Rise and Demise of the Qing Empire Imperial Hegemony, Popular Resistances and Arrested Capitalism in China’s Long Eighteenth Century Ho-fung Hung Johns Hopkins University The Enigma of China-Europe Divergence Now, it is widely recognized that the “rise of the West” and the “fall of the East” were two complementary, mutually constitutive processes. But when and how the East, China in particular, fell behind Europe is a topic of constant debate. Abu-Lughod’s (1989) and Mark Elvin’s (1973) contention that China turned stagnant after its fifteenth-century retreat from the maritime world is recently challenged by Frank and others. It is shown that China’s post-medieval economic slowdown was only temporary, and was soon followed by a resurgence of commerce in sixteenth through eighteenth centuries as a result of the massive influx of American silver (Frank 1998; Atwell 1998). Qing China was reputed as the “sink of silver” that absorbed most of the bullion originating in the Americas, and was the largest market formation in the eighteenth-century global economy. As pointed out by Chase-Dunn and Hall (1997: 189-192), in most of the early modern period, Europe at large was a peripheral zone in the Afroeurasian prestigegood networks, and Europe’s “long-distance trade with China was one of unequal exchange in which the Chinese were gaining greater returns” (1997: 191). Commercial prosperity and political stability in China were admired by many contemporaneous philosophers and court-advisers in Europe, such as Quesnay and Voltaire, who wrote emphatically and convinced the absolute monarchs that China was the model to follow regarding the development of laissez-faire economy and absolutist rule. Europe’s global hegemony was never a reality before the latter half of the eighteenth century when China’s market economy (as an economic system based on generalized commodity exchange, or the formula of C-M-C) continued its quantitative expansion without any qualitative transformation into capitalism (as an economic system based on the ceaseless accumulation of capital, or the formula of M-C-M’), while the capitalist development in Europe entered a new phase of industrial expansion (see Arrighi’s [1994: 1-26] and Braudel’s [1977; 1992] delineation of the distinction between market and capitalism) Hence, the central question was why the early modern market economy in Europe led to the rise of capitalism, whereas a more advanced market formation in China did not give rise to capitalism. Currently, the geopolitical and ecological arguments were the most popular explanations of China-Europe divergence. The geopolitical explanation asserts that it was the fragmented political system in Europe that led to incessant interstate competition for mobile capital 1 and stimulated the private and ceaseless accumulation of capital there (Wong 1997; cf. Arrighi and Hung 2002). The ecological explanation inferred that the European conquest of the New World created a vast new frontier for Europe and enabled the latter to surpass the ecological constraints that put a ceiling over productivity growth in both China and Europe (Pomeranz 2000). Notwithstanding the insights that these two perspectives offer, their explanations are far from sufficient. Both perspectives try to explain the dynamic emergence or non-emergence of capitalism in terms of unchanging political economic structures. The arguments are ahistorical and deterministic. Bin Wong sees the non-emergence of capitalism in China had almost been predestined by the end of the Warring States Period in 221 B.C.E. (Wong 1997: 73-104). Pomeranz sees the great divergence between Europe and China was predestined at the point of the European conquest of America. The complex socio-political processes and unfolding of events that linked up the macro-geopolitical or ecological settings concerned and the outcome of transition or non-transition to capitalism are missing. A more historical and nuanced account of the China-Europe divergence is not possible unless historical actors are brought into the analysis. To Wallerstein (1974; 1989), the transition to capitalism in Europe was as much the emergence of new actors – the section of aristocratic elites that shifted to capital accumulating activities as a new strategy of class reproduction – as the emergence of a new system. This theme in the classical world-system formulation is recently developed by Lachman (2000), who contends that the rise of capitalism in early modern Europe was a consequence of a chain of piecemeal calculations and actions of the feudal elites who were in constant conflict with one another and part