Returns to Acquirers of Privatizing Financial Services Firms: An International Examination Kimberly Gleason James E. McNulty Anita K. Pennathur* Department of Finance College of Business Florida Atlantic University 777 Glades Rd. Boca Raton, FL 33431 *corresponding author pennathu@fau.edu; phone: 954-236-1272. Returns to Bidders of Privatizing Financial Services Firms: An International Examination Abstract While the literature reports improved performance for privatizing firms, banking markets are different. Many privatizing financial services firms face unique problems such as an overhang of problem loans and weak credit cultures and legal systems. We investigate the returns to successful bidders in privatization acquisitions of financial services firms. We examine both short- and longhorizon performance and test if such acquisitions result in a change in risk for the bidding firm. Our results show that the cumulative abnormal returns to bidding shareholders are positive, perhaps reflecting initial optimism that the foreign firm acquiring the privatizing firm would share in the success associated with privatization. However, we find that this short-run superior performance is not sustainable for the bidder. Nonetheless, bidders experience an increase in their total risk following the acquisition. Long-run returns are higher when the target country has an effective legal system to enforce contracts and protect private property rights. 1 Returns to Bidders of Privatizing Financial Services Firms: An International Examination 1. Introduction. We examine the short- and long-run impact on bidders in acquisitions of privatizing firms in one of the most protected segments of the economy in many countries – the financial services sector. While there is a substantial body of literature on the performance of post-privatization entities, and while many studies have investigated US and cross-border bank acquisitions, our study is the first to investigate short- and longhorizon returns and changes in systematic risk for bidders in financial services privatizations. Furthermore, our study provides insights into the returns to both American and foreign firms bidding on privatizing banks, as well as for both bank and non-bank acquirers. The literature suggests that acquisitions of privatizing financial services firms would present unique opportunities and challenges that have not been examined to date. In an extensive review of the literature, Megginson and Netter (2001) find that privatizing non-bank entities improve, sometimes dramatically, in terms of performance and efficiency following their listings. However, as Verbrugge, Megginson and Owens (1999) discuss, banking markets are different for two major, and a number of subsidiary but closely related, reasons: (1) banking systems play a crucial role in economic growth in that banks possess unique resources to identify positive net present value projects and fund them at reasonable cost (e.g. Levine (1997); (2) an efficient banking and financial system requires a well functioning legal system (e.g., LaPorta et al (1997), but entrenched political constituencies often represent major obstacles to this objective. In 2 fact, as they note, the state, which regulates the banking system, is often a major source of opposition to a non-politicized financial system. In addition, (3) there are efficiency, safety and transparency issues in banking that are quite complex; (4) reflecting the transparency issue, there is often a significant problem loan portfolio in the privatized banks, which is partly unrecognized in financial reports; (5) banking requires unique managerial talent, which is often lacking in former government-owned banks. Government owned banks often perform poorly, and poor performance could make the bank a likely candidate for privatization. For instance, in their study of the determinants of bank privatization in Argentina, Clarke and Cull (2002) find that poorly performing banks are more likely to be privatized. Consequently, foreign bidders may be able to acquire the privatizing entity at a bargain, and also reap the benefits of the improved performance following restructuring. The barriers to entry in virtually all banking markets, combined with the forced disclosure inherent in privatization may work to the advantage of a large foreign bidder, especially when the bidding firm already has international experience and reputational capital. Governments may be willing to allow foreign entities in privatization contests to obtain a favorable price for the liberalizing bank, particularly if development funds from international institutions are at stake. The entrance into these newly liberalizing markets may provide opportunities to establish an important first mover advantage. Furthermore, as anecdotal evidence suggests, developed country banks, faced with low margins on traditional activities in their home countries as well as loss of franchise value due to competition from unregulated nonbank entities, may find it beneficial to pursue higher margin activities abroad. 3 Cross-border privatization acquisitions have implications for the total and systematic risk of the bidders. The potential decline in systematic risk from international diversification has been documented in the literature (Errunza and Rosenberg (1982)). On the other hand, as suggested by Amihud, DeLong, and Saunders (2002), such acquisitions could increase the insolvency (total) risk of the bidders because of a moral hazard problem facing regulators. For instance, a US bank may be interested in acquiring a foreign entity with the knowledge that it could share in the superior performance following privatization, particularly when one considers the kinds of concessions foreign governments make in order to induce foreign firms to take over ailing state-owned banks, such as capital increases, taking over problem loans, and central bank bailout funding1. If this risky investment fails, the US bank is safe in the knowledge that either the domestic (US) or foreign regulatory agencies will provide a safety net in the case of insolvency. Furthermore, Gruben and McComb (2003) suggest that despite short-term inefficiencies such as overlending and undercharging, newly privatized banks may engage in super-competitive behavior via short-term efforts to increase market share in order to obtain long-term profits. Thus, banks may accept current losses if they believe that the new market share provides them with a positive present value of expected future returns. Nonbank bidders, in contrast, do not have similar regulatory constraints in terms of capitalization and domestic product market diversification as banks, but nor do they 1 An example of the kinds of concessions granted to foreign bidders is the sale of the healthy part of Agrobanka to GE Capital. The Czech government agreed to pay GE Capital the difference between liabilities taken over and the value of assets acquired. Vladamir Vana, one of the minority shareholders, asserted that the transfer was “more than excessive” and confessed to being “puzzled by the Czech National Bank lending money in any way to a strong foreign partner” (CTK Business News, 1998). 4 enjoy risk subsidization in the form of deposit insurance or too big to fail policies. Their expansion motivations may be similar to bank bidders – to obtain global market share, to pre-empt competitors, to diversify, to compete for position within the global network, and to have a first mover advantage2. Nonbank institutions may have an advantage over bank bidders from the perspective of host governments. For example, when Newbridge Capital bid against banking giants JP Morgan and Citibank for a 20% stake in Shenzhen Development Bank, it was chosen by the selection panel because “it was a non-banking institution and therefore raised no fears that as a foreign investor it would see a stake in a Chinese bank as an extension of its existing operations or a Chinese branch”. In other words, large transnational banks are viewed as more of a threat than nonbank institutions (Chan, (2002)). Our results, which are based on an analysis of 97 privatizations, have relevance for regulators, policymakers, and the international business community. They indicate that short-run returns from acquiring privatized financial services firms are positive and are greater for non-bank bidders (e.g., finance companies such as General Electric Capital) than bank bidders. This is in contrast to most studies of domestic bank acquisitions, which generally find negative returns to acquirers. Nonetheless, long-run acquirer returns are negative. These long-run returns are positively related to the rule of law, suggesting again that legal systems affect the performance of financial firms operating within such systems, along the lines first suggested by LaPorta et al (1997). In For example,. Metlife acquired Mexican insurer Hidalgo because “the current mix of Hidalgo’s insurance products plays to Metlife’s core competencies in individual life, group products, and worksite marketing, and that its product development capabilities can be utilized to update, expand and improve on Hidalgo’s product mix” (Associated Press, 2002). Despite the optimism, Metlife’s debt was downgraded by Moody’s immediately following the acquisition. 