1 2003-01-07 CGE Modeling of Environmental Policy and Resource Management 1 Prof. Lars Bergman and Prof. Magnus Henrekson) Stockholm School of Economics Department of Economics Box 6501 (Sveavaegen 65) SE-113 83 Stockholm, Sweden 1. Introduction General equilibrium theory is a formalization of the simple but fundamental observation that markets in real world economies are mutually interdependent. Theoretical general equilibrium analyses have provided important insights about factors and mechanisms that determine relative prices and the allocation of resources within and between market economies. As witnessed by, for instance, Debreu (1959) general equilibrium theory has reached a very high level of rigor and elegance. However, most contributions to general equilibrium theory have focused on the allocation of private goods and privately owned resources. The prime exception is Mäler (1973) who, inspired by Ayres and Kneese (1969), extended the general equilibrium framework to encompass externalities and environmental resources with public goods characteristics. Computable General Equilibrium (CGE)2 modeling is an attempt to use general equilibrium theory as an operational tool in empirically oriented analyses of resource allocation and income distribution issues in market economies. The first CGE model was presented in Johansen (1960), and with the development of fast computers and suitable software a large number of CGE models has been developed and used for policy analysis. The applications include analyses of major tax reforms, changes in trade policy regimes, economic integration, agricultural policies and energy policies. A number of CGE models have been designed to elucidate various policy issues in developing countries3. Since the beginning of the 1990´s CGE modeling has also become a widely used tool for analysis of environmental policy and natural resource management issues. The purpose of this chapter is to review this branch of CGE modeling. The aim is to elucidate the modeling approaches adopted and the policy and resource management issues dealt with in “environmental” CGE models. In addition some specific problems in environmental CGE modeling will be discussed. A number of specific models will be referred to, but the chapter is 1 Professor of economics at the Stockholm School of Economics, Stockholm, Sweden. Financial support from the National Swedish Energy Administration, as well as research assistance by Martin Hill and Charlotte Nilsson, is gratefully acknowledged. The author is grateful for comments by Eirik Amundsen, Martin Hill and the editors of the Handbook on an earlier version, but is solely responsible for all remaining errors and mistakes. 2 Sometimes this class of numerical economic models is called Applied General Equilibrium (AGE) models. However, as theoretical models of specific classes of economic problems, for instance international trade theory, can be seen as applications of general equilibrium theory the label “computable” seems more appropriate than the label “applied”. 3 Robinson et.al. (1999) provide something like a handbook for building CGE models for policy analysis in developing countries. 2 far from an exhaustive survey of all CGE models intended for environmental resource management or policy analysis4. The exposition is organized in the following way. In the ensuing section the distinguishing features, and the potential usefulness, of CGE models are briefly discussed. Section 3 is devoted to a short summary of the history of CGE modeling. In section 4 some general modeling issues in relation to environmental CGE models are discussed. In section 5 global models are discussed, while section 6 is devoted to regional multi-country models. Then single-country models are discussed in section 7 and 8, while some concluding remarks on environmental CGE modeling are made in section 9. 2. What is a CGE model – and what is it good for? There is no precise definition of a CGE model, but whenever this particular label is used the model in question tends to have certain specific features. A very basic one is that it is a multisector model based on real world data of one or several national economies. However, while general equilibrium theory is concerned with the interactions of large numbers of individual households and firms most CGE models are rather aggregated. Thus, in a typical CGE model there is only one or possibly a few “households”, while the number of production sectors generally is in the interval 5 – 50. It is a matter of taste whether numerical models with only a couple of sectors should be denoted CGE models5. In general the technology is assumed to exhibit constant returns to scale, and preferences are assumed to be homothetic. Utility and profit maximization behavior on the part of households and firms is generally assumed, and excess demand functions are homogenous of degree zero in prices and satisfy Walras´ law. Moreover, product and factor markets are assumed to be competitive, and relative prices flexible enough to simultaneously clear all product and factor markets. A key difference compared to Leontief´s input-output model is that in a typical CGE model the technological coefficients are flexible and determined by relative prices. CGE models almost always are focused on the real side of the economy and thus do not include markets for financial assets. This is one of several differences between CGE models and the numerical models based on microeconomic theory that increasingly are used in macroeconomics (see Ljungqvist and Sargent (2000))6. Consequently a typical CGE model endogenously determines relative product and factor prices and the real exchange rate, but cannot determine nominal prices and the nominal exchange rate. This means that CGE models generally are aimed at elucidating equilibrium resource allocations and growth paths rather than business cycle or disequilibria phenomena. In particular CGE models are aimed at quantifying the impact of specific policies on the equilibrium allocation of resources and relative prices of goods and factors. Categories of CGE models In spite of these basic similarities there are also significant differences between individual CGE models, and a number of distinct categories of CGE models can be distinguished. While several classification alternatives can be envisaged the distinction between static and dynamic 4 Se Conrad (1999) for a recent survey. One-sector numerical models such as the climate-change models DICE (Nordhaus (1994)) and RICE (Nordhaus and Yang (1996)), however, should not be classified as CGE models. Yet there is reason to discuss these models in a survey of environmental CGE modeling. 6 Other features found in these but not in standard CGE models are heterogeneous agents and incomplete markets. 5 3 models seems to be appropriate for a broad classification of modeling approaches. However, there is a slight ambiguity with respect to the precise meaning of “dynamic” in this context. It is obvious that models in which forward looking behavior on the part of households and firms is assumed and stock accumulation relations are explicitly included should be denoted “dynamic”7. But several static CGE models are used for multi-period analyses. Thus solutions are obtained for each one of a number of consecutive years, and the solution for an individual year t is used to define the stock of capital and other relevant assets available in year t+1. As the model is static the agents are implicitly assumed have myopic expectations, i.e. to base resource allocation decisions entirely on current conditions. In the following I will denote these models “quasi-dynamic”. In addition to the static-dynamic dimension it is useful to distinguish between single-country, multi-country and global models. Single-country models tend to be more detailed in terms of sectors and household types, and they are in general used for analyses of country-specific policy issues and proposals. Multi-country and global models, on the other hand, tend to have less sector detail and to be designed for analysis of proposed multi-lateral policies such as free-trade agreements. In the case of environmental CGE models the multi-country and global models in most cases are designed for analysis of trans-boundary pollution problems. Needless to say the models within each one of these categories can differ in many ways. In particular they may differ with respect to the number of production sectors, the number of primary factors and the specification of international trade relations. CGE models and environmental policy analysis As an initial observation it should be noted that in general there is a case for using a CGE model if proposed policy measures, or other expected changes in exogenous conditions, are likely to have general equilibrium effects. However, far from all policy measures related to environmental and natural resource issues are likely to have general equilibrium effects. Some environmental problems are local and site-specific. This is the case for air quality and noise problems in urban areas and in the vicinity of major industrial installations. Other environmental problems are related to specific substances, such as CFCs, that are used only in a few industrial processes or products, or relatively easily can be replaced by other substances. Although measures to solve these environmental problems may be quite costly for some firms and households, the repercussions to the rest of the economy often are small or close to non-existent. However, there are indeed major environmental problems with a much wider geographic and economic scope, and calling for measures with potentially quite significant effects on the allocation of resources in the entire national, or even global, economy. “Acid rain”, which is related to emissions of sulfur and nitrogen oxides, is one example. The prime example, however, is “climate change”, which is related to emissions of carbon dioxide and other socalled greenhouse gases8. In both of these cases there is a strong link between the use of energy and the emissions of pollutants. Moreover, in both cases very significant emission reductions are considered to be necessary in order to protect the environment. Not surprisingly CGE models are widely used for evaluation of policies related to climate change and acid rain issues. 7 8 A very nice introduction to this class of CGE models is given in Devarajan and Go (1998). See the Handbook chapter by Charles Kolstad and Michael Toman. 