of whom, given the particular socio-political milieus they were embedded, unintentionally converted themselves into full-scale capital accumulators. Another flaw of the geopolitical and ecological perspectives is that they fail to delineate the specificity of China’s social and political formations positively. The specificity of China is defined as a collection of lacks – the lack of interstate competition, the lack of an outlet of ecological pressure (cf. the lack of Protestant ethics as to Weber). This approach is not wrong per se, but it leads us to neglect half of the equation. It is equally important to look for political, social, or ideological formations that China possessed and Europe lacked, formations that prevented the logic of capital accumulation from being predominant in China, or in a Polanyian formulation, formations that protected the Chinese society from the unchecked emergence of a self-regulatory market (Polanyi 1944; cf. Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997: 18990). 2 In this paper, I will explicate the complex socio-political processes that led to the non-transition to capitalism in China by focusing on the class reproduction process of the gentry elites. I argue that in early modern China as in early modern Europe, the expansion of generalized commodity exchange opened a new window of opportunity for the preexisting elites to reproduce themselves by participating in trade and accumulating monetary wealth. However, the particular habitus – structured structures and structuring structures that constrained and enabled actors’ actions as defined by Bourdieu (1990: 52-65) – in which the Chinese gentry embedded constricted their self-transformation into full-fledged capital accumulator. Great Transformation, Chinese Style Commercial Expansion and Ecological Pressure China’s long eighteenth-century, beginning in 1683 (when the empire recovered from a deflationary depression) and ending in 1820 (when the empire began to enter another round of deflationary depression), is generally known as the Shengshi (Age of Prosperity) or the High Qing period in China (see Figure 2 below). This period covered the late Kangxi reign (1662-1722), the Yongzheng reign (1723-1735), the Qianlong reign (1736-1795), and part of the Jiaqing reign (1796-1820). The century-long economic boom was attributed by many to the massive influx of American silver and the huge demand for Chinese products in the world market, as the imported silver stimulated commercial growth by vastly increasing the monetary supply in the economy (e.g. Quan 1987, 1996a; Frank 1998: 108-11, 160-1; Naquin and Rawski 1987: 104; Rowe 1998: 177; Chao 1993; Atwell 1977, 1982, 1998). Though American silver began to flow into China in the late sixteenth century, the inflow was soon hampered by the turbulent dynastic transition in the mid-seventeenth century, when the Ming dynasty collapsed and the Manchus conquered China. Internal peace had been restored under the unified rule of the Qing government by 1650. But the early Qing ban on sea trade that cut off the Ming loyalists in Taiwan from mainland supply disrupted the flow of silver into China and dragged the nascent Qing empire into a prolonged period of deflationary depression. The depression ended in 1683 after the Taiwan regime surrendered and the ban on foreign trade was lifted (Kishimoto-Nakayama 1984). Besides the commercial expansion, the long eighteenth century was also characterized by a mounting ecological pressure. Thanks to the political and social stability after the late seventeenth century and the popularization of New World Crops such as sweet potato and maize that turned originally unproductive lands into productive ones, population of China tripled between the mid-seventeenth and the mid-nineteenth century. The total acreage of cultivable land, however, 3 only doubled during the same period (Wang 1973: 7; Naquin and Rawski 1987: 24-6; Ho 1959). The diminishing of landman ratio, together with the depletion of natural resources caused by rapid commercial expansion, led to a looming ecological crisis in the empire (Elvin 1998, Marks 1996). Fig. 1. Index of population, cultivated land and average cultivated land per head, 1380-1930 (1380=100) population 800 cultivated land land-man ratio 700 600 Index 500 400 300 200 100 1930 1880 1830 1780 1730 1680 1630 1580 1480 1430 1380 1530 0 Year Source: official data adjusted with reference to Perkins (1969: 16); compiled by Liu and Hwang (1979: 81-2) The dual increase in monetary supply and population pressure triggered a century-long inflation known as the “Chinese price revolution” of the