Oztoprak & Scholtes (2008): The Economics of Uncertainty in Technology Development The Economics of Uncertainty in Technology Development A Spreadsheet Teaching Case* Niyazi Oztoprak & Stefan Scholtes Judge Business School University of Cambridge May 2008 Introduction Research and development of new and potentially disruptive technologies requires a concerted effort of investors, companies, government, and research institutions. All stakeholders are concerned with the creation of future value. But the realisation and magnitude of that value is highly uncertain, driven by technological, commercial and political risks and opportunities. A solid understanding and effective communication of these uncertainties and their effects on development plans is paramount for an efficient allocation of effort and funds, relative to alternative opportunities, and the design of effective development strategies that take account of unfolding uncertainties and maximise the value of R&D projects over time. Investments in R&D activities have a number of important characteristics in relation to uncertainty. Firstly, R&D projects are typically staged, often with significant increase of investment as development stages are successfully passed. The specifics of the staging depends on the technology; an example could be i) Discovery is concerned with fundamental science and typically not directly associated with a particular product idea; this phase is typically pre-patenting ii) Exploration – discoveries are associated with a product; tests are conducted to establish proof of concept; a patent is filed iii) Prototyping – a prototype is built to confirm the proof of concept on a lab- scale iv) Industrial development of processes for large-scale production, followed by the launch of the product. The staging of R&D activity lends itself naturally to the development of contingency plans, dynamic development strategies, which allow mitigation of risk and exploitation of opportunity. A second feature of R&D projects is that they typically display an interesting dichotomy between technical uncertainties and commercial uncertainties. In their early phases the focus is largely on technological success. Once past proof-of-concept, the emphasis shifts to manufacturing costs. Both of these uncertainties are largely driven by complex science and engineering considerations and their understanding are a primary concern of any science-driven project team. The commercial success, however, (revenues, market share or other benefits...), is not only driven by technological success but also by market phenomena, consumer behaviour, * Teaching and solution spreadsheets as well as a teaching note can be downloaded at http://www.eng.cam.ac.uk/~ss248/ikc P a g e |1 Oztoprak & Scholtes (2008): The Economics of Uncertainty in Technology Development competitors, and the development of complementing technology. These variables are outside the control, and often outside the immediate perception of the engineers and scientists. Commercial considerations become increasingly important as the R&D project moves downstream through the R&D phases, closer to market, not least because the required investments become much larger and investors require more rigorous demonstration of “value for money”. Traditional economic evaluation Commercial value is traditionally estimated using discounted cash flow (DCF) models. The gold standard is the net present value (NPV), obtained by deducting the upfront investment costs from the discounted future cash flows generated by the project. NPV analyses, however, are based on projections of the future, both in terms of exogenous variables, such as market size, as well as endogenous controls, such as partnering, abandoning, etc. They do not communicate the risk and opportunity, nor do they account for the interplay between uncertainties and future decisions. NPV is appropriate for “cash cow” investments, where efficiency gains are primary drivers of value. It is much less appropriate for R&D investments, where the creation of new value propositions, as opposed to improvement of existing value, is the goal. In this case study, we will illustrate valuation mechanisms that allow the articulation of uncertainty and the assessment of the value effects of risk-mitigating and opportunity-exploiting dynamic development strategies. The valuation processes will take account of the two characteristics mentioned above: The staging of R&D and the interplay between technological and commercial uncertainties. IKC- ALPS Micro-projector Development Case Several companies are investing in the development of micro-projectors. These are coin sized projection devices that may ultimately be placed on laptops and cell phones. Companies are working on different technologies for the same market. They are forming partnerships with universities, to stay in touch with the most recent advances in research, as well as with other companies with complementary capabilities, to ensure fast development and higher market penetration once their product is launched. The total market for a particular technology, provided it is technically successful, is typically highly uncertain. The uncertainty is not only driven by the technical characteristics of the product or technology that is being developed, but equally by the success of competing technologies or potential substitution products, regulatory changes and highly unpredictable consumer behaviour. A key figure in any economic evaluation is the projection of future revenues generated from the technology. As time passes these forecasts will be updated, in particular at times when new investments need to be made to push the development into its next phase. The revenue projection is likely to change, in light of changing market conditions and actions taken by key players such as competitors or governments. In the light of the updated revenue projection, investors will take decisions on the fate of the product. Modelling these decisions, in a simple form, is important if one wishes to understand the economic value of a project. In this teaching P a g e |2 Oztoprak & Scholtes (2008): The Economics of