These devices had only very rudimentary organizing features, and could not be considered as a substitute for a PDA. But this is changing at the moment. Telecommunication companies Kyocera, Samsung, Motorola and Nokia, and Handspring have all released “intelligent cell phones” in late 2001, with many more models to follow in 2002. These hybrid products are integrating the salient product characteristics of a PDA and a mobile phone into one compact design. Thus, due to advances in miniaturization 32 the product convergence in complementarities is paralleled by the convergence in product substitutes of PDAs and cell phones (Figure 8). Figure 8 Product Convergence in wireless communications and handheld computers The technological opportunities in this constellation are high, since the emerging wireless telecommunications technologies are leading to changes in the complementary markets. First, there are the technological spillovers into the mobile phone and handheld computer markets. The new possibilities for data communications and the resulting convergence in complements prompt the search for new or enhanced product characteristics, thereby speeding up the convergence of PDAs and cell phones. Second, innovations are also induced in the online service and media industries. Here, new product offerings like wireless Video/Music-on-Demand, gaming, and mobile commerce are becoming technically feasible. The firms in the mobile phone and the handheld computer markets are reacting in different ways to the new challenges. Virtually all companies are trying to exploit the growth opportunities opened up by the complementary product convergence, and they are accordingly extending the communications and multimedia features of their products. Many of these firms are pursuing a focus strategy at the moment. For example, Palm has released its first wireless, Internet-enabled handheld in 1999, and a handheld with a color LCD display in early 2000. Palm’s strategy is to focus on the PDA market and not to develop convergent hybrid cell phone/PDAs. Its latest model, the Palm i705, features instant messaging and push e-mail technology like the Blackberry. For these communication services, Palm has formed alliances with AOL (instant messaging), Ericsson (paging technology) and Cingular Interactive (paging network). Furthermore, Palm has built up their own wireless network for Internet access, Palm.net. In 2002, Palm introduced a Bluetooth extension card for its PDAs that has been developed together with Toshiba. Palm has also entered alliances with Texas 33 Instrument and start-up company Broadcom to develop wireless technologies and applications. At present, Palm’s only stakes in the emerging market segment for hybrid products are licenses for their PalmOS operating system to telecommunication companies Kyocera and Samsung. Introduced in 2001, the Kyocera QCP 6035 and the Samsung SPHI300 were one of the first hybrid products on the market. Beside Kyocera and Samsung, other telecommunication companies like Nokia, Ericsson, and Motorola are also pursuing an active diversifying strategy by developing hybrid models. Nokia has been an early mover in this market segment. In 1996, Nokia had released the Communicator 9000, an early cell phone/PDA hybrid. While not very successful commercially, it started Nokia’s ongoing involvement in the development of hybrids. In 1998, Nokia was one the founding members of Symbian, a joint venture founded by Psion, Ericsson, and Motorola. Symbian was formed to promote Psion’s EPOC operating system, originally developed for Psion’s handhelds, as the standard operating system for wireless communications. Matsushita joined as a stockholder in 1999, while Siemens became a stockholding member in early 2002. Other, non-stockholding Symbian partners include Sony, Philips, NTT DoCoMo, Oracle, Qualcomm, IBM, Sonera, and Sun Microsystems, but also the music entertainment company Beatnik. In 2001, Nokia has released the latest Communicator smart phone, the 9210, with great success in Europe. Building on former models, Nokia has added a color screen, a powerful browser, and improved organizing features. Motorola and the Sony Ericsson joint venture also released Symbian-based smartphones in 2001 and 2002. In the PDA market, it is Handspring that has committed itself to a diversification strategy. In late 2000, Palm shipped the VisorPhone module for Handspring’s Visor PDA. Developed together with Belgian company Option International, the VisporPhone adds voice and data communications to the Visor. With the acquisition of BlueLark Systems in 2000, Handspring has extended its in-house technological capabilities in data communications. BlueLark had developed the Blazer browser which can access not only Internet content explicitly designed for mobile content but also standard HTML sites. To commercialize this technology, Handspring has licensed the