Institutional Distance and the Multinational Enterprise Author(s): Dean Xu and Oded Shenkar Source: The Academy of Management Review, Vol. 27, No. 4 (Oct., 2002), pp. 608-618 Published by: Academy of Management Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/4134406 Accessed: 23/02/2010 01:11 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=aom. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Academy of Management is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Academy of Management Review. http://www.jstor.org &Academy of Management Review 2002,Vol. 27, No. 4, 608-618. NOTE DISTANCEAND THE INSTITUTIONAL ENTERPRISE MULTINATIONAL DEANXU Peking University ODED SHENKAR The Ohio State University We draw from the recently developed construct of institutional distance to propose a framework that explains foreign direct investment by the multinational enterprise. We decompose the institutional distance between the host and home countries into distances on the regulative, normative, and cognitive dimensions of institutions, and match these with firm-level attributes to produce propositions regarding host country selection and foreign market entry strategies. In this note we focus on a newly developed measure of cross-country differences-institutional distance (Kostova, 1999;Kostova & Zaheer, 1999)-to explain multinational enterprise (MNE) behavior. Institutional distance is the extent of similarity or dissimilarity between the regulatory, cognitive, and normative institutions of two countries (Kostova, 1996).It is derived from institutional theory-a nonefficiency perspective in which institutional environment is seen as the key determinant of firm structure and behavior (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983, 1991;Scott, 1995).We focus on the MNEbecause of the key role it plays in the global economy (e.g., over one-third of international trade consists of transfer among MNE units) and because of its interface with multiple institutional environments. The MNE literature has shown "a growing appreciation of the importance of the institutional context and of the patterns in the way MNEs respond to that context" (Westney, 1993:60). This appreciation of institutions was preceded by a dominance of economic theories attributing competitiveness to variables ranging from industry structure (Porter, 1990)to location- We thank Christine Oliver for helpful comments on earlier versions of this paper, as well as the editor and three anonymous reviewers for constructive suggestions. Thanks also go to group participants of the 2000AMRTheory Development Workshop: Tatiana Kostova, Mark Sharfman, and Davina Vora. 608 specific advantages (Buckley & Casson, 1986; Dunning, 1980;Hennart, 1982;Hill & Kim, 1988).In a departure from economic explanations, Kogut (1991) credited competitiveness to national differences in organizing principles and societal institutions. This coincides with the internationalization process model, in which internationalization is viewed as a series of incremental adjustments to changes in the firm and its environment. The main variable in this model, "psychic distance," is "the sum of factors preventing the flow of information from and to the market" (Johanson & Vahlne, 1977: 24)-for example, differences in language, education, business practices, culture, and development. Using Hofstede's (1980) classification of culture, Kogut and Singh (1988)formed a "cultural distance" index that has become the proxy of choice for national differences (Barkema, Bell, & Pennings, 1996; Brouthers & Brouthers, 2001; Hennart & Larimo, 1998;Li, Lam, & Qian, 2001). This index, however, does not capture the complexity of cross-country differences; in particular, it neglects the critical role of societal institutions in articulating, disseminating, and arbitrating cultural and social cues. Applied to the realm of foreign direct investment (FDI), it fails to yield consistent empirical evidence (Shenkar, 2001). Institutional distance provides an alternative explanation for MNE behavior. The construct has been linked so far to two aspects of MNE 2002 Xu and Shenkar operations: (1) the establishment of legitimacy in the host country (Kostova & Zaheer, 1999)and (2) the transfer of strategic orientations and organizational practices from the parent firm to the foreign subsidiary (Kostova, 1999). In this paper we extend the treatment of institutional distance to the realm of MNEstrategy, focusing on two critical steps in the FDI process: (1) host country selection and (2) foreign entry strategy. These aspects are key ingredients in the FDI decision since they pertain to location and internalization choices (Buckley & Casson, 1976, 1998)and directly impact the external and internal legitimacy of the MNE. We first decompose the institutional distance construct into three component parts and match each with a set of firm-level attributes to explain MNE country choice strategy. We then discuss the effect of each part on entry and ownership mode in the host country. THEORY:A BRIEFREVIEW INSTITUTIONAL Contemporary institutional theory (Scott, 1995) indicates that, in order to survive, organizations must conform to the rules and belief systems prevailing in the environment (DiMaggio &Powell, 1983;Meyer & Rowan, 1977),because institutional isomorphism, both structural and procedural, will earn the organization legitimacy (Dacin, 1997; Deephouse, 1996; Suchman, 1995). The theory has been supported in unitary, domestic environments and with organizations such as public schools (Rowan, 1982) and day care centers (Baum & Oliver, 1992). It has received less support in complex environments with multiple institutional demands (Meyer, Scott, & Strang, 1987)and where strategic choice is vital (Oliver, 1991). Three streams of research in institutional theory have established the basis for theory development in the realm of MNEstrategy. The first is the emerging focus on the interjection of institutional forces and strategic responses. This stream reflects a realization that an organization can only gain legitimacy from some source(s), based on its adopted practices (D'Aunno, Sutton, & Price, 1991), and that its discretion in responding to institutional forces is influenced by such contextual variables as uncertainty (Goodrick & Salancik, 1996). This approach fits well with the MNE's environment of high uncertainty and multiple demands. Response to insti- 609 tutional and competitive