VALUING CORPORATE GROWTH USING REAL OPTIONS Latypov Gennady Faculty of economics, Kyoto University, e-mail: petrenko_spb@yahoo.com Corporate DCF model has been often criticized for limitations in valuing investments with significant multi-period growth opportunities. Current paper offers practical methodology that employs recombining binomial trees and real option techniques for valuing companies pursuing organic growth strategy in case of demand uncertainty. Specially constructed recombining tree is adapted to valuations of multiple American type compound growth options. Computational complexity is considerably reduced that makes these solutions feasible to implement in business practice and empirical testing. Keywords: real growth option, corporate valuation, organic growth. JEL classification: G31, G11, D92. I. INTRODUCTION Currently, traditional discounted cash flow (DCF) analysis based on shareholder value maximization is being widely used in corporate budgeting practice as a criterion for evaluating projects and companies. However, despite its popularity, corporate DCF model has inherent limitations in valuing investments with significant flexibility options (Mun [2004]) and is often criticized for undervaluation of investment opportunities that lead to myopic decisions, underinvestment problem and potential loss of competitive position. Instead, other alternative methods have been developed to effectively capture management flexibility to respond to future uncertain developments, namely: revised 1 (dynamic) DCF model, decision analysis, and contingent claim analysis (real options). All methods are concerned with valuing risky alternatives by backward recursion, however, the probabilities and discount rate used in each type of analysis differ, and hence, principally the results may substantially differ depending on the employed approach. To overcome the shortcoming of static DCF approach of assuming a predetermined decision path, the dynamic DCF model employs decision trees to plot future contingencies and expected future cash flows are estimated using real probabilities extracted from similar projects and then discounted by the risk-adjusted opportunity cost of capital. The dynamic DCF analysis offers a significant improvement over static DCF in that it incorporates management reaction to uncertain future states; however, this approach has main drawback in that it is highly sensitive to the subjective choice of risk-adjusted discount rates. Decision analysis differs from dynamic DCF model in that discounting of future cash flows is done by risk-free rate to capture investor’s time preference, and adjustments for risk aversion appear in the characterization of the utility function of a decision maker. Decision analysis typically focuses on the expected utilities of an individual decision maker and, therefore, may not be a proper measure of a project value from a shareholder’s viewpoint. Instead, option theory adopts the perspectives of investors based on market equilibrium and determines the value of investment opportunity using the values of other traded assets. The famous classic option model is that of Black and Scholes [1973]. Later Cox, Ross and Rubinstein’s [1979] developed a binomial option pricing method that converges in the limit to Black and Scholes’s [1973] prominent model. Subsequently, based on Myers’ [1977] seminal idea that one can view a firm’s discretionary investments as a call option on real assets, 2 the real option approach (McDonald and Siegel [1986], Dixit and Pindyck [1994], Trigeorgis [1996]) extended the classic option theory to applications to partially or completely irreversible investments with uncertain future payoffs and flexibility around the investment timing. Unlike DCF and decision analysis, option valuation methods are based on “no-arbitrage” assumption and use the portfolio composed of a traded underlying asset (or traded twin asset perfectly correlated with the underlying if it is not traded) and risk-free asset to replicate the payoffs of an option in any uncertain state. Being independent of risk preferences of individual investors, such valuation enables taking expectations of future payoffs using risk-neutral probabilities and discounting of expected risk-neutral cash flows by risk free rate; therefore, actual probabilities of future uncertain states are not necessary to estimate. Respectively, the option valuation of investment opportunity is significantly simplified compare to dynamic DCF or decision analysis, if the value of the underlying asset or the corresponding correlated traded asset is observable and easy to model. However, if the value of underlying asset is unobservable and there are no correlated traded twin-assets, which is frequently the case of real options, special approaches should be used to estimate the value of flexibility option. Copeland and Antikarov [2001], Mun [2002] have proposed an appropriate solution algorithm based on the “Marketed Asset Disclaimer” assumption to value options in case of incomplete markets. Under their assumption, to value such real options, first, the stochastic process of the underlying non-traded asset without options is simulated, and then various embedded options are treated as if they were assets whose cash flows are derived from the value of the underlying asset without options. Hence, the present value of the “as-if-traded” asset without options is used to construct a replicating portfolio and flexibility options are quantitatively estimated using traditional option pricing methods. 3 The main attention of the current paper is the application of real option theory to sequential investment decision-making that maximizes a company’s value under uncertainty. Trigeorgis [1993] points out that the presence of subsequent options can alter the value of underlying risky asset, and hence, combined value of portfolio of real options may differ from the sum of values of individual options. Addressing this issue, the current research focuses on firm-level investment behaviour and explicitly considers the effects of multiple corporate growth options on a firm’s market value. Using real option framework it allows theoretical and quantitative capturing of the value of a firm’s activities around building capabilities and exploring new opportunities in dynamic environment. The paper is organised as follows. The following section presents a brief review of the theoretical and empirical real option literature related to corporate valuations. Section III provides detailed description of the model for arbitrage free valuation of corporations with careful attention paid to the type of exogenous uncertainty and the treatment of risk. The analysis will display the problem of choosing the optimal reinvestment strategy in a discrete-time compound option framework to obtain numerical arbitrage-free solutions of a corporate value with strategic flexibility. Simple numerical examples that are discussed in section IV illustrate the results. Section V concludes the discussion. II. THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL BACKGROUND The way how corporations structure and govern their activities remains the central issue to the theory of the firm. The real option thinking in corporate finance stresses the 4 additional value of flexibility that a firm’s governance structure has if it can efficiently recognize, create and properly manage the various real options in different states of uncertain environment. The bulk of real option studies have showed that sequential decision-making better describes organizational behaviour than the “now-or-never” commitment structure implied by traditional valuation techniques like static DCF model. Earlier research has been focusing on the analysis of the relationship between value of a single real option and a firm’s value (McDonald and Siegel [1985], Pindyck [1988]). The recent developments have extended the real option analysis in a broader context of corporate strategy with focus on portfolio of options and studied the irreversible investments in building strategic capabilities such as R&D, mergers & acquisitions, developments of new technologies, etc. (See Copeland and Antikarov [2001], Mun [2002], Smit and Trigeorgis [2004], Schwartz and Trigeorgis [2004] for a thorough review of real option theory and practice). Real option analysis has been widely applied to analyze optimal market entry (Folta and O’Brien [2004]), joint ventures (Kogut [1991]), and foreign expansions (Campa [1994]). A number of recent papers in the strategic management literature investigated the influence of uncertainty on the value of specific growth options. For instance, Kogut [1991], Kogut and Kulatilaka [2001] explored the option value associated with investing in platform capabilities based on which a firm may better respond to uncertain changes in external environment. Similarly, McGrath and Nerkar [2004] have found that pharmaceutical companies intend to create a growth option by investing in patent in a new area of exploration if the surrounding uncertainty and respective upside potential is large. Other authors (Hall [2000]) have showed the presence of real option logic in the market valuations of innovations and R&D activities. 