Blazer to telecommunication companies OmniSky and Sprint, and to PDA maker Xircom. In late 2001, Handspring finally released a hybrid, the Treo, with built-in voice communication. The GSM radio module had been developed by French company Wavecom. Handspring is cooperating with telecommunications company Sprint and telecommunications start-up Airprime to develop the 3G-enabled Treo during 2002, and it has also forged ties to wireless carriers such as VoiceStream, Cingular, and Rogers, and online content providers like Microsoft’s MSN. 34 It is too early to tell how the two types of product convergence will play out in the handheld computer and mobile phone markets. But some of the salient features of these types of convergence are already visible. The convergence of complements extends the technological opportunities in these markets, and stimulates innovative activity in the existing markets. For the underlying technologies of the complementary technologies, established firms are looking for alliance partners in horizontal markets. The Symbian joint venture, Palm’s licenses to Kycoera and Samsung, and Handspring’s cooperation with Sprint, Xircomm, and MSN are examples. In addition, the product convergence in complements also encourages entry by new firms like AirPrime, BlueLark, Broadcomm, and Wavecom into the market for complementary technologies. These firms pursue highly focused strategies, and they are important alliance partners for established firms. As already explained, the product convergence of complements is also an important driver of the product convergence in substitutes. Here, the established firms in the handheld computer and mobile phone markets are introducing hybrid smart phones that substitute for PDAs or cell phones. So far, the threat of new entrants has been negligible. The established firms are building on their existing products, and use these as the starting point for the development of these hybrid products. Over the years, Nokia has incrementally extended the Communicator’s organizing features, while Handspring started from a PDA, first with an addon, later with a built-in voice communication module. An important consequence will be the slow convergence of the technological capabilities of handheld computer and mobile phone makers, probably leading to the long-term technological convergence of these diversifiers. On the other hand, other established firms in both markets are continuing to pursue focus strategies. Palm is the prime example. It remains to be seen how successful the hybrid products really are, and how large the market segment for these convergent offerings will turn out to be. This will influence the future viability of focus and diversification strategies. 5. Conclusions This paper has tried to contribute to the question of what kind of impact market convergence has on innovations, market structure, and firm behavior. It has been argued that four different ideal types of market convergence can be distinguished, and that these differ markedly in their effects on industry evolution. To illustrate the framework, it has been applied to explain the evolution of the handheld computer market in the last 20 years. It was shown that different types of convergence shaped the evolution of handheld computers at 35 various times. The observed patterns of market evolution broadly correspond to the theoretical patterns of market convergence. In the early stage of the market, market dynamics were driven by complementary technological convergence of the computer, consumer electronics, and telecommunications industries. These industries were the commercial backgrounds of entrants into the handheld computer market, since they could exploit their existing technological capabilities to develop new markets. To access missing technological capabilities, firms formed horizontal, usually knowledge using alliances to access the technologies, or relied on off-the-shelf products. This was also part of the reason why a start-up company eventually came to dominate the market. Successful entry was also fostered by the low cumulativeness of the established firms’ marketing capabilities for entry into the handheld computer market. Recent developments in the handheld computer market are influenced by product convergence. Emerging telecommunications standards and technologies like 3G lead to a product convergence of complements in the wireless telecommunications, handheld computer, and online services industries. Innovative entrants are especially important for the development of the new complementary technologies, since the cumulativeness of technological knowledge is low. These entrants are important alliance partners for the established firms. Furthermore, advances in miniaturization increasingly lead to the product convergence in substitutes of the handheld computer and cellular phone industries. In this case, established firms of the two markets are diversifying by developing hybrid products that incorporate product characteristics of cell phones and PDAs. Since the cumulativeness of technological and marketing knowledge is high, the role of entrants in this process of convergence has been negligible. By looking at one particular market in quite some detail, this qualitative case study complements the more quantitative, inter-industry studies of technological convergence (Gambardella/Torrisi 1998, Fai/Tunzelmann 2001). 