4 CGE models focused on climate change or acid rain problems basically deal with externalities and policies aimed at internalizing externalities. However, environmental problems may also reflect ill-defined property rights, badly functioning capital or insurance markets or some other kind of market failure leading to poor management of natural resources and losses of environmental amenities. Thus in economies highly dependent on natural resources like forests, fisheries, agricultural land or grazing land changes in the natural resource management regime may have economy-wide effects, and appropriately designed CGE models may be able to elucidate and quantify these effects. However, CGE models designed for analysis of this type of natural resource management issues are likely to differ substantially in many respects from CGE models designed for analysis of problems related to externalities. The two types of CGE models are also likely to be used in quite different settings. In the following I will treat each category as a separate type of environmental CGE model. Lacking a better terminology the first category will be called “Externality CGE Models”, while the second will be called “Resource Management CGE Models”. It should immediately be pointed out, however, that in terms of numbers the “Externality CGE Models” completely dominate the field of environmental CGE modeling. What are CGE models good for? Most authors in the field would probably claim that a CGE model is an appropriate substitute for an analytical general equilibrium model whenever the size and complexity, in terms of the number of households and production sectors or pre-existing taxes and other distortions, make such a model mathematically intractable. They would probably also claim that a CGE model is useful whenever the magnitude, and thus not only the sign, of the impact of changes in exogenous conditions on key economic variables are to be estimated. Needless to say most evaluations of policy proposals have to be concerned about the magnitude of the impacts of proposed policy measures, and the effects usually have to be estimated on a relatively detailed sector level. Thus in many instances there are a strong case for using multi-sector numerical models for policy analysis. Whether a specific CGE model, or CGE models in general, can satisfy this need is of course a slightly different issue. CGE models obviously rest upon strong assumptions about optimizing behavior, competitive markets, and flexible relative prices. In addition lack of data usually prohibits econometric estimation of key supply and demand parameters. In view of this the validity and usefulness for policy evaluation of the results generated by CGE models might be, and often is, seriously questioned. However, there is no general answer to the question about what CGE models are good for. The usefulness of a carefully designed and implemented CGE model depends on what it is intended for and what the alternatives are. A CGE model of a complex real-world economy may be useful simply because it can help the analyst to identify general equilibrium effects of changes in exogenous conditions that initially were not obvious. This is the case even if key parameters of the model are quite uncertain. Moreover, even if uncertainty about the numerical values of key parameters makes the magnitude of computed effects of policy changes uncertain, the analyst may be able to safely conclude that the effects in question are “small” or “big”. This is particularly the case as the computational capacity of modern computers has made it possible to carry out very extensive sensitivity analyses, and thus to find out how uncertainty about parameter values 5 and structural aspects of the model affect the results and conclusions of the analysis 9. Sometimes CGE model results may seem counter-intuitive and in the process of explaining such results the modeler gains deeper insights into the interdependencies in the economy. 3. The history of CGE modeling10 The current literature on CGE modeling and economic analyses based on CGE models is vast. It has developed from three quite distinct origins, each one associated with the contributions of a particular author. The three authors are Leif Johansen, Herbert Scarf and Dale W. Jorgenson. In this section I will briefly discuss the contributions of these authors and how they have influenced the development of CGE modeling. I will also briefly comment on the impact of increasingly efficient computers and software on the development of CGE modeling, and close the section with a brief account of the origins of environmental CGE modeling. Leif Johansen and the MSG model In his dissertation A multi-sectoral study of economic growth (1960), the Norwegian economist Leif Johansen presented a numerical model that soon became known as the “MSG model”. This model, which is generally seen as the first CGE model, was primarily intended to be a tool for long term economic forecasting and economic policy evaluation. In the original version there were 20 production sectors and one aggregated household sector. Public consumption, net investments and exports were exogenously determined. Johansen saw the MSG-model as an extended version of an input-output model. Thus, keeping the fixed input coefficients for intermediate inputs, Johansen added value-added production functions and factor markets where market-clearing prices for labor and capital were determined. Although the MSG-model had an obvious flavor of Walrasian general equilibrium theory, it also contained what seemed to be ad hoc assumptions about the determination of wages and the rates of return on capital. Thus, although both labor and capital were entirely mobile across sectors, there were equilibrium inter-sector differences in wages and rates of return on capital. These deviations from Walrasian general equilibrium theory were motivated by the existence of factors and conditions not explicitly dealt with in the model but likely to have an impact on the sectoral development of the economy. Among the factors and conditions mentioned by Johansen were persistent inter-sector differences with respect to the composition of the labor force, working conditions, uncertainty and the degree of monopolization of product markets. In view of these conditions a model entirely based on Walrasian general equilibrium theory was not considered appropriate. Instead the MSG-model was intended to be an approximation of a complex but largely unknown “true” model. The MSG model soon became a key instrument for long term economic planning and forecasting in Norway, and it has been extended in several stages and directions (see Førsund, Hoel and Longva (1985). In particular a considerably more elaborated treatment of factor substitution and energy demand has been incorporated, and a recent version, MSG-EE, is 9 Leif Johansen, whose so-called MSG model is generally regarded as the first CGE model, commented upon the usefulness of his model in the following way: “The data and the quantitative analysis do serve the purpose of illustrating the method and the model. But, at the same time, if I were required to make decisions and take actions in connection with relationships covered by this study, I would (in the absence of more reliable results, and without doing more work) rely to a great extent on the data and the results presented in the following chapters. Thus, the quantitative analysis does not solely serve the purpose of illustrating a method. I do believe that the numerical results also give a rough description of some important economic relationships in the Norwegian reality” (Johansen (1960)). 10 This section is partly based on Bergman (1990). 6 especially designed for analysis of issues related to energy use and environmental pollution (Alfsen et.al. (1996)). It was also the role model for ORANI (see Dixon et.al.(1982)), which is a very elaborated CGE model of the Australian economy and often referred to as a “Johansen model”11. The MSG-model also had an influence on the design of CGE models of developing countries (see for instance Adelman and Robinson (1982)). Herber Scarf and Scarf´s algorithm Herbert Scarf´s famous algorithm for computing a Walrasian general equilibrium (Scarf (1967)) was another point of departure for the development of CGE modeling. Using Scarf´s algorithm John Shoven and John Whalley proved the existence of and designed a computational procedure for finding a general equilibrium with taxes (Shoven and Whalley (1983)). Together with early work on a two-sector model by Arnold Harberger (Harberger (1962)) this inspired a series of analyses of tax and trade policy issues within the frame of Walrasian and Heckscher-Ohlin general equilibrium models. A contribution in the same spirit, but focused on international trade and resource allocation issues in a small open economy, is Norman and Haaland (1987). An early survey is found in Shoven and Whalley (1984), and a more textbook-like one in Shoven and Whalley (1992). In contrast to Johansen´s MSG-model the models developed within the Scarf-ShovenWhalley tradition were firmly rooted in Walrasian general equilibrium theory. To some extent the purpose of the modeling was to “put numbers on the theory”. While Johansen obviously was very concerned about the ability of the model to approximately reflect real world conditions, authors in the Scarf-Shoven-Whalley tradition have stressed transparency and consistency with basic economic theory. Moreover, while Johansen focused on economic growth and long-term structural change, most authors in the Scarf-Shoven-Whalley tradition have had a static welfare economic perspective and focused on the efficiency and distributional effects of various economic policy measures. Dale W. Jorgenson and econometric general equilibrium modeling Dale W. Jorgenson has made several contributions to CGE modeling, but the most unique of these is the systematic use of econometric methods for parameter estimation. This is in sharp contrast to most other CGE models where supply and demand function parameters are estimated with simple calibration techniques12. The development of econometric general equilibrium modeling was made possible by significant contributions by Jorgenson (and coauthors) to production and utility analysis, econometrics and national accounting (see Jorgenson (1998)). An early user of Jorgenson’s approach to CGE modeling was Hazilla and Kopp (1990). Jorgenson´s approach to CGE modeling to some extent combines the Johansen tradition and the Scarf-Shoven-Whalley tradition. Thus, as in Johansen´s work there is a focus on capital accumulation and economic growth. However, while Johansen could only compute the rates of change of key economic variables at a specific point in time, Jorgenson´s analyses are based on a fully dynamic model (of the US economy). Like the models in the Scarf-ShovenWhalley tradition Jorgenson´s models are firmly rooted in neoclassical economic theory and have been used for analyses of the welfare effects of various forms of taxation. But while the static models in the Scarf-Shoven-Whalley tradition were focused on reallocation effects, Jorgenson´s dynamic models were focused on growth effects of various tax policies. 11 It should be noted, however, that this label often was motivated by the fact that ORANI, like the MSG-model, was solved on the basis of a linearization procedure. 12 For a discussion of calibration techniques, see Whalley and Mansur (1984). 