The Impact of Government Land Regulation on House Prices Alan Moran The Impact of Government Land Regulation Alan Moran, Institute of Public Affairs Address to the 6th Annual Housing Congress, Brisbane 28 June 2011 The Big Picture House price increases throughout the world reflect two sorts of forces. First there is the intrinsic scarcity of some locations – which economists call “positional goods”. These places are in the scenic areas or close to the fashion shopping or to major prestige offices. Like the best footballers, they are automatically valuable and, in the face of consumers’ rising income levels, competition for them lifts the prices they can command. Secondly, there is new housing, mainly located on the urban periphery on land that is plentiful. We should be relatively indifferent to escalating prices in areas of intrinsic scarcity since the price system offers the best way to ration and allocate the supply. But the story of the Australian housing tragedy is one of increasing land prices on the urban peripheries, and, not unrelated to this, declining lot sizes. Using the median house price allows us to examine housing costs which exclude the prices for the dwellings in intrinsically scarce areas. Demographia collects data on house prices for over 300 cities across the world. To adjust house prices for different incomes, multiples of household income levels are used. On this basis, for Australia house prices have increased relative to incomes by between 60 and 100 per cent over recent years. 1 The Impact of Government Land Regulation on House Prices Alan Moran As I shall demonstrate, what has amplified prices is a scarcity driven by contrived shortages of land that might be used for housing, which has amplified prices. Australian Housing Cost Trends Australia has one of the smallest urban footprints in the world. Whereas the built environment accounts for around 8 per cent of southern England and more in some other European countries it accounts for only 0.3 per cent of Australia, and only two per cent of Victoria, the most densely populated state. In spite of this, zoning creates a regulatory shortage of land available for conversion into housing blocks on the urban fringes of all major Australian cities. Government planning policies have, as a result, boosted the costs of housing. The most direct effect of the creation of housing land price premiums is on new “starter” homes but the impact has flow-on effects throughout the housing market. For “starter” homes, price in the absence of regulated land shortages would be determined by costs, since the housing and land development industries are highly competitive with few barriers to entry. The costs of a new house comprise three components: the land, the cost of preparing it for housing and the building of a house itself. These three elements are shown for three major Australian cities The cost of preparing a block, depending on terrain and size is between $40,000 and $80,000. This involves putting in local roads, leveling putting in water, gas, electricity and so on. Finished houses with three bedrooms, two bathrooms and a double garage are readily available from many builders across Australia at $130,000 or less. Land itself in its dominant use, farming, is worth around $10,000 per hectare, or around $1,000 per housing block. A regulatory induced shortage of land raises this to between $100,000 and $190,000 in the areas on the fringes of major Australian cities. 2 The Impact of Government Land Regulation on House Prices $'000s Alan Moran New Housing Costs 180 160 House Cost 140 120 Land preparation 100 80 Cost of Unserviced block 60 40 20 0 Melbourne Brisbane Perth Source: UDIA and IPA estimates Cost boosting regulatory measures are evident in all three of the housing cost components. But, in spite of these, neither house building nor land preparation costs have outstripped inflation. The effect of land-use regulation is different. Government induced shortages of housing land have created a major boost in existing prices and the tightening regulatory vice has also been the main contributor to house prices having doubled in relation to income levels over the past 20 years. The following pictures show lot approvals and the inflation-adjusted price of land in major cities. In Perth, notwithstanding the city servicing the mining boom, the provision of new blocks declined in the period post 2003. The Government’s policy was to concentrate new developments on in-fill. This led to a doubling of the real price per block. Lots 18000 $000s 450 Perth 16000 400 14000 350 12000 300 10000 250 8000 lots 6000 4000 Inflation adj price 2000 0 200 150 100 50 0 2001 2002 2003 2004 20052006 2007 2008 2009 Source: Derived from UDIA 3 The Impact of Government Land Regulation on House Prices Alan Moran In Melbourne there was a similar though less painful outcome. Lot releases dipped but then recovered somewhat. Even so, real prices per block increased by 60 per cent. Lots 25,000 Melbourne $000s 300 250 20,000 200 15,000 150 10,000 lots 5,000 100 Inflation adj price 50 0 0 2001 2002 2003 2004 20052006 2007 2008 2009 In Brisbane the government responded to a steady increase in demand by reducing the supply of land. The number of lots produced fell 40 per cent below those of the mid noughties. The result was a doubling of real prices since 2001. Lots 12,000 Brisbane $000s 300 10,000 250 8,000 200 6,000 150 lots 4,000 2,000 100 Inflation adj price 0 50 0 2001 20022003 2004 2005 2006 20072008 2009 All of these increased cost trends are in fact even greater than they appear. This is because the planning process and higher land costs have conspired to bring about a reduced lot size. This is illustrated in the data for Brisbane. While the average lot price increased 190 per cent in nominal terms, the price per square metre rose by 215 per cent due to the smaller lot size. Lot sizes fell from 700 to 600 square metres. 