forces in this stream balances strategic similarity and differentiation (Deephouse, 1999).It is best represented by Oliver's (1991) model of strategic responses to institutional forces, and has been applied to issues ranging from work-family (Goodstein, 1994; Ingram & Simons, 1995)to MNE strategies (Tsai & Child, 1997). The second stream is research on industry creation and on firms facing a new institutional environment-conditions that are akin to those of an expanding MNE. Aldrich and Fiol (1994) examined strategies that founders can pursue in seeking sociopolitical legitimacy and reshaping institutional environments. Haveman (1993) tested the hypothesis that organizations will follow similar and successful counterparts into new markets. In an earlier study Singh, Tucker, and House (1986)found that the lack of institutional support experienced by young organizations was found to be an important reason for the "liability of newness"-a metaphor later extended in the MNEliterature to include the "liability of foreignness" (Zaheer, 1995). If we view the MNEas a network of subsidiaries situated in different environments, the third relevant research stream is that involving interorganizational relationships. Most institutional theory studies have been conducted at the industry (Baum & Oliver, 1992;Holm, 1995),line of business (Tsai & Child, 1997), and profession/ task (Gupta, Dirsmith, & Fogarty, 1994) levels. However, in one line of research, scholars have conducted their studies at the interorganizational (Galaskiewicz & Wasserman, 1989; Oliver, 1988),state, or national (e.g., Dacin, 1997;Rowan, 1982) levels of analysis. Their work recognizes that a firm may be situated in multiple institutional fields (Hoffman, 1999) and operate under multiple institutional pressures (D'Aunnoet al., 1991;Oliver, 1991).Some of these pressures are local in origin; others are national (Rosenzweig & Singh, 1991; Thomas & Meyer, 1984; Zucker, 1987), leading to "collective action" (Meyer & Rowan, 1977: 360) typical of all organizations in a nation. This is critical to the applicability of institutional theory to the MNE, which operates in multiple institutional environments and under diverse institutional pressures (e.g., that of the host and that of the home countries). In turn, it implies that institutional theory may explain one of the fundamental issues for the MNE: the 610 Academy of Management Review dual pressures for global integration and local orientation (Westney, 1993). In recent years institutional theory has been shown to have the potential to make a significant and direct contribution to research on MNEs. Rosenzweig and Singh (1991) proposed that the relative influence of home and host country institutional environments was dependent on a set of contextual, strategic, and structural variables. Some of their propositions were tested in subsequent studies on MNE human resource management (Rosenzweig & Nohria, 1994), organizational practices of international trading rooms (Zaheer, 1995), and MNE entry mode choice (Davis, Desai, & Francis, 2000). DISTANCEAND THEMNE INSTITUTIONAL Based on Scott (1995),Kostova (1996)developed a new construct-institutional distance-referring to the extent of dissimilarity between host and home institutions. Kostova and Zaheer (1999)then proposed that the larger the institutional distance, the more difficult it is for the MNEto establish legitimacy in the host country and to transfer strategic routines to foreign subsidiaries (Kostova, 1999).In other words, a large institutional distance triggers the conflicting demands for external legitimacy (or local responsiveness) in the host country and internal consistency (or global integration) within the MNE system. Balancing these conflicting demands has been a key challenge for the MNE(Bartlett & Ghoshal, 1989; Fayerweather, 1969; Prahalad, 1975;Westney, 1993). While Kostova and Zaheer stopped short of developing the strategic implications of institutional distance, their approach has a direct bearing on it. If institutional distance affects MNElegitimacy in the host country and the transfer of routines to the subunit, then it should be a key determinant of FDI decisions. To develop this angle, we first decompose institutional distance into its three component parts-regulative, normative, and cognitive distances-and then discuss the implications of the three for two strategic decisions: country choice and entry strategies. Country choice in terms of institutional distance has direct implications for local legitimacy of the MNE. Entry strategy indicates the extent to which the MNE internalizes its foreign subsidiary (Buckley & Casson, 1976, 1998); it pertains to the level of legitimacy resulting from being internally consistent within October the MNE system. Thus, country choice and entry strategy channel the external and internal isomorphic pressures exerted on the MNEfor conformity and legitimacy. According to Scott (1995), the three pillars of institutions are distinct-a division that has been validated empirically (Busenitz, Gomez, & Spencer, 2000).The regulative pillar rests on the setting, monitoring, and enforcement of rules. It is based on instrumental logic and uses legal sanctioning as the basis of legitimacy. The normative pillar prescribes desirable goals and the appropriate means of attaining them; legitimacy is rooted in societal beliefs and norms. The cognitive pillar highlights internal representation of the environment by actors; legitimacy is anchored in cultural orthodoxy. We suggest that each of the three pillars produces its own measure of institutional distance and that these measures vary in terms of their implications for MNE behavior. For example, property rights are more sensitive to regulative distance because they are anchored in legal provisions, whereas differentiation strategies are more susceptible to cognitive distance because they might violate national symbols. Finally, normative distance may undermine import of MNEpractices that deviate from societal expectations. Institutional Distance and Country Choice Strategies The MNE literature proposes that FDI strategies are shaped by the resource advantage, strategy, and structure of the parent firm (Collis, 1991; Dunning, 1980; Ghoshal & Nohria, 1989; Hill, Hwang, & Kim, 1990;Rosenzweig & Singh, 1991; Tallman, 1991). These parent firm attributes provide a basis for strategic decisions with respect to a foreign market. We argue that the choice of host country, in terms of institutional distance, must be matched to firm-level attributes such that the legitimacy of the foreign subsidiary in the host country is established and the transfer and sustainability of competitive advantage are ensured. Once a host country has been targeted, entry strategies must be matched with institutional distance to that country in order to enhance competitive advantages resulting either from a small institutional distance or from the ability to mitigate the negative impact of a large distance. 