2 5 addition, the U. S bidders experience a reduction in systematic risk after such acquisitions. The remainder of the study is organized as follows: Section 2 describes the relevant literature. We describe the data and develop our hypotheses and methodology in Section 3, and present the empirical results in section 4. Section 5 concludes. 2. Literature Review. Our research draws from extant literature in several areas: (a) privatization; (b) bank mergers; (c) banking problems in transition economies; and (d) asymmetric information. 2.1. Privatization and performance The first strand of literature is research on the impact of privatization on the operating and financial performance of the firms being privatized. The majority of this research demonstrates that private ownership leads to better firm performance, and that foreign ownership, when allowed, is associated with better post privatization performance. In general, for both developed and developing economies, the post- privatization performance is superior. For instance, LaPorta and Lopez-de-Silanes (1999) report that former Mexican state-owned enterprises (SOEs), while unprofitable prior to privatization, dramatically improve their performance after privatization, and eventually become very profitable. Studies examining privatization through share offerings also document evidence that privatization via public share offerings results in improved operating and financial performance. Megginson, Nash, and van Randenborgh (1994) 6 and Boardman, Laurin, and Vining (1989) examine such offerings and find significant increases in post-privatization productivity, output, and efficiency. In a study closely related to ours, Verbrugge, Megginson, and Owens (1999) document marginally significant increases in profitability and capital adequacy for commercial banks that are privatized in OECD countries. For example, return on equity for a sample of banks in high-information economies increases from 13.7% to 17.1%. They also find that capital ratios increase, but also report on-going continued partial state ownership in many cases, which they consider problematic In their study of acquisitions of former SOEs in transition economies, Uhlenbruck and Castro (2000) report that SOEs that are privatized via purchase by foreign firms fare better than any other method of privatization. Such acquisitions require a prolonged and expensive commitment, and post-privatization performance is related to the strategic fit between the merging firms, and continued government involvement. Otchere and Chan (2003) examine the intra-industry effects of the privatization of the Commonwealth Bank of Australia (CBA). They find that rival banks reacted negatively to the privatization announcement. Interestingly, they find that the long-term performance of CBA improved as the proportion of government ownership decreased over the three-year post-privatization period. CBA outperformed its peers on financial and operating ratios in the post-privatization period, leading Otchere and Chan (2003) to conclude that the best gains in efficiency are obtained from complete privatization. Along a similar vein, Frydman et al. (1999), and Harper (2002) find that privatization in transition economies results in better firm performance relative to firms that remain state controlled. Concentrated private ownership is linked to better firm 7 performance, as is majority ownership by outside investors. Studies such as Black et al (2000) on the privatization in the former Soviet republics lead to an interesting insight: privatization through a concentrated insider managerial and ownership structure leads to poorer post-privatization performance. The best performance is associated with outside ownership, which, as noted, is the subject of this paper. Djankov (1999) also documents that foreign share ownership results in considerably improved performance for privatizations conducted in the former Soviet countries. Moreover, merely following the correct technical process of privatization is not sufficient for improving performance. Unal and Navarro (1999) describe the process of the Mexican bank privatization that occurred in 1991. While the Mexican government designed a transparent and effective privatization program, they failed to provide adequate regulatory and legal oversight. The authors suggest that the subsequent banking crisis of 1994 was a result of this lax oversight. 2.2. Returns to shareholders, changes in risk, and efficiency gains in bank mergers. Despite voluminous research on domestic bank mergers and acquisitions, there is relatively little agreement on the impact on shareholder wealth or the efficiency gains from such mergers. For instance, while Hannan and Wolken (1989) and Houston and Ryngaert (1994) find no wealth gains from mergers, Cornett and Tehranian (1992) and DeLong (2003) find positive shareholder wealth effects.3 Along the same lines, while Spindt and Tarhan (1993) find that operating gains accrue due to scale economies in mergers of small banks, other studies (for e.g., Berger and Humphrey (1992), Rhoades 3 In DeLong (2003) the positive returns were only experienced by banks in which the mergers were well focused. 8 (1993), and Pilloff (1996)) do not find any operating gains from bank mergers. The potential gains from mergers can be even more elusive when banks attempt to merge across national lines. Although managers no doubt seek and anticipate gains from such mergers, it appears that cultural and organizational differences make long-term gains difficult to realize. Amihud, De Long, and Saunders (2002) examine the impact of cross-border bank mergers on the risk and abnormal returns of acquiring banks. They find that while the acquirer’s risk does not change, the abnormal returns to the acquirer are significantly negative. Focarelli and Pozzolo (2001) suggest that asymmetric information and regulation reduce the number of cross border acquisitions. Moreover, they conclude that the banks that expand abroad tend to be the large and efficient banks that are located in developed banking markets. Confirming these results is the study by Buch and DeLong (2003) who examine over 3000 cross-border bank mergers that occur between 1985 and 2001. They consider such mergers relatively rare and find support for the notion that one reason for this is the high information costs associated with acquiring a bank in another country. Especially relevant to our study is their finding that a very common occurrence is a bank from a developed country acquiring a bank from a developing country. Information costs are important variables in determining whether a bank merger occurs between a country pair. Acquisitions are more likely when two countries have the same language, the same legal system and are not far from one another. 9 2.3. Banking Problems Arising From State Ownership. A well developed literature exists on banking and overall economic problems in the former communist countries as a result of their transition to a market economy; this literature provides examples of the types of problems that foreign financial service firms may face when they acquire privatizing financial institutions. (We explain the relevance of this literature to the other sample countries below (see Section 2.3.4). In addition, approximately 25% of the privatizations analyzed in this paper occur in these countries. 2.3.1 The Economic Environment. La Porta, de Silanes, and Shleifer (2002) provide an overview of government ownership of banks around the world. Their comprehensive research indicates that even in countries which are relatively developed and market oriented, such as Australia, Germany, and Austria, government ownership is nontrivial, and increasing levels of government involvement in the banking sector are related to lower levels of economic growth. The textbook case of the sundry inefficiencies produced by state ownership is the transition economies of Central and Eastern Europe. Campos and Coricelli (2002) note that expectations at the beginning of the transition in the early 1990’s were extremely positive because of the move toward liberalized markets. However, the actual experience has been quite different. Output fell in each country during the first four years and in many the decline continued. 