Uncertainty in Technology Development case we will build a model for the joint dynamic development of micro-projectors by the Cambridge Integrated Knowledge Centre (IKC) and ALPS Electric Co. Company and Technology Background ALPS Electric Co. is a Tokyo, Japan based company which invents and develops technologies for the mobile, automotive and home markets. In October 2004 a research contract was signed between ALPS and Cambridge University in order to cooperate with Cambridge Advanced Photonics and Electronics (CAPE) and Cambridge Integrated Knowledge Centre in Advanced Manufacturing Technologies for Photonics and Electronics (IKC). The collaboration between Cambridge University and ALPS Electric Co. resulted in the development of a novel holographic projection technology that generates an image on a small, fast, high-definition liquid crystal over silicon (LCOS) panel. As the name suggests, the most desirable property of micro-projectors is their size. The small size of these projectors may very well allow them to be placed on devices such as laptops or cell phones. Nevertheless, these technologies can not yet provide the high level of resolution and screen size that is demanded by most prominent users of projectors. Yet, there are consumers that are excited about the mere idea of being able to project pictures or video to the back of a train seat. This suggests that there is potential for the product to be launched in emerging niche markets and that there is room for improving the product and moving into different market segments. We now develop a methodology to evaluate such an investment opportunity. Valuation Principles In order to understand the value added to a project through the incorporation of dynamic development strategies we first need to understand how projects are evaluated without such contingency plans. To this end, we briefly review the traditional discounted cash flow (DCF) analysis. DCF is based on projections of cash inflows (revenues) and cash outflows (costs), which sum up to a net cash flow profile over time, typically in annual periods. Cash flows will typically be negative for an initial period and then become positive. P a g e |3 Oztoprak & Scholtes (2008): The Economics of Uncertainty in Technology Development Fig 1: Predicted Revenues and Costs if all R&D completed Successfully The cash flow projection must be accompanied by a financing plan, detailing how any cash shortfall will be financed and what return any cash surplus will achieve. DCF is based on a concept that simplifies financing considerations. A DCF analysis essentially assumes that a company finances its projects from a bank account with practically unlimited overdraft and will also put all proceeds into this bank account. The interest rate applied to the bank account is the company’s weighted average cost of capital of d% p.a.†. The beauty of this concept is that it allows a comparison of cash flows at different points in time in a very simple manner: A cash flow of $x in n years time, whether positive or negative, is worth the same to the company as a discounted cash flow of $x/(1+d)n today. If x is negative then the company will need to inject $x into the project in n years to keep it afloat. Do do this, the company can depost $x/(1+d)n now in its bank account, which will grow to the required injection of $x over n years. If x is positive then, instead of withdrawing $x from the project in n year’s time the company can withdraw $x/(1+d)n from its bank account today and balance the account by putting the project’s cash flow $x back in the bank account after n years. A DCF analysis amounts to estimating the cash flows over time, discounting all future cash flows to today at the company’s cost of capital, and then summing them up. This is called the present value of the future cash flows. A project will typically have some initial set-up investments that the company commits to at the start. This investment is subtracted from the present value to obtain the Net Present Value of the project. † WACC p.a. is defined as d = Expected return on equity (% p.a.) * Percentage equity of total capital + Cost of debt (% p.a.) * Percentage debt of total capital. P a g e |4 Oztoprak & Scholtes (2008): The Economics of Uncertainty in Technology Development Taking technical uncertainty into account. The projected cash flows in a technology development project will assume that the project is developed to its end. This, of course, is often not the case. Quite frequently the technological characteristics of project turn out to be insufficient to continue investing in the project. In other words, all future cash flows have to be multiplied with the probability that they actually occur, i.e. with the probability that the project is still alive at the time. When the discounted cash flows are multiplied with their probability of occurrence before they are summed up, then the value obtained is the expected Net Present Value, also called the Risk-adjusted Net Present Value (rNPV) of the project. P a g e |5 Oztoprak & Scholtes (2008): The Economics of Uncertainty in Technology Development Task 1 Consider the investment in a micro-projector technology with the following parameters. The product needs another two years to be complete. Until then two stages of investments need to be made. Investment in the first stage to develop a working prototype will cost £1M and will be successful with 70% probability. Investment in the second stage to develop the final product will cost £10M and will be successful with 60% probability. We adopt a discount rate of 25% per stage before the product is launched and a discount rate of 12% after the product is launched. Manufacturing cost and revenue estimates once the product is launched (Stage 3) are given in table 1 below. Year Costs 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 -190 -50 -50 -45 -45 -45 -40 -35 -35 -35 -30 Revenues Net Cash Flow 70 80 85 90 100 90 80 80 70 60 -190 20 30 40 45 55 50 45 45 35 30 Table 1: Costs and Revenues if Product Successful A. Perform a discounted cash flow analysis of the project described above. Calculate the risk adjusted net present value of the