5 Levitas and Chi [2001] found that firms which signalled the holding of technological competences through patenting enjoyed higher market values in more volatile environment. Berger et al. [1996] analysed the market valuations of the option to abandon a firm and showed that firms with greater exit value and less specialized assets have a large value of flexibility to abandon the business in case of financial distress. Several empirical studies have also examined how financial markets value real growth options possessed by a firm. Kester [1984] measured the value of growth options as the difference between a firm’s current market value and the value of its assets-in-place and estimated that the value of the growth options is more than the half of the market value of equity for a lot of firms and as much as 70 of 80% for volatile industries. Following the work of Kester, other authors (Danbolt, Hall and Jones [2002], Tong and Reuer [2006]) also suggested that the value of growth options can represent a sizable portion of a firm’s market value, however, even adopting the real option framework, none of these studies tested an analytic model of multiple growth options. Pindyck [1988] employed numerical simulation and suggested that if demand volatility exceeds 0.2 the value of growth options occupies more than half of a firm’s total value. Most of the mentioned real option literature provides a compelling framework for capturing management flexibility under uncertainty and implications for its quantitative valuation in case of individual investment projects; however, it is important to recognize several pitfalls in practical applications of the theory to valuing corporations (Philippe H. [2005], Lander and Pinches [1998]). Proponents of real option theory (Kogut and Kulatilaka [1994], etc.) stress its numerous advantages: no more biased discount rates, ability to fully utilize the uncertain information, the quantitative measure of managers’ 6 flexibility, etc. However, according to several studies the usage of real options is still limited in business practice. Graham and Harvey [2001], Triantis [2001] found that real option techniques are often being used only as a strategic qualitative tool rather than an instrument for exact quantitative estimation. According to another investigation fulfilled by Ministry of Economy Trade and Industry (METI [2003-04]), in 2003-04 years in Japan there were no corporate finance officers actually using real option techniques in investment appraisal. One more fact about real options was published in “Economist” in April, 2000: 46% of American companies that tried real option techniques gave up because those methods were too complicated to be used in practical evaluation of real investments. As for the valuing of corporations, developing appropriate real option methodology remains one of the hottest topics in research agenda (Triantis [2005], Kellogg and Charnes [2000]). In the following, I briefly discuss the major conceptual and practical issues concerning the applicability of the real option pricing techniques in corporate valuations. In general, the option pricing models may not be readily applicable to real corporations, since corporate real options have several properties that are quite distinct from traded financial options. The unique feature of real options embedded in corporate growth is that they are usually considered as characteristics of a firm’s asset-in-place (Tong and Reuer [2006]) and, hence, can not be separated and independently valued. One more feature of corporate real options is their effect on the underlying company’s value. If exercising of financial option has no impact on the value of underlying asset, the value of real option may be severely influenced by managerial actions. If a company develops or enters new markets or executes large-scale investments in R&D it may alter the competitive structure of the firm’s industry and, hence, change the underlying asset 7 value (i.e. expected cash flows from market operations). Often, this impact on the underlying asset’s value is not included in formal contracts but implicitly embedded in strategic investments. The time of option expiration and exercising rules are also, generally, not as clear as those for financial options. Other problem lies in the way of formalizing uncertainty in real option models. Uncertainty that has the strong impact on investment behavior is central to real option theory of investment (Dixit and Pindyck [1994]); however, real option models traditionally treat the value of a whole investment project itself as the exogenous uncertainty variable and do not focus on the individual (usually multiple) sources of uncertainty that drive the project’s value. This ambiguity creates difficulties for research studies as to what are the most relevant and important sources of uncertainty. In addition, current researches do not have a consensus on the empirical measure of uncertainty (see, for example, Ghosal and Loungani [2000], Ogawa and Suzuki [2000]). Regarding the application of quantitative models to growth reinvestments and corporate valuations, the complexities of real-world investments create difficulties in specifying a proper mathematical model for capturing the sequential interdependence among multiple growth reinvestments over time. Traditionally, real option analysis of multiple growth options focuses on multi-stage investment opportunities. In this framework, first-stage investment is undertaken to create growth option, whereas second-stage investment may be made to exercise this growth option (Copeland T. and Tufano P. [2004], Panayi and Trigeorgis [1998], Luehrman [1998]). In case of multiple growth opportunities, this model setting is limited to European type options. In contrast, the practical real option problems usually involve American-type options with several state 8 variables and path-dependent pricing dynamic which is extremely difficult to solve analytically. For multiple American-type growth options that give its owner the right to exchange one asset for another at any time prior to expiration, complexity accompanying real investments can even may make it difficult to solve the problem computationally. Few attempts (Smit and Trigeorgis [2004], Copeland and Antikarov [2005], Brandao, Dyer, Hahn [2005]) to model portfolio containing large number of growth options have utilized non-recombining binomial trees and possess the problem of exponential complexity that makes these solutions difficult to implement in practice. Hence, testing propositions derived from applications of real option theory to research in strategic management presents a challenge since the value of growth options embedded in a company’s value could not be directly measured. As a result, past researches haven’t relied on the precise measure of the value of real options and utilized, instead, estimations based on reduced-form relationships between observed proxies that in theory depend on the value of real options and strategic investments (Folta, Johnson, O’Brien [2006]). The main attention of this paper is to provide computationally efficient valuation technique to directly measure the value of a firm with regard to the value of its portfolio of multiple growth options. To overcome the gap between corporate finance theory and practice, current paper utilises specially constructed lattice with recombining property and applies Marketed Asset Disclaimer concept to properly value interacting multiple options embedded in corporate growth. The results show that for high/moderate growth firms operating in highly dynamic business environment the value of growth option portfolio is significantly undervalued by traditional corporate Discounted Cash Flow model. The paper offers several contributions to existing corporate finance literature and 9 practitioners. First, it builds a computationally effective model of a firm’s flexibility that explicitly includes potentially very large number of compound American-type growth options. Second, it validates an arbitrage-free valuation tool alternative to traditional corporate DCF model that, the author believes, can find its useful practical applications. III. THE MODEL The strategic interest in any real option lies mainly in its ability to truncate the distribution of unfavorable moves of the uncertain environment in the value of investment. This section is to investigate the effects of introducing multiple growth options in the value of corporations and the optimal operating rules for companies that possess many American-type growth options. Building on Myer’s [1977] original idea of treating the investment opportunities as “growth options”, traditional corporate finance theory prescribes that a firm’s standalone value consists of two components: value of its assets in place and value of growth opportunities (Damodaran [2002]; Copeland, Koller, Murrin [2000]). Corporate DCF values both parts by dividing the infinite life of the firm into two periods: 10 • period of abnormal growth when the company enjoys extra rents due to competitive advantage (for example, economies of scale/scope, absolute cost advantage or product differentiation), and/or high entry/exit barriers in an industry (like capital intensity, minimum efficient scale, advertising intensity, etc.) • and period of stable growth when the state of competitive equilibrium has been achieved and the firm can not earn excess return given current conditions of technology, customer tastes, etc., thus, earning only market average return on its capital. DCF model further assumes that firm’s management execute growth reinvestments in each period (Copeland T., Weston J. F., Shastri K. [2005], Damodaran [2001]). In contrast, real option theory treats the pattern of reinvesting in a different way since each reinvestment can be considered as an exercising of a “growth option” similar to financial option with the underlying asset being “real” cash flows. Real option theory maintains that the expansion investments made by corporations are often sunk in the form of firm- or market-specific production/distribution infrastructure, brand enhancement, knowledge base, etc. and executing such (partly) irreversible reinvestment is not the obligation, but the right of the management (Dixit and Pindyck [1994]); therefore, these rights should be exercised only if market turns out to be favourable. Hence, before making a final investment decision a firm faces a critical trade-off between flexibility and commitment. On the one side, if a firm makes investments to develop a market it will actually install additional expansion/growth options that may set the path for future corporate development. On the other side, despite earlier investment may bring immediate cash flows and provide platform for 11 future follow-on investments, it may “kill” the value of option to “wait and see”. As a result, traditional cut-off rule like a positive NPV itself is not a sufficient criterion for a viability of individual investment and instead of accepting all projects with positive NPV it is necessary to choose the NPV-maximizing “wait-reinvest” strategy, recognizing that future decisions and appropriate discount rates will be conditioned on the realizations of stochastic variables and previously executed decisions. Thus, the apparatus of real option theory enables a formal analysis of these sequential discretionary reinvestment decisions. There are several issues that should be considered in direct practical implementation of real option theory to corporate growth valuation. Traditionally, real option models treat the value of a project (or a company) itself as the exogenous stochastic variable. The underlying assumption of modelling the stochastic process of the value of the whole project lies in Samuelson’s [1965] proof that multiple sources of uncertainty driving the project’s value can be eventually combined into a single random walk. Although appealing from a theoretical perspective, the practical use of the company’s value in the valuation process is limited due to the lack of intuition associated with the solution techniques and the restrictive assumptions that are difficult to estimate empirically. Despite greatly reducing dimensional complexity of valuation model to single uncertainty, this approach has also the drawback of aggregating information about individual risk factors into single number of dispersion of a company’s value. As the result, based on the current models it is very difficult to provide clear threshold values of individual uncertainty drivers that trigger investments. Moreover, Smith [2005] showed that procedures for calculating integrated volatility may overstate the actual uncertainty in the cash flows and, hence, overstate the value of many options. The 12 presence of multiple real options embedded in corporate growth also influences the company’s value in nonlinear way. If a company has only one growth option, it is possible to characterize the company’s value with a single growth option as following, suppose, a lognormal process. However, if the company adds two or more subsequent growth options, this inclusion results in the company’s value process being nonlinearly transformed from the original and no longer following the same process. Hence, due to truncation of the distribution of option pay-off, it is very difficult to consistently estimate the volatility of underlying cash flows of the each individual growth option. Moreover, it is not possible to separately identify the effects of individual uncertainty drivers, company-specific factors (like tax shields, etc.) and compound growth options. Based on these considerations, in the current model it is assumed that an individual output factor, rather then a company’s value is exogenous stochastic variable. This uncertainty is then further incorporated into the fundamental variable of a company’s value: the company’s cash flows. These cash flows will therefore be the function of the driving exogenous uncertainty and represent the underlying stochastic process that drives the valuation model. In addition, the use of company’s cash flows provides a greater level of detail in modeling a firm’s business processes and allows accounting for non-linear effects of marginal income taxes, real tax shields, capital structure, etc. First, consider no-growth case when the firm constantly produces and sells the same output S0. Due to exogenous uncertainty, the future value of this output is also uncertain. A common assumption regarding exogenous risk variable is that its current level incorporates all public information available at this point in time and all future fluctuations will be pure random and, thus, modeled as a random walk. Specifically, the 13 exogenous risk faced by a firm with a constant output is characterized as demand uncertainty, Snomt, which follows a continuous-time diffusion process of the form: dS nom = μ ⋅ dt + σ ⋅ dW , where S tnom (1) dW is a standard Wiener process, dW ∈ N (0,1) , while µ is inflation rate in the firm’s product market and σ is volatility of demand changes. Next, for the general case when the firm has the rights to expand capacity, assume that the life of distinctive competitive advantage, during which the firm earns extra economic rents, is T periods, after which shareholders get continuing value depending on a reinvestment policy during high growth period 1 . To simplify the model, the share of variable cost in sales is assumed to be state-independent (although, this assumption can be gradually relaxed to incorporate cost uncertainty). Demand uncertainty is resolved and market opens at times t = 0, 1, …, T. One restriction is placed on the form of demand volatility σ . At any future time t, σ must be modeled as non-stochastic and known with certainty at the time of analysis. Let Snom = {Snom1, Snom2, …, SnomT} denote the (finite) set of possible demand realizations. At each time t, a firm possesses all the information ωt about past states of demand prior to this time. The firm’s beliefs about future states based on information ωt available at the current time t are captured by subjective probabilities p. Given the state of information ωt the firm’s value is written E[ … ׀ωt ] or simply Et[…]. Following Tong and Reuer [2006] who found that firm-specific effects and heterogeneity in the firm’s proprietary options always dominate over industry effects in the value of a firm’s growth options, it is assumed that when considering a reinvestment 1 See Copeland, Weston, Shastri [2005] for deviation of the formula for continuing value. 14 strategy, a firm is engaged only in a game with nature (i.e., exogenous environmental uncertainty) and agents formulate exercise strategies as a response to changes in uncertain market demand in isolation. Reinvestment decision is made at the beginning of the period and uncertainty surrounded demand is fully resolved at the end after the investment installation. Let t be the valuation date and T the growth option expiration date which is bounded by the length of abnormal growth stage for any growth option. To fit the general model of corporate flexibility, I characterize the firm that undertakes only replacement investment to maintain sales and postpones net expansion reinvestment as being in mode mt = 1 (“wait to reinvest”). Once a firm makes both replacement investment and an additional net reinvestment to increase sales, the firm will be operating in mode mt = 2 (“reinvest”). By making net reinvestment of Inewt (ξ), a firm will expand the scale of its operations by a factor ξ. Here, the exercise price of growth option which is represented by net reinvestment costs of capital installation assumed to be nonstochastic and invariant to changes in the exogenous demand. At each state, a firm’s management may execute either strategic decision (wait or reinvest) with each mode having its own free cash flow function FCFmt for mt ∈ (1,2 ) . Operating in the mode 1 entails