2.3.2. Credit Markets and Problem Loans. One of the problems foreign banks face in entering many of the transition economies is weak credit standards and an enormous volume of bad loans. Newly 10 created commercial banks opened their doors in the 1990s with a large volume of bad loans inherited from central planning, and even new loans quickly became problem loans ((Buch (1996) p.29). Scholtens (2000) reports very high levels of problem loans/total assets in many of these countries. Banks, however, often have an incentive to continue to fund weak or failing enterprises because to do otherwise would create large loan writeoffs and cause the firm to contract operations and employment ((Perotti (1993), Gorton and Winton (2001)). There is a striking similarity to the U.S. savings and loan crisis since the undermining of credit standards and the weak competitive and regulatory environment caused many of the new banks to fail (Gorton and Winton (1998, p. 634)). 2.3.3 Legal Systems. In many of the transitional countries, banks are reported to be unwilling to lend to small firms because contracts are either unenforceable or very difficult to enforce.4 Weaknesses in legal systems mirror weaknesses in other institutions that are normally part of a market economy. Developing a banking system and a credit culture without the rule of law to protect private property transactions is a difficult problem. Rapaczynski (1996) argues that this problem cannot be corrected quickly because legal systems are endogenous, and property rights are quite complex. Pistor Raiser and Gelfer (2001) document significant problems in enforcement of business contracts in some of the transition economies, including Russia and Ukraine (both of which are in our sample). 4 This problem is discussed in detail in the various studies in Entrepreneurship (1997), some which have been published in Wachtel (1999). 11 2.3.4. Relevance of this literature to other sample countries. Similar problems exist in other countries in our sample. For example, Baer and Nazmi (2000) describe how decades of high inflation in Brazil distorted bank decisionmaking. Just like the former Soviet countries, Brazilian banks were faced with large volumes of problem loans when the monetary authorities belatedly attempted to bring inflation under control. The need for new revenues caused lenders to extend credit to riskier borrowers, which further aggravated the bad loan problem. Also, just like the former communist countries, lenders in this environment were frequently unable to distinguish good loans from bad loans, which may have led to a restriction of credit because of an adverse selection process. Similar overlending experiences have been reported for the Brazil and the Philippines by Hassan (2002), and also for a number of other sample countries in various conference volumes (e.g., Caprio et al, (1998), Kaufman (1999)). Corruption is also prevalent in countries where the rule of law is not strongly established; several firms in our sample were subsequently investigated for illegal or unethical business transactions during the bidding process.5 Smith and Malkin (2001) consider the Mexican government bailout during the peso crisis of 1994 and subsequent sale of banks to foreign buyers. All did not work as planned for the shareholders of foreign banks entering these markets; apparently the uncompetitive insider “sweetheart” deals were not all they were touted to be and the 5 An example is Spanish BBV, whose executives admitted that they used cash hidden offshore in slush funds to convince a Mexican official to allow them to acquire a stake in Probursa. BBV confessed that it reported its $239 million secret accounts as extraordinary gains during the year (Brooks, 2003). BBV was also implicated in a bribery scandal involving Alberto Fujimori and his security advisor in the 1995 Peruvian Banco Continental acquisition. 12 challenges of restructuring were understated. In the case of the acquisition of Conifa by Citibank, Smith and Malkin (2001) point out: “Even though the bank had been cleaned up by Mexican banking regulators, it was still a mess…and it took several years for Citibank to integrate its operations with Conifa.” Lane (2003) finds that macroeconomic volatility is approximately twice as great in emerging markets as in developed countries. Thus, the abovementioned problems, many of which resulted from such volatility in, e.g., the transition economies, should be much less in the developed countries in our sample (e.g., Austria, Italy and New Zealand). On the other hand, the emerging markets may provide diversification benefits for acquiring banks. As described by Castillo (1997), when explaining why European banks tended to dominate the acquisition of privatizing Argentine banks, “European banks like to do business in Mercosur countries where their investments tally with their other strategic interests. Large transnational banks feel the need to diversify their holdings, taking numerous positions in developing countries in order to minimize their overall risks in a famously volatile sector.” 2.4. Asymmetric Information. Boot (2002) concludes a detailed review of the literature on bank relationships with the observation that the reduction in asymmetric information is the major function of banks and their major source of value creation. Relationships with borrowers are probably more problematic and asymmetric information may be more difficult to reduce when financial services firms acquire banks in other countries. In the context of the present paper, there is an additional asymmetric information problem between the 13 managers of the acquiring bank and the loan officers at the acquired bank. The two groups do not share a common corporate culture, are not used to doing business the same way and often have different languages and legal systems6. Loans that appear to be good loans to one group may appear to be potential problem loans to the other group, and vice versa. On the other hand, given Boot’s observation, banks in which the two management groups work together effectively to resolve these problems should have major opportunities to create value for shareholders. In addition, banks acquiring privatized banks in transition and other developed countries have a wealth of skills in credit analysis loan monitoring that is sorely needed in these countries. Thus, asymmetric information issues provide one reason why we might expect to see positive announcement period returns from such acquisitions. 3. Data and methodology 3.1 Data. We obtain announcements of acquisitions of privatizing financial services firms from the Securities Data Corporation (SDC) International Mergers and Acquisitions database and from World Bank Privatization database. Specifically, we search for announcements via a keyword search using target Standardized Industrial Classification (SIC) code in the 6000s, privatization flag = yes, and acquirer ultimate parent stock exchange as the New York, NASDAQ, or American Stock Exchange. We also use target ultimate parent public status = government in the SDC database. SDC provides Castilho (1997), using the example of Argentine bank acquisitions, elaborates “multinational banks bring in new banking technology and manageable long term credit mechanisms… providing skills that were largely lost during the Latin American banks’ long years enduring high inflation, an experience that left the region’s bankers with the habit of putting trust in short term credit first.” 6 14 detailed information on both the acquirer and the target, and the sample from the World Bank database lists all privatization transactions as well as entity size, form of privatization (voucher, listing, or sale to a domestic or foreign investor) and SIC code. Our initial sample comprises 121 privatizing financial services firms. We then verify these announcements with a Lexis Nexus search, which reduces our sample to 105 verifiable announcements. We also select financial services SIC codes and search Lexis Nexis for news regarding privatizing financial services entities that were listed as sold to a foreign entity. We obtain financial data on the US-listed acquirers from Standard and Poor’s Research Insights database. Target data are obtained from Banker’s Almanac, news announcements surrounding the privatization, SDC, and the World Bank. Stock price data for successful bidders are obtained from the Center for Research in Securities Prices (CRSP) tapes. Acquiring firms which do not have prior year Research Insights data, or CRSP data 110 days prior to and following the announcement date are removed from the sample. The final sample of 97 transactions comprises only US and foreign bidders for which data are available from CRSP, producing a unique sample consisting of US and foreign bidders that acquire privatizing banks and nonblank financial services firms in both culturally related and culturally dissimilar areas. We also set up a control sample of similar non-acquiring financial services firms from the same SIC codes and size groups as the sample firms. We use various macroeconomic data for the target country to help us understand the determinants of both short and long run returns. Nominal GDP (1986-1997) is from the United Nations Statistical Yearbook CD-ROM and World Bank Development Indicators Online (1997-2002). Since the two sources report different results, the series 15 are linked at 1997, the last year that the UN data is available. GDPit/GDPUSt is Gross Domestic Product in current U.S. dollars for the year of the acquisition for the country where the privatized bank is located divided by nominal U.S. GDP for the same year. This is a measure of market size. We hypothesize that both short and long run returns will be higher if the market served by the target bank is larger. We use a relative measure because the acquisitions take place over a long time period (1986 to 2002). It is difficult to directly compare absolute dollar GDP figures from different countries for different years. For example, if GDP in Brazil were five percent of U.S. GDP in 1986 and five percent in 2002, then Brazil would be (approximately) as attractive a market to acquirers in 2002 as it was 16 years earlier. 