An Immodest Proposal: Internalizing the External Costs Of Cigarette Smoking Bryon Tilley-Rovira WEMBA 17 ABSTRACT: I will examine first the extent of cigarette smoking in the United States population, the amount of tobacco consumed, and the present pricing of cigarettes. Next, I will examine the related medical and social costs due to the negative health effects of smoking. These facts will indicate in incomplete but quantifiable way part of the true costs of cigarette smoking. An examination of the economic principles of underlying internalization of cost externalities predicts a strong decrease in tobacco smoking. Lastly, I will propose taxation as a possible tool to internalize these cost externalities. I conclude with some additional comments on the feasibility of such taxes. In the United States, cigarette smoking remains a relatively common addiction, in part, because the price of cigarettes reflects the private cost of production, not the social or personal costs, of the consequences of this habit. If these cost externalities were explicitly internalized, that is, included in the retail price, smoking would decrease dramatically. I will examine first the extent of cigarette smoking in the United States population, the amount of tobacco consumed, and the present pricing of cigarettes. Next, I will examine the related medical and social costs due to the negative health effects of smoking. These facts will indicate in incomplete but quantifiable way part of the true costs of cigarette smoking. An examination of the economic principles of underlying internalization of cost externalities predicts a strong decrease in tobacco smoking. Lastly, I will propose taxation as a possible tool to internalize these cost externalities. I conclude with some additional comments on the feasibility of such taxes. How many United States adults smoke cigarettes, and who are they? Although the number of US adults who smoke has declined perceptibly over the last several decades, nevertheless, as of 2005, “an estimated 20.9% of all adults (45.1 million people) smoke cigarettes in the United States; of these, 80.8% (36.5 million) smoked every day.” 1 Cigarette smoking is most prominent in young to pre-retirement adults, and declines with age: “Cigarette smoking estimates by age are as follows: 18–24 years (24.4%), 25–44 years (24.1%), 45–64 years (21.9%), and 65 years or older (8.6%).”1 Note the sharp decline of the number of smokers among the retired population. This is due in part to deaths (significantly decreased life-spans; see below) and disease-enforced cessation among senior citizens. The propensity to smoke cigarettes is inversely correlated with degree of education: “Cigarette smoking estimates are highest for adults with a General Education Development (GED) diploma (43.2%) or 9–11 years of education (32.6%), and lowest for adults with an undergraduate college degree (10.7%) or a graduate college degree (7.1%).”1 Cigarette smoking correlates inversely to economic class: “Cigarette smoking is more common among adults who live below the poverty level (29.9%) than among those living at or above the poverty level (20.6%).”1 This may indicate the cigarettes are in some sense an inferior good. Consider as well the strong correlation between degree of education and earning power. Cigarette smoking is unevenly distributed by race and ethnicity: “Prevalence of cigarette smoking is highest among American Indians/Alaska Natives (32.0%), followed by whites (21.9%), African Americans (21.5%), Hispanics (16.2%), and Asians [excluding Native Hawaiians and other Pacific Islanders](13.3%).”1 How much do they smoke, and how is this induced or reinforced? “An estimated 371 billion cigarettes were consumed in the United States in 2006,”2 “and cigarettes account for more than 90 percent of expenditures on all tobacco products in this country.”3 “The total United States expenditures on tobacco were estimated to be $88.8 billion in 2005, of which $82 billion were spent on cigarettes.”3 This averages to 8,226 cigarettes per year per smoker, or ~22 cigarettes per day, or slightly more than a pack a day. The number of cigarettes smoked is specific to the individual, of course, but the average is a useful index of typical smoking behavior. “In 2005, cigarette companies spent $13.11 billion on advertising and promotion, down from $15.12 billion in 2003,4 but nearly double what was spent in 1998.5 This amounted to more than $36 million per day,4 more than $45 for every person in the United States,4,5 and more than $290 for each U.S. adult smoker annually.”5,6 What are the personal and social costs of smoking, both monetarily and nonmonetarily? The most tragic cost is the high loss of life directly due to cigarette smoking. “Cigarette smoking remains the leading preventable cause of death in the United States, accounting for approximately 1 of every 5 deaths (438,000 people) each year.”1 “Based on data collected in the late 1990s, the US Centers for Disease Control (CDC) estimated that adult male smokers lost an average of 13.2 years