36 6. References Abell, D.F. (1980): Defining the Business. Englewood Cliffs 1980. Abbot, L.: Quality and Competition. New York 1955. Adner, R./Levinthal, D.A. (2000): Technology Speciation and the Path of Emerging Technologies. In: Day, G.S./Schoemaker, P.J. (eds.): Wharton on Managing Emerging Technologies. New York et al. 2000,5774. Andersen, B. (1998): The evolution of technological trajectories 1890-1990. In: Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, Vol. 9, 1998. Bladwin, T.F./McVoy, D.S./Steinfield, C. (1996): Convergence: Integrating Media, Information, and Communication. Thousand Oaks. Bayus, B.L./Jain, S./Rao, A.G. (1997): Too Little, too Early: Introduction Timing and New Product Performance in the Personal Digital Assistant Industry. In: Journal of Marketing Research, Vol. XXXIV, 1997, 5063. Bettis, R.A./Hitt, M.A. (1995): The New Competitive Landscape. In: Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 16, 1995, S. 7-19. Bettis, R.A. (1998): Comment on ‘Redefining Industry Structure For the Information Age’ by J.L. Sampler. In: Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 19, 1998, S. 357-362 Bresnahan, T./Trajtenberg, M. (1995): General Purpose Technologies: Engines of Growth. In: Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 65, 1995, 83-108. Butter, A./Pogue, D. (2002) : Piloting Palm. New York 2002. Cantwell, J.A./Fai, F. (1999): Firms as the source of innovation and growth: the evolution of technological competence. In: Journal of Evolutionary Economics, Vol. 9, 1999, 331-366. Choi, D./Valikangas, L. (2001): Patterns of Strategy Innovations. In: European Management Journal, Vol. 19, 2001, 424-429. Christensen, C.M./Suárez, F.F./Utterback, J.M. (1998): Strategies for Survival in Fast-Changing Industries. In: Management Science, Vol. 44, S207-S220. Collis, D.J./Bane, P.W./Bradley, S.P.: Winners and Losers: Industry Structure in the Converging World of Telecommunications, Computing, and Entertainment. In: Yoffie, D.B. (ed.): Competing in the Age of Digital Convergence. Boston 1997, 159-199. Consumer Reports (1991): Need Organizing? November 1991, 768-774. Demsetz, H. (1991): The Theory of the Firm Revisited. In: Williamson, O.E./Winter, S.G. (eds.): The Nature of the Firm: Origins, Evolution, and Development. Oxford 1991, 159-177. Dittrich, K. (2001): Internet alliances: a whole new game. Paper presented at the ECIS Conference, Eindhoven, Netherlands, September 20-23, 2001. Dosi, G. (1988): Sources, procedures and microeconomic effects of innovation. In: Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 36, 1988, 1126-1171. Dosi, G./Malerba, F./Orsenigo, L. (1994): Evolutionary Regimes and Industrial Dynamics. In: Magnusson, L. (ed.) Evolutionary and Neo-Schumpeterian Approaches to Economics. Boston/Dordrecht/London. Duysters, G./Hagedoorn, J. (1998): Technological Convergence in the IT Industry: The Role of Strategic Technological Alliances and Technological Competencies. In: International Journal of the Economics of Business, Vol. 5, 1998, 355-368. Economist (2000): The Great Convergence Gamble, 12/09/2000, Vol. 357 Issue 8200, 2000, 67-68. 37 Fai, F./Tunzelmann, Nicolas von (2001): Industry-specific competencies and converging technological systems: evidence from patents. In: Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, Vol. 12, 2001, 141-170. Gaffard, J.L./Krafft, J. (2000): Telecommunications: understanding the dynamics of the organization of the industry. Working Paper October 2000. Gallouji, F./Weinstein, O. (1997): Innovation in services. In: Research Policy, Vol. 26, 1997, 537-556. Gambardella, A./Torrisi, S. (1998): Does technological convergence imply convergence in markets? Evidence from the electronics industry. In: Research Policy, Vol. 27, 1998, 445-463. Geroski, P.A. (1998): Thinking creatively about markets. In: International Journal of Industrial Organization, Vol. 16, 1998, 677-695. Gomes-Casseres, B. (1996) : The Alliance Revolution. Cambridge (Ma.) 1996. Gomes-Casseres, B./Leonard-Barton, D. (1997): Alliance Clusters in Multimedia. In: Yoffie, D. (ed.): Competing in the Age of Digital Convergence, Boston, 1997, 325-369. Granstrand, O. (1998): Towards a theory of the technology-based firm. In: Research Policy, Vol. 27, 1998, 465489. Greenstein, S./Khanna, T. (1997): What does industry convergence mean? In: Yoffie, D. (ed.): Competing in the Age of Digital Convergence, Boston, 1997, 201- 226. Hamel, G./Prahalad, C.K (1994): Competing for the Future. Boston 1994. Harianto, F./Pennings, J.M. (1994): Technological convergence and scope of organizational innovation. In: Research Policy, Vol. 23, 1994, 293-304. Helpman, E., editor (1998): General Purpose Technologies and Economic Growth. Cambridge, Ma. 1998. Hippel, E. von (1988): The Sources of Innovation. New York/Oxford 1988. Himowitz, M. (1996): Why users love the Pilot. In: Fortune, Vol. 134, Issue 9, 224-226. Jorgenson, D.W./Stiroh, K.J. (2000): Raising the Speed Limit: US Economic Growth in the Information Age. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Issue 1, 2000. Kaplan, J. (1994): Start Up: A Silicon Valley Adventure. London 1994. Katz, M.L. (1996): Remarks on the Economic Implications of Convergence. In: Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol. 3, 1996, 1079-1095. Kodama, F. (1992): Technology Fusion and the New R&D. In: Harvard Business Review, Vol. 70, No.4, 1992, 70-78. Lancaster, K.J. (1966): A new approach to consumer theory. In: Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 14, 1966, 133-156. Malerba, F./Orsenigo, L. (2000): Knowledge, Innovative Activities and Industrial Evolution. In: Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol. 9, 2000, 289-314. Malerba, F. (2002): Sectoral systems of innovation and production. In: Research Policy, Vol. 31, 2002, 247-264. Marsili, O. (2001): The Anatomy and Evolution of Industries. Cheltenham, UK 2001. McGahan, A.M./Vadasz, L.L./Yoffie, D.B. (1997): Creating Value and Setting Standards. In: Yoffie, D.B. (ed.): Competing in the Age of Digital Convergence. Boston 1997, 227-264. Mowery, D.C./Oxley, J.E./Silverman, B.S. (1996): Strategic Alliances and Interfirm Knowledge Transfer. In: Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 17, 1996, Winter Special Issue, 77-91. Mowery, D.C./Oxley, J.E./Silverman, B.S. (1998): Technological overlap and interfirm cooperation: implications for the resource-based view of the firm. In: Research Policy, Vol. 28, 1998, 507-523. 38 Nelson, R.R. (1995): Recent Evolutionary Theorizing About Economic Change. In: Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 33, 1995, 48-90. Pavitt, K. (1984): Patterns of Technical Change: Towards a Taxonomy and a Theory. In: Research Policy, Vol. 13, 1984, 343-373. Pennings, J.M./Puranam, P. (2001): Market Convergence & Firm Strategy: New Directions for Theory and Research. Paper presented at the ECIS Conference, Eindhoven, Netherlands, September 20-23, 2001. Penrose, E.T. (1959): The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. London 1959. Piscitello, L. (2000): Relatedness and coherence in technological and product diversification of the world’s largest firms. In: Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, Vol. 11, 2000, 295-315. Pleatsikas, C./Teece, D. (2001): The analysis of market definition and market power in the context of rapid innovation. In: International Journal of Industrial Organization, Vol. 19, 2001, 665-693. Potter, D. (1998): Entrepreneurship: Psion and Europe. In: Business Strategy Review, Vol. 9, 1998, 15-20. Porter, M.E. (1985): Competitive Advantage. New York 1985. Reve, T. (1990): The Firm as a Nexus of Internal and External Contracts. In: Aoki, M./Bo, G./Williamson, O.E. (ed.): The Firm as a Nexus of Treaties. London 1990, 133-161. Rao, P.M. (1999): Convergence and unbundling of corporate R&D in telecommunications: is software taking the helm? In: Telecommunication Policy, Vol. 23, 1999, 83-93. Robinson, J. (1956), The Economics of Imperfect Competition. London 1956. Rosenberg, N. (1976): Perspectives on technology. Cambridge 1976. Rosenberg, N. (1982): Inside the Black Box. Cambridge/New York 1982. Sahal, D. (1985): Technological guideposts and innovation avenues. In: Research Policy, Vol. 14, 1985, 61-82. Santangelo, G.D. (2000): Corporate strategic technological partnerships in the European information and communications technology industry. In: Research Policy, Vol. 29, 2000, 1015-1031. Saviotti, P./Metcalfe, S. (1984): A theoretical approach to the construction of technological output indicators. In: Research Policy, Vol. 13, 1984, 141-151. Saviotti, P. (1996): Technological Evolution, Variety and the Economy. Cheltenham 1996. Stigler, G./Sherwin, R. (1985): The Extent of the Market. In: Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 28, 1985, 555585. Teece, D.J. (1986): Profiting from Technological Innovation. In: Research Policy, Vol. 15, 1986, 285-305. Teece, D.J./Dosi, G./Rumelt, R./Winter, S. (1994): Understanding Corporate Coherence: Theory and Evidence. In: Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Vol. 23, 1994, 1-30. Teece, D.J./Pisano, G./Shuen, A. (1997): Dynamic Capabilities and Strategic Management. In: Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 18, 1997, 509-533. Tushman, M./Anderson, P. (1986): Technological Discontinuities and organizational environments. In: Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 31, 1986, 439-465. Wirtz, B. (2001): Reconfiguration of Value Chains in Converging Media and Communications Markets. In: Long Range Planning, Vol. 34, 2001, 489-507. Yoffie, D.B. (1997): Introduction: CHESS and Competing in the Age of Digital Convergence. In: Yoffie, D.B. (ed.): Competing in the Age of Digital Convergence. Boston 1997, 1-35. Yoffie, D.B./Kwak, M. (2001): Mastering Strategic Movement at Palm. In: MIT Sloan Management Review, Fall 2001, 55-63. 