2002 Xu and Shenkar The firm-level variables discussed below, while not an exhaustive list, are representative of those resource, strategic, and structural attributes. The source of competitive advantage is possibly the most important strategic determinant for firms in a competitive market place. Global strategy is the guiding principle for and often distinMNEs' global operations guishes firms with similar competitive advantages. Organizational diversity identifies differences across the firm's constituencies, capturing the firm's interface with the environment (input and output) and in its internal operations. Source of competitive advantage. Scholars have long argued that the MNE operating overseas incurs special costs (Hymer, 1976; Kindleberger, 1969). It must overcome the "liability of foreignness" (Zaheer, 1995), either by transferring firm-specific competitive advantages to a foreign subsidiary (Dunning, 1981, 1988) or by utilizing the host country-specific advantages of the subsidiary (Kogut, 1991; Porter, 1990). Firmspecific competitive advantages have been preroutines sumed embedded in organizational (Barney, 1991; Reed & DeFillippi, 1990) or strategic practices (Kostova, 1999). Correspondingly, researchers have discussed host country-based competitive advantage in terms of local practices in human resources management and control, among others (Rosenzweig & Nohria, 1994; Zaheer, 1995). An MNE may gain competitive advantage over local firms via its routines or over other MNEs by conforming to local practices. Kostova (1999) argues that since organizational practices are shaped by the institutional environment, successful transfer of these practices from the parent firm to the foreign subsidiary depends on the distance between the host and home environments: the larger the distance, the more difficult the transfer. Among the three pillars of institutions, the normative component, which defines organizational goals and objectives as well as the appropriate ways to pursue them, has direct bearing on organizational practices. To the extent that MNEs' routines are not in violation of host country laws and regulations, regulative distance will not have much impact on the MNE whose competitive advantage lies in those routines. While a government may outlaw a certain routine to keep an MNE out (e.g., the attempt to prohibit Avon's direct selling in China), this is not a common occurrence. Similarly, cognitive distance will have little impact 611 on investment by the routine-driven MNE,except where the routines constitute a symbol challenging host country identities. The transfer of MNE routines, therefore, is mainly constrained by the normative distance between the host and home countries. If a large normative distance makes the transfer of organizational routines difficult, the MNE with strong, firm-specific, routine-based competitive advantages will invest in host countries with a normative institutional environment similar to its own. MNEs that invest in normatively distant markets are more likely to lack strong, routine-based competitive advantages but intend for their subunits to imitate local practices (Rosenzweig & Nohria, 1994;Zaheer, 1995). The latter firms are less constrained by normative distance when making FDI but may purposefully choose to enter normatively distant markets where their freedom to adapt will confer a competitive advantage over MNEs from the same home country that will not adapt. Proposition 1: Other things being equal, the MNE with routine-based competitive advantages is more likely to enter markets that are normatively adjacent, whereas the MNE with host country-based competitive advantages is more likely to enter markets at a greater normative distance. Global strategy. MNE strategies have often been encapsulated as ranging from "global" to "multidomestic" (Ghoshal & Westney, 1993;Porter, 1986),or from high to low integration. Global strategy (or high integration) implies that the MNEconcentrates production and management in one location to reap scale economies and exercise control. Multidomestic strategy (or low integration) implies that foreign subsidiaries focus on local markets, carry out production and marketing locally, and exercise significant autonomy (Ghoshal & Westney, 1993).Rosenzweig and Singh (1991)argue that foreign subsidiaries in multidomestic industries are more dependent on local resources and, hence, have a greater need to gain legitimacy locally. In contrast, MNE affiliates in global industries are more dependent upon other MNE units for know-how, technology, capital, and personnel and, hence, are more subject to institutional pressures from the parent firm. 612 Academy of Management Review An important theme in the strategy literature is that firms will seek out market niches that match their strategic thrust (Miller, 1988;Porter, 1980).In the case of the MNE,the level of global integration is determined by the structural characteristics of its industry (Kobrin, 1991; Porter, 1986), as well as home country characteristics (Duysters & Hagedoorn, 2001);the adopted strategy, in turn, will influence the choice of host market (Ohmae, 1985).A logical extension of the above arguments is that MNEs with a global strategy will invest in host countries where institutional distance is small; otherwise, they will encounter difficulties in parent-subsidiary cooperation. In contrast, MNEs with a multidomestic strategy have the latitude of investing in institutionally distant markets, since they do not rely as heavily on parent-subsidiary coordination and are less concerned with institutional conflict within the MNE. They may, however, enjoy a competitive advantage over their competitors, who cannot make similar adjustments, in countries where institutional distance is large. The key distance between institutional environments here is that pertaining to prescribed normative. Cognitive