of life and female smokers lost 14.5 years of life” because of cigarette smoking alone.7 The monetary costs include medical and productivity losses. “For 1997–2001, cigarette smoking was estimated to be responsible for $167 billion in annual health-related economic losses in the United States ($75 billion in direct medical costs, and $92 billion in lost productivity),”13 “or about $3,702 per adult smoker,”7,8 annually, a staggering figure! “The total economic costs associated with cigarette smoking are estimated at $7.18 per pack of cigarettes sold in the United States.”9 These, then, are the external costs which largely do not become evident until after many years of indulgence. How do these costs compare to the retail price of cigarettes? “As of 2006, the average retail price of a pack of cigarettes in the United States was $4.26, but ranges widely across states.”11 This wide variability in the retail price is based chiefly on how much state penal tax is levied. “The federal excise tax is 39 cents per pack of cigarettes.”10 “The median state cigarette excise tax rate, as of January 1, 2007, was 80 cents, but varied from 7 cents in South Carolina to $2.58 in New Jersey.”12 Nevertheless, it is quite clear that the external costs are not levied to any appreciable degree. The combined federal and average state excise taxes amount to $1.19 added to the retail price of a pack of cigarettes. Deducting these taxes from the average retail price, we deduce an average un-taxed retail price of $3.07 per pack. Taxes add a 39% premium to the retail price on average. However, even if we considered all the taxes levied ($1.19) as an attempt to internalize the external medical and productivity costs ($7.18), they would amount to only 17% or one-sixth of the external costs per pack. What happens to cigarette smoking behavior when these external costs are internalized, at least in part? Contrary to prior expectation, it has been shown that addictive consumption is susceptible to standard economic analysis. The demand for tobacco products follows the basic laws of economics when constraints (such as cost) are raised against use. Numerous studies of cigarette smoking, including several recent studies that explicitly account for tobacco’s addictive nature, find a strong inverse relationship between price and consumption. Thus, “increases in cigarette prices lead to significant reductions in cigarette smoking.13 A 10 percent increase in price has been estimated to reduce overall cigarette consumption by about 3 to 5 percent.”13 Increases in cigarette prices can lead to significant reductions in smoking prevalence by increasing cessation among smokers and reducing smoking initiation among potential young smokers.13 “Price elasticity (the percentage change in the quantity demanded resulting from a 1-percent increase in price) estimates obtained from recent studies using aggregate data fall in the overall wide range of –0.14 to –1.12, but most of these estimates are between –0.3 and –0.5.”13 “Almost all of the estimates obtained from time series methods based on alternative economic theories and applied to various data produced estimates of the price elasticity of demand in a relatively narrow range, which was centered on –0.4.”13 However, it must be noted that maximum range of price increase for which data was collected was between $1.00 and $1.20. The price elasticity estimates may be valid only for price changes within the studied range of price increases. What effects would be predicted, if the full quantifiable external costs were internalized through taxes as part of the retail price of cigarettes? Let us look at the demand curve based upon the effect of price changes on the overall demand for cigarettes. For the purpose of constructing a demand curve, let us use a figure of -0.4 for the price elasticity, and assume that the price elasticity remains constant throughout this price range. Below is the (theoretical) demand curve for cigarettes. Demand Curve for Cigarettes $14.00 $12.00 $10.00 Price $8.00 $6.00 $4.00 $2.00 $0.00 0 1000 2000 3000 4000 5000 6000 7000 8000 Quantity Net Price = Tax change Tax Price % change $3.07 Price Quantity Quantity % change $8.52 $9.71 200 $12.78 1645 -80 $8.09 $9.28 190 $12.35 1974 -76 $7.67 $8.86 180 $11.93 2303 -72 $7.24 $8.43 170 $11.50 2632 -68 $6.82 $8.01 160 $11.08 2961 -64 $6.39 $7.58 150 $10.65 3290 -60 $5.96 $7.15 140 $10.22 3619 -56 $5.54 $6.73 130 $9.80 3948 -52 $5.11 $6.30 120 $9.37 4278 -48 $4.69 $5.88 110 $8.95 4607 -44 $4.26 $5.45 100 $8.52 4936 -40 $3.83 $5.02 90 $8.09 5265 -36 9000 10000 $3.41 $4.60 80 $7.67 5594 -32 $2.98 $4.17 70 $7.24 5923 -28 $2.56 $3.75 60 $6.82 6252 -24 $2.13 $1.70 $1.28 $0.85 $0.43 $0.00 -$0.43 -$0.85 -$1.28 $3.32 $2.89 $2.47 $2.04 $1.62 $1.19 $0.76 $0.34 -$0.09 50 40 30 20 10 0 -10 -20 -30 $6.39 $5.96 $5.54 $5.11 $4.69 $4.26 $3.83 $3.41 $2.98 6581 6910 7239 7568 7897 8226 8555 8884 9213 -20 -16 -12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12 Based upon this demand curve, we may predict that a tax increase to $7.15, (close to