7 Computers and software Needless to say the development of CGE modeling would not have been possible without the dramatic development of fast computers and suitable software. In the early days of CGE modeling lack of sufficient computer capacity put serious constraints on the size and specification of CGE models, and lack of user-friendly software made CGE modeling a field for specialists in numerical methods. Computer codes were model-specific and could not easily be used by other modelers. Moreover, sensitivity analyses to evaluate the uncertainty about parameter values were time-consuming. A major change came with the introduction of GAMS (General Algebraic Modeling System, Brooke et. al. (1988)), which allowed non-specialists in numerical methods to design and solve Walrasian models. More efficient computers made it possible to solve models with more sectors, and to take the first steps towards dynamic CGE modeling. It also made extensive sensitivity analysis feasible. As a result the use of CGE models expanded rapidly. The recent developments of GAMS/PATH (Ferris and Munson (2000)13) have made it easy to solve dynamic models with a relatively large number of sectors at a low cost in terms of time and money. This means that CGE modeling gradually has become an accessible tool for applied economics, and “solution time” is no longer an issue for CGE modelers. Instead it is a typical feature of modern CGE studies that a very extensive sensitivity analysis, in which the model is solved for several thousands of randomly selected combinations of values of the uncertain parameters, is carried out. Environmental CGE modeling In connection with the Energy Policy Project in the early 1970´s, summarized in the volume A Time to Choose (Ford Foundation (1974)), Hudson and Jorgenson developed an econometric CGE model for energy policy analysis (see Hudson and Jorgenson (1975)). This turned out to be the first of a large number of models designed for analysis of energy policy issues in the wake of the oil price increases in 1973 and 1979. However, most of these models were energy sector models in which the rest of the economy was represented by an exogenously determined rate of growth of energy demand. A well-known exception is Alan Manne´s so called ETA-MACRO model in which a detailed energy technology assessment model was linked to a neoclassical one-sector model of the rest of the economy (see Manne (1977)). However, in the beginning of the 1990´s the focus shifted from problems associated with the supply of energy to the external effects associated with the use of energy, particularly fossil fuels. One concern was acid rain, but the prime concern was climate change caused by emissions of carbon dioxide. Many of the energy models could easily be redesigned for analysis of carbon taxation and other types of climate policies. In addition a new set of CGE models, designed for climate policy analysis, was developed. One of the most well known is the GREEN model developed at the OECD secretariat (see Burniaux et.al. (1992)) for analysis of climate policy issues at a global scale. At the same time a number of single-country models for environmental policy and resource management analysis in different individual countries were developed. Thus, Hazilla and Kopp (1990) estimated the social cost of environmental quality regulations using a CGE model of the US economy. Bergman (1990) estimated the social cost of phasing out nuclear 13 See also www.gams.com. 8 power in the presence of SO2, NOx and CO2 emission constraints, using a CGE model of the Swedish economy. In the following sections I will discuss the approaches adopted, the issues addressed, and some of the conclusions that have been drawn in environmental CGE modeling. 4. Some General Issues in Environmental CGE modeling Most environmental CGE models are designed to elucidate various aspects of climate change or, in some cases, acid rain policies. To a large extent climate change and acid rain problems are caused by emissions from the combustion of fossil fuels. In both cases the environmental damage depends on the accumulated stock rather than the current flow of pollutants. Moreover, the stocks of the pollutants in question accumulate slowly so there is a considerable time lag, particularly in the case of climate change, between the emission of pollutants and the resulting impact on the environment. These observations have several implications for the design of CGE models intended for policy analysis. One obvious implication is that the model should have an elaborated treatment of the supply and demand for energy. In particular it should have an elaborated treatment of the possibilities to substitute other forms of energy, or other factors of production, for fossil fuels. It should also have an explicit treatment of the relation between the use of fossil fuels and the emission of various pollutants. Another implication of the nature of the environmental problems in question is that the model should take stock accumulation over very long periods of time into account. While the time horizon is one or two decades into the future in typical CGE model analyses of tax or trade policies, the relevant time horizon in climate change policy analysis is several decades or even a century or two into the future. The key modeling problem with such a distant time horizon is that the potential impact of new technologies is quite significant. A third implication for CGE modeling is related to the fact that the benefits of environmental policy measures are “non-economic”, i.e. that they come in the form of better environmental quality. Thus a CGE model intended for cost-benefit analyses of environmental policies should have an “environmental module”, i.e. a module in which the environmental benefits of reduced pollution are quantified and converted into a monetary measure of environmental benefits. The environmental module could also include “feed-back” mechanisms, i.e. a submodel of the impact of environmental improvement (or deterioration) on factor productivity and household utility of environmental services. It is obvious that environmental CGE modeling is quite a demanding task, and that the modeler is bound to encounter a number of intricate modeling issues. It is also obvious that environmental CGE models should be dynamic or at least quasi-dynamic. The purpose of this section is to briefly discuss some commonly adopted modeling approaches in this particular field of CGE modeling. Production sectors CGE models intended to elucidate climate change or acid rain policies need to have an elaborated treatment of the demand for fossil fuels. This has certain implications for the specification of production functions, but also for the production sector division of the model. In particular there is a case for treating the fossil fuel intensive sectors as separate production sectors. For this reason a typical “externality” CGE model has separate production sectors for electricity, transportation, metals, pulp and paper, and chemicals, while the rest of the 9 economy may be aggregated into only a few production sectors. When an elaborated environmental module is incorporated, however, sectors that are affected by climate change (for instance agriculture) or acid rain (for instance forestry) are treated as separate production sectors (see Nordhaus (1994) and Hill (2001)). However, production sectors that are fossil fuel intensive may consist of sub-sectors that differ significantly from this point of view. This is clearly the case for the electricity sector where the output can be produced both by fossil fuel intensive technologies such as coal and oil power, and fossil fuel free technologies such as hydroelectric power and nuclear power. Thus part of the electricity sector response to climate policy measures is to change the mix of different technologies used for power production. In order to capture these substitution possibilities in a realistic way the technological constraints of the electricity sector, or the entire energy sector, is sometimes represented by a separate sub-model rather than by a standard neoclassical production function. The common origin of the energy sector sub-models is the linear activity models used for planning and technology assessment in the energy sector. An elaborated example of a global model in this tradition is Nordhaus (1974). The key feature of these models, often called “bottom-up” models, is that individual technologies for energy extraction, conversion and transportation are distinguished. Among other things this modeling approach makes it easy to incorporate new technologies, such as wind power, with factor input proportions that radically differ from existing technologies. On the other hand the linear energy sector model has to be integrated with “neoclassical” models of the non-energy sectors. An early example of an integrated “bottom-up” energy sector model and a neoclassical “rest-of-the-economy” model is Alan Manne´s above mentioned ETA-MACRO model. Other examples are Jorgenson (1982) and Lundgren (1985), The transportation sector is similar to the electricity sector in the sense that there are several different modes of transportation that exhibit very different properties with respect to the use of fossil fuels per unit of output. The long run response to climate policy measures affecting the transportation sector are likely to include adjustments and substitutions both on the supply and the demand side. However, the modeling of the transportation sector is usually not very elaborated in CGE models intended for environmental policy analysis. The different modes of transportation are often not explicitly distinguished, and there is no measure of the transportation services produced by ordinary firms and households. Moreover, while the demand for transportation services obviously reflects the location of production and consumption activities, most CGE models do not have a spatial dimension. And while the choice between different modes of transportation to a large extent depends on the amount of time that the user has to spend, time is usually not treated as a scarce factor in CGE models. In addition the relative competitiveness of different modes of transportation to a large extent depends on the transportation infrastructure, i.e. roads, railways, airports, etc. Altogether this means that the CGE models developed so far have little to say about the demand for and substitution between different modes of transportation. In order to account for the relevant substitution opportunities some kind of “bottom up” approach might be needed. Production functions The sectoral production functions basically define substitution possibilities between explicitly defined input factors. In CGE models focused on environmental policies related to climate change or acid rain it is important to distinguish not only between capital, labor, non-energy 10 intermediate inputs and energy, but also between fossil and non-fossil energy. Often it is also convenient to distinguish between fuels and electricity. Thus the production function of a representative production sector j in such a CGE model can be written X j f j (K j , L j , M j , Fj , E j ) ; (1) where X is gross output, K capital, L labor, M non-energy intermediate inputs, F fuels and E electricity. In most cases F is an aggregate of various fossil and non-fossil fuels. In the following non-energy intermediate inputs are denoted “materials”. In some CGE models the production function fj(.), or rather its dual cost function, is assumed to have a so called flexible form (translog or generalized Leontief) and the parameters are econometrically estimated. The use of flexible functional forms is a way to circumvent the strong assumptions about the elasticities of substitution between different pairs of inputs implied by the standard production functions. To some extent these functional forms were developed in order to properly deal with the substitutability of energy and other factors of production in econometric general equilibrium models (see Jorgenson (1998a)). However, lack of data often prevents econometric estimation of the sector cost functions. Instead the elasticities of substitution between different inputs generally are “guesstimated”. This means that both the nesting structure of the production functions and the adopted numerical values are based on literature surveys of relevant econometric studies. Thus, based on available external information about elasticities of factor substitutions the technology in most CGE models is described by some kind of nested production function structure in which CES (constant elasticity of substitution), Cobb-Douglas and Leontief production functions are combined. The existing literature on econometric studies of production does not lead to definite conclusions about the most appropriate nesting structure. However, in most models fuels and electricity, i.e. F and E in the equation above, are combined in a CES function with a relatively high elasticity of substitution. The input “fuels” is often defined as a CES-aggregate of different types fossil and non-fossil fuels. The elasticities of substitution between different types of fuels are usually taken to be relatively high. In the case of capital and energy the econometric evidence is conflicting. Some studies indicate that capital and energy are substitutes at the relevant level of aggregation, while others suggest that capital and energy are complements. However, most CGE models assume that capital and energy are substitutes, although the elasticity of substitution between capital and energy is generally taken to be quite low. The nesting structure may differ between different models, but the structure of the sector production function (2) below can be found in many CGE models intended for climate change or acid rain policy analysis. X j f j ( L j , M j , Q j ( K j , H j ( F j ( F j1 ,..., F jn ), E j )) (2) Thus fuels (F), which is an aggregate of n different types of fossil and non-fossil fuels, and electricity (E) are combined in a CES aggregate that defines a composite energy good (H). The composite energy input is combined with capital in a CES aggregate of capital-energy. Then the composite capital-energy input Q is combined with labor (L) and materials (M). In some models, however, capital and labor rather than capital and energy are combined. 