disbehavior-namely, tance will also have some impact where global strategy is perceived to be a symbolic challenge to local orthodoxy (e.g., cultural industries in France). Differences in the regulative environment, in contrast, will not have much impact on market choice, because such differences are codified and built into the MNE's routines. The one exception may be where regulative requirements are perceived to undermine core strategy-for example, where the host country rules require mandatory technology transfer that conflicts with the MNE'sproprietary strategy. Proposition 2: Other things being equal, the MNEwith a global strategy is more likely to enter markets that are adjacent normatively and cognitively, whereas the MNEwith a multidomestic strategy is more likely to enter markets that are institutionally distant on the same dimensions. Organizational diversity. Organizational diversity may be defined as the degree of difference across key organizational inputs (e.g., and employees), shareholders outputs (e.g., product lines), and internal operations (e.g., cor- October porate culture and decision making). Diversity means an organization is not dependent on a single resource source (Pfeffer & Salancik, 1978) and is open to influences by multiple stakeholders (Evan &Freeman, 1988)and institutional constituents (Oliver, 1991). It also implies that the organization is open to diverse operational modes. Kondra and Hinings (1998) suggest that organizations within an institutional field are likely to apply institutional pressure on deviants. We propose that diversity in the institutional field will reduce isomorphic pressure on deviant members. Thus, Miller and Chen (1995) found that the diversity of a firm's social context (such as its product market) leads to nonconformity to norms. Similarly, DiMaggio and Powell (1983)argued that the extent to which an organizational field is dependent on a single source of resources influences the level of isomorphism in the field. The MNE system has been regarded as an institutional field that exerts institutional pressures on its subunits (Kostova & Zaheer, 1999; Rosenzweig & Singh, 1991;Westney, 1993).One can argue that high diversity across the MNE system reduces the level of institutional pressure that the MNE,as an institutional field, can impose on a foreign subsidiary. In other words, high diversity raises the MNE'stolerance toward different institutional rules and norms exhibited in the foreign subsidiary. The subsidiaries of a less diversified MNE, in contrast, will show strong conformist tendencies. To avoid institutional conflict between local norms and its own, therefore, the firm with lower diversity will tend to invest where the institutional rules and norms are similar to those of the home country-that is, where institutional distance is small. Evidence shows that cross-national expansion is negatively related to performance in nondiversified firms (but positively related in highly diversified firms), because, among other factors, such firms lack an organizational structure appropriate for the information-processing demands of very different environments (Hitt, Hoskisson, & Kim, 1997). Kondra and Hinings (1998) note that within an institutional field, response to deviations of other organizations takes a coercive or a mimetic form, which is associated with the regulative or cognitive pillar, respectively. We suggest, however, that the two become relevant at different phases. Regulative distance is the Xu and Shenkar 2002 most relevant in the input phase, because it determines the "rules of the game," which, once established, constrain the resources that can be deployed in the subsidiary (e.g., limits on expatriates). In the output phase, cognitive distance is the most applicable, since it is associated with symbols that are most likely linked to the identity of a finished product. Further, in the transformational phase, the normative pillar becomes relevant, because social norms influence the legitimacy of the organizational practices employed. Proposition 3: Other things being equal, the MNE with low diversity is more likely to enter institutionally adjacent markets than the MNE with high diversity. Institutional Distance and Foreign Entry Strategies Entry mode: acquisition versus greenfield investment. Most studies on foreign entry strategy have followed a transaction cost approach (Hennart & Park, 1993; Hennart & Reddy, 1997) or learning approach (Barkema et al., 1996; Barkema & Vermeulen, 1998). Typically, entry strategy is related to the extent to which the MNEinternalizes its overseas operations (Buckley & Casson, 1976)and, hence, the level of internal control and consistency (Gatignon & Anderson, 1988; Hill et al., 1990). Meanwhile, country differences are viewed as a barrier to obtaining local knowledge, making it difficult for the MNE to manage its foreign subsidiaries on its own or to enlist the help of a local partner efficiently (Hennart&Larimo, 1998).With respect to the choice between acquisition and greenfield investment, empirical evidence indicates that MNEs tend to set up new ventures rather than acquire existing firms when country differences are substantial (Cho & Padmanabhan, 1995; Kogut & Singh, 1988), since these differences magnify implementation problems in acquisitions (Barkema & Vermeulen, 1998). Kostova (1999) suggests that large institutional distances constitute a barrier to transferring organizational practices from the parent firm to the foreign subsidiary. Implicitly, such transfer, as well as the resulting internal consistency, will be more difficult to achieve if the subsidiary is a locally acquired firm. Local firms 613 that have been institutionalized in the host country environment will have difficulty obtaining legitimacy within the MNE when the two institutional environments are materially different. In contrast, a newly established subsidiary may be viewed as the MNE'sdescendant. Compared to locally acquired subsidiaries, start-up ventures may also be more receptive to the parent's routines. The MNE, therefore, will tend to enter institutionally distant markets via greenfield investment in order to avoid intraorganizational conflict and difficulty in integrating the foreign subsidiary. The choice between acquisition and greenfield investment is seldom influenced by legal issues; laws and regulations rarely distinguish between these two types of investment. The external legitimacy