no switching costs, hence c1 = 0, whereas switching from mode “wait” to mode “reinvest” has the cost in form of net reinvestment, hence, c2 = Inewt(ξ). The cash flow in the interval (t, t+Δt) depends on the value of stochastic variable, Snom t, and on past and current decision modes mt, hence FCFmt =FCF(Snom t, mt, mt-1, …, m0, t) 〜 FCF(Snom t, mt, t). After adjusting for inflation effect, the value of free cash flows from operations (excluding net reinvestments) that are dedicated to mode mt can be expressed as: 15 FCFt (S t , mt , t ) = EBITt (S t , mt , t ) ⋅ (1 − tax ) + At′(mt ) − I treplace (mt ) − dWCt′( mt ) (2) where: EBITt(St, mt, t) – real earnings before interest and taxes which are calculated as: EBITt (S t , mt , t ) = S t (mt , t ) ⋅ (1 − VC ) − At′( mt ) VC is share of variable costs in real sales St, tax is marginal corporate tax rate, At′ is adjusted real depreciation2 , Itreplace is real replacement investment, dWCt′ is adjusted change in working capital. At the end of high-growth stage, future cash flows are represented by continuing value of the firm CVt that can be calculated using simplified formula approach (see Gordon growth model in Copeland, Weston, Shastri [2005]). The valuation algorithm is fulfilled working backwards in a stochastic dynamicprogramming fashion (Dreyfus [1965]) and is similar to numerical methods for valuing American call option on a stock. Unfortunately, closed form solution for a value of a company with multiple American growth options is not available; therefore, I solve the outlined optimization problem numerically by using recombining binomial-decision tree that specifies cash flows associated with management decisions at each uncertain state. The binomial model of Cox, Ross, Rubinstein [1979] gives accurate approximation of continuous Geometric Brownian motion of demand uncertainty with the added 2 In order to match financial statements in nominal and real terms for the firms operating in high-inflation environment, it is critical to adjust the levels of depreciation, interest expense, and changes in working capital (see Copeland, Koller, Murrin [2000] for a detailed discussion of adjustment techniques). 16 advantage of providing necessary flexibility to adapt a model to real world situations and allowing a solution for the value of embedded American options. However, working through traditional recombining lattice becomes computationally cumbersome and non-intuitive if a project involves several compound options and is not suitable for dealing with multiple American growth options. Hence, tree was modified to accommodate the dynamic of uncertain demand and, hence, cash flows both without and with associated American-type growth options. In order for the modified tree to recombine, I imposed following model restrictions: • Companies use straight-line amortization method both for financial reporting and tax purposes. • There are no losses carried forward. • Firms do not have financial constraints and can raise additional debt or equity capital to finance profitable investments. One more condition is fulfilling all the calculations in real terms. Strictly speaking, this is not the restriction because if done properly calculations in real terms match estimations in nominal terms. This is rather technical condition that is necessary to make the tree recombine and reduce the model’s dimension. For example, if the same real volume of invested funds is calculated in nominal monetary terms, the amount of nominal reinvestment will depend on the time of investing due to inflation effect. Hence, level of capital calculated in nominal units at each node will be path dependent and the tree will not recombine. However, if all calculations are done in real monetary terms, path-dependence is eliminated. Applied for other cash inflows and outflows, this logic serves as the basis for the whole methodology and secures the practical applicability of Bellman algorithm. 17 Applying conventional binomial model for the case of a firm producing constant output under demand uncertainty, the next period nominal sales can go up by factor u with objective probability p or down by factor d with probability 1-p: Insert figure 1 here Factors u and d are the functions of dispersion in demand growth rate σ : u = exp(σ ⋅ k −1 ) , d = 1 u , where (3) k is number of time steps in one period (used to increase a sample of the binomial distribution in order to improve the approximation to GBM). Transition probability among states p is the function of consumer inflation rate µ and up/down factors: p= 1+ μ k − d u−d (4) Next, let St (j, q) indicate the volume of real sales at period t when demand jumped up jtimes, down t-j times and management executed growth reinvestment q-times before the period t. Assume that management has the rights (growth options) to execute net reinvestments in any period during abnormal growth phase; therefore, q may range from zero (no growth case) to t. Mathematically, sales at each state (j, q) is equal initial level of sales S0 multiplied by factor uj and dt-j due to market uncertainty and by expansion factor ξ(q) due to reinvestments executed by the firm’s management (and adjusted finally by inflation index 1+µ): 18 q S t ( j, q ) = So ⋅ u j ⋅ d t − j ⋅ ∏ ξ i (1 + μ ) i =0 t , where (5) 0 ≤ j ≤ t , 0 ≤ q ≤ t , ξi – expansion factor of i-th growth option. On figure 2 is shown the fragment of multinomial recombining tree containing information about states of uncertain demand conditioned upon the past states and decision policies and currently possible decision modes at each state. Due to the fact that all cash flows in the model are estimated in real terms, the final tree of underlying cash flows from operations possesses the recombining property similar to the tree depicted in figure 2 that dramatically reduces the computational complexity of the model from order 2n to order (n+1)2. Insert figure 2 here Given that a firm at each state is operating in a particular mode, the present value of future cash ( flows given optimal behaviour henceforth is ) denoted Λ t FCF (S t + Δt , mt + Δt , t + Δt ) S t , mt , t . Optimal behaviour assumes that a firm will maximize the value of current payoff plus the present value of expected future payoffs net of switching costs. At each uncertain state the optimization algorithm compares the conditional expected value from waiting with the conditional expected value of immediate reinvesting. In my notation, the dynamic Bellman equation can be written as (where the firm arrives at time t operating at mode mt with possible switching to mode lt+△t=1,2): 19 ( ) Λ t FCF (S t + Δt , mt + Δt , t + Δt ) S t , mt , t = { (( = max FCF (S t , mt , t ) − cl + ρ ⋅ E t Λ FCF (S t + Δt , l ... m0 , t + Δt ) S t , mt , t l (6) ))} where ρ denotes the risk-adjusted discount rate. At terminal period T we have boundary condition that reflects payoffs of available options: ( ) Λ T FCF (S T + Δt , mT + Δt , T + Δt ) S T , mT , T = { (( = max FCF (S T , mT , T ) − cl + ρ ⋅ ET Λ CV (S T + Δt , l ... m0 , T + Δt ) S T , mT , T l ))} (7) Where CV(l) (l=1,2) denotes continuing value of a firm at stable growth period in case of “wait” and “reinvest” decisions. At this step in order to value future cash flows that depend on uncertain state variable, S, and can be modified by reinvestment decisions, q, it is necessary to derive the appropriate discount rates in order to reflect properly the changing risk levels of these cash flows. Traditional corporate DCF model discounts expected future cash flows by risk-adjusted rate which is usually represented by weighted average cost of capital. However, this approach does not provide a correct valuation for growth options. The reason is that, if management decide to switch to “reinvest” mode, this decision will change the expected future cash flows, and thereby alters the original risk profile of the company. Thus, original WACC can no longer be considered as a suitable measure of future corporate risks and it is necessary to apply different discount rate to adjust for changed risk of cash flows. The best method is to make these cash flows riskless and then discount them by risk free rate. Traditional procedure in option theory is to 20 construct a replicating portfolio with B units of risk-free asset and l units of a traded underlying asset that generates cash flows which exactly match the option’s future uncertain payoffs at all times and in all states. To justify the arbitrage-free valuation for the general case of a company with growth options, I used the Marketed Asset Disclaimer (MAD) approach as in Copeland and Antikarov [2001]. The fundamental assumption underlying MAD approach is that the fair value of a non-traded underlying asset without any flexibility options is “the price the asset would have if it were traded” (Mason and Merton [1985]) and various embedded options are treated as if they were assets whose cash flows are derived from the value of that underlying asset without options. Hence, the present value of a company’s cash flows without any growth options is