the estimated $7.18 in external costs), will reduce overall cigarette consumption by a predicted 56%. However, as the price increases from a staple good to a luxury good, the fall in consumption may be more rapid. That is, the price elasticity may have an increasing magnitude as the total price increases. Note that an overall reduction in cigarette smoking encompasses both a decrease in the prevalence of smoking, and in the number of cigarettes smoked by those continuing the habit. The decrease in prevalence is due to smokers quitting and fewer people taking up the habit.13 It should be noted that there are distinct short-run and long-run effects to be seen due to price increases. The short-run effect represents the slow decrease in cigarette consumption among currently addicted smokers. The long-run effect represents the decrease in demand long-term due to potential smokers who never start. The long-run price elasticity is up to double the short-run effect.13 As one might intuit, those people living below the poverty level are especially sensitive to price increases.13 Are steep excise taxes a realistic mechanism to reduce cigarette smoking? The use of significant excise taxes to curb consumption would ordinarily be quite effective in the case of ordinary goods. However, here we have a good which is highly addictive, suggesting active resistance by consumers to steep, rapid price increases. Nevertheless, the cases of California and Canada, which increased prices $1.00 and $1.20, respectively, in a single increment, showed the predicted sharp declines in consumption.13 Of political importance, neither government suffered serious consequence for the sharp tax increase. If the price increase on cigarettes could not be avoided by smokers, then alternative strategies would emerge. Cigarette smokers could switch to substitute goods, such a generic or discount-brand cigarettes, hand-rolled cigarettes, pipes and cigars, and smokeless tobacco products. Alternative tobacco products would need to have tax increases comparable to those of cigarettes, in order to block this consumption strategy. How do we implement a higher excise tax on tobacco? I propose a “Social and Medical Equity Tobacco Tax.” The rationale for the tax is that cigarette smokers need to pay the full cost of their habit as they consume cigarettes; otherwise, the market in tobacco is highly distorted by passing on only the very deficient private costs of production. This results in an inequitable deferment of social (productivity/mortality) and medical costs to the future, and this impacts tobacco producers not at all. In return for smokers paying the higher excise tax, they would not be charged more for health insurance than non-smokers. Instead, health insurers will collect indirectly a supplemental “smokers’ premium” paid by the excise tax. As a priority, the excise tax will fund smoking cessation products and programs without charge to participants. Payment for products and programs will be on a performance-based scale, proportional to the effectiveness and duration of abstinence. This tax would be phased-in over a ten year period, with proportionate tax increases of about 36-cents (in real dollars) on a semi-annual basis. Cigarettes smoking would be the major target, but all tobacco products would sustain similar price increases. The taxes raised would be directed to tax enforcement, subsidies for smoking cessation programs, and “smokers’ premiums” to health insurers. One exception to the excise tax would be nicotine gums and patches. Although subject to abuse by desperate smokers (nicotine addicts!), their hazard is much less than regular forms of tobacco consumption, and they are “gateways” to cessation. We also can anticipate a brisk business in smuggled or contraband tobacco. (Such smuggling exists today in order to evade state excise taxes.) An expanded Department of Alcohol, Tobacco, and Firearms will be needed to police such illegal activities. Organized crime likely will take an interest in supplying black market cigarettes. However, unlike alcohol under Prohibition, cigarettes would still remain a legal product, albeit an expensive luxury good. This should blunt the appeal of contraband tobacco to some degree. It would be rather like the present case of the very high penal taxes levied on alcohol. (Despite the high tax, not many people drink moonshine or bathtub gin.) Such steep price increases would undoubtedly involve political tests, with strong resistance from addicted smokers, the tobacco industry, and vested economic interests (such as Big-Tobacco state governments). I think that this tax might only be implemented by counter-balancing vested interests with other competing interests and formation of a new social compact. For example, big businesses, in the form of pharmaceutical firms, health maintenance organizations, health insurers, et cetera, could be promised a portion of the tax revenues as reimbursement for smoking-cessation products and services, and reduced insurance payouts. A new social compact would be needed