project. B. Is this a good project to invest in? What are some benefits and drawbacks to the methodology employed in our analysis? P a g e |6 Oztoprak & Scholtes (2008): The Economics of Uncertainty in Technology Development Task 2 The fundamental concern of a more sophisticated valuation method should be an improved incorporation of value uncertainty. R&D projects are, by their very nature, highly uncertain. Clearly, technical uncertainty is at the forefront of consideration and can lead to outright failure and the abandonment of the project before the first cash inflow has occurred. Technical uncertainty will also largely determine the cost base for the new product. Revenue uncertainty of new products is equally, and quite often even more important. Will the product successfully substitute existing products? Will it efficiently scale and thereby further grow into substitution markets? Will it trigger new applications and create new markets? Are there stable barriers to entry in the case of success? Are there competing product developments that may set a different standard? Such questions lead naturally to the development of scenarios, which is the first step in the development of a mature relationship with uncertainty. To conceptualise uncertainty, it helps to break the project up in several phases. For the sake of simplicity, we will use three main phases: 1. Research, success establishes proof-of-concept 2. Development, success establishes working prototypes 3. Launch, establishes manufacturing capability and viable demand Such phasing is conducive to contingency planning. Indeed, a transition from one phase to the next requires a significant additional capital commitment and therefore a re-evaluation of the project. We will assume, for simplicity, that within each phase, the activity plan decided on at the beginning of the phase is largely unchanged and phase expenditure is committed but at the transition points the project can be re-shaped and plans for the future phases can be changed in the light of the new information gained during the given phase. To illustrate how a DCF analysis can be improved to provide a more informed and more reliable valuation of an R&D project, we improve the previous DCF analysis according to the following guidelines. 1. We introduce a financing plan that is more realistic than the “company bank account” concept that DCF relies on by allowing a range of possible financing parameters. 2. We acknowledge value uncertainty by allowing for a range of development scenarios of project parameters. 3. We plan for contingencies by including action points at which management will check the unfolding uncertainties, both on project and financing parameters, and will take action on further development and financing of the project. P a g e |7 Oztoprak & Scholtes (2008): The Economics of Uncertainty in Technology Development To make the spreadsheet work without simulation software we have saved data sets comprising 20,000 scenarios for the change of the projected launch value of the product, as development unfolds. The scenarios are saved as a Stochastic Library Unit with Relationships Preserved (SLURP)‡. You can copy and paste other scenario lists into the designated area in the Task 2 tab. The tab SLURPS contains five different SLURPs with increasing levels of variability. A. What happens to the value increase due to dynamic development as volatility around value at launch increases? Can you explain why? ‡ A scenario generator is available at http://www.eng.cam.ac.uk/~ss248/ikc . For details on stochastic library units see Savage, Scholtes, Zweidler, Probability Management, Part I and II, OR/MS Today, February and April 2007. P a g e |8 Oztoprak & Scholtes (2008): The Economics of Uncertainty in Technology Development Task 3 In the previous section we incorporated staging, uncertainty and decision making into our valuation. An important aspect of financing a new venture is partnering. Different parties might be involved in financing different parts of a project. While some partnerships are rewarding for all parties involved, others don’t function as well and lead to failures. Let’s take the investment opportunity discussed in our case study as an example. We will assume that the inventor does not have any more funds to continue the project. A business angel will finance stage I while a private equity firm will finance stage II. How should the shares be split between the three parties? In the Task 3 tab we adjust the model from task 2 to incorporate the three partners, their investment decisions and their payoffs. Familiarise yourself with the formulation of this worksheet by making use of the descriptive text boxes. A. Copy and paste the SLURPS with varying levels of variability in the SLURPs tab into the designated area in the Task 2 tab. Two cells in the Charts tab give the expected value under dynamic development and partnering for the current simulation. Copy and paste these values into the table above the two cells to create two graphs comparing the value from the partnership to the value under dynamic development. What happens to the difference between these two values as volatility increases? Can you explain why? B. Can you find a way to ease the discrepancy between total value from partnership and the value from dynamic development for the intermediate levels of volatility? P a g e |9 Oztoprak & Scholtes (2008): The Economics of Uncertainty in Technology Development Appendix A: Partnering Terms in Task 3 One way to model the shares, decisions and payoffs of each of the partners may be as follows: Business Angel Share = Value Invested / Expected Value at Launch in Stage 1 Decision: Invest when rNPV is positive. Payoff: Share times realised value at launch. Private Equity Share = Value Invested / Expected Value at Launch in Stage 2 Decision: Invest whenever the required percentage of shares can be attained. Payoff: Share times realised value at launch. IP Holder Share = Shares remaining if both partners have decided to invest - otherwise zero. Payoff: Share times realised value at launch. Please see spreadsheet for how the above rules are applied. P a g e |10