characterized as a traded security to construct a portfolio that replicates the payoffs of cash flows with growth options. The value of a company without growth options is represented exactly by the current value of a firm’s “assets-in-place” which may be consistently determined using traditional DCF analysis by applying original WACC to discount expected cash flows. The dynamic value of a company with growth opportunities is then replicated by the firm’s assets-in-place and risk-free asset and estimated via traditional option pricing techniques. It should be noted that using the framework of recombining tree it is easy and intuitively clear to construct replicating portfolios for estimating the value of different managerial alternatives. I provide an example of computational procedure with 2 growth options for two-period tree that is enough to understand the algorithm which can be extended to any number of periods and options. Let me again present a recombining tree similar to the one described in figure 2, but now in each node will be Free Cash Flow (FCF) estimated in formula (2) (see figure 3). At node j, slightly changed notation FCFt (uj, dt-j, ξq) 21 characterises cash flow in case market demand jumped up j times, down t-j times and new reinvestments to bring this cash flow were executed q times (t is period of estimation, j = t to 0). First, consider a node belonging to a path where management were choosing “wait” mode in every state of nature (for example, node FCF1(u)). In this case, the present value of the expected future cash flows is equal to the value of cash flows generated by the company’s assets-in-place at time 0 which can be determined using traditional corporate DCF model by taking the real expectations Et over possible realizations of FCF and discounting them by a company’s WACC at initial time t = 0: PV wait (FCF1 (u )) = FCF2 (u 2 ) ⋅ p + FCF2 (u, d ) ⋅ (1 − p ) 1 + WACC (8) Further, under the MAD assumption, expected FCF without growth options calculated in formula (8) are considered as if they were a traded asset, and used to replicate the payoffs (cash flows) of the “reinvest” mode for the current node. Then algorithm moves on the lower branch where management have already executed one growth option (“reinvestment” decision) at a previous time point. Similarly, it is necessary to estimate the arbitrage free expected value of FCF in case of „wait“ and “reinvest” modes for a current node (FCF1(u,ξ)). However, due to the tree recombining property „wait“ decision at the current node FCF1(u,ξ) exactly equals the value of „reinvest“ mode of the node at the upper branch, FCF1(u). The latter value has been already calculated using arbitrage free principle at the previous step and, hence, is used to replicate the payoffs of the “reinvest” mode for the current node. The similar procedures presented in the figure 3 are then applied sequentially to other nodes and the present values of all other cash flows are estimated. 22 Insert figure 3 here Moving backwards and repeating all the steps, one can solve both for the arbitrage free value of the company at initial node and the optimal strategic mode at each uncertain state. The calculated amount will represent the value of the company whose management has flexibility to choose optimal reinvestment strategy in case of uncertainty. IV. NUMERICAL EXAMPLE I illustrate the valuation of a company with many growth options by applying it to a hypothetical corporation XYZ. The abnormal growth phase was assumed to be 7 periods during which the company’s management has the right to execute 7 growth options. To achieve the desired probability distribution, the number of sub-periods was set to 40 per period. Numerical assumptions for three growth scenarios are summarised in Appendix A. Corporate DCF model’s estimations of moderate growth scenario with 20% volatility in demand produced following valuations 3 : Assets in place (no growth case): 41,148 million yen Assets in place plus Net reinvestments (growth case): 84,254 million yen The calculations based on the described model gave the company value of 86,339 million yen, which is 2.5% bigger than DCF “growth case”. If accounts only for the value of growth opportunities, which in case of DCF model equals 43,107 million yen and in case of proposed real option model 45,191 million yen, DCF results in 4.8 % 3 Continuing value was estimated simplistically assuming no growth in cash flows in stable period. 23 undervaluing of the company’s growth options because of inability to account for management flexibility. I now examine the impact of greater uncertainty on the value of a corporation. Following the concept of mean-preserving spread as in Rothschild and Stiglitz [1970], the increase of uncertainty over demand parameter S is defined in such a way that it does not affect its mean. Both in the field of real option theory and strategic management, it has been remarked that the value of real options is positively related to the underlying uncertainty. In case of increasing market uncertainty, the value of installed growth options should also increase since the possible loss is limited to the initial investment and the potential gains from future growth opportunities has no upper bound (Kulatilaka and Perotti [1998]). Hence, overall firm’s value should be positively linked to the value and uncertainty of the underlying cash flows that can be acquired through potential exercise of the growth options included in them. Insert figure 4 here Figure 4 summarizes the results of simulations of the mean-preserving increases in volatility of demand changes and its effects on the values of the firm and its growth options. The results suggest that the value of portfolio of compound growth options is strictly increasing with the uncertainty over demand S. The figure 5 further clarifies that the impact of volatility depends also on the degree of future potential growth gained by exercising the strategic growth options. It shows that companies which expect high sales growth with high volatility have much higher flexibility premium defined as: 24 Flexibility premium = Value of the firm with flexibility −1 DCF Value of the firm (9) Insert figure 5 here Next, I investigate critical values of demand, S, that trigger option execution at different growth scenarios. Figure 6 shows low-sales-growth scenario for different values of demand volatility with appropriate critical boundary at which it is optimal to execute growth reinvestment conditioned upon the previous waiting/reinvesting decisions (or in other words, on the level of capital stock at time t). Insert figure 6 here The optimal investment policy given the capital level at each period t is “wait” when actual level of sales lies lower critical boundary space and “reinvest” if actual level of demand exceeds the boundary. Clearly, higher expected demand favours reinvestments and reduces the value of waiting, whereas higher volatility lowers the critical threshold and induces early reinvestment. Next figure emphasizes the non-linear effect of growth and volatility on a firm’s investment behavior. In figure 7 depicted the company that faces the same demand uncertainty as the company XYZ, but expects much higher growth rates of demand in future and, respectively, must invest more heavily in fixed capital to maintain growth. Insert figure 7 here 25 Higher expected growth achieved through executing real options and, respectively, higher levels of installed capital increase the absolute value of investment threshold; however, the portfolio of growth options is more valuable under high uncertainty and reinvestment will be committed even when the level of current demand is low. Now I examine the effect of the heterogeneity in resources and capabilities on investment patterns in relation to option creation and exercise. From a resource-based view, one may argue that the optimal management of real options requires managerial efforts that are enabled and constrained by firm-specific resources and capabilities. Using numerical example, I show that different firms facing the same opportunity may display different investment behaviour. Assume that there are 3 firms facing the same demand uncertainty and the same growth prospects, but having differences in capital productivity, say, high, average and low productivity of capital. The results of the simulations are presented in Figure 8. Insert figure 8 here Figure 8 shows that a firm with high productivity of capital invest at much lower levels of demand compare to its less productive competitors; hence, a capital-effective firm is much more alert in dynamic environment and react quicker to changes in uncertain market demand. Respectively, one of the conclusions of the current study is the proposition that when managers of highly productive companies have the bundle of 26 successive growth options, they may be willing to accept lower levels of current performance thresholds in order to gain access to future growth options. Using the framework of the current model, it is also possible to observe the effects