7 We use the same procedure (and sources) for per-capita GDP (PCIit/PCIUSt). Rule of Law is a measure of the extent to which private property rights and contracts are governed and protected by well functioning legal systems. This is a commercial measure published by Political Risk Services (prsgroup.com) entitled “Law and Order” and is the same data series used by LaPorta et al (1997) in their classic study of the impact of legal systems on financial markets. Each country is rated on a scale of one to six, with six reflecting the greatest protection of private property rights and enforcement of contracts. < insert Table 1 about here > 7 The alternative of using only GDPit is rejected because it implies that a market is more attractive in, say 2002 than in say, 1986 simply because nominal GDP has risen. However, the increase could have been anemic, or due to inflation, or both. Our procedure also implicitly adjusts for inflation. For example, if inflation (and real growth) were precisely the same in Brazil and the U.S. between 1986 and 2002, ceteris paribus, Brazil would be just as attractive a market in both years. If the increase in GDP were due primarily to inflation, both the exchange rate and GDP it/GDPUSt would decline. 16 The number of acquisitions for the different time periods is presented in Panel A of Table 1. Table 1A indicates that the announcements are distributed over time, although the largest number of transactions occurred between 1995 and 1998. The distribution of the sample by bank/nonbank, US/foreign, by percent acquired, and by geographic distribution is shown in Table 1B. While 56.8% of the sample consists of depository institutions – SIC codes 6021 and 6022 – many of the bidders (43.3%) are nonbank financial services institutions8. This number is not surprising, given that nonbank institutions have scaled up their competitive engagements with banks domestically. About 48% of the sample consists of banks headquartered in the US, while 52% are foreign banks with equity traded in the US. Foreign banks, such as Banco Santander, and foreign financial services firms, such as Aegon, facing growth limitations at home, may anticipate less competition and greater growth opportunities in markets with which they have a larger cultural familiarity relative to US banks. Panel B of Table 1 also provides detail on the ownership impact resulting from such acquisitions. Approximately 32% of sample transactions involve an equity stake of 100%. Table 1 Panel C provides information regarding the distribution of the sample by location. About 25% of the sample targets are in the transitional economies; approximately 40% are located in Southeast Asia and Latin America. The countries with the largest number of transactions (not shown in the table) are China, Hungary, Poland and Mexico. Developing countries were not the only ones engaged in financial services liberalization during the time period covered; many western European countries also allowed foreign firms to bid for firms that had previously been state owned, including Italy, Australia, and New Zealand. 8 As noted, an example of a sample nonbank bidder is General Electric Capital. 17 < insert Table 2 about here > Table 2 provides descriptive statistics for bidding sample firms as well as their control counterparts. Table 2 indicates that the sample firms are extremely large in terms of both assets and market value. Mean assets are $119.8 billion; mean market value is $33.08 billion9. These averages indicate that, for the most part, only the largest entities, are able to participate in privatization. Acquiring firms are larger than the control group in terms of both asset size and market value. In addition, the sample firms are more profitable than their matched firms in terms of return on equity; while their return on assets and net profit margins are insignificantly different. For the subsample of bidders that are financial services firms, we examine indicators of bank profitability. Sample banks, with a loan to asset ratio of 42.7%, are less dependent on traditional sources of banking revenue than matched financial services firms. They have lower charge-offs, lower provisions for loan losses, but a higher level of nonperforming assets, in the year prior to the acquisition. 3.2 Methodology. 3.2.1. Event Study. Event study methodology is used to identify the wealth effects to bidders and targets associated with announcements of acquisitions of privatizing financial services firms. The ordinary least squares market model is used to specify the returns generating process. Daily excess returns (ARs) are computed by estimating the market model parameters over the period from t = -110 to t = -11 relative to the announcement day t=0. 18 The standardized cross-sectional method (Boehmer, Musumeci, and Poulsen (1991)) with Scholes-Williams (1977) betas is used to test for significance. The average excess return for each day is calculated by summing the ARs for the N firms in the sample and dividing by N. The cumulative average excess returns (CARs) over a multi-day event period are calculated by summing the average excess returns over the t day event window. 3.2.2. Long-Horizon Returns. We hypothesize that acquirers will experience long run losses from acquisitions if the costs of restructuring outweigh the benefits of any favorable terms and early entrant advantage. Using the Barber and Lyon (1997) procedure, we estimate matching sampleadjusted long-horizon average holding-period abnormal returns (AHAR) for our sample bidders. AHARs are calculated starting with the month after the announcement date for 6, 12, and 18 month holding periods. 3.2.3. Changes in accounting performance. We hypothesize that bidders of privatizing financial services firms may experience gains or losses in terms of both traditional accounting measures as well as performance of their loan portfolios. We examine performance changes using controladjusted univariate tests. 9 For comparison purposes, the mean assets of banks with data in S&P Research Insights between 1992 and 1998 was $5.28 billion. Thus, bidders in privatization acquisitions were, on average, 35 times larger. 19 3.2.4. Changes in Risk. We hypothesize that the acquisition of a privatizing financial services firm may be a way for bidders to lower systematic risk, relative to the home market, by obtaining the diversification benefits of operations in markets that are, for the most part, not fully integrated into the global economy. For each bidding firm, we estimate the changes in its risk characteristics surrounding the announcement of the acquisition. The pre- announcement risk measure, VARPRE [post-announcement risk measure, VARPOST ] is estimated over the period from t-110 to t-11 [t+11 to t+110], where t=0 is the announcement date for both sample firms and matched firms. We estimate (a) total risk, or Var (Ri ), where Ri is the security return on the ith security, and (b) systematic risk, or i. 4. Empirical Results. 