problem arises, however, at the normative level, where an acquisition involves a change from current practices that creates a conflict with host institutions. An acquisition is especially acute at the cognitive level, because a takeover of existing operations is often viewed as a blow to national sovereignty and is a painful reminder of the loss of competitiveness. Acquisitions are often questioned in terms of their contribution to the national wellbeing, given the sometimes lack of new capital injection and downsizing of ongoing operations with adverse consequences on employment (see GM's takeover of Daewoo, for instance). Proposition 4: Other things being equal, an MNEis more likely to enter a foreign market via acquisition where normative and cognitive distances are small and via greenfield investment where normative and cognitive distances are large. Ownership strategies. In the literature scholars have extensively discussed ownership mode (joint venture versus wholly owned subsidiary) and equity share in a joint venture as control mechanisms & Anderson, 1988; (Gatignon Makino & Beamish, 1998). Greater control is associated with enhanced resource commitment and higher risk (Delios & Beamish, 1999). Higher levels of intercountry differences, such as a large cultural distance, require higher levels of cooperation in the form of equity involvement by local partners (Contractor & Kundu, 1998; Kim & Hwang, 1992; Kogut & Singh, 1988). 614 Academy of Management Review From an institutional perspective, firms will refrain from investing in markets that are institutionally distant, because business activities in those markets require conformity to institutional rules and norms that conflict with those of the home country. When they do enter distant markets, firms will choose the lower levels of control and resource commitment commonly associated with a joint venture (Agarwal & Ramaswami, 1992;Anderson & Gatignon, 1986;Hill et al., 1990) so as to lower the risk of institutional conflicts. Given a large institutional distance, the MNE will encounter difficulties in obtaining legitimacy in the host country (Kostova & Zaheer, 1999)and in transferring routine-based competitive advantages (Kostova, 1999).Equity involvement by local partners may partially compensate for those difficulties by mobilizing local legitimacy and by enabling the MNE to rely more on host country-based competitive advantages as a substitute for transferring MNEpractices internally (Makino & Delios, 1996;Shan & Hamilton, 1991).Research suggests that external legitimacy is more important to the MNE than internal consistency in countries with very different institutional environments (Rosenzweig & Nohria, 1994;Zaheer, 1995). The most regulated aspect of FDI is that of whole or majority versus minority control. Even in today's liberalized investment environment, many nations block whole or majority foreign ownership in "strategic" industries. Normative and cognitive elements also impact the legitimacy of equity arrangements. For instance, joint control may be considered less of a "sell-off" and brings in a local mediator of foreign institutional pressures. However, such institutional concerns tend to be already embedded within the regulative sphere or may indicate risk to the MNE in terms of future legal and regulative changes. Proposition 5a: Other things being equal, an MNEis more likely to enter a foreign market via a wholly owned subsidiary or majority joint venture where regulative distance is small and via a minority joint venture where regulative distance is large. When it comes to level of control within the same ownership category (majority or minority), regulative distance becomes less important. Legal and regulatory systems are more likely to October limit foreign majority ownership than to distinguish, say, between a 51 percent and 90 percent stake. Nor is it likely that the two levels of investment will be perceived differently at a cognitive, symbolic level. The higher level of control will probably be translated, however, into further imposition of MNEroutines and practices in a tacit fashion, as the bargaining power of the local partner declines (Yan & Gray, 1994). Proposition 5b: Other things being equal, and within the same ownership category, an MNE is more likely to pursue high equity control over a joint venture where normative distance is small and low equity control where normative distance is large. DISCUSSIONAND CONCLUSIONS In line with recent attempts to develop institutional theory in the international arena (Brouthers & Brouthers, 2000; Davis et al., 2000; Hoskisson, Eden, Lau, & Wright, 2000; Lu, 2002), we extend, in this note, the "strategic responses" perspective of the theory (Oliver, 1991) to the MNE.In international business research, institutions have been regarded as part of the countrylevel environment. Scholars have emphasized the effects of local isomorphism (Rosenzweig & Nohria, 1994),foreignness (Zaheer, 1995),and institutional distance (Kostova, 1996)on firm survival and success. However, firms' responses to different institutional pressures have not been studied systematically-a gap we seek to fill here. Further, the decomposition of institutional distance into component parts serves other institutional theory applications-for example, the legitimacy of new firms and organizational forms (Singh et al., 1986)that encounter different challenges at the regulative, normative, and cognitive levels. The framework endorsed in this paper is clearly distinct from current theoretical streams outside institutional theory and can be helpful in complementing these approaches. For instance, Gatignon and Anderson (1988) acknowledge that transaction cost theory accommodates contrasting predictions regarding the impact of high cultural distance on entry mode: the firm will relinquish control in the face of low knowledge and high uncertainty, or it will internalize in the face of agents whose intentions and ac- 2002 Xu and Shenkar tions are poorly understood. By introducing the concept of regulative distance, the approach we propose here predicts when each of these choices will occur. The MNE will choose low control when the host environment presents a regulative system very different from the one in its home environment, but it will opt for full ownership when the host system is more similar. This explains, for instance, the gradual shift in U.S. investments in China from cooperative ventures to wholly owned subsidiaries, as China's legal system incrementally adds U.S.