of constraints on the exercise of growth options in the corporate portfolio. Consider the situation of two identical companies that face the same demand uncertainty, but one firm can choose m growth options whereas the other can execute only m – k options (here, k is any positive number less then m) determined by the firms’ capital capacity and the strength of competitive advantage. For example, the firm-2 can have production capacity constraints limiting the number of available investments. Notwithstanding the value of k variable, the model’s results presented in table 1 show the nonlinearity of the differences between the values of companies with different level of flexibility provided by growth options. Insert table 1 here Finally, I show the effect of corporate tax rate on the value of a firm’s growth options. Taxes influence on cash flows in non-linear way, since they are levied in case there is taxable income, and not if the firm incurs current loss. Figure 9 shows that although absolute value of portfolio of growth option linearly decreases with marginal tax rate, the value of management flexibility is much more profound at higher levels of uncertainty and in high tax regime environments. Insert figure 9 here 27 It can be seen from the analysis that the presence of firm-specific effects expands the critical parameters in the real option analysis of determinants of a firm’s investment behaviour from the focus on demand volatility to also inclusion of taxes, market potential, which can be measured by attainable sales expansion ratio, and marginal efficiency of capital and new investment. The current framework integrates all these firm-specific factors and effectively captures the portfolio effects of a firm’s growth options. IV.1. DISCUSSION The following discussion focuses on comparison between proposed algorithm and other alternative numerical methods of valuing corporations and multiple American options embedded in firm’s growth: namely, corporate DCF, decision binomial trees and binomial lattices. The key advantage of the current paper is that it integrates corporate valuation with the real option framework and allows quantitative estimation of how capital allocation made in any year can enhance the company’s value under uncertainty. Such “optionbased” thinking provides new focus for corporate CFOs by shifting the emphasis from choosing projects with maximum static NPV to paying attention to NPV maximizing flexible reinvesting policy. It was shown that the values and insights from the proposed analysis may be significantly different from DCF model that assumes predetermined reinvestment pattern and uses subjectively defined risk-adjusted discount rate to calculate the present value of corporate cash flows. Concerning the real option applications, the use of the MAD assumption (Copeland and Antikarov [2001]) has 28 been criticized in that the value of a non-traded asset without flexibility, which is used to create a complete market, cannot be tested empirically and, hence, may lead to significant errors in estimation of the value of option on that asset. However, the described model recognizes the value of the company’s current assets-in-place as the basis for arbitrage-free replicating for the company’s growth options. This value is usually observable on the market or can be estimated by direct comparisons with peer companies and, hence, the model’s results can be empirically tested. The main drawback of traditional binomial lattices is in that that they do not deal with multiple American growth options that are compound and path-dependent. As an alternative, non-recombining binomial decision trees were proposed that can handle potentially any number of American type growth options. The current model is able to capture the same number of American type growth options; however, the computational procedure is more efficient. The straight-forward computation at each node j of nonrecombining tree at each period t would require 2j calculations ( j ∈ [0, t ] ), whereas with the proposed recombining tree, the number of endpoints is equal to (j+1)2. Model of this dimension can be implemented in Excel by writing a VBA code or directly in a spreadsheet. The difference in size become much more pronounced if somebody considers more periods, either by increased length of abnormal growth period or finer time steps. I further conducted a test of the computational performance of real option evaluation using proposed recombining binomial tree. According to Hull [2003], solving a lattice with number of periods 30 or more gives reasonable results; therefore, I used it as an upper limit for the testing range. The results were obtained using notebook with Intel(R) Core(TM)2 Duo 1.20 GHz processor and 0.99 Gb RAM. As indicated in figure 10, recombining binomial tree is computationally very efficient especially for 29 cases with large number of options or when a high degree of accuracy is required. In contrast, the binomial tree as in Brandao, Dyer, Hahn [2005] requires several hours to evaluate using the powerful professional decision tree software. Insert figure 10 here Figure 11 depicts the visual layout of the model’s output example. Providing the same clarity in visualising threshold values as a non-recombining decision tree, the recombining tree is visually more compact and helps the management structure the investment choice problem by mapping out all feasible alternatives contingent on the uncertain “nature” moves in a clear-cut hierarchical manner. The author believes that practical financial managers, even without technical background in real options, can grasp the fundamental properties of the recombining decision tree. Insert figure 11 here Finally, real option theory with its origin in stochastic calculus is not a theory of a firm that focuses on organizational and behavioural issues. Hence, no quantitative decisionmaking technique can guarantee the optimal policy and substitute for proper managerial efforts and discretion. Therefore, for further research it is crucial to consider also various organizational and managerial issues that can stimulate or, on the contrary, limit the optimal execution of real growth options in business practice. 30 V. CONCLUSION Major source of value from growth reinvestments arises from their ability to enhance the upside cash generating capacity of a corporation during favourable market conditions by making follow-on expansion reinvestments. Myers [1987] observed that “the standard discounted cash flow techniques will tend to understate the option value attached to growing, profitable lines of business” and that “the most promising line of research is to try to use option pricing theory to model the time-series interactions between investments”. Trying to address this issue, current article contributes to existing corporate finance literature in several directions: z It develops a general model of corporate flexibility where a company pursuing organic growth uses capacity as a strategic variable to adjust discretely to a stochastic demand. Each period a company may operate in two modes (wait or reinvest) with costly switching that provides a set of multiple American-type compound options. z It provides a modelling framework for valuing multiple growth options embedded in corporate growth, which are essentially compound American options on American options. z Finally, it validates a computationally effective tool for valuing corporations providing an alternative to traditional corporate DCF model. 31 Described methodology shows that the combined value of multiple growth options can be quite large and that corporate DCF criterion which does not account for these options can be misleading. In general, generating the growth options should drive the corporate value. At the same time, as growth reinvestments are costly and may be (partially) irreversible, it is not certain that this generating process is always done efficiently and creates value for shareholders. Applied dynamic-programming framework enables a computationally feasible evaluation of the effects of many such growth options. Proposed model explicitly accounts both for exogenous (market demand) and endogenous (net reinvestments) determinants of the firm’s growth and shows that binomial model combined with decision tree analysis allows quantitative estimation of optimal reaction of a firm to uncertain nature moves. The primary advantage of this approach is that it provides greater transparency in the modelling of real growth options of a company by focusing on individual uncertainty factor that drives company’s future cash flows. The methodology also provides clear threshold information for management (for example: based on currently employed capital, invest if and only if sales reach the level of $X), because the model explicitly accounts for the values of each individual cash flow in every period. Hence, applying Marketed Asset Disclaimer for a firm’s current assets-in-place, the model offers arbitrage free algorithm for corporate valuation that properly accounts for changing