whereby any person might use tobacco as he will, but he must pay the full monetary price for such indulgence. The new excise tax should be used to assist the smoker to quit, to reward effective cessation products and programs, and to reimburse health care expenses for smokers. What can we conclude? Approximately one adult in five in the U.S. smokes cigarettes. Of those smokers, an estimated 70% of want to quit.13 However, so long as only the private cost of tobacco production is passed on the consumer, the cost of this highly addictive product is priced at an unrealistically low price. When prices increase to reflect the external costs as well, economics lends an effective hand to motivate smoking cessation. Initially, I was skeptical there could be enough political will in the U.S. to enact increasingly higher excise taxes on tobacco. (Images of the Boston Tea Party came to mind.) Yet I recall a recent trip I made to Spain where, as in all of Europe, the government charges an excise tax on gasoline and diesel fuel that is several times the cost of these goods. All citizens, not just a minority, pay these taxes without revolting against the government. The citizens may complain occasionally, but they almost all drive highly fuel-efficient cars and use public transportation regularly. Conservation and alternative energy are by-words in these countries. Perhaps the Spanish possess a certain level of political maturity that allows them to formulate worthy social goals and use the “visible hand” of government to implement the tough measures needed to bend economic principles (the “invisible hand”) to our purposes. When it comes to reducing cigarette smoking and its ill effects, maybe it is time we Americans grew up too. References: 1. Centers for Disease Control and Prevention. Tobacco Use Among Adults— United States, 2005. Morbidity and Mortality Weekly Report [serial online]. 2006;55(42):1145–1148. Available from: http://www.cdc.gov/mmwr/preview/mmwrhtml/mm5542a1.htm. 2. Tobacco Outlook. Harvest Intentions for 2007-Crop Tobacco Advance 2 Percent..(PDF–278KB) Market and Trade Economics Division, Economic Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture, April 2007, TBS—262. Available from: http://usda.mannlib.cornell.edu/usda/ers/TBS//2000s/2007/TBS-04-242007.pdf. 3. Capehart, Tom. Expenditures for Tobacco Products and Disposable Personal Income, 1989–2005. (PDF–7KB) Compiled from reports of the Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. Available from: http://www.ers.usda.gov/Briefing/Tobacco/Data/table21.pdf. 4. Federal Trade Commission. Cigarette Report for 2004 and 2005.(PDF– 880KB) Washington, DC: Federal Trade Commission; 2005. Available from: http://www.ftc.gov/reports/tobacco/2007cigarette2004-2005.pdf. 5. U.S. Census Bureau. 2005 American Community Survey. Available from: http://factfinder.census.gov/servlet/ADPTable?_bm=y&-geo_id=01000US&ds_name=ACS_2005_EST_G00_&-_lang=en&-_caller=geoselect&-format=. 6. Centers for Disease Control and Prevention. Tobacco Use Among Adults— United States, 2005. Morbidity and Mortality Weekly Report [serial online]. 2006;55(42):1145–1148. Available from: http://www.cdc.gov/mmwr/preview/mmwrhtml/mm5542a1.htm 7. Centers for Disease Control and Prevention. Annual Smoking-Attributable Mortality, Years of Potential Life Lost, and Economic Costs—United States, 1995–1999. Morbidity and Mortality Weekly Report [serial online]. 2002;51(14):300–303. Available from: http://www.cdc.gov/mmwr/preview/mmwrhtml/mm5114a2.htm. 8. Centers for Disease Control and Prevention. Annual Smoking-Attributable Mortality, Years of Potential Life Lost, and Productivity Losses—United States, 1997–2001. Morbidity and Mortality Weekly Report [serial online]. 2005;54:625-628. Available from: http://www.cdc.gov/mmwr/preview/mmwrhtml/mm5425a1.htm. 9. Centers for Disease Control and Prevention. Annual Smoking-Attributable Mortality, Years of Potential Life Lost, and Economic Costs—United States, 1995–1999. Morbidity and Mortality Weekly Report [serial online]. 2002;51:300B303. Availabe from: http://www.cdc.gov/mmwr/preview/mmwrhtml/mm5114a2.htm. 10. Tobacco Outlook. Harvest Intentions for 2007-Crop Tobacco Advance 2 Percent..(PDF–278KB) Market and Trade Economics Division, Economic Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture, April 2007, TBS—262. Available from: http://usda.mannlib.cornell.edu/usda/ers/TBS//2000s/2007/TBS-04-242007.pdf. 11. The Tax Burden on Tobacco. Historical Compilation, Volume 31 2006. Arlington, VA: Orzechowski and Walker; 2007. 12. Federation of Tax Administrators. State Excise Tax Rates on Cigarettes, January 1, 2007 . Washington, DC: Federation of Tax Administrators; 2006. Available from: http://www.taxadmin.org/fta/rate/cigarett.html. 13. U.S. Department of Health and Human Services. Reducing Tobacco Use: A Report of the Surgeon General. Atlanta, GA: U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Centers for Disease Control and Prevention; 2000. Available from: http://www.cdc.gov/tobacco/data_statistics/sgr/sgr_2000/index.htm.