11 Emissions and abatement In general the emissions of pollutant per unit of output can be reduced if the input of one, or several, of the other inputs is increased. Thus the possibility to emit pollutants into the environment can be seen as a kind of input in the production process, and it should be possible to estimate the elasticity of substitution between emissions into the environment and other input factors. Estimation of these substitution possibilities obviously requires that the factor inputs and the emissions of pollutants can be appropriately measured. However, the emissions of pollutants such as sulfur and nitrogen oxides and carbon dioxide generally are not measured directly, and in many cases direct measurement is difficult and costly. Instead the emissions are estimated on the assumption that they are proportional to the use of various types of fossil fuels14. This assumption implies that emission reductions can be brought about only by reductions of the consumption of fossil fuels or by changes in the composition of fossil fuel consumption. In practice inter-fuel substitutions can lead to quite significant emission reductions. For instance, the combustion of natural gas gives rise to less emissions of carbon dioxide per unit of energy than coal. Thus substitution of natural gas for coal ceteris paribus reduces the emissions of carbon dioxide at give output levels. However, the emissions of sulfur and nitrogen oxides can be reduced not only by output reductions and by fuel switching. There are also direct abatement possibilities. In order to capture abatement measures some environmental CGE models incorporate abatement cost functions, usually estimated on the basis of generic rather than site-specific engineering data. In representative CGE models the abatement activity is assumed to depend on economic incentives so that abatement takes place whenever the marginal cost of abatement is less than or equal to the cost to the firm, or household, of marginal emissions. The marginal cost of emission, in turn, is determined by charges on emissions or by the price of emission permits (see for instance Hill (2001)). From an institutional point of view it is assumed that specialized firms are supplying abatement services to industries obliged to comply with emission constraints. Technological change In the short and medium term substitution between inputs is a key mechanism in the adjustment to various environmental policy measures. This is why the elasticity of substitution parameters of the sector production functions are so important in CGE models intended for environmental policy analysis. However, as was mentioned above the time horizon in environmental policy analyses often extends several decades or even a century or two into the future. Thus the development and implementation of new technologies might affect emissions and other impacts on the environment much more than substitution between currently existing technologies. Expectations about future relative prices, taxes and regulations clearly have an impact on the speed and direction of technological development. The links between past and current conditions, the formation of expectations about the future and the development and implementation of new technologies are not well understood. Nordhaus (1997) discusses induced technical change in the context of the optimal timing of abatement measures. Goulder and Schneider (1999) introduce a market for R&D services in a CGE model. As the R&D services can be used as a substitute for other factors of production, this means that technological change in effect becomes an endogenous process. 14 Even if the emissions of sulfur and nitrogen oxides could be independently measured, the lack of uniform prices (or emission charges) would cause estimation problems. 12 However, in most CGE models technological change is an exogenous factor making the total factor productivity an increasing function of time. In CGE models intended for energy or environmental policy analysis it is quite common to incorporate specific assumptions about “autonomous energy efficiency improvements” (AEEI). The AEEI-factor is assumed to be exogenously determined and to reflect all factors, except current price-induced substitutions, that make the input of energy in a given production sector grow slower than the output of that sector. The numerical value of the AEEI-factor is often assumed to be in the interval 0-2 percent per annum. Needless to say an AEEI-factor at the level of one percent per annum or more has a very significant impact on energy use, and thus on emissions, in a 50-100 years time perspective. Thus the assumptions made about the numerical value of AEEI in key production sectors may have a very significant impact on the results of the whole modeling exercise. As the CGE model is supposed to elucidate the impact of changes in relative prices on the allocation of resources in the economy, it is of course somewhat disturbing to be forced to treat technological change as an exogenous factor. What is even more disturbing is that the assumptions about positive AEEI-factors seem to rest on somewhat uncertain empirical grounds. Thus Hogan and Jorgenson (1991) show that there is no clear evidence of autonomous energy efficiency increases if price-induced substitution effects are taken into account. In environmental CGE models with a “bottom-up” description of the technology of the energy sector it is quite common to incorporate a “back-stop” technology that becomes available some time in the future. The back-stop technology is typically based on non-exhaustible resources. The date when the back-stop technology is available is exogenously determined, but whether the back-stop technology will be used at that date, at some later date or not at all is endogenously determined in the model. Environmental benefits One way of using an environmental CGE model is to focus on the cost of specific environmental policy measures (such as a ban on the use of nuclear power), or on the cost of attaining a specific environmental policy goal (such as reducing the total sulfur emissions by 30 percent). However, if the model is to be used for evaluation of policies it should be capable of quantifying both the costs and the benefits of the policies in question. This means that the CGE model needs to have an “environmental module” in which the environmental benefits of reduced pollution are quantified and expressed in monetary units. From a purely theoretical point of view the development of such an environmental module is fairly straightforward. In reality a lack of relevant and reliable data makes it an almost impossible task. What is needed in order to construct a “benefit function” can be divided into two sets of functional relationships. The first is a set of physical damage functions that convert emissions and other environmental effects of production and consumption into measures of physical environmental damage (in the case of increased emissions etc.) or improvements (in the case of reduced emissions etc.). The estimation of such functions is obviously outside the realm of economics, and it does not seem to be a prime concern for natural scientists. The second is a set of functions defining the value, in monetary units, of changes in the physical characteristics of the environment. From an economic point of view these changes can take two different, but not mutually exclusive, forms (see the Handbook chapter by Nancy Bockstael and A. Myrick Freeman III). 13 One is that the physical changes in the environment affect the supply of environmental services that are directly “consumed” by the households. In terms of a CGE model this means that changes in environmental quality affect welfare directly via the utility functions of the household(s). Obvious examples of such services are clean air and water. In these and most other cases the environmental services in question can be characterized as public goods. Thus the relevant values cannot be determined on the basis of regular market prices. Instead the valuation has to be based on some estimate of the willingness to pay for the environmental services in question. The other alternative is that the changes in the physical characteristics of the environment only affect the productivity in sectors producing “ordinary” goods and services that are traded on regular markets (see the Handbook chapter by Kenneth McConnell and Nancy Bockstael). In terms of a CGE model this means that changes in environmental quality affect welfare indirectly via the cost of producing ordinary goods and services. The impact of environmental damage on the cost of ordinary goods and services is an example of what is sometimes called “feed-back effects”15. One example of such a feedback effect is the reduction of factor productivity in forestry that may be the result of acid deposition caused by emissions of sulfur. In this case the cost of the environmental damage can be estimated on the basis of regular market prices for forest products. Many environmental CGE models lack a module for environmental benefit calculation, or have an environmental module that is based on shaky data and/or very bold assumptions. Basically two types of approaches have been adopted. One is to focus on feedback effects. An elaborate example is Nordhaus (1994) in which an advanced climate model is used to estimate feedback effects of the emissions of green-house gases. Examples of CGE models with explicit feedback effects are Harrison et.al. (1989), Vennemo (1995) and Hill (2001). Another approach is to assume that politically determined environmental goals, or international agreements on emission reductions, represent an efficient trade-off between the relevant costs and benefits. Given this assumption the parameters of an environmental benefit function can be determined. The benefit function can then be used to evaluate other policy proposals. One example of this approach is Whalley and Wigle (1992). International trade in CGE models The specification of international trade relations is an important aspect of all open-economy CGE models, but seems particularly important in environmental CGE models. The primary reason for this is that international relocation of economic activity is a key potential response to unilateral environmental policy measures. It is beyond the scope of this chapter to discuss specification issues in any detail, but a few words should be said about the treatment of international trade in CGE models of open economies. The natural point of departure then is the Heckscher-Ohlin model of a small open economy in which the technology exhibits constant returns to scale, and the domestic producers are pricetakers on international markets for tradable goods. However, with n goods and m factors, and n>m, the equilibrium output levels in such a model are positive in at most m sectors. Moreover, a small change in a world market price, or a domestic tax rate, may reduce the equilibrium output level in a given sector from a relatively large positive value to zero, or from zero to a relatively large positive value. As most CGE models have many more sectors 15 Another type of feedback effect is the change in the demand for ordinary goods and services caused by changes in environmental quality. 