eighteenth century (Quan 1996b). Thorough the century, the price level of China had increased by 3-4 times (Wang 1980; Guo 1996; Quan 1996b & c). Figure 2. Rice price s in the Yangz i De lta, 1650-1900 (tae ls pe r shi) 4.5 Price 25 years moving average 4 3.5 3 Price 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 Year Source: modified from Wang (1992: 40-47) 4 1890 1875 1860 1845 1830 1815 1800 1785 1770 1755 1740 1725 1710 1695 1680 1665 1650 0 The inflationary pressure was not distributed evenly over space, as it hit the economically advanced regions most. Price level was the highest in the Lower Yangzi Delta, lowest in the Southwest, and intermediate in the Mid-Yangzi region (Quan 1996d). The inflation and inter-regional price difference touched off extensive regional specialization and economic growth driven by Smithian dynamics (see Wong 1997: Part I; Pomeranz 2000). While the Lower Yangzi region (southern Jiangsu province and northern Zhejiang province) and the southern-southeastern coast (the Fujian and Guangdong provinces) witnessed sweeping urbanization and proto-industrialization, and increasingly concentrated on producing high value-added products such as silk and cotton textiles, areas with lower inflationary pressure such as the Upper Yangzi region (the Sichuan province) and the empire’s Southwest (the Guangxi and Yunnan province) were transformed into peripheral zones that supported the development of the economically advanced regions by exporting foodstuffs and other raw materials like timber, silk cocoon and raw cotton to the latter. An empire-wide market with a core-periphery division of labor was in shape (Hung 2001: 491-7). Price movements in different regions of the empire were more or less in phase (Rowe 1998; Xu 1999; Wu 1983; Naquin and Rawski 1987: 214-6; Li 1999; Fan 1992; Marks 1996, 1998; Fan 1998: ch. 2; Quan 1996d). Class Formations and the Making of an Imperial-Hegemonic State The eighteenth-century expansion of commerce and population brought forth profound social transformations. The predominantly serf-based manorial order gave way to a peasant economy in the countryside. Though the transition had already begun in the Ming dynasty (Elvin 1973: 235-67), a substantial portion of the agrarian economy was still dominated by large estates in early Qing, especially in North China. The final demise of serfdom did not come until the eighteenth century when population explosion overloaded the manorial order and commercialization of social relations enabled full-fledged development of contractual relations (Huang 1985: 85-96; see also Buoye 2000). As most estates were fixed in size, estate owners were increasingly incapable of maintaining a rapidly expanding serf population that grew alongside with the rest of the population. To get rid of the increasing burden of feeding their serfs, many estate owners partitioned their estates into small slots and rented them out, or came to rely on hired-laborers to work on their land. Serfdom henceforth gave way to contractual relations between landlords and tenants, and between managerial landlords and hired laborers. Commercialization of land ownership also triggered the polarization of the peasantry into labor-employing rich peasants and labor-selling poor peasants. The aristocrat-serf stratification based on hereditary status was replaced by a landlord-tenant-hired laborers stratification based on alienable ownership of land and labor. This transition was reflected in the revised Qing legal code and changing legal practices in the late eighteenth 5 century when landlords, tenants and agrarian laborers began to be treated as equal commoners (Huang 1985: 97-105). We shall also see later that when the shortage of cultivable land intensified after the mid-eighteenth century, a substantial portion of the peasantry was demoted to the rank of landless and jobless vagrants, or what can be categorized as the subaltern class. Whereas serfdom was in decline, the somewhat meritocratic gentry elites remained to be a dominant sociopolitical force. In Qing China as in previous dynasties, the class reproduction of the gentry elites were carried out through the accumulation of degrees in the imperial examination, bureaucratic-officials titles, and land. Given the sweeping commercialization in the eighteenth century, accumulation of monetary wealth through mercantile activities became a legitimate and desirable means of class reproduction as well (Brook 1990; Rowe 1990). Accordingly, the gentry elites were differentiated into gentry-officials, gentry-landlord, and gentry-merchants. There were also gentry degree holders