risk profiles in each period depending on reinvestment decisions. As was noted in the introductory sections, a big challenge to empirical research in strategic management under the real option framework is the difficulty in measurement of the value of a firm’s growth opportunities. The current study addresses this issue and provides theoretically consistent and computationally effective algorithm for future 32 studies to improve the precision in measuring corporate growth options using public accounting data. Recombining property of the final tree of FCF allows improving the accuracy of the model output by increasing the number of subperiods without placing excessive burden on computer memory. Moreover, the algorithm, although complicated, does not use higher mathematics; therefore, it can be effectively presented to decisionmakers. Presented model may be also used to incorporate other risk factors such as cost uncertainty for companies with volatile variable costs or foreign exchange rate uncertainty for firms with high export/import exposure. The methodology has also parallel application, because if slightly modified it can be used to value switching options when the number of alternative assets is (infinitely) large. This paper is not without limitations. It is based on several restrictive assumptions concerning the real cash flows and does not account for the effects of competitive interactions in the value of portfolio of growth real options and optimal investment decisions. Future research should address the mentioned limitations, as well as empirically test the arguments presented. 33 VI. REFERENCES [1]. Berger P., Ofek E., Swary I. (1996) “Investor valuation of the abandonment option”, Journal of financial economics, 63 (2). [2]. Black F. and Scholes M. (1973) “The pricing of options and corporate liabilities”, Journal of Political economy, 81 (May/June). [3]. Brandao L. E., Dyer J. S., Hahn W. J. (2005) “Using Binomial Decision Trees to Solve Real-Option Valuation Problems”, Decision Analysis, Vol. 2 (2), June. [4]. Campa J. (1994) “Multinational investment under uncertainty in the chemical processing industries”, Journal of international business studies, 25(3). [5]. Copeland T., Koller T., Murrin J. (2000) Valuation: measuring and managing the value of companies, 3rd ed., McKinsey & Company, Inc. [6]. Copeland T., Antikarov V. (2001) Real options: a practitioner's guide, Texere. [7]. Copeland T. and Antikarov V. (2005) “Real Options: Meeting the Georgetown Challenge”, Journal of applied corporate finance, Volume 17 (2). [8]. Copeland T. and Tufano P. (2004) “A Real-World Way to Manage Real Options”, Harvard Business review, March. [9]. Copeland T., Weston J. F., Shastri K. (2005) Financial theory and corporate policy, 4th ed., Pearson Addison Wesley. [10]. Cox J. C., Ross S. A., Rubinstein M. (1979) “Option Pricing: A Simplified Approach.”, Journal of Financial Economics, 7. [11]. Damodaran A. (2001) Corporate finance: theory and practice, 2nd ed., John Wiley (Wiley series in finance). [12]. Damodaran A. (2002) Investment valuation: tools and techniques for determining the value of any asset, 2nd ed., John Wiley & Sons. [13]. Danbolt J., Hall B, and Jones E. (2002) “Measuring growth opportunities”, Applied financial economics, 12(3). [14]. Dixit A. K. and Pindyck R. S. (1994) Investment under uncertainty, Princeton University Press. [15]. Dreyfus S. E. (1965) Dynamic programming and the calculus of variations, Academic Press. 34 [16]. Folta T. and O’Brien J. (2004) “Entry in the presence of duelling options”, Strategic management journal, 19(11). [17]. Folta T., Johnson D., O’Brien J.(2006) “Uncertainty, irreversibility, and the likelihood of entry: An empirical assessment of the option to defer”, Journal of economic behaviour and organization, 61. [18]. Ghosal V. and Loungani (2000) “The differential impact of uncertainty on investment in small and large businesses”, Review of Economics and Statistics, 44. [19]. Graham J. R. and Harvey C. R. (2001) “The theory and practice of corporate finance: evidence from the field”, Journal of Financial Economics, Volume 60 (23). [20]. Hall B. (2000) “Innovation and market value”, in Barrel R. and Omahoney M. Productivity, innovation and economic performance, Cambridge: Cambridge University press. [21]. Hull J. (2003) “Options, futures, and other derivatives”, Prentice Hall, NJ. [22]. Kellogg D. and Charnes J. M. (2000) “Real-Options Valuation for a Biotechnology Company”, Association for Investment Management and Research. [23]. Kester W. (1984) “Today’s options for tomorrow’s growth”, Harvard Business Review, 62 (March-April). [24]. Kogut B. (1991) “Joint ventures and the option to expand and acquire”, Management science, 37(1). [25]. Kogut B. and Kulatilaka N. (1994) „Option thinking and platform investments: Investing in opportunity“, California management review, 36. [26]. Kogut B. and Kulatilaka N. (2001) „Capabilities as real options“, Organization science, 37(1). [27]. Kulatilaka N. and Perotti E. (1998) “Strategic growth options”, Management science, 44. [28]. Lander D. M., Pinches G. E. (1998) “Challenges to the Practical Implementation of Modeling and Valuing Real Options”, The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 38, Special Issue. [29]. Levitas E. and Chi T. (2001) “A real option perspective on the market valuation of a firm’s technological competence”, Academy of Management best conference paper, BPS. [30]. Luehrman T. A. (1998) “Investment Opportunities as Real Options: Getting Started on the Numbers”, Harward Business Review, July-August. 35 [31]. Mason S. and Merton R. (1985) “The role of contingent claim analysis in corporate finance” in E. Altman and M. Subrahymanyam (Eds.), Recent advances in corporate finance, Irwin, Boston, MA. [32]. McDonald R. and Siegel D. (1985) “Investment and the valuation of firms when there is an option to shut down”, International Economic review, 26. [33]. McDonald R. and Siegel D. (1986) “The value of waiting to invest”, Quarterly journal of economics, 101, 4 (November). [34]. McGrath R. and Nerkar A. (2004) “Real option reasoning and a new look at the R&D investment strategies of pharmaceutical firms”, Strategic management journal, 25. [35]. METI (2003-04) Setsubitoushichousa, http://www.meti.go.jp/statistics/ [36]. Mun J. (2002) Real options analysis: tools and techniques for valuing strategic investments and decisions, Wiley. [37]. Mun J. (2004) Real Options and Monte Carlo Simulation versus Traditional DCF Valuation in Layman’s Terms, www.crystalball.com/articles/download/ro-vsdcf.pdf. [38]. Myers S. C. (1977) “Determinants of corporate borrowing”, Journal of Financial Economics, 5, 2 November. [39]. Myers S. C. (1987) “Finance theory and Financial strategy”, Midland corporate finance journal 5, 1 (Spring). [40]. Ogawa K., Suzuki K. (2000) “Uncertainty and investment: some evidence from the panel data of Japanese manufacturing firms”, The Japanese economic review, vol. 51, no. 2, June. [41]. Panayi S., Trigeorgis L. (1998) “Multi-stage Real Options: The Cases of Information Technology Infrastructure and International Bank Expansion”, The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 38, Special Issue. [42]. Pindyck R. (1988) “Irreversible investment, capacity choice, and the value of the firm”, American Economic Review, 78, 5 (December). [43]. Philippe H. (2005) “Corporate governance: a new limit to Real Option valuation?”, Journal of management and governance, (2005) 9. [44]. Rothschild M. and Stiglitz J. (1970) “Increasing risk: a definition”, Journal of economic theory, 2 (September). [45]. Edited by E. S. Schwartz and L. Trigeorgis (2004) Real options and investment under uncertainty: classical readings and recent contribution, MIT Press. 36 [46]. Samuelson P.(1965) “Proof that properly anticipated prices fluctuate randomly”, Industrial management review, Spring. [47]. Smit H.T.J., Trigeorgis L. (2004) Strategic investment: real options and games, Princeton University Press. [48]. Smith J. (2005) “Alternative approaches for solving real-option problems (comment on Brandao et. al. 2005)”, Decision analysis, vol.2, no. 2, June. [49]. Triantis A. (2001) “Real Options: State of the Practice”, Journal of applied corporate finance, vol. 14 (2). [50]. Triantis A. (2005) “Realizing the Potential of Real Options: Does Theory Meet Practice?”, Journal of applied corporate finance, vol. 17 (2). [51]. Trigeorgis L. (1993) “The nature of option interactions and the valuation of investments with multiple real options”, Journal of financial and quantitative analysis 28, 1 (March). [52]. Trigeorgis L. (1996) “Real options”, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. [53]. Tong T. and Reuer J. (2006) “Firm and industry influences on the value of growth options”, Strategic organization, 4(1). 