14 than factors this feature of models in the Heckscher-Ohlin tradition tends to produce rather extreme and unrealistic patterns of specialization. This so-called overspecialization problem has attracted a lot of attention in the CGE-modeling literature, and several “solutions” have been proposed. The most widely used approach is to adopt the “Armington assumption” (Armington (1969)), which implies that goods with the same statistical classification but different countries of origin are treated as non-perfect substitutes. The application of this idea in CGE models amounts to defining domestically consumed goods as CES-aggregates of domestically produced and imported goods with the same statistical classification. As a result 16 the import of a given type of goods depends on the relation between the prices of imported and domestically produced goods of that type. Moreover, if the same assumption is applied on the rest of the world the producers of the small open economy will face relative-price dependent export demand functions, and the terms of trade will depend on the volume of exports. This means that the properties of CGE models based on the Armington assumption17 may differ quite significantly from the properties of models based on standard Heckscher-Ohlin assumptions. Another widely adopted approach to the “overspecialization” problem in CGE models is to retain the assumption about exogenously given terms of trade, while relative-price dependent export supply functions are added. These functions usually are derived from constant elasticity of transformation (CET) functions defining the output of a given sector as a revenue-maximizing aggregate of goods for the domestic market and goods for foreign markets. This means that if the price of, say, goods for foreign markets increase the composition of domestic supply is shifted in the direction of more goods for foreign markets and less for the domestic market. The magnitude of the response to changes in relative prices depends on the elasticity of transformation between goods for the two types of markets. Both the Armington assumption and the CET function approach prevent extreme specialization patterns in CGE models with more tradable goods than factors. However, the empirical basis for these approaches seems somewhat questionable. Product differentiation, which is implied by both approaches, clearly is a real world fact, but the patterns of product differentiation depend on market conditions and change over time. In CGE models employing the Armington assumption or using the CET function approach, however, the current patterns of product differentiation in effect are assumed to persist. This means that the models are likely to underestimate the structural effects of long run changes in relative prices. As will be discussed in some detail below this feature might be particularly important in CGE models intended for analysis of environmental policies. 5. Global “Externality” CGE Models During the 1990´s a number of global CGE models intended for analysis of climate change policies were developed and used for policy analysis. The major field of application has been evaluations of various aspects of the Kyoto protocol, i.e. the (not yet ratified) agreement to 16 The Armington assumption implies that the price of the domestically consumed composite of a given type of goods is a linearly homogenous function of the prices of imported and domestically produced goods of that type. By Shephard´s lemma the share of imports in the composite good is given by the partial derivative of the price function with respect to the price of imports. 17 From a microeconomic point of view an Armington model of a small open economy is somewhat questionable in the sense that the firms in a given sector collectively face a downward sloping export demand function, but refrain from forming an export cartel and exploiting their market power on foreign markets. Harris (1984) avoided this problem by modeling product markets as monopolistically competitive. 15 reduce the emissions of carbon dioxide and other greenhouse gases. In fact the commitments by industrial countries under the Kyoto protocol seem to be the primary reason so many global environmental CGE models were developed during the 1990´s. The purpose of this section is to briefly present some of the most well known models, and to discuss some of the results obtained from simulations with global “externality” models. In particular I will discuss what we can learn from the models about the so-called “leakage” problem, i.e. the alleged international relocation of emission-intensive production induced by unilateral climate policy measures. The models The key characteristics of the selected models are summarized in Table 1. This is not a complete list of all existing global CGE models for environmental policy analysis. However, the collection of models included in the list should give a fairly complete account of the modeling approaches, in terms regional and sector division and several other dimensions, generally adopted in this field of CGE modeling. Moreover the list to some extent reflects the continuing development of the several of the models. Thus MIT-EPPA is an upgraded and extended version of GREEN. In the same way 12RT is an extended version of Global 2100, and RICE is a regionalized version of DICE (Nordhaus (1994)). A common feature of the models is that baseline GDP growth essentially is determined by the assumptions made about aggregate savings, technological change and the growth of the labor force in different regions of the world. This means that the emissions of green-house gases to a large extent also is determined by these assumptions. However, the Kyoto commitments are defined in terms of emission reductions in relation to a historical benchmark. Thus the stringency of the imposed emission constraints, and to a large extent the cost of complying with these constraints, in effect is determined by the assumptions about baseline economic growth. For instance, in Manne and Richels (1992) the baseline growth assumptions imply that China will grow faster than the world average, and increase its share of world GDP from 1.8 percent in 1988 to 22.1 percent in the year 2100. Under these conditions it turns out that global emission reduction policies will be very costly, particularly if no emission reduction measures are implemented in China. If China grows more slowly than the world average, however, attaining the emission reduction targets will be considerably less costly. Another common feature is that the models are used for simulations over periods that are long enough to make resource depletion effects important. In order to capture depletion effects Global 2100 and 12RT distinguish between two categories of oil and gas resources. Thus the cost of extracting oil and gas from currently proven reserves is lower than the corresponding cost for the remaining but still unproven stock of reserves. In GREEN coal reserves are assumed to be (practically) infinite, while oil and gas are assumed to be exhaustible resources. The cost of these resources is taken to depend on the initial levels of proven and unproven reserves, the rate of reserve discovery, and the rate of extraction. Moreover the rate of reserve discovery is assumed to depend on world oil and gas prices. Mechanisms that reflect increasing cost of oil and gas as currently proven reserves are exhausted are also incorporated in CRTM, IIAM and the G-Cubed model. However, in the models where a back-stop technology is incorporated the long run cost of energy is capped by the cost of using the backstop technology for energy production. The “leakage” issue According to the Kyoto protocol the so-called Annex I countries, i.e. the high-income OECD countries, should start reducing their carbon dioxide emissions before the countries in the rest 16 of the world. One possible effect of such a policy is “carbon leakage”, i.e. emission sources migrate from abating to non-abating countries. The possibility of carbon leakage is a matter of great concern in several countries, and it seems to be a major obstacle to unilateral emission reduction policies. From a theoretical point of view it is obvious that unilateral action will induce some “leakage”. The question is whether the leakage is quantitatively significant or not. A global CGE model should be suitable tool for assessing the magnitude of carbon leakage due to unilateral emission reduction policies. Pezzey (1992) used the WW-model to estimate the leakage effects of unilateral European Community and OECD carbon dioxide emission reduction policies. Assuming that the emission target was 20 percent below the baseline level, the leakage turned out to be 70 percent. Thus, if OECD reduced emissions by 100 tons of carbon dioxide, the resulting reduction of global emissions would only be 30 tons. Rutherford (1992) also finds that the leakage is significant. In particular he finds that if OECD increases the emission reduction target from 4 percent to 5 percent of current emissions, there would be no reduction at all of global emissions. Thus, according to this particular study the “marginal” leakage effect is 100 percent! However, other CGE-based studies have come to very different results concerning the leakage effect. McKibbin and Wilcoxen (1995) studied unilateral emission abatement by the Annex I countries in accordance with the Kyoto protocol, and found that the leakage effect was 6 percent. In experiments with GREEN the leakage effect was only 3.5 percent when the OECD carbon dioxide emissions were stabilized at the 1990 level. In 12RT the leakage effect is smaller than in the studies by Pezzey and Rutherford, but significantly bigger than in GREEN and the study by McKibbon & Wilcoxen. Thus the estimated leakage effect in 12 RT when Annex I countries act unilaterally is 35 percent. In order to explain these big differences Manne and Martins (1994) made a systematic comparison of 12RT and GREEN simulation results. They found that the leakage effect reflected two main effects of climate policy measures. The first was due to the fact that a tax on carbon dioxide emissions raised the cost of energy intensive production in the abating countries. Thus the relative competitiveness of tradable energy intensive production in the non-abating countries increased, and part of the production decrease in the abating countries was compensated by increased production and net export in the non-abating countries. This effect can be called the “relocation effect”. The second effect was due to the fact that a reduction of energy consumption in the abating countries tends to reduce the world market prices of oil and coal. As a result of the lower prices the consumption of energy, and the emissions of carbon dioxide, increases in the non-abating countries. This effect can be called the “rebound effect”. The large difference between the two models in terms of the leakage effect turned out to primarily depend on the relocation effect, which in turn depended on differences in the treatment of international trade. In GREEN international trade is modeled in accordance with the Armington assumption. This means that similar goods with different country of origin are treated as imperfect substitutes, which tends to dampen the relocation effect. In 12RT, on the other hand, non-energy goods with different country of origin are assumed to be homogenous, which tend to make international trade flows sensitive to changes in relative cost conditions between countries. These findings suggest that the specification of international trade in global CGE models may have a significant impact on the results and thus deserves considerable attention. However, as is demonstrated by McKibbin and Wilcoxen (1995) any 17 factor that makes structural change costly tends to reduce the leakage effect of unilateral climate policies. In their case international relocation of capital is hampered by capital installation costs in the non-abating countries. Concluding remarks A lot more can of course be said about the global models and the studies in which such models have been used for analyses of environmental policy proposals. However, it suffices to conclude that these models and studies to a large extent have formed the “common wisdom” about the economic consequences of the policies suggested by the Kyoto protocol. It could be added that the Kyoto protocol has created an ideal case for using CGE models: the time horizon is far into the future so that short term adjustment problems can be neglected. At the same time the proposed emission reductions are significant and clearly call for policy measures that are likely to have general equilibrium effects both within and between countries and regions. 