4.1. Short-horizon Returns. < insert Table 3 about here > Table 3 presents mean and median cumulative abnormal returns (CARs) and the number of cumulative abnormal returns that are positive and negative for the bidders and targets for two-day windows (-1,0), event date (0,0), and three day windows where day 0 is the announcement day. Panel A shows that the announcement of the acquisition is a wealth generating event for the bidders in general; the three-day event window CAR is 0.61%, which is significant at the 5% level. We further parse the bidders by US or foreign and participant type and present these results in Panel B. While US bidders 20 experience significant positive CARs, interestingly, we find that the largest and most statistically significant gains (0.86%) at the announcement accrue to US nonbank bidders. US banks do not experience significant CARs at the privatization announcement. Similarly, all foreign bidders experience a positive three-day event window CAR of 0.53%; further parsing demonstrates that it is the foreign non-bank bidders that experience the significant gains. Thus, unlike Amihud, DeLong, and Saunders (2002) who find negative abnormal returns for announcements of cross-border acquisitions, financial services firms that acquire other such firms through privatization are met with a positive market reaction. We suggest that the market perceives some of the abovementioned benefits from privatizing as accruing to the firm that acquires the privatizing entity. These results also are contrary to other studies on the effects of domestic (US) bank mergers (e.g., Houston and Ryngaert (1994)) and Hawamini and Swary (1990)). < insert Table 4 about here > We attempt to explain the returns summarized in Table 3 by regressing them on several explanatory variables. We focus on the (-1,0) abnormal returns. To evaluate robustness, we estimate seven separate models and present the results of these crosssectional regressions in Table 4. Event window abnormal returns are less for larger bidders (Log (Market Value)) and for US banks. Furthermore, participant type significantly impacts the event window abnormal return; consistent with the raw data in Table 3, CARs are significantly lower when the bidder is a bank as opposed to a nonbank 21 firm. We suggest that this negative relationship could be due to market concern about regulation constraining bank bidders. Concern about excess interference in the operation of a privatized banking firm or restrictions on their activities may lead the market to place a lower valuation on acquisitions in which the bidding firm is a bank. We also find that CARs are negatively impacted when bidders acquire a majority stake in the privatizing firm. (This effect is less pronounced than the others since it is only significant in three of the seven regressions and only at the 10% level.) Interestingly, returns are also less when the privatization and acquisition is conducted in a transition economy. We also test if the event window returns are related to changes in acquirer total risk and/or systematic risk. Similar to Ahimud, Delong, and Saunders (2002), we find that event window CARs are positively related to the change in the total risk of the bidder. Assuming, for the sake of argument, that market participants expect these changes in risk, one possible explanation is that investors in the acquiring bank are exante confident in the regulatory umbrella and safety net and are willing to pay higher share prices even when they expect the total risk of the bidding firm to increase. Our cross-sectional analysis of short-run returns indicates that factors such as the rule of law in the host country, GDP, per capita income, and change in the systematic risk measure are not important considerations to market participants evaluating these acquisitions. 22 4.2. Changes in Risk. Table 5 provides details on changes in risk for the acquiring banks after the merger announcement. We find that total risk increases for the sample of all bidders. Subsampling by US vs. foreign firms shows that the total risk increase is statistically significant only for US bidders. In addition, we find that total risk increases for all banks, although only at the ten percent significance level, with US banks driving this result. Furthermore, nonbank bidders also experience a significant increase in their total risk, (significant at the five percent level) and once again, the US non-bank bidders drive this result. Taken together, the implications of these findings are as follows. US bidders in general increase their total risk in the privatization process. However, the regulatory impact is different for banks and for nonbanks. As mentioned earlier, acquiring banks have more incentive to take on risky lending if they are confident in the regulatory safety net. As the acquiring banks in our sample increase their total risk, the burden of the risk taking behavior shifts from the banks to the regulatory agencies, which is the classic moral hazard problem. In addition, we find from Table 5 that all US bidders and US bank bidders in particular reduce their systematic risk exposure with the privatization process. Perhaps banks, due to more stringent regulatory oversight than nonbank entities, are more concerned with risk-adjusted return improvements and seek to engage in acquisitions that provide diversification benefits by exploiting market segmentation. In contrast, Amihud, DeLong, and Saunders (2002) do not find that cross-border bank mergers result in a change in either total or systematic risk. < insert Table 5 about here > 23 4.3 Long-Horizon Returns. These initial positive market reactions are not sustained since the long-term holding period returns are negative. We present these results for six months, twelve months, and eighteen months after the acquisition in Table 6. For the overall sample, long-horizon average holding period eighteen-month returns are negative. Again parsing the sample by US vs. foreign bidders, we find that US bidders experience negative returns in all three periods tested, with statistically significantly lower long-run returns in the eighteen months following the acquisition. While foreign bidders initially experience statistically significant positive six-month holding period returns, they are unable to sustain this momentum. Further sub-sampling indicates that these six-month gains accrue primarily to non-bank foreign bidders. Thus, while the market is initially optimistic about foreign firms conducting privatization acquisitions, perhaps because it expects synergy due to cultural similarity, further long-horizon average holding periods are not positive. Moreover, bank bidders fare significantly worse in both the twelve-month and eighteen-month horizons than do non-bank bidders. < insert Table 6 about here > We provide an analysis of the potential causes of the poor long-horizon postprivatization performance in Table 7 by examining percentage changes in several key operating performance ratios for the bidders as compared to the abovementioned control sample. We calculate the change from three years prior to three years post-privatization. < insert Table 7 about here > 24 Profitability, as measured by return on equity (ROE) and the net profit margin (NPM), deteriorates for the acquirers over this period; this decline is significantly different from the control group, which actually experiences an increase. The percentage change in operating expense, SGAX/Total Assets (the ratio of commercial expenses of operation incurred in the regular course of business pertaining to the securing of operating income (but not allocated to costs of goods sold) to total assets) is not significantly different for the bidding firms relative to the control firms. Similarly, the change in the loans to total assets ratio is not significantly different for the bidders and the control firms. Finally, the change in both the non-performing assets/total assets ratio and the net charge offs to net income ratio is quite different for the two samples of firms. Both non-performing loans and charge-offs increase for the acquirers and decrease for the control group. Thus, the change in operating performance is worse for the acquirers in several areas compared to their non-acquiring peers. <insert Table 8 about here> We next investigate the factors that affect longer-term performance with multivariate regressions with 12-month control adjusted buy and hold returns as the dependent variable. The regression models in Table 8 indicate that the most important determinants of the twelve month long-horizon returns are: (a) the size of the bidder (Ln (Market Value)) which has a positive impact; (b) the rule of law measure, which is also positive; and (c) the bank/non-bank status of the bidder (banks have lower returns); and (d) the ROE of the bidder, which surprisingly has a negative impact. The positive 25 relationship to the rule of law measure indicates, not at all surprisingly, that when a US (or foreign bank listed in the US) acquires a privatized bank in a country which has a well developed system of protecting private property rights and enforcing contracts, it experiences better long-term returns.10 This result is quite robust. Similarly, long-term performance is better for larger bidders, perhaps because the market views them as better able to manage political risk and operate successfully in different business cultures. An example is Citibank, which has long-term experience operating in about 100 countries. Performance is negatively impacted when the acquirer is a bank. Perhaps regulatory requirements in the home country reduce the ability of the bank to make the necessary investment to achieve maximum performance from the target. This result is consistent with the regressions on event date CARs; the market perceives that non-banks would generate more wealth than banks upon the announcement of the acquisition. Majority acquisition and whether the bidder is a US firm or not are insignificantly related to long run returns. Interestingly, we find that long-term performance is negatively related to ROE. We surmise that better performing firms are able to obtain higher returns on contributed capital domestically, and when they expand overseas, they may overextend limited resources. Firms facing growth constraints and limited returns on equity at home may find it advantageous to expand in foreign markets, especially those where their services and products are relatively new. 10 We also estimate the regression using a corruption index, and do not find that long-horizon performance is impacted by target country corruption factors. To evaluate the effect of asymmetric information, we also used cultural similarity variables (e.g., common language, geographic proximity) similar to those used by Buch and DeLong (2003) and do not find any significant relationship. 