4 The Impact of Government Land Regulation on House Prices Alan Moran Land Use Restrictions Raw agricultural land sells for around $10,000 per hectare or around $1 per square metre. But once approval for housing development is given, that square metre of raw land on an urban periphery of a major Australian city becomes worth $200 or more. In no Australian city is there an intrinsic shortage of land. Sydney, although it is hemmed in by parks and mountains, has a considerable acreage of accessible residential land – the Plain of Cumberland alone could comfortably accommodate an increase in the city’s population by 50 per cent. Other cities are surrounded by vast acreages of farm land, most of it somewhat unproductive. Planning creates a dichotomous land market around major cities: that which is in use for farming and that which has been given regulatory approval to be used for housing. This results in three tiers of value for what is a homogenous product: tier one is fully approved for development; a second tier is outside of any likely development approval; and in between is land that might at some future time be permitted to be developed for housing. The regulatory restraint raises the value of land with approvals because it creates a scarcity of that land. This does not reflect intrinsic value but is simply due to government. Without requirements for planning approvals the cost of a block of ready-to-build-upon serviced land on the urban perimeter would be not $200,000$400,000 but less than $100,000. Existing home owners see their own house values rise and are protected – even enriched – by the knock-on effects of inflated prices at the periphery. The losers are those who don’t own their homes. In my book, The Tragedy of Planning1, restrictions on land use are traced back to the UK developments in the 1930s which became progressively more restrictive after the 1947 Town and Country Planning Act required all new developments to be approved and set out to restrict certain areas, though it was not until the late 1960s that the restrictions in favour of conservation started to bite. 1 The Tragedy of Planning, Alan Moran, IPA 2006 5 The Impact of Government Land Regulation on House Prices Alan Moran The Australian states followed this approach, led by NSW which from the late 1960s was starting to focus on planning and provision of services that would lead, rather than follow, development. Gradually, we have seen the planning process morph from facilitative to restrictive. What commenced as a seemingly sensible approach to allow for long term planning of infrastructure like trunk roads, schools and medical facilities as well as confirming environmental land use has become a land rationing system. The affects of restraining supply are seldom understood by those proposing the zoning system and its further tightening. Most land use restrictions advocates simplistically assume that, denied space to build on the periphery, people will accept greater concentrations of homes in existing areas. But imposing these second best solutions raises the price of all land throughout the urban area. The price increases stemming from government-induced housing land scarcity is further exacerbated by other factors. Among these is that new house building on sites designated for denser redevelopment within existing areas often turns out to be more sparsely built upon than planned. Incumbent home owners often consider new high density developments would reduce their own amenity values and downgrade the value of their properties. The outcome is delays (which add to costs) and reductions in the numbers of individual titles the development originally envisaged (which further adds to average property costs). This is facilitated by planning processes. In Victoria the various steps are A. Land preparation 1. Agricultural 2. Strategic plan designates it “future residential” a status that could remain unchanged for years 3. Once trunk infrastructure is closing in on the area a “Planning scheme amendment” is created with full plans, traffic assessment, vegetation assessment etc. 4. If this is supported by the local government, they then approach the State Government and seek a “Ministerial consent” to place proposals on public exhibition 5. Then goes on exhibition 6. Any objections to the proposal are assessed by a Planning Panel 7. Minister examines and rules on objections in the light of advice from the panel 8. The ruling can then be appealed at VCAT B. Having received consent, the infrastructure providers are approached by the developer C. Planning permit application is made which incorporates detailed engineering design. The losers from this process are those not presently owning their own homes. 