6. Regional Multi-Country “Externality” CGE Models A model in this category typically covers a region, such as the European Union, and consists of sub-models of each one of the countries within that region. From an environmental policy point of view regional models are suitable for analyses of regional environmental problems, such as acid rain. Regional multi-country CGE models are also used for analyses of policy proposals that imply coordination of the national policies within the region. One example is analyses of the implications of the Kyoto protocol where the European Union, rather than the individual member states, is a signatory party. In this section three representative models and a special problem associated with this category of CGE models will be briefly discussed. The models The main features of the three models are summarized in Table 2. GEM-E3, where E3 stands for Energy, Environment and Economy, is the result of a major project within the JOULE program funded by the European Union. The GEM-E3 model has a quite detailed treatment both of the energy sector and the emissions to the environment. Thus, within the “top-down” energy sector four types of energy, namely electricity, coal, oil and gas, are distinguished. Among other things this allows for a relatively detailed link between the consumption of energy and the emissions to the environment. In GEM-E3 the emissions of five different pollutants, CO2, SO2, NOx and PM (particulate matter), are distinguished, and abatement cost functions for all pollutants except CO2 are included. In addition to “end of pipe” abatement options possibilities to substitute less polluting forms of energy, and other factors of production, for polluting forms of energy are included in the model. The GEM-E3 also has a module in which emissions to the environment are converted into damage to the ecosystem and to public health. In addition damage to materials is included. However, no feedback-effects are included in GEM-E3. In the extended version of the HRWmodel, on the other hand, feedback effects are included. Thus the environmental module distinguishes the emissions of CO2, SO2 and PM, and mortality and morbidity effects are assumed to depend on the stocks and flows of these pollutants. Increased morbidity has both direct welfare effects and feedback effects on the demand for “ordinary” goods and services. Increased mortality is modeled as separable and turns out to be the most significant welfare effect of emissions to the environment. The BFR, model, finally, only treats CO2 emissions, and does not include environmental benefit functions or feedback effects. 18 Specific features and problems Regional multi-country CGE models share many of the features of global CGE models. Both types of models are often used for evaluations of unilateral vs. internationally coordinated policies. As in global CGE models an elaborated treatment of international trade between the individual countries is needed in a regional multi-country model. Data problems are usually less severe in regional multi-country models than in global models, and problems associated with aggregation of data for individual countries can in general be avoided. However, there is a modeling problem that is unique to the regional multi-country models, namely the treatment of “the rest of the world” (ROW). In global models there is by definition no ROW, so the problem does not have to be addressed. In single-country models there is clearly a ROW, but in general it is reasonable to adopt the “small country assumption”. In other words it is assumed that world market prices are given and unaffected by changes in the export, import and factor prices of the single country in question. In regional multi-country models, however, the small country assumption often is untenable. For instance, the European Union accounts for a very significant share of the world trade, and it is likely that the changes the Union’s trade with the rest of the world would influence world market prices. However, if the small country assumption is not adopted some other type of “world closure” has to be included in the model. The problem of “world closure”, i.e. the modeling of how ROW would act in response to the actions of the countries explicitly included in the model, has been widely discussed in the literature on CGE modeling. Early contributions are Whalley and Yeung (1982) and de Melo and Robinson (1989). Koschel and Schmidt (1998) used the GEM-E3 model for an extensive test of the closure rules suggested by Whalley & Yeung and de Melo & Robinson. In the standard version of GEM-E3 it is assumed that the ROW export prices are given and independent of the demand for ROW goods by the European Union. The ROW import demand functions are modeled in accordance with the Armington assumption. Thus the ROW demand for imports from the European Union countries depends on the ratio between exogenously given ROW prices and endogenously determined European Union export prices, and an exogenously given level of output in ROW. In various experiment versions of GEME3 alternative trade specifications were used. The key difference was that ROW prices were assumed to depend on the quantity of ROW exports to the European Union. The conclusion was that the assumptions about the behavior of ROW did influence the results for the countries explicitly treated in the model. This is hardly surprising, and suggests that the only satisfactory way to deal with the “world closure” problem is to extend the regional multicountry model to become a global model, albeit one with a less detailed treatment of ROW. 7. Single-country “Externality” CGE models A large number of single-country environmental CGE models were developed during the 1990´s. Most were designed to elucidate environmental problems or policies that are specific to the country in question. The most commonly studied environmental problem is emissions to air that contribute to climate change or acid rain. Thus most single-country environmental CGE models can be characterized as “externality” CGE models. However, there are also a few single-country models that can be classified as “resource management CGE models”, i.e. are designed to elucidate problems like depletion of natural resources and other natural resource management issues. A selection of representative models is briefly described in Table 3. 19 Single-country environmental CGE models can broadly be divided into three main categories. The first consist of models that primarily are constructed and used for analyses of specific theoretical issues. The prime example is CGE analyses aimed at testing the existence of a socalled “double dividend” (see the Handbook chapter by Anil Markandya for a detailed discussion of this issue). Goulder et.al. (1997) and Bovenberg and de Moij (1994) both belong to this category. The second category is CGE models that are constructed for testing of new model features or modeling approaches, which, if the testing is successful, may be incorporated in models intended for policy analysis. Vennemo (1995), where an approach to incorporate feedback effects from the environment to the economy, belongs to this category. Another example is Abler et.al. (1999) where the impact of parameter uncertainty on simulation results is studied. The third is “multi-purpose” CGE models that are designed for analyses of a wide range of economic and environmental policies. Harrison (1997) belongs to this category. In the following the use of single-country CGE models for analysis of the “double dividend” issue and some natural resource management issues will be briefly discussed. The double dividend issue. The idea that revenues generated by emission taxes could be used to reduce distortionary taxes, and thus produce benefits in addition to those resulting from reduced emissions, has been widely discussed in relation to environmental policy in several countries. Goulder (1995a) contributed to the discussion by defining three types of “double dividends”. The most interesting was the “strong” double dividend which refers to a case where a revenue-neutral substitution of an environmental tax for a representative distortionary tax would lead to a nonpositive welfare cost. In other words emission taxes could be welfare improving even if the environmental benefits were small or even zero! The existence of a strong double dividend seems to have been taken for granted by many politicians. In particular replacement of part of the labor income tax with emission taxes has been seen as an environmentally attractive way of increasing the demand for labor, and such tax reforms have been proposed in several and implemented in some countries. Economists, however, have been more skeptical and the issue has become subject to extensive research. To a large extent this research has been based on CGE models. The double dividend issue offers an ideal case for CGE modeling. It is not a matter of studying the impact of an environmental tax in an economy without taxes, but in an economy with an extensive system of distortionary taxes. Thus the existence of the strong double dividend depends both on how the environmental tax interacts with other taxes, and on how the revenues are recycled. Moreover, even if the sign of the double dividend is a key issue its magnitude is quite important from a policy point of view. What, then, can we learn about the double dividend from CGE model based studies? Using a static CGE model Bovenberg and de Moij (1994) show that a strong double dividend is possible only if the labor supply function is backward-bending, which is not consistent with the findings in empirical studies of labor supply behavior. On the basis of this result they concluded that the strong double dividend does not exist for realistic values of the relevant elasticity parameters. However, a static model is not well suited for analyses of investments and capital taxation. Thus there is a case for using a dynamic CGE model for the analysis of the double dividend issue. 