39 7. Appendix a) Major market entries and exits 1984 to 2001 in the handheld computer market Year Entrant Product Origin Exit ? 1984 Psion Organiser Computer Software 2001 1988 Casio Boss Consumer Electronics Sharp Wizard Consumer Electronics Atari Portfolio Computer Hardware 1996 Poqet Poqet PC Startup 1996 1991 HP LX 95 Computer Hardware 1993 Amstrad PenPad Consumer Electronics 1996 Apple Newton Computer Hardware 1998 AT&T EO440 Telecommunications 1994 Tandy Zoomer Consumer Electronics 1995 IBM/BellSouth Simon Computer Hardware /Telecommunications 1996 Motorola Envoy, Marco Computer Hardware 1996 Sony MagicLink Consumer Electronics 1996 1995 Texas Instrument Pocket Solution Computer Hardware 1998 1996 Compaq PC Companion Computer Hardware Hitachi Handheld PC Computer Hardware Nokia Communicator Telecommunications Palm Pilot Startup Everex Freestyle Consumer Electronics Franklin Rex-3-DS PDA Consumer Electronics IBM (reentered) WorkPad Computer Hardware LG Electronics GP40MHPC Consumer Electronics NEC MobilePro Computer Hardware Philips Velo, Nino Consumer Electronics Rolodex REX PC Companion Consumer Electronics 1989 1994 1997 (later: Xircomm) 1998 Olivetti/Royal DaVinci Computer Hardware 1999 Handspring Visor Startup TRG TRGpro Startup (renamed: HandEra) 1999 RIM Blackberry Startup 2000 Acer Slim Mate Computer Hardware Sony (reentered) Clié Consumer electronics Toshiba Genio Computer hardware 2001 40 b) Alliances in the handheld computer industry for major products released in 1993 Product Apple Newton Company Ameritech AOL ARM BellSouth Cirrus Logic GEC Plessy LSI Logic Motorola ParaGraph Pen Magic Random House Sharp Siemens Sky-Tel Texas Instrument Toshiba US West AT&T EO Tandy Zoomer VLSI Technology Active Book Company Aha! GO Industry Communication Hardware/Services Communication Services Computer Hardware Communication Services Computer Hardware Computer Hardware Computer Hardware Computer/ Communications Hardware Computer Software Computer Software Publishing Consumer Electronics Electronics Communication Services Computer Hardware Computer Hardware Communication Services Computer Hardware Computer Hardware Computer Software Computer Software Ink Development Lexis Marubeni Computer Software Computer Software Electronics Matsushita Notable Technologies Olivetti Consumer Electronics Computer Software Pen Magic PenSoft Sharp Slate Sunselect Casio Computer Hardware Computer software Computer Software Consumer Electronics Computer Software Computer Software Consumer Electronics GeoWorks Palm Computing Computer Software Computer Software Intuit AOL Computer Software Communication Services Task Messaging Direction Horizontal Motivation Knowledge Using Online Services Horizontal Knowledge Using Microprocessor ARM 610 Development OnlineBanking ARM licensee ARM licensee Vertical Horizontal Knowledge Using Knowledge Creating Vertical Vertical Knowledge Using Knowledge Using Application specific chip Newton licensee Vertical Horizontal Knowledge Using Knowledge Using Handwriting Recognition Horizontal Knowledge Creating Software Reference content LCD display Manufacturing Netwon licensee ARM licensee Newton licensee E-mail services Horizontal Horizontal Horizontal Knowledge Using Knowledge Creating Knowledge Using Horizontal Horizontal Knowledge Using Knowledge Using ARM licensee CD-ROM Communication Services Horizontal Horizontal Horizontal Knowledge Using Knowledge Using Knowledge Using ARM licensee Hardware and Software Design Software Handwriting Recognition Operating System Software Software Sourcing Distribution Manufacturing Software Vertical Horizontal Knowledge Using Knowledge Creating Horizontal Horizontal Knowledge Using Knowledge Using Horizontal Horizontal Horizontal Knowledge Using Knowledge Using Knowledge Using Horizontal Horizontal Knowledge Using Knowledge Using Sourcing Distribution Financial Software Software LCD Display Software Software LCD display Microprocessor Manufacturing Operating System Handwriting Recognition Software Financial software Online Services Horizontal Knowledge Using Horizontal Horizontal Horizontal Horizontal Horizontal Horizontal Knowledge Using Knowledge Using Knowledge Using Knowledge Using Knowledge Using Knowledge Using Horizontal Horizontal Knowledge Using Knowledge Using Horizontal Horizontal Knowledge Using Knowledge Using 41