-like provisions. Further development of our framework, therefore, can make theoretical contributions by calling attention to the dynamic nature of firms (Penrose, 1959; Schumpeter, 1950) and institutions (North, 1990; Oliver, 1992). This approach fits well with recent work on MNE subsidiary evolution (Birkinshaw & Hood, 1998),but it goes beyond in recognizing the duality of changes of both firms and institutional environments. Indeed, because cultural distance has been taken to be a static measure (Shenkar, 2001), institutional distance can help us better understand changing national differences and the role of dynamic firm capabilities in dealing with those changes. As hinted above, however, we propose that institutional distance complements, rather than replaces, the cultural distance construct. Neither construct captures the full spectrum of national differences with relevance to MNE foreign investment behavior. The inconsistent results reported for cultural distance's impact on foreign investment launch, entry mode, and performance show that it may be too narrow a construct to capture the decisions of firm-level actors, but they do not compromise its underlying role in those decisions (Shenkar, 2001).National institutions add to the context that shapes "national character" and influences investment decisions (Hennart & Larimo, 1998).It is, hence, the combination of both cultural and institutional distance that offers the best hope for a comprehensive assessment of the tacit portion of the environment. Future research based on the present framework can be extended to other international business areas-for example, sequence and of entry, expatriate adjustforeign performance ment and performance, and receptivity toward foreign brands. Regardless of application, mea- 615 surement challenges must be met. Institutional distance has only recently been operationalized (Busenitz et al., 2000; Kostova, 1996). Kostova (1997)argues that a country institutional profile is issue and country specific, which discounts the necessity for eventual comparison. Here we suggest learning from the "early mover"-the cultural distance literature-which has grappled with those issues for over a decade. This literature shows, for instance, that cultural distance may be asymmetric (Shenkar, 2001),which suggests the need to distinguish between home and host country specifics across institutional environments as well. Finally, while institutional distance constitutes one more challenge in obtaining legitimacy and transferring strategic practices, it also introduces a new dimension on which the MNE competes globally. From this perspective, the MNE's advantage is rooted in its ability to link institutional distance to its resources, strategy, and structure, as well as to its FDIdecisions and processes. Because these links are firm specific, they constitute a competitive advantage that is difficult to imitate. This is in line with Oliver's (1996, 1997)argument that the institutional context and process of resource selection influence the firm's heterogeneity, with competitive advantage derived from the ability to exploit the uneven distribution of resources and institutional capital. For the MNE,asymmetrically embedded in its host and home environments, developing the capabilities to bridge institutional distances is key to obtaining sustainable competitive advantage. REFERENCES Agarwal, S., & Ramaswami, S. N. 1992. Choice of foreign market entry mode: Impact of ownership, location and internalization factors. Journal of International Business Studies, 23: 1-26. Aldrich, H. E., & Fiol, C. M. 1994.Fools rush in? The institutional context of industry creation. Academy of Management Review, 19:645-670. Anderson, E., & Gatignon, H. 1986.Modes of foreign entry: A transaction cost analysis and propositions. Journal of International Business Studies, 17: 1-26. Barkema, H. G., Bell, J. H. J., & Pennings, J. M. 1996. Foreign entry, cultural barriers, and learning. Strategic Management Journal, 17: 151-166. Barkema, H. G., & Vermeulen, F. 1998. International expansion through start-up or acquisition: A learning perspective. Academy of Management Journal, 41: 7-26. 616 Academy of Management Review Barney, J. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17: 99-120. Bartlett, C. A., & Ghoshal, S. 1989. Managing across borders: The transnational solution. Boston: Harvard Business School Press. Baum, J. A. C., & Oliver, C. 1992. Institutional embeddedness and the dynamics of organizational populations. American Sociological Review, 57: 540-559. Birkinshaw, J., & Hood, N. 1998. Multinational subsidiary evolution: Capability and charter change in foreignowned subsidiary companies. Academy of Management Review, 23: 773-795. Brouthers, K. D., & Brouthers, L. E. 2000. Acquisition or greenfield start-up? Institutional, cultural and transaction cost influences. Strategic Management Journal, 21: 89-97. a question (and theory) of strategic balance. Management Journal, 20: 147-166. October Strategic Delios, A., & Beamish, P. W. 1999. Ownership strategy of Japanese firms: Transactional, institutional, and experience influences. Strategic Management Journal, 20: 915933. DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. 1983. The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 48: 147-160. DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. 1991. Introduction. In W. W. Powell & P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.), The new institutionalism in organizational analysis: 1-38. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Dunning, J. H. 1980. Toward an eclectic theory of international production: Some empirical tests. Journal of International Business Studies, 11: 9-31. Brouthers, K. D., & Brouthers, L. E. 2001. Explaining the national cultural distance paradox. Journal of International Business Studies, 32: 177-189. Dunning, J. H. 1981. International production and the multinational enterprise. London: Allen and Unwin. Buckley, P. J., & Casson, M. C. 1976. The future of the multinational enterprise. London: Macmillan. Dunning, J. H. 1988. The eclectic paradigm of international production: A restatement and some possible extensions. Journal of International Business Studies, 19: 1-31. Buckley, P. J., & Casson, M. C. 1986. An economic model of international joint venture strategy. Journal of International Business Studies, 17: 849-876. Buckley, P. J., & Casson, M. C. 1998. Analyzing foreign market entry strategies: Extending the internalization approach. Journal of International Business Studies, 29: 539-561. Busenitz, L. W., Gomez, C., & Spencer, J. W. 2000. Country institutional profiles: Unlocking entrepreneurial phenomena. Academy of Management Journal, 43: 994-1003. Cho, K. R., & Padmanabhan, P. 1995. Acquisition vs. new venture: The choice of foreign establishment mode by Japanese firms. Journal of International Management, 1: 255-285. Collis, D. J. 1991. A resource-based analysis of global competition: The case of the bearings industry. Strategic Management Journal, 12: 49-68. Contractor, F. J., & Kundu, S. K. 1998. Modal choice in a world of alliances: Analyzing organizational forms in the international hotel sector. Journal of International Business Studies, 29: 325-357. Dacin, M. T. 1997. Isomorphism in context: The power and prescription of institutional norms. Academy of Management Journal, 40: 46-81. D'Aunno, T., Sutton, R. I., & Price, R. H. 1991. Isomorphism and external support in conflicting institutional environments: A study of drug abuse treatment units. Academy of Management Journal, 34: 636-661. Davis, P. S., Desai, A. B., & Francis, J. D. 2000. Mode of international entry: An isomorphism perspective. Journal of International Business Studies, 31: 239-258. Duysters, G., & Hagedoorn, J. 2001. Do company strategies and structures converge in global markets? Journal of International Business Studies, 32: 347-356. Evan, W., & Freeman, E. 1988. A stakeholder theory of the modern In Katian capitalism. corporation: T. Beauchamp & N. Bowie (Eds.), Ethical theory and business: 75-93. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Fayerweather, J. 1969. International business management: A conceptual framework. New York: McGraw-Hill. Galaskiewicz, J., & Wasserman, S. 1989. Mimetic processes within an interorganizational field: An empirical test. Administrative Science Quarterly, 34: 454-479. Gatignon, H., & Anderson, E. 1988. The multinational corporation's degree of control over foreign subsidiaries: An empirical test of a transaction cost explanation. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 4: 305-336. Ghoshal, S., & Nohria, N. 1989. Internal differentiation within multinational corporations. Strategic Management Journal, 10: 323-337. Ghoshal, S., & Westney, D. E. (Eds.). 1993. Organization theory and the multinational corporation. New York: St. Martin's Press. Goodrick, E., & Salancik, G. R. 1996. Organizational discretion in responding to institutional practices: Hospitals and cesarean births. Administrative Science Quarterly, 41: 1-28. Goodstein, J. D. 1994. Institutional pressures and strategic responsiveness: Employer involvement in work-family issues. Academy of Management Journal, 37: 350-382. Deephouse, D. L. 1996. Does isomorphism legitimate? Academy of Management Journal, 39: 1024-1039. Gupta, P. P., Dirsmith, M. W., & Fogarty, T. J. 1994. Coordination and control in a government agency: Contingency and institutional theory perspectives on GAO audits. Administrative Science Quarterly, 39: 264-285. Deephouse, D. L. 1999. To be different, or to be the same? It's Haveman, H. A. 1993. Follow the leader: Mimetic isomor- 2002 Xu and Shenkar Sci- Kogut, B. 1991.Country capabilities and the permeability of borders. Strategic Management Journal, 12:33-47. enterprise. Ann Kogut, B., & Singh, H. 1988.The effect of national culture on the choice of entry mode. Journal of International Business Studies, 19:411-432. phism and entry into new markets. Administrative ence Quarterly, 38: 593-627. Hennart, J. F. 1982. A theory of multinational Arbor: University of Michigan Press. 617 Hennart, J. F., & Larimo, J. 1998. The impact of culture on the strategy of multinational enterprises: Does national origin affect ownership decisions? Journal of International Business Studies, 29: 515-538. Kondra,A. Z., & Hinings, C. R. 1998.Organizational diversity and change in institutional theory. Organization Studies, 19:743-767. Hennart, J. F., & Reddy, S. 1997. The choice between mergers/ acquisitions and joint ventures: The case of Japanese investors in the United States. Strategic Management Journal, 18: 1-12. Kostova, T. 1996. Success of the transnational transfer of organizational practices within multinational companies. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, University of Minnesota, Minneapolis. Kostova, T. 1997.Country institutional profile: Concepts and measurement. Best Paper Proceedings of the Academy of Management: 180-184. Hill, C. W. L., Hwang, P., & Kim, W. C. 1990. An eclectic theory of the choice of international entry mode. Strategic Management Journal, 11: 117-128. Kostova, T. 1999.Transnational transfer of strategic organizational practices: A contextual perspective. Academy of Management Review, 24: 308-324. Hill, C. W. L., & Kim, W. C. 1988. Searching for a dynamic theory of the multinational enterprise: A transaction cost model. Strategic Management Journal, 9: 93-104. Kostova, T., & Zaheer, S. 1999. Organizational legitimacy under conditions of complexity: The case of the multinational enterprise. Academy of Management Review, 24: 64-81. Hennart, J. F., & Park, Y. R. 1993. Greenfield vs. acquisition: The strategy of Japanese investors in the United States. Management Science, 39: 1054-1070. Hitt, M. A., Hoskisson, R. A., & Kim, H. 1997. International diversification: Effects on innovation and firm performance in product-diversified firms. Academy of Management Journal, 40: 767-798. Hoffman, A. J. 1999. Institutional evolution and change: Environmentalism and the U.S. chemical industry. Academy of Management Journal, 42: 351-371. Hofstede, G. 1980. Culture's consequences: International differences in work-related values. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage. Holm, P. 1995. The dynamics of institutionalization: Transformation processes in Norwegian fisheries. Administrative Science Quarterly, 40: 396-421. Hoskisson, R. E., Eden, L., Lau, C. M., & Wright, M. 2000. Strategy in emerging economies. Academy of Management Journal, 43: 249-267. Hymer, S. H. 1976. The international operations of national firms: A study of direct investment. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Li, J., Lam, K., & Qian, G. 2001. Does culture affect behavior and performance of firms? The case of joint ventures in China. Journal of International Business Studies, 32: 115-131. Lu,J.2002.Intra-and inter-organizational imitative behavior: Institutional influences on Japanese firms' entry mode choice. Journal of International Business Studies: 33: 19-37. Makino, S., & Beamish, P. W. 1998.Performance and survival of joint ventures with non-conventional ownership structures. Journal of International Business Studies, 29: 797818. Makino, S., & Delios, A. 1996.Local knowledge transfer and performance: Implications for alliance formation in Asia. Journal of International Business Studies, 27: 905927. Ingram, P., & Simons, T. 1995. Institutional and resource to workdependence determinants of responsiveness family issues. Academy of Management Journal, 38: 1466-1482. Meyer, J. W., & Rowan, B. 1977. Institutionalized organizations: Formal structure as myth and ceremony. American Journal of Sociology, 83: 340-363. Meyer, J. W., Scott, W. R., & Strang, D. 1987.Centralization, fragmentation, and school district complexity. Administrative Science Quarterly, 32: 186-201. Johanson, J., & Vahlne, J. E. 1977. process of the firm: A model of and increasing foreign market International Business Studies, The internationalization knowledge development commitments. Journal of 8: 23-32. Miller, D. 1988. Relating Porter's business strategies to environment and structure: Analysis and performance implications. Academy of Management Journal, 31: 280-308. Kim, W. C., & Hwang, P. 1992. Global strategy and multinationals' entry mode choice. Journal of International Business Studies, 23: 29-53. Miller, D., & Chen, M.-J.1995.Nonconformity in competitive repertoires. Best Paper Proceedings of the Academy of Management: 256-260. Kindleberger, C. 1969. American business abroad. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. North, D. C. 1990.Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Kobrin, S. J. 1991. An empirical analysis of the determinants of global integration. Strategic Management Journal, 12: 17-31. Ohmae, K. 1985. Triad power: The coming shape of global competition. New York:Free Press. Academy of Management Review 618 Oliver, C. 1988. The collective strategy framework: An application to competing predictions of isomorphism. Administrative Science Quarterly, 33: 543-561. Oliver, C. 1991. Strategic responses to institutional processes. Academy of Management Review, 16: 145-179. Oliver, C. 1992. The antecedents of deinstitutionalization. Organization Studies, 13: 563-588. Oliver, C. 1996. The institutional embeddedness of economic activity. Advances in Strategic Management, 13: 163-186. Oliver, C. 1997. Sustainable competitive advantage: Combining institutional and resource-based views. Strategic Management Journal, 18: 697-713. Penrose, E. T. 1959. The theory of the growth of the firm. New York: Wiley. Pfeffer, J., & Salancik, G. 1978. The external control of organizations. New York: Harper & Row. October Schumpeter, J. A. 1950. Capitalism, socialism and democracy (3rd ed.). New York: Harper & Row. Scott, W. R. 1995. Institutions and organizations. Oaks, CA: Sage. Thousand Shan, W., & Hamilton, W. 1991. Country-specific advantage and international cooperation. Strategic Management Journal, 12: 419-432. Shenkar, 0. 2001. Cultural distance revisited: Towards a more rigorous conceptualization and measurement of the cultural distance construct. Journal of International Business Studies, 32: 519-535. Singh, J. V., Tucker, D. J., & House, R. J. 1986. Organizational legitimacy and the liability of newness. Administrative Science Quarterly, 31: 171-193. New York: Free Suchman, M. C. 1995. Managing legitimacy: Strategic and institutional approaches. Academy of Management Review, 20: 571-610. Porter, M. E. 1986. Competition in global industries. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Tallman, S. B. 1991. Strategic management models and resource-based strategies among MNEs in a host market. Strategic Management Journal, 12: 69-82. Porter, M. E. 1990. The competitive advantage York: Free Press. Thomas, G. M., & Meyer, J. W. 1984. The expansion state. Annual Review of Sociology, 10: 461-482. Porter, M. E. 1980. Competitive Press. strategy. of nations. New Prahalad, C. K. 1975. The strategic process in a multinational corporation. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Harvard University, Boston. Reed, R., & DeFillippi, R. J. 1990. Causal ambiguity, barriers to imitation, and sustainable competitive advantage. Academy of Management Review, 15: 88-102. Rosenzweig, P. M., & Nohria, N. 1994. Influences on human resource management practices in multinational corporations. Journal of International Business Studies, 25: 229-251. Rosenzweig, P. M., & Singh, J. V. 1991. Organizational environments and the multinational enterprise. Academy of Management Review, 16: 340-361. Rowan, B. 1982. Organizational structure and the institutional environment: The case of public schools. Administrative Science Quarterly, 27: 259-279. of the Tsai, S. H. T., & Child, J. 1997. Strategic responses of multinational corporations to environmental demands. Journal of General Management, 23(1): 1-22. Westney, D. E. 1993. Institutionalization theory and the multinational corporation. In S. Ghoshal & D. E. Westney (Eds.), Organization theory and the multinational corporation: 53-76. New York: St. Martin's Press. Yan, A., & Gray, B. 1994. Bargaining power, management control, and performance in United States-China joint ventures: A comparative case study. Academy of Management Journal, 37: 1478-1517. Zaheer, S. 1995. Overcoming the liability of foreignness. Academy of Management Journal, 38: 341-363. Zucker, L. G. 1987. Institutional theories of organization. Annual Review of Sociology, 13: 443-464. Dean Xu is an assistant professor of strategic and international management at Guanghua School of Management, Peking University, China. He received his Ph.D. in strategy from Schulich School of Business, York University, Canada. His current research interests include entry mode, diversification, and growth strategy in transition economies. Oded Shenkar is the Ford MotorCompany Chair in Global Business Management and professor of management and human resources at the Fisher College of Business, The Ohio State University. He received his Ph.D. from Columbia University. His research interests cover comparative and international management, including methodological issues and the management of international alliances.