26 5. Conclusions We analyze the performance of bidders of privatizing financial services firms. Our interest in this subject stems in part from some research on domestic and international mergers that reports that acquisitions can be wealth destroying events for bidding banks, and from research that demonstrates that privatizations result in significantly improved firm-level performance. Perhaps acquirers of privatized firms can share in this improved performance. We find that, unlike the findings of prior research, acquisitions of privatizing financial services firms are wealth-generating events to the bidders at the time of announcement. In particular, non-bank firms that perform such acquisitions experience significantly positive wealth gains. We find evidence that event window returns are less when the bidders are banks, perhaps signifying some market concern about continued regulation of a privatizing entity. While the initial reaction to the privatization announcement is positive, our results show that these returns are not sustained; in other words, the long-horizon returns are negative for the bidders. Thus, the costs of assimilating privatizing firms may be greater than any benefits. We perform some further analysis along these lines by examining several key ratios for the bidders and a control group of financial services firms, prior to and post-privatization. This analysis shows that the bidders fare worse than their counterparts on changes in ratios such as the net profit margin and charge-offs. Overall, although there is an initial market enthusiasm for bidders acquiring privatizing firms, the long-term performance for bidders is weaker than the control group of non-acquirers. We also find that such acquisitions lead to an increase in total risk for bidding firms; 27 however, for US banks, lower returns are commensurate with lower systematic risk relative to the US market. Our study is relevant to regulators, policymakers and for the international financial services community. Of particular interest is the robust positive relationship of long run returns to the rule of law measure. As we would expect, when a bidder acquires a privatized bank in a country which has a well developed system of protecting private property rights and enforcing contracts, it experiences better long-term returns than other banks in the sample. This suggests that in many cases, such as acquisitions in some of the transitional economies of Central and Eastern Europe, the market did not anticipate that elements of the infrastructure of a market economy, including legal protections and other cultural factors taken for granted in the home country, are severely underdeveloped and may remain so for some time. Also of interest is our finding that the bank bidders are able to reduce their systematic risk, relative to the home country market, following such acquisitions. From a regulatory perspective, the increase in total risk after privatization acquisitions, and the relationship between event-window returns and change in total risk, indicate both an increase in risk-taking behavior by bidding banks and an implied confidence in the regulatory safety net. 28 References Amihud, Y., DeLong, G., Saunders, A., 2002, The effects of cross-border bank mergers on bank risk and value, Journal of International Money and Finance 21, 857-877. Baer, W., Nader, N., 2000, Privatization and restructuring of banks in Brazil, Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 40, pp. 2-24. Barber, B., Lyon, J., 1997, Detecting long-run abnormal returns: The empirical power and specification of test statistics, Journal of Financial Economics 43, 341-372. Berger, A.H., Humphrey, D.B., 1992, Megamergers in banking and the use of cost efficiency as an antitrust defense, Antitrust Bulletin 37, 541-600. Black, B., Kraakman, R., Tarassova, A., 2000, “Russian privatization and corporate governance: What Went Wrong? Stanford Law Review. Boardman, A., Vining, A.R., 1989, Ownership and performance in competitive environments: A comparison of the performance of private, mixed, and stateowned enterprises, Journal of Law and Economics 32, 1-33. Boehmer, E., Musumeci, J., Poulsen, A.B., 1991, Event-study methodology under conditions of event-induced variance, Journal of Financial Economics 30, 253272. Boot, Arnoud W. A., 2000, Relationship banking: What do we know? Journal of Financial Intermediation 9, 7-25. Brooks, Bradley. 2003, Spanish bank admits to secret account. Associated Press, Rio De Janeiro, Brazil (January 17). Buch, C., 1996, Creating Efficient Banking Systems: Theory and Evidence from Eastern Europe, (J.C.B. Mohr, Tubingen). Buch, C., DeLong, G., 2003, Cross border bank mergers: What lures the rare animal, Journal of Banking and Finance (Forthcoming). Campos, N. F., Coricelli, F., 2002, Growth in transition: What we know, what we don’t and what we should, Journal of Economic Literature 40 (3), 793-836. 29 Caprio, Gerald, William C. Hunter, George G. Kaufman and Danny M Leipziger, 1998, Preventing Banking Crises: Lessons From Recent Global Bank Failures, Washington D.C.: World Bank. Castilho, Carlos. June 8, 1997, Latin America: Europeans scooping up region's privatized banks, InterPress Service. Chan, Elaine. 2002. US control set at Shenzhen Bank, WorldSources Emerging Market Datafile, Hong Kong Imail (October 17). Czech News Agency, 1998, CNB pays KC20BN to raise equity of GE Capital Bank, CTK Business News Wire (July 21). Clarke, G.R.G., Cull, R., 2002, Political and economic determinants of the likelihood of privatizing Argentine public banks, Journal of Law and Economics 45, 165-198. Cornett, M.M., Tehranian, H., 1992, Changes in corporate performance associated with bank acquisitions, Journal of Financial Economics 31, 211-234. DeLong, G., 2003, Does long-term performance of mergers match market expectations? Evidence from the US banking industry,” Financial Management 32, 5-25. Djankov, S., 1999, Ownership structure and enterprise restructuring in six newly independent states, Comparative Economic Studies, 41;1, 75-95. Entrepreneurship in the Transition Economies of Central and Eastern Europe, 1997, Conference Proceedings, New York University, Stern School of Business (November). Errunza, V., and B. Rosenberg, 1982, Investment in developed and less developed countries, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 17, 741-762. Focarelli and Pozzolo, Frydman, R., Gray, C.W., Hessel, M., Rapaczynksi, A., 1999, When does privatization work? The impact of private ownership on corporate performance in transition economies, Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, 1153-1191. Gazeta Wyborcza, 1999. Allied Irish Banks - Re Bank Zachodni. Polish Daily Newspaper (April 14). Gorton, G. and Winton, A., 1998, Banking in transition economies: Does efficiency require instability? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 30 , 621-650. 30 Gruben, W.C., and McComb, R.P., 2003, Privatization, competition, and supercompetition in the Mexican commercial banking system, Journal of Banking and Finance 27(5) 229-249. Hannan, T.H., and Wolken, J.D., 1989, Returns to bidders and targets in the acquistion process: Evidence from the banking industry, Journal of Financial Services Research 3, 5-16. Harper, J. T., 2002, The performance of privatized firms in the Czech Republic, Journal of Banking and Finance 26, 621-649. Hassan, Mohamed, 2002, Three essays on capital flows, banking weakness and real exchange rates in East Asia and Latin America, Unpublished doctoral dissertation. Hawawini, G., and Swary, I., 1990, Mergers and Acquisitions in the US Banking Industry, North Holland, Amsterdam. Houston, J.F., Ryngaert, M.D., 1994., The overall gains from large bank mergers, Journal of Banking and Finance 18, 1155-1176. Kaufman, G. G., 1999, Bank problems: A global perspective, Research in Financial Services and Public Policy, 11, Stamford, CT: JAI Press. Levine, R., 1997. Financial development and economic growth: Views and agenda, Journal of Economic Literature 35 (June), pp. 688-726. Lane, Phillip, 2003, Business cycles and macroeconomic policy in emerging market economies, International Finance, 6 (1), pp. 89-108. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R., 1997. Legal determinants of external finance, Journal of Finance 52, (July), pp. 1131-1150. La Porta, R. and Lopez-de-Silanes, F., 1999, Benefits of privatization – evidence from Mexico, Quarterly Journal of Economics 114,1193-1242. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., and Shleifer, 2000, Government ownership of banks”. Harvard University Working Paper. Megginson, W.L., Nash, R.C., and van Randenborgh, M., 1994, The financial and operating performance of newly privatized firms: An international empirical analysis, Journal of Finance 49, 403-452. Megginson, W. L. and Netter, J., 2001, From state to market: A survey of empirical studies on privatization, Journal of Economic Literature 35, 2 (April), 321-389. 31 Otchere, I., and Chan., J., 2003, Intra-industry effects of bank privatization: A clinical analysis of the privatization of the Commonwealth Bank of Australia, Journal of Banking and Finance, 27(5), 949-975. Park, Zeno, 1999, Seoul shelves sale of top banks amid corporate restructuring analysis. Associated Press, Seoul. (September 14). Perotti, 1993, Bank lending in transition economies, Journal of Banking and Finance 17, 1021-1032. Pilloff, S.J., 1996, Performance changes and shareholder wealth creation associated with mergers of publicly traded banking institutions, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 28, 284-310. Pistor, K., M. Raiser and S. Gelfer, 2000, Law and finance in transition economies, Economics of Transition 8, (2), 325-368. Rapaczynski, A., 1996, The roles of the state and the market in establishing property rights, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10 Spring), 87-103. Rhoades, S.A., 1993, Efficiency effects of horizontal (in-market) mergers, Journal of Banking and Finance 17, 411-422. Rostowski, J., 1995, The Banking System, Credit and the Real Sector in Transition Economies, in J. Rostowski (editor), Banking Reform in Central Europe and the Former Soviet Union, New York, (Oxford Economic Press, New York), 16-41. Scholes, M., Williams J, 1977, Estimating betas from nonsynchronos data, Journal of Financial Economics. 5(3):309-327. Scholtens, B., 2000, Financial regulation and financial system architecture in Central Europe, Journal of Banking and Finance 24, 525-553. Smith, G. and E. Malkin, 2001, "Citigroup's surprise Mexican marriage." Business Week Online (May 18). Spindt, P.A., and Trahan, V., 1993, The impact of mergers on bank operating performance, Working paper, Tulane University Uhlenbruck, K., and De Castro, J.O., 2000, Foreign acquisitions in Central and Eastern Europe: Outcomes of privatization in transitional economies, Academy of Management Journal, 43(3), 381-402. Unal, H., and Navarro, M., 1999, The technical process of bank privatization in Mexico, Journal of Financial Services Research, 16(1) 61-83. 32 Verbrugge, J. A., Megginson, W.L., Owens, W.L, 1999, “State ownership and the financial performance of privatized banks: An empirical analysis,” Paper presented at the World Bank/Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Conference on Banking Privatization (March). Wachtel, P., 1999, “Summary and introduction to special issue: Entrepreneurship in the transition economies of Central and Eastern Europe,” Journal of Business Venturing, 14, 5/6 (September/November), 17-25. 33 Table 1 Distribution of Financial Services Privatization Acquisition Announcements Panel A. Distribution of announcements over time Transactions Announcement Year 1980-1990 6 Percent of Total 6.19% 1991 3 3.09% 1992 7 7.22% 1993 3 3.09% 1994 5 5.15% 1995 10 9.70% 1996 11 11.34% 1997 1998 15 15.46% 11 11.34% 1999 5 5.15% 2000 7 7.22% 2001 2002 7 7.22% 7 7.22% Total 97 100 Panel B. Distribution of bidders Number of Announcements 55 Percent of Announcements 56.77 42 43.23 97 100 47 48.45 Foreign 50 51.55 Total 97 100 Percent of Acquisition Full (100%) Partial (10 to 99%) Majority 31 66 31.95 68.04 59 60.82 (Minority < 50%) 38 39.18 Total 97 100 Industry Sector Depository institutions Non-Banks Total Country United States 34 Panel C. Distribution of privatizing financial services firms by region Number of Percent of Industry Sector Announcements Announcements Australia New Zealand 2 2.06 Central Asia 3 3.09 China 7 Europe 21 21.65 27 Latin and South America 27.84 Transition Economies Southeast Asia Total 25 25.77 12 12.37 97 100% 35 Table 2 Sample and Control Descriptive Statistics Sample Firms Mean Size Assets ($M) Market Value ($M) Profitability ROA (%) ROE (%) NPM (%) Performance – Bank Bidders SGAX/ Total Assets (%) Loans/Total Assets (%) Nonperforming Assets/ Total Assets (%) Provision for Loan Losses/Assets (%) Net Charge Offs/Net Income (%) Control Firms Mean T-statistic 112,297 2.56** 33,077 15,030 3.56*** 1.16 15.55 9.11 0.95 11.71 8.71 0.57 3.43*** 0.53 3.02 42.70 2.30 47.44 2.09 0.92 -2.11** 1.05 0.47 1.91* -298.88 2.39** 119,802 17.24 0.65 -34.93 This table shows mean descriptive statistics for both sample (bidding) firms and control firms for the year prior to the announcement of the acquisition. Return on Assets (Equity) is the ratio of net income to total assets (shareholders equity). Net profit margin is the ratio of net income to sales. SGAX/Total Assets is the ratio of commercial expenses of operation incurred in the regular course of business pertaining to the securing of operating income not allocated to costs of goods sold to total assets. Loans/total assets is the ration of loans to total assets. Provision for loan losses/Assets is the “expense charged to earnings which increases the allowance for possible losses on assets owned due to the decline in value of collaterized assets or foreclosed assets and includes provision for loan losses, provision for other real estate owned losses, specific and general provision for other real estate owned losses, and provision for loss on assets held for sale (S&P Research Insights). Net Charge Offs/Net Income is the ratio of the “reported amount of asset write-downs minus recoveries of previous write downs to net income. If losses exceed recoveries, this value is shown as a negative amount”. Nonperforming assets/Total Assets represents the ratio of nonperforming assets, defined as the reported amount of assets that are considered nonperforming, including loans and leases carried on a non-accrual basis, loans which are 90 days past due both accruing and non-accruing, renegotiated loans, real estate acquired through foreclosure, repossessed movable property but excluding past due loans not yet placed on non-accrual status (unless specifically included in nonperforming assets by the bank) divided by total assets. T-statistics are reported for the difference in sample and control means for each variable. *, ** and *** significant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively, using a two-tailed test. 36 Table 3 Cumulative abnormal returns CAR Event Windows No. (-1, +1) Panel A. Total Sample All Bidders 97 Panel B. by Participant Type US 47 US Nonbank 26 US Bank 21 Foreign 50 Nonbank 16 Bank 34 Bank Bidder 55 Non-Bank Bidder 42 (-1, 0) +/- 0.61 0.27 2.20** 0.48 0.24 2.28** 58/39 2.35** 0.71 0.38 1.88* 0.86 0.64 1.98** 0.49 0.16 0.94 0.53 0.31 2.28** 0.79 0.23 2.21** 0.40 0.35 0.73 0.43 0.25 1.15 0.83 0.42 2.02** 0.33 0.15 1.11 0.77 0.49 1.57 -0.24 -0.69 -0.03 0.63 0.30 2.11** 0.97 0.89 1.76* 0.46 0.24 1.35 0.20 0.09 1.05 0.85 0.54 2.27** 25/22 0.69 14/12 0.61 11/10 0.48 33/17 2.52** 11/5 1.67* 22/12 1.93* 33/22 1.82* 25/17 1.50 This table presents the mean (first line) and median (second line) announcement period cumulative abnormal returns (CARs) for the (-1, +1), (-1, 0) and (0) event windows for the 97 privatization announcements. Abnormal returns are calculated using the market model estimated from 110 to 11 days prior to the event announcements. CARs represent the cumulative market model-adjusted abnormal returns over the relevant event window. The CRSP equally-weighted market index is used. The Z statistics (given in parentheses) are based on the standardized cross-sectional method. The number of positive and negative CARs for the (-1, +1) window (+/-) are reported in the last column, with the test statistic for the nonparametric generalized sign test reported in parentheses under +/-. *, ** and *** significant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively, using a two-tailed test. 37 R2 F N Constant Majority US = 1 Model 1 10.1 3.51*** 89 0.052 (2.79)*** -0.005 (-1.05) -0.012 (-2.48)** Model 2 9.3 2.82** 89 0.052 (2.77)*** -0.005 (-1.08) -0.011 (-2.45)** -0.013 (-2.71)*** -0.003 (-2.23)** -0.013 (-2.74)** -0.003 (-2.26)** Transition = 1 Bank/Nonbank Ln (Market Value) Rule of Law ROE 0.001 (0.46) Table 4 Cross-Sectional Regressions Model 3 Model 4 11.8 12.2 2.99** 2.38** 89 89 0.060 0.058 (3.16)*** (2.67)** -0.008 -0.005 (-1.75)* (-1.09) -0.012 -0.001 (-2.59)** (-2.42)** -0.009 (-1.86)* -0.015 -0.014 (-3.14)*** (-2.77)*** -0.004 -0.004 (-2.40)** (-2.31)** -0.001 (-0.52) 0.001 0.001 (0.64) (0.50) PCIit/PCIUSt GDPit/GDPUSt D(Total Risk) Model 5 17.8 3.28*** 89 0.076 (4.15)*** -0.009 (-1.95)* -0.011 (-2.56)** -0.010 (-1.96)* -0.019 (-4.04)*** -0.005 (-3.09)*** -0.002 (-0.89) 0.001 (0.24) -0.001 (-0.470) 0.032 (0.77) Model 6 13.9 3.05** 89 0.058 (3.01)*** -0.007 (-1.34) -0.012 (-2.64)** -0.008 (-1.60) -0.014 (-2.95)*** -0.004 (-2.52)** Model 7 12.4 2.80** 89 0.061 (3.21)*** -0.009 (1.80)* -0.013 (-2.78)*** -0.010 (-1.99)** -0.016 (-3.22)*** -0.004 (-2.44)** 0.001 (0.75) 0.001 (0.71) 0.003 (2.03)** D (Beta) -0.004 (-1.23) 38 This table provides the results of cross sectional regressions for the full sample of 97 financial services privatization acquisitions. The dependent variable is the (-1,0) cumulative normal return, where 0 is the announcement date and -1 is the day prior to the announcement date. Return on Equity is defined as the ratio of net income to total equity for the acquiring firm for the year prior to the acquisition. Ln(Market Value) is the natural log of market value in the year prior to the acquisition. Early is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the acquisition took place prior to 1996 and 0 otherwise. Bank/Nonbank is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the bidder is a commercial bank (sic codes 6021, 6022, or 6029) and 0 otherwise. Transition is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the privatizing target is in an Eastern Europe transition economy (Hungary, Poland, the Czech Republic, Russia, Moldova, Kazakhstan, Russia, Ukraine). Majority is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the acquisition is over 50% of the shares of the privatizing firm. US is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the bidder is a US firm. GDPit/GDPUSt is nominal Gross Domestic Product in the home country of the acquired privatized bank divided by US GDP for the same year . PCIit/PCIUst is the same measure for percapita GDP. Rule of Law is a commercial political risk management index measuring on a one (lowest) to six scale the extent to which contracts and private property rights are governed and protected by the rule of law. D(Total Risk) and D(Beta) are the changes in total risk and systemic risk, respectively, for the acquiring firm from before to after the merger, as estimated through the regression equations, and as described in Table 5. *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively, using a two-tailed test. 39 Table 5 Changes in Risk Sample Total Risk Beta 0.237 -0.059 (2.91)*** (-0.75) 0.287 -0.075 (2.39)** (-1.69)* 0.171 -0.016 (1.69)* (-0.13) 0.182 -0.073 (1.81)* (-0.65) 0.306 -0.119 (1.70)* (-2.19)** 0.087 -0.033 (0.80) (-0.17) 0.301 -0.022 (2.33)** (-0.36) 0.273 -0.041 (1.68)* (-1.48) 0.347 0.008 (1.62) (0.10) Number Panel A. Total Sample All Bidders 94 Panel B. by Participant Type US Bidder 47 Foreign Bidder 47 Bank Bidder 53 US Bank Bidder 25 Foreign Bank Bidder 28 Non-Bank Bidder 41 US Non Bank 22 Foreign Non Bank 19 This table reports the changes in total risk and systematic risk or beta around the announcement of the acquisition announcement. For each bidder, we estimate the pre-announcement variable, VARPRE [postannouncement variable, VARPOST ] over the period from t-110 to t-11 [t+11 to t+110], where t=0 is the announcement date. The difference is calculated as VARPOST -VARPRE . A positive [negative] change in the bank’s risk measure represents an increase [a decrease] in risk over the measurement period. Tstatistics are reported in parentheses. * and **significant at the 10% and 5% levels, respectively, using a two-tailed test. 40 Table 6 Long-Horizon Average Holding-Period Returnsa Maximum Holding Period Return Event Windows, % Sample Type No. (+1, +6) Panel A. Total Sample 92 -1.88 (-0.30) Overall Sample (+1, +12) (+1, +18) -6.86 (`-1.42) -10.06 (-1.79)* -11.56 (-1.44) -2.65 (-0.48) -14.31 (-2.06)** -23.09 (-1.88)* -7.18 (-0.96) 5.15 (1.04) 5.08 (0.78) 5.22 (0.67) -13.98 (-1.69)* -6.61 (-0.87) -14.29 (-1.71)* -24.12 (-1.96)* -6.61 (-0.62) -3.45 (-0.50) 0.11 (0.01) -7.45 (-0.75) Panel B. By Bidder Characteristics US Bidder 45 Foreign Bidder 47 Bank Bidder 53 US Foreign 25 28 Nonbank Bidder US Foreign 39 20 19 -13.03 (-1.54) 8.77 (1.80)* -4.11 (-0.67) -19.84 (-1.56) 6.42 (0.97) 1.08 (0.12) -8.96 (-0.81) 12.36 (1.70)* a This table reports the long-horizon average holding-period abnormal returns (AHAR) for our sample banks. We compute long-horizon holding period raw returns for the sample firms (HPRFi) and for the matched firms (HPRCi). AHARi = HPRFi - HPRCi. HPRFi, HPRCi and AHARi are calculated starting with the month after the announcement date for 6, 12, and 18 month holding periods. Banks in the sample with multiple transactions that confound the long-horizon analysis are omitted from the analysis. Further, due to size considerations, we are unable to match certain banks in the sample. Thus, the sample sizes in these tests are smaller than those in the near-term event study. The t statistics are given in parentheses. ***, **, *Significant at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. 41 Table 7 Percent Change in Operating Performance After Acquisition Profitability ROA (%) ROE (%) NPM (%) Performance – Bank Bidders SGAX/ Total Assets (%) Loans/Total Assets (%) Nonperforming Assets/ Total Assets (%) Net Charge Offs/Net Income (%) Change for Sample Firms Change for Control Firms T (Sample – Control) -0.121 -0.094 -0.064 0.059 0.101 0.127 1.63 1.66* 1.80* 0.491 0.012 0.269 -0.058 -0.446 -1.54 -1.59 -3.74*** -0.259 -1.75* 0.134 0.446 Variables shown are computed as the pre-announcement variable, VARPRE [post-announcement variable, VARPOST ] over the period from t +0 to t-2years [t+0 to t+2 years], where t=0 is the announcement date. The change is calculated as (VARPOST -VARPRE )/VARPRE for the firms participating in these privatization transactions. Return on Assets (Equity) is the ratio of net income to total assets (shareholders equity). Net profit margin is the ratio of net income to sales. SGAX/Total Assets is the ratio of commercial expenses of operation incurred in the regular course of business pertaining to the securing of operating income not allocated to costs of goods sold to total assets. Loans/total assets is the ration of loans to total assets. Provision for loan losses/Assets is the “expense charged to earnings which increases the allowance for possible losses on assets owned due to the decline in value of collaterized assets or foreclosed assets and includes provision for loan losses, provision for other real estate owned losses, specific and general provision for other real estate owned losses, and provision for loss on assets held for sale (S&P Research Insights). Net Charge Offs/Net Income is the ratio of the “reported amount of asset write-downs minus recoveries of previous write downs to net income. If losses exceed recoveries, this value is shown as a negative amount”. T statistics are reported to represent the change in variable for both sample and control firms, and for the difference in sample and control means for each variable. *, ** and *** significant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively, using a two-tailed test. 42 Table 8 Multivariate Analysis of 12 Month Long-Horizon Returns Rsq F N Constant US = 1 Rule of Law Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 6.00 2.91** 90 -0.156 (-0.94) -0.105 (-1.09) 0.061 (1.89)* 16.50 3.93*** 84 -0.047 (-0.23) -0.001 (-0.01) 0.084 (2.46)** 0.044 (0.42) -0.229 (-2.15)** 14.20 2.2888 84 -0.082 (-2.21)** -0.030 (-0.36) 0.090 (2.33)** 0.016 (0.19) -0.058 (-0.73) -1.336 (-1.71)* -0.001 (-1.32) 0.083 (3.09)*** -0.017 (-2.89)*** Majority Bank/Nonbank -0.173 (-1.73)* GDPit/GDPUst PCIit/PCIUSt Ln(Market Value) ROE -0.225 (-3.04)*** This table presents the results of multivariate regressions on 12 month control adjusted buy and hold returns for the sample of 52 acquisitions for which data was available. Asset Growth and Change in ROE are computed as the pre-announcement variable, VARPRE [post-announcement variable, VARPOST ] over the period from [t+0 to t+2 years], where t=0 is the announcement date. The change is calculated as (VARPOST -VARPRE )/VARPRE for the firms participating in these privatization transactions. US = 1 if the bidder is a US company, 0 otherwise. Majority is if the percent of the acquisition was 50% or greater. Bank/Nonbank =1 if the acquirer is a bank, 0 otherwise. Ln(Market Value) is the natural log of market value in the year prior to the acquisition. Bank/Nonbank is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the bidder is a commercial bank (sic codes 6021, 6022, or 6029) and 0 otherwise. Majority is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the acquisition is over 50% of the shares of the privatizing firm. US is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the bidder is a US firm. GDPit/GDPUSt is nominal Gross Domestic Product in the home country of the acquired privatized bank divided by US GDP for the same year. PCIit/PCIUst is the same measure for percapita GDP. Rule of law is a commercial political risk management index measuring on a one (lowest) to six scale measuring the extent to which contracts and private property rights are governed and protected by the rule of law. *, ** and *** significant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively, using a two-tailed test. 43