20 Jorgenson and Wilcoxen (1993), used a dynamic model and they found that a strong double dividend exists when the revenues from the environmental tax are used to reduce capital taxes. If the revenues instead were used to reduce labor taxes, however, there was no strong double dividend. However, neither Goulder (1995b) nor Bovenberg and Goulder (1997), who also used dynamic models of the U.S. economy, found evidence of a strong double dividend. One reason for this was that both Goulder and Bovenberg & Goulder assumed that capital was immobile across sectors, while Jorgenson and Wilcoxen assumed full inter-sector capital mobility. In contrast to the results by Jorgenson and Wilcoxen (1993) Bye (2000), who used a dynamic model of the Norwegian economy, found that a revenue-neutral swap between an increased environmental tax and a reduced tax on labor income was welfare increasing. According to Bye the differences between Jorgenson´s and Wilcoxens´s results and her own results depend on the fact that the marginal excess burden is higher for capital taxation than for labor taxation in the U.S., while the opposite holds in Norway. However, in Böhringer and Pahlke (1997), who also used a dynamic model, no strong double dividend could be found. Thus the conclusion that emerges from the CGE model analyses is that the existence of a strong double dividend can neither be taken for granted nor entirely ruled out. 8. CGE models of resource depletion and management As developing countries tend to be more dependent on natural resources than industrialized high-income countries CGE models focused on natural resource management issues are typically models of developing countries. However, the “externality” type of environmental CGE models completely dominates the field. In fact very few models are focused on natural resource management and policy issues. Devarajan (1988) surveys the issues that have to be dealt with in a CGE model of a developing country in which the economy to a large extent depends on a depletable resource. Three different perspectives are adopted, and the related CGE modeling issues are discussed. In the first the natural resource is seen as an input to production. In the second, denoted the “Dutch disease” perspective, it is seen as a source of revenue for the economy. In the third the analysis is focused on the exhaustibility of the resource and the inter-temporal resource allocation issues related to that. However, most models of developing countries are focused either on pollution problems or issues related to excessive exploitation of natural resources. A few examples are given in the following. Xie and Saltzman (2000) present both a general framework for CGE models of developing countries and a specific model of the Chinese economy. As a basis for the CGE model they develop an environmentally extended social accounting matrix (ESAM) to serve as a consistent data set for calibrating the model. The China model is used for an evaluation of pollution control policies focused on wastewater, smog dust and solid waste. A recent model with an elaborated treatment of natural resources is Abler et.al. (1999). It is a model of Costa Rica, and one of the distinguishing features of the model is that it includes eight different environmental indicators, including the degree of deforestation and the degree of over-fishing. The impact of production and consumption activities is essentially modeled as external effects, and the environmental indicators are in effect treated as public goods. 21 Persson and Munasinghe (1995)18 also use a model of Costa Rica and focuses on deforestation. In the model deforestation is an endogenous result of ill-defined rights to forestland. Thus, when property rights to forest land are not well defined and protected loggers and squatters neglect the value of maintaining the land in question for forestry in the future, and the incentives to deforestation are strong. When, on the other hand, property rights to forestland are well defined the owners take the value of maintaining the forest into consideration, and the incentives for deforestation are much weaker. Another example of a CGE model focused on natural resource management issues is Unemo (1995). The purpose of the study is to analyze unintended side effects of government policies in Botswana. One key feature of the model is that “capital” in the livestock sector has the form of cattle. Another key feature is a measure of land pressure, measuring the ratio between the number of hectares of grazing land and the number of cattle held on that land. Grazing land is treated as a common property resource. The idea is that an increase in the number of cattle per unit of grazing land has a negative impact on productivity in the livestock sector. The land pressure variable can also been seen as an indicator of environmental quality. Using the model Unemo finds some interesting relations between, on the one hand, economic policy measures and changes in world market conditions and, on the other hand, environmental quality. Thus in one case it was assumed that there was a fall in the world market price of diamonds, which is a major export product of Botswana. According to the model the lower world market price of diamonds would lead to a deterioration of environmental quality, in terms of land pressure, in Botswana. The reason is that lower revenues from diamond export lead to lower demand for manufactured goods and thus a lower rate of return of capital in the manufacturing sector. As a result of that capital is reallocated to the livestock sector, i.e. the number of cattle increased. As a result the pressure on land increases. This result illustrates that a CGE model can reveal indirect interdependencies in the economy that are not immediately obvious to the analyst. 9. Concluding remarks In terms of the number of models, and studies based on these models, CGE modeling has expanded very significantly, particularly during the 1990´s. Currently CGE modeling is both a field for specialized research, and an almost standard part of the toolbox of economists concerned with policy-oriented research. A major reason for the widespread use of CGE modeling probably is that a CGE model is an ideal bridge between economic theory and applied policy research. The “bridge” perspective, however, suggests that CGE modeling is a way of using rather than testing economic theory. Yet carefully designed and estimated CGE models have a lot to say about real world economies. CGE modeling has made significant progress in terms of the size and complexity of the models that can be solved. Thus, while the early CGE models were simple static Walrasian models of a single economy, later CGE models to a large extent are dynamic, multi-country or global. There are also models with imperfect competition in one or several markets. In environmental CGE modeling both the dynamic and the multi-country features have made CGE models useful for in analyses of important policy issues such as climate change and acid rain. However, in many cases the damage caused by emission of pollutants is uncertain and policy measures could in effect be seen as an insurance against future catastrophic damage. 18 Their model is described in detail in Persson’s PhD dissertation, Haksar (1997). 22 Thus a desirable further development of environmental CGE modeling is to incorporate uncertainty. Yet complexity should never be an end in itself in CGE modeling. Much of the usefulness of a CGE model stems from its solid foundation in basic economic theory. Thus, even if simulation results from a standard CGE model sometimes may be surprising they can always be explained in terms of well known income and substitution effects in combination with interdependencies between markets. The addition of non-standard features, such as imperfect competition on product and factor markets, price rigidities and inter-temporal relations, may make the model more “realistic”. But that may also imply that the transparency of the CGE model is lost. References Abler, D., A.G. Rodriguez and J.S. Shortle (1999), “Parameter Uncertainty in CGE Modeling of the Environmental Impacts of Economic Policy”, Environmental and Resource Economics, 14, 75-94. Adelman, I. and S. Robinson (1982), Income Distribution Policy in Developing Countries. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Alfsen, K.H., T.A. Bye and E. Holmøy (1996), “MSG-EE: An Applied General Equilibrium Model for Energy and Environmental Analyses”. Social and Economic Studies. Oslo: Statistics Norway. Armington, P. (1969), “A Theory of Demand for Products Distinguished by Place of Production”, IMF Staff Papers, 16, 159-78. Ayres, R.U. and A.V. Kneese (1969), “Production, Consumption and Externalities”, American Economic Review, vol. 59, no. 3, June, 282-297. Babiker, M.H., K.E. Maskus and T.F. Rutherford (1997), “Carbon Taxes and the Global Trading System”. Paper presented at the International Energy Workshop and Energy Modeling Forum Meeting, IIASA, June 23-25. Bergman, L. (1990), “Energy and Environmental Constraints on Growth: A CGE Modeling Approach”, Journal of Policy Modeling, 12(4):671-691. Bergman, L. (1990), “The Development of Computable General Equilibrium Modeling”, in Bergman, L., D.W. Jorgenson and E. Zalai (1990), General Equilibrium Modeling and Economic Policy Analysis. Cambridge and Oxford: Basil Blackwell. Bernstein, P.M., W.D. Montgomery, T.F. Rutherford and Gui-Fang Yang (1999), “Effects of Restrictions on International Permit Trading: The MS-MRT Model”, The Energy Journal, Special Issue: The Costs of the Kyoto Protocol: A Multi-Model Evaluation. Böhringer, C. and A. Pahlke (1997), “Environmental Tax Reforms and the Prospects for a Double Dividend” Böhringer, C., M. Ferris and T.F. Rutherford (1998), “Alternative CO2 Abatement Strategies for the European Union”, in Braden, J. and S. Proost (eds.) Climate Change, Transport and Environmental Policy: Empirical Applications in a Federal System. London: Edward Elgar. Bollen, J., A. Gielen and H. Timmer (1999), “Clubs, Ceilings and CDM: Macroeconomics of Compliance with the Kyoto Protocol”, The Energy Journal, Special Issue: The Costs of the Kyoto Protocol: A Multi-Model Evaluation. 23 Bovenberg, A.L. and R.A. de Moij (1994), “Environmental Levies and Distortionary Taxation and Labor Market Distortions”, European Journal of Political Economy, 10(4), 655-683. Bovenberg, A.L. and L.H. Goulder (1997), “Costs of Environmentally Motivated Taxes in the Presence of Other Taxes: General Equilibrium Analyses”, National Tax Journal, Brooke, A., D. Kendrick and A. Meeraus (1988), GAMS. A User´s Guide. Redwood City, Ca.: Scientific Press. Burniaux, J-M, J.P. Martin and J.O. Martins (1992), “GREEN: A Global Model for Quantifying the Cost of Policies to Curb CO2 Emissions”, OECD Economic Studies, no. 19. Bye, B. (2000), “Environmental Tax Reform and Producer Foresight: An Intertemporal Computable General Equilibrium Analysis”, Journal of Policy Modeling, Vol. 22, No. 6, 719-752. Capros, P., T. Georgakopoulos, D. Van Regemorter, S. Proost, K. Conrad, T. Schmidt,Y. Smeers, N. Ladoux, M. Vielle and P McGregor (1995), GEM-E3.Computable General Equilibrium Model for Studying Economy-Energy-Environment Interactions. European Commission. EUR 16714 EN. Conrad, K. (1999), “Computable General Equilibrium Models for Environmental Economics and Policy Analysis”, in J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (ed.) Handbook of Environmental and Resource Economics, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. De Melo, J. and S. Robinson (1989), “Product Differentiation and the Treatment of Foreign Trade in Computable General Equilibrium Models”, Journal of International Economics, 27, 47-67. Debreu, G. (1959), Theory of Value. Cowles Foundation. New York: John Wiley & Sons. Devarajan, S. (1988), “Natural Resources and Taxation in Computable General Equilibrium Models of Developing Countries”, Journal of Policy Modeling, 10(4), 505-528. Devarajan, S. and D.S. Go (1998), “The Simplest Dynamic General-Equilibrium Model of an Open Economy”, Journal of Policy Modeling, 20(6):677-714. Farmer, K. and K.W. Steininger (1999), “Reducing CO2 Emissions under Fiscal Retrenchment”: A Multi-cohort CGE model for Austria”, Environmental and Resource Economics, 13(3):309-40. Ferris, M.C. and T.S. Munson (2000), GAMS/PATH User Guide, www.gams.com. Ford Foundation (1974), A Time to Choose: America´s Energy Future (1974). Final Report by the Energy Policy Project of the Ford Foundation. Cambridge: Ballinger. Førsund, F.R., M. Hoel and S. Longva (1985), Production, Multi-Sectoral Growth and Planning. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Goulder, L.H. (1995a), “Environmental Taxation and the ‘Double Dividend’: A Reader´s Guide”, International Tax and Public Finance, 2(2), 157-183. Goulder, L.H. (1995b), “Effects of Carbon Taxes in an Economy with Prior Tax Distortions: An Intertemporal General Equilibrium Analysis”, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, October. Goulder, L.H., I.W.H Perry and D. Burtraw (1997), “Revenue-Raising vs. Other Approaches to Environmental Protection: The Critical Significance of Pre-Existing Tax Distortions”, RAND Journal of Economics. Winter. Goulder, L.H. and S.H. Schneider (1999), “Induced Tecnical Change and the Attractiveness of CO2 Abatement Policies”, Resource and Energy Economics, 21(2-3), 211253. Haksar, A. (1997), Environmental Effects of Economywide Policies: Case Studies of Costa Rica and Sri Lanka. PhD dissertation, Stockholm School of Economics. 24 Harberger, A.C. (1962), “The Incidence of the Corporate Income Tax”, Journal of Political Economy, 70 (3), June, 215-40. Harris, R. (1984), “Applied General Equilibrium Analysis of Small Open Economies with Scale Economies and Imperfect Competition”, American Economic Review, 74, December, 1016-31. Harrison, G.W., T.F. Rutherford and I. Wooton (1989), “The Economic Impact of the European Community”, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 79 (May) 288-294. Harrison, G.W. and T.F. Rutherford (1997), “Burden Sharing, Joint Implementation, and Carbon Coalitions”, in C. Carraro (ed.) International Environmental Agreements on Climate Change, Amsterdam: Kluwer Academic Press. Harrison, G.W., J. Jensen, M.I. Lau and T.F. Rutherford (1997), “”Passing the Laugh Test: Version 0 of the MobiDK Model”. Available at www.gams.com/projects/dk/mobiDK.htm. Hazilla, M. and R.J. Kopp (1990), “Social Cost of Environmental Quality Regulations: A General Equilibrium Analysis”, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 98, no. 4, 853-873. Hill, M. (2001), “Essays on Environmental Policy Analysis: Computable General Equilibrium Approaches Applied to Sweden”, PhD dissertation, Stockholm School of Economics. Hogan, W.W. and D.J. Jorgenson (1991), “Productivity Trends and the Cost of Reducing CO2 Emissions”, The Energy Journal, 12(1), 67-85. Hudson, E.A. and D.W. Jorgenson (1975), “U.S. Energy Policy & Economic Growth 19752000”, Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5(2), Autumn, 461-514. Johansen, L. (1960), A Multi-sectoral Study of Economic Growth. Amsterdam: NorthHolland. Jorgenson, D.W. (1982), “Econometric and Process Analysis Models for Energy Policy Assessments”, in R. Amit and M. Ariel (eds.), Perspectives on Resource Policy Modeling: Energy and Minerals. Cambridge: Ballinger. Jorgenson, D.W. (1998a), Growth. Volume 1: Econometric General Equilibrium Modeling. Cambridge: The MIT Press. Jorgenson, D.W. (1998b), Growth. Volume 2: Energy, the Environment and Economic Growth. Cambridge: The MIT Press. Jorgenson, D.W. and P.J. Wilcoxen (1993), ”Reducing U.S. Carbon Emissions: An Econometric General Equilibrium Assessment”, Resource and Energy Economics, 14, 243-268. Kainuma, M., Y. Matsuoka and T. Morita (1999), “Analysis of Post-Kyoto Scenarios: The Asian-Pacific Integrated Model”, Ljungqvist, L. and T.J. Sargent (2000), Recursive Macroeconomic Theory. Cambridge: MIT Press. Lundgren, S. (1985), “Model Integration and the Economics of Nuclear Power”. PhD dissertation, Stockholm School of Economics. Mäler, K.G. (1974), Environmental Economics. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press. Manne, A. (1977), “ETA-MACRO: A Model of Energy-Economy Interactions”, in Hitch, C.J. (ed.) Modeling energy-economy interactions: Five approaches.Washington DC: Resources for the Future. Manne, A. and R. Richels (1990), “Global 2100: Model Formulation”. Stanford University. Manne, A. and R. Richels (1992), Buying Greenhouse Insurance: The Economic Cost of CO 2 Emission Limits. Cambridge: MIT Press. 25 Manne, A. and J.O. Martins (1994), “Comparison of Model Structure and Policy Scenarios: GREEN and 12RT”, OECD Economics Department Working Paper. No. 146. McKibbin, W.J. and P.J. Wilcoxen (1995), “The Theoretical and Empirical Structure of the G-Cubed Model”, Brookings Discussion Papers in International Economics # 18. The Brookings Institution. Washington D.C. Nordhaus, W.D. (1974), “The Allocation of Energy Resources”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 4:1974, 529-577. Nordhaus, W.D. (1994), Managing the Global Commons: The Economics of Climate Change. Cambridge: The MIT Press. Nordhaus, W.D. and Z. Yang (1996), “A Regional Dynamic General-Equilibrium Model of Alternative Climate Change Strategies”, American Economic Review, vol. 86, No. 4, September, 741-765. Nordhaus, W.D. (1997). Modeling Induced Innovation in Climate Change Policy. Paper presented at the Workshop on Induced Technological Change, June 1997, IIASA, Austria. Norman, V.D. and J. Haaland (1987), “VEMOD – a Ricardo-Viner-Heckscher-Ohlin-Jones Model of Factor-Price Determination”, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 89 (3), 251-70. Parry, I.W.H, R. Williams and L.H. Goulder (1998), “When Can Carbon Abatement Policies Increase Welfare? The Fundamental Role of Distorted Factor Markets”, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, Persson, A. and M. Munasinghe (1995), “Natural Resource Management and Economic Policies in Costa Rica: A Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) Approach”, The World Bank Economic Review, 9(2), 259-85. Pezzey, J. (1992), “Analysis of Unilateral CO2 Control in the European Community and OECD”, The Energy Journal, 13(3), 159-171. Pohjola, J. (1999), “Economy-wide effects of reducing CO2 emissions: A comparison between net and gross emissions”, Journal of Forest Economy, 5:1, 139-168. Robinson, S., A. Yúnez-Naude, R. Hinojosa-Ojeda, J.D. Lewis and S. Devarajan (1999), “From stylized to applied models: Building multisector CGE models for policy analysis”, North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 10, 5-38. Rutherford, T.F. (1992), “The Welfare Effects of Fossil Carbon Restrictions: Results from a Recursively Dynamic Trade Model”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 112. Scarf, H.E. (1967), “On the Computation of Equilibrium Prices”, in Feliner, W.J. (ed), Ten Economic Studies in the Tradition of Irving Fisher. New York: John Wiley & Sons. Shoven, J.B. and J. Whalley (1984), “Applied General Equilibrium Models of Taxation and Trade: An Introduction and Survey”, Journal of Economics Literature, 22, September, 1007-51. Shoven, J.B. and J. Whalley (1992), Applying General Equilibrium. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Unemo, L. (1995), “Environmental Impact of Governmental Policies and External Shocks in Botswana: A Computable General Equilibrium Approach”, in Perringer, C.A. et.al. (eds.), Biodiversity Conservation. Amsterdam: Kluwer. Vennemo, H. (1995), “A Dynamic Applied General Equilibrium Model with Environmental Feedbacks”, Economic Modeling, 14, 99-114. Whalley, J. and A. Mansur (1984), “Numerical Specification of Applied General Equilibrium Models: Estimation, Calibration and Data”, in H.E. Scarf and J.B. Shoven (eds), 26 Applied General Equilibrium Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 69-127. Whalley, J. and R. Wigle (1991), “The International Incidence of Carbon Taxes”, in R. Dornbush and J.M. Poterba, Economic Policy Responses to Global Warming. Cambridge: MIT Press. Whalley, J. and R. Wigle (1992), “International Linkages and Carbon Reduction Initiatives”, in K. Anderson and R. Blackhurst (eds.), The Greening of World Trade Issues. Harvester, Wheatsheaf. Whalley, J. and B. Yeung (1982), “External Sector “Closing” Rules in Applied General Equilibrium Models”, Journal of International Economics, 16, 123-138. Xie, J. and S. Saltzman (2000), “Environmental Policy Analysis: An Environmental Computable General Equilibrium Model for Developing Countries”, Journal of Policy Modeling, 22(4):453-489. Yang, Z., R.S. Eckaus, A.D. Ellerman and H.D. Jacoby (1996), “The MIT Emissions Predictions and Policy Analysis (EPPA) Model”. Report 6. MIT Joint Program on the Science of Global Change. 27 Table 1. Key characteristics of selected global CGE models Model Reference WW Whalley and Wigle (1991) Burniaux et.al. (1992) GREEN Global 2100 Regions 6 Sectors per Dynamics region 3 Static 12 11 5 2 12RT Manne and Richels (1992) Manne (1993) 12 2 CRTM Rutherford (1992) 5 3 G-Cubed McKibbin et.al. (1995) 8 12 MIT-EPPA Yang et.al. (1996) 12 8 RICE 13 1 5 2 UR Nordhaus and Yang (1996) Harrison and Rutherford (1997) Babiker et.al. (1997) 26 13 MS-MRT Bernstein et.al. (1999) 10 6 IIAM AIM WorldScan Quasidynamic Fully dynamic Fully dynamic Quasidynamic Fully dynamic Quasidynamic Fully dynamic Fully dynamic Static Energy sector Top-down Backstop technology No Technological change None Environmental benefits Yes Top-down Yes AEEI No Bottom-up Yes AEEI No Bottom-up Yes AEEI No Bottom-up Yes AEEI No Top-down No None No Top-down Yes AEEI No ** Yes AEEI Yes Top down No None No Top down No None No AEEI No AEEI No None No Fully Top down Yes dynamic Kainuma et.al. (1999) 21 11 QuasiTop-down No dynamic Bollen et.al. (1999) 13 11 QuasiTop-down No dynamic * No trade between regions. In some cases carbon permits can be traded against the aggregate good. ** The energy sector is a part of the single aggregated production sector. 28 Table 2. Key characteristics of selected regional multi-country CGE models Model GEM-E3 BFR HRW Reference Regions Sectors per Dynamics Energy sector region Capros et.al All EU Member States 18 Quasi-dynamic Top-down (1995) and ROW Böhringer et.al. Germany, France, UK, 23 Static Top-down (1998). Italy Spain Denmark and ROW Harrison et.al. US, Japan, France, 6 Static Top-down (1989) Italy, UK, Ireland Germany, Netherlands, Belgium, Denmark, and ROW Backstop technology No Technological change AEEI Environmental benefits Yes No - No No - Yes 29 Table 3. Key characteristics of selected single-country CGE models Reference Country Number of sectors 36 Dynamics Energy goods Emissions Quasi-dynamic Electricity, coal, natural gas, oil - 7 13 Static Dynamic SO2, NOx, CO2 - 6 Static Electricity, fuels Electricity, coal, natural gas, oil Natural gas, coal, oil Jorgenson and USA Wilcoxen (1993) Alfsen et.al. Norway (1996) 35 Dynamic 33 Dynamic Vennemo (1995) Norway Harrison et.al. Denmark (1997) Pohjola (1999) Finland 6 117 18 Dynamic Static and dynamic versions Quasi-dynamic Abler et.al. (1999) Costa Rica Austria 15 Static 8 Sweden 17 Overlapping generations Dynamic China 7 Static Hazilla and Kopp (1990) USA Bergman (1990) Bovenberg and Goulder (1997) Parry et.al. (1998) Sweden Farmer and Steininger (1999) Hill (2001) Xie and Saltzman (2000) CO2 Electricity, coal, natural CO2 gas, oil Electricity, natural gas, oil SO2, NOx, VOC, O3, CO, CO2, CH4, N2O, Electricity, oil Electricity, natural gas, coal, oil Coal, natural gas, peat, wood, heating fuels, gasoline Electricity, oil Electricity, fossil fuels Electricity, gas, coal, oil Aggregated energy SO2, NOx, CO, PM CO2, CO2, Special features Econometrically estimated parameters; technology-based environmental regulations Tradable emission quotas Synthetic fuel as a backstop resource Tradable CO2 quotas and taxes Econometrically estimated parameters; endogenous productivity growth Damage functions defining damage to public health, forests, lakes and building materials Feedback effects. Carbon sinks Eight environmental quality indicators CO2, SO2, NOx, CO2 Waste water, smog dust, solid waste Different cohorts Inter-temporal emissions trading; feedback effects Pollutant-specific abatement sectors