6 The Impact of Government Land Regulation on House Prices Alan Moran Infrastructure Charges - Sharing the Regulatory Spoils In the eastern states land close to the urban development areas incurs a “growth areas infrastructure tax” allegedly “to pay for new schools, roads, community facilities and services, public transport and healthcare.” This is a totally fraudulent rationale. New areas require no greater government services’ costs than existing areas. Indeed, with respect to schools, an ageing population profile in established suburbs allows under utilized school land to be sold generating revenues that far exceed the costs of new schools in new suburbs. Hence the charge is a tax designed to ensure a share by government exchequers of the shakedown on new home buyers caused by land rationing from governments’ planning systems. Rather than removing the reason for that excessive price, governments prefer a share of the price increase their policies create. These special levies across the different states are designed not to add to costs. And in Sydney levies have been reduced to prevent them bringing extra costs. In June 2010, the Government announced a $20,000 cap on council imposed charges (known as Section 94 Contributions)– a reduction from up to $60,000 per lot in some areas – which the State Government recognised, “can make a good project unviable”. The HIA estimates the levies (which include a water headworks component) are as follows Infrastructure Charges $80,000 $70,000 $60,000 $50,000 $40,000 $30,000 $20,000 $10,000 $- 2000 a Bu nd ab ur g ild ur M el bo ur ne Br is ba ne Q ue an be ya n Bu nb ur y M Sy dn ey 2010 Source: HIA Although infrastructure charges are intended to be set at a level that does not impose additional costs, should the value of the land fall (either because of a collapse in demand or because of a reform in the planning regulations) the charges would constitute a genuine price raising tax. 7 The Impact of Government Land Regulation on House Prices Alan Moran Other Adverse Effects of Planning Regulations Land restraint also brings other distortions within the economy. Among these is the likelihood of a shortage bringing speculative bubbles. Housing is well documented as being a key trigger of the Global Financial Crisis post 2007. However the housing boom and bust cycle was largely confined to those jurisdictions where government land use regulation has caused price escalation. In Germany, a Constitutional provision gives a landholder a near automatic right to build a house on his land and house prices have been stable for many years. In most of Canada and the US south and mid west, land regulations do little to restrict the quantity of land available for housing. House prices in these areas are far lower and more stable than in the areas like Florida, California, Arizona, and in the UK and Australia. The lack of price escalation in areas where there is easy entry into home ownership can be most readily demonstrated with different US jurisdictions since these all had the same national fiscal and monetary policies. The S&P Case Shiller Index measures prices of stand-alone US houses taking into consideration for quality changes. If the Index is deflated by the CPI to offer a measure of real price changes, the picture is as follows. Real house prices 1.6 CA-Los Angeles CA-San Diego 1.4 CA-San Francisco 1.2 CO-Denver DC-Washington 1 FL-Miami 0.8 FL-Tampa 0.6 GA-Atlanta 0.4 IL-Chicago 0.2 MA-Boston MI-Detroit Jan-09 Jan-07 Jan-05 Jan-03 Jan-01 Jan-99 Jan-97 Jan-95 Jan-93 Jan-91 Jan-89 Jan-87 0 MN-Minneapolis NC-Charlotte NV-Las Vegas NY-New York This cacophony of change illustrates two facts. First, California (Los Angeles, San OH-Cleveland Francisco and San Diego) and Florida (Miami and Tampa), where land supply is constrained, had the most pronounced price surges between 2001 and 2007. Falls over the past three years have led to as much as a halving of inflation-adjusted prices. Secondly, markets with few land constraints have shown no increases in real prices. Dallas, Cleveland, Charlotte and Atlanta have shown little movement. Detroit, where real house prices are down by a quarter from their levels of 20 years ago, is probably a special case. 8 The Impact of Government Land Regulation on House Prices Alan Moran The message is that when supply is not regulated it adjusts to demand and roller coaster price movements are transformed into gentle undulating trends. Australian Political Parties’ Approaches Opinion surveys regularly rate housing as among the most important issues. House purchasing is also the most significant expenditure item for the vast majority of people. But in spite of the issue’s importance, it was not prominent in the 2010 Federal election campaign. Labor confined its policy statements to social housing. The Greens discussed housing policy at length, proclaiming “affordable housing is a human right”. But their proposals would further restrain land use and inflate land prices. The Greens’ plans to require higher spending on insulation and bicycle paths would require increased housing costs that would need to be passed on to buyers. Family First explicitly called on “state and federal governments to release more land suitable for housing”. The Liberals, in a late policy announcement, proposed measures that would actually promote the relaxation of restrictions on land being made available for housing. The Liberal Party announced that it would use federal funding to make the States increase the supply of housing land and reform their planning and approval systems. Relaxing land restraints allows greater efficiency and reduces discrimination against the young and others adversely affected by price-boosting regulations. Even so, political parties pander to existing home owners and some anti-sprawl interests and are reluctant to back-off once regulatory restraints have been introduced. 9