37 VII. APPENDIX A List of assumptions for numerical examples in the text: Scenario of demand conditions High sales growth Moderate sales growth Low sales growth 1 162.0% 130.0% 107.0% Sales expansion factor of i-th growth option, i: 2 3 4 5 6 7 150.0% 145.0% 142.0% 129.0% 114.0% 109.0% 125.0% 120.0% 117.0% 114.0% 111.0% 108.0% 106.5% 106.0% 105.5% 105.0% 104.5% 104.0% Capital efficiency Assumption 4.73 yen of sales per 1 yen of capital 5 yen of sales per 1 yen of capital Average productivity of initial assets-in-place Marginal productivity of new investment Income Statement Initial level of sales 61,500 million yen Length of high growth phase 7 periods Sales expansion factor at stable growth phase 100.8% Variable cost of sales 90.0% Marginal income tax 40.7% Balance Sheet Working capital, % of sales 4.9% Initial fixed capital 13,000 million yen Remaining usage life 7 periods Capital structure Net debt ratio 19.8% After-tax nominal cost of debt 0.6% Nominal cost of equity 9.0% Real WACC 6.9% Market Consumer inflation rate 0.5% Inflation of capital assets 1.0% Real risk free rate 1.0% 38 Figure 1. Demand uncertainty experienced by a firm with constant output S0. S0*u p S0 1-p S0*d 39 Figure 2. Fragment of recombining decision/binomial tree for reinvestment policy in sales expansion *. Now Year 1 Year 2 u wait d S1(1,0)=S0*u S2(2,0)=S0*u2 S2 (2,1)=S0*u2* ξ u reinvest d u S2 (2,2)=S0*u2* ξ2 u d wait d u S1(1,1)=S0*u* ξ S2 (1,0)=S0*u*d reinvest d wait S2(1,1)=S0*u*d* ξ S0 u reinvest d wait u S2 (1,2)=S0*u*d* ξ2 u S1(0,0)=S0*d reinvest d u d d S2(0,0)=S0*d2 wait u S1(0,1)=S0*d*ξ reinvest S2(0,1)=S0*d2* ξ d S2(0,2)=S0*d2* ξ2 * Inflation adjustment parameter is hided for preserving space. “Wait” means execution of replacement investment to maintain sales and postponement of net reinvestment. “Reinvest” means execution both replacement investment and net reinvestment to increase sales. For expositional simplicity and without loss of the generality, sales expansion factor ξ is represented by a constant. 40 Figure 3. Applying MAD to properly value forecasted cash flows for 2-period model with 2 American-type growth options. STEP 1. Calculate the value of “wait” decision for a path with cash flows generated by the firm’s original assets-in-place using objective probabilities and WACC discount rate. STEP 2. Construct replicating portfolio to estimate arbitrage free value of “reinvest” decision. STEP 3. Choose maximum value at decision node. u wait d FCF1(u) FCF2(u2) FCF 2 (u2, ξ) u reinvest d u FCF 2 (u2, ξ2) u d wait d u FCF1(u, ξ) FCF 2(u, d) reinvest d wait FCF 2 (u, d, ξ) FCF0 u reinvest d wait u FCF 2 (u, d, ξ2) u FCF1(d) reinvest d u d d FCF 2 (d2) wait u FCF1(d, ξ) reinvest FCF 2 (d2, ξ) d FCF 2 (d2, ξ2) Terminal period t=1 Period t=2 STEP 4. Go to lower branch decision node with already installed additional capital: here the value of “wait” decision has been calculated at step 2. STEP 5. Repeat steps 2 and 3. STEP 6. Repeat steps 1 – 5 for decision nodes in all other states. 41 Figure 4. Value of the firm as a function of volatility of demand changes. million yen Flexibility value 120,000 100,000 80,000 Value of growth opportunities 60,000 40,000 70.0% 67.5% 65.0% 62.5% 57.5% 60.0% 55.0% 52.5% 50.0% 47.5% 45.0% 42.5% 40.0% 37.5% 35.0% 32.5% 30.0% 27.5% 25% 22.5% 20.0% 17.5% 15.0% 12.5% 7.5% 10.0% 0 5.0% 20,000 Volatility of sales growth, % Value of the firm with flexible growth strategy (real option value) Value of the firm's current assets in place Value of the firm with fixed growth strategy (DCF value) Inputs: Moderate sales growth scenario. Figure 5. Flexibility premium of different growth scenarios as a function of volatility of demand changes. Flexibility premium, % 70% 60% 50% Low sales growth Moderate sales growth 40% High sales growth 30% 20% 10% 0% 5.0% 10.0% 15.0% 20.0% 25% 30.0% 35.0% 40.0% 45.0% 50.0% 55.0% 60.0% 65.0% Volatility of sales growth, % 42 70.0% Figure 6. Boundary space of critical values of sales that trigger reinvestments as a function of capital level (previously installed options) and the time of option execution (in parenthesis are shown the number of growth options executed in previous periods). Volatility of sales growth: 10% Volatility of sales growth: 30% 40,000 40,000 35,000 35,000 30,000 30,000 (5) (6) (Million yen) (3) Level of (4) capital (Million yen) (5) (6) 1 2 3 4 5 6 Period (1) (2) Level of capital (3) (Million yen) Inputs: Low sales growth scenario. 43 (4) 16,375 (2) 16,375 (1) 13,861 Period 20,000 14,716 3 20,000 13,000 1 2 6 20,997 (4) 16,375 (3) 20,997 Level of capital 15,557 13,861 (2) 14,716 13,000 (1) 4 5 25,000 “Wait” zone 25,000 15,557 25,000 (5) 20,997 30,000 15,557 35,000 13,861 40,000 20,000 45,000 45,000 14,716 45,000 Sales “Reinvest” zone Sales 13,000 Sales Volatility of sales growth: 50% (6) 1 2 3 4 5 6 Period Figure 7. Boundary space of critical values of sales that trigger reinvestments as a function of capital level (previously installed options) and the time of option execution (in parenthesis are shown the number of growth options executed in previous periods). Volatility of sales growth: 10% Volatility of sales growth: 30% . Sales Sales 250,000 250,000 200,000 200,000 150,000 150,000 100,000 100,000 50,000 (5) (6) (Million yen) (2) Level of capital (3) (4) 62,241 (1) 30,589 Period 0 13,000 3 0 20,626 2 6 (5) (Million yen) 80,088 (4) 1 4 5 44,039 (3 ) 80,088 Level of capital 44,039 (2) 62,241 (1) 30,589 20,626 13,000 50,000 (6) 1 2 3 4 5 6 Period (1) (2) Level of capital (3) (Million yen) Inputs: High sales growth scenario. 44 (4) (5) 80,088 50,000 44,039 100,000 62,241 150,000 30,589 200,000 13,000 250,000 20,626 Sales 0 Volatility of sales growth: 50% (6) 1 2 3 4 5 6 Period Figure 8. The effect of heterogeneity in firm’s capabilities on demand threshold values. Average productivity of capital at t = 0: 3.1 yen (sales) per yen (capital) Sales Sales (4) (5) (6) (2) Level of capital (3) (4) (5) (6) 1 3 4 Period (1) (2) Level of capital 21,041 2 (3) (4) 29,488 Period (1) 13,000 5 5 25,223 2 4 20,000 6 (5) 33,597 1 3 6 40,000 51,455 (3) 101,535 Level of capital 76,516 (2) 89,258 (1) 64,023 51,531 40,000 70,000 38,666 120,000 60,000 45,180 170,000 80,000 32,280 220,000 100,000 20,000 160,000 140,000 120,000 100,000 80,000 60,000 40,000 20,000 270,000 25,895 Sales 20,000 High productivity of capital at t = 0: 4.8 yen (sales) per yen (capital) 16,860 Low productivity of capital at t = 0: 1.5 yen (sales) per yen (capital) (6) Inputs: Moderate sales growth scenario, Volatility of sales growth – 20 %, Number of available options in the whole high growth period -7, Length of high growth phase – 7 periods, number of simulated time steps in one period – 40. 45 1 2 3 4 5 6 Period Table 1. Difference between corporate values of firms with different supply of growth options. Firm-N, Number of growth options N: 1 2 3 4 5 6 Value of Firm-M Firm-M, Number of growth options M: 1 2 3 4 5 6 Value of Firm-N 0 (7,848) (15,148) (22,084) (28,294) (33,440) 7,848 0 (7,300) (14,236) (20,446) (25,592) 15,148 7,300 0 (6,936) (13,145) (18,292) 22,084 14,236 6,936 0 (6,209) (11,355) 28,294 20,446 13,145 6,209 0 (5,146) 33,440 25,592 18,292 11,355 5,146 0 48,905 56,753 64,054 70,990 77,199 82,345 48,905 56,753 64,054 70,990 77,199 82,345 Inputs: Moderate sales growth scenario, Volatility of sales growth – 20 %, Number of available options in the whole high growth period – variable. 46 Figure 9. Value of a firm and flexibility premium as a function of corporate tax rate and expansion rates. million yen 160,000 140,000 120,000 100,000 80,000 60,000 40,000 20,000 0 10.0% 15.0% 20.0% 25.0% 30.0% 35.0% 40.0% 45.0% 50% 55.0% 60.0% Marginal tax rate, % Value of the firm with flexible growth strategy (real option value) Value of the firm's current assets in place Value of the firm with fixed growth strategy (DCF value) Inputs: Moderate sales growth scenario, Volatility of sales growth – 40 %. Volatility of sales growth: 15% Volatility of sales growth: 40% Flexibility premium, % Flexibility premium, % 8% 60% 7% 50% Low sales growth 6% Moderate sales growth 5% Moderate sales growth 40% High sales growth 4% Low sales growth High sales growth 30% 3% 20% 2% 10% 1% Marginal tax rate, % 60 .0 % 55 .0 % 50 % 45 .0 % 40 .0 % 35 .0 % 30 .0 % 25 .0 % 20 .0 % 15 .0 % 10 .0 % 60 .0 % 55 .0 % 50 % 45 .0 % 40 .0 % 35 .0 % 30 .0 % 25 .0 % 20 .0 % 0% 15 .0 % 10 .0 % 0% Marginal tax rate, % 47 Figure 10. Computational efficiency of the proposed model*. Total computational time, minutes 13 10 8 5 3 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 (30) (60) (90) (120) (150) (180) (210) (240) (270) (300) Number of growth options (Total number of time steps in the model) * Number of simulated time steps in one period – 30, total number of time steps is shown in parenthesis. 48 Figure 11. Example of presentation of optimal reinvestment strategy in sales growth dependent on the changes in state of nature. Now Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 u wait d S1(1,0)=S0*u S2(2,0)=S0*u2 S2 (2,1)=S0*u2* ξ u reinvest d u reinvest S2 (2,2)=S0*u2* ξ2 … u d wait d u S1(1,1)=S0*u* ξ S2 (1,0)=S0*u*d reinvest d wait wait S2(1,1)=S0*u*d* ξ S0 u reinvest d wait u wait 2 S2 (1,2)=S0*u*d* ξ … … u S1(0,0)=S0*d reinvest d u d d S2(0,0)=S0*d2 wait wait u S1(0,1)=S0*d*ξ S2(0,1)=S0*d2* ξ d reinvest S2(0,2)=S0*d2* ξ2 49 …