who did not serve in the bureaucracy but acted as local magnates in their home areas, exercising informal yet hegemonic influences in local affairs and facilitating the formal governance of the state (Jing 1982: 163-4). Attainment and maintenance of gentry status were invariably lineage-based and intergenerational. Many powerful lineages dispersed their risks by simultaneously pursuing different strategies of class reproduction. Needless to say, the specific choice of combination of strategies varied in time and space. Synchronic with the rise of absolutist states in northwestern Europe in the late seventeenth and early eighteenth century, the Qing regime during the same period fostered centralization and rationalization of its governance. By the turn of the eighteenth century, the Manchu monarch had leveled the powers of local warlords and noblemen (Wakeman 1985). Then, through the successive empire-wide land surveys and a “rationalizing fiscal reform” in the 1720s and 1730s, the Manchu rulers successfully stamped out bureaucratic corruption and tax evasion of local elites (Zelin 1984). New institutions and techniques of government, such as the Grand Council (which allowed the emperor and his closest advisors to handle the most urgent matters and surpassed the bureaucracy) and the secret palace memorial system (which enhanced the emperor’s access to information on local affairs as well as control of local officials) were invented (Bartlett 1991). The centralization process was in tandem with the military mobilization and territorial expansion of the empire which was to exterminate the threat to the empire’s security posed by the nomadic states in Central Asia. Mongolia, Xinjiang and Tibet were incorporated and became part of China for the first time. Contrary to what the traditional “oriental despotism” thesis suggests, the Qing state was very active in facilitating commercial growth. Pro-commercial stance of the Chinese state gestated in the late Ming period when a growing 6 commercial economy began to be recognized as an unalterable reality. Since the late sixteenth century, hostility toward silver, internal commerce, foreign trade and merchants in traditional Confucianist thoughts had lost ground to the school of thought emphasizing the “natural law” of the market economy and proposed that the market economy would flourish under appropriate facilitation but not control by the government. This pragmatic attitude toward commerce continued to grow in the Qing bureaucracy and had become a mainstream position by the eighteenth century (Rowe 2001; Xiao 1987: 331-339; Zheng 1994: 133-150; Lin 1991: 9, 13-7; Chao 1993: 40; Chen 1991b; von Glahn 1996: 215-6). The Qing government also promoted commerce through various means such as developing the empire’s commercial transport infrastructure and stimulating new production and marketing sectors by offering incentive packages for entrepreneurs in target areas (Rowe 1998: 184-5). The idea of paternalist and benevolent rule was another major component of the Manchu governance. Relieving the burden of the poor was claimed to be the first priority of the imperial government. At times of regional famines, the central government never hesitated to grant tax breaks to the affected areas. When local conflicts between lower classes and local elites broke out, the emperor often sided with the former and blamed the latter (as we shall see in detail later). Above all, the Qing government instituted an extremely conservative fiscal regime in the name of enhancing the livelihoods of the peasants. In 1713, the Kangxi emperor promised that the government would never increase its subjects’ burden by permanently fixing the per capita tax quotas, despite the fact that the Qing government was still suffering from fiscal stringency at that time. This promise was closely kept by his successors (Guo 1996: 13-14). The paternalist ideology was to enhance the imperial hegemony of the Manchus, who were despised by many Han Chinese as inferior nomadic invaders subjugating China by naked violence. It was also to prevent the recurrence of massive social unrest in late Ming caused by unchecked privileges of the elites and heavy tax burdens. The organic articulation of the pro-commercial and paternalist dispositions of the Qing state was best illustrated by the official granary system. Though the Qing government relied primarily on the free circulating of grains in the grain market to feed the expanding population, the government instituted a large-scale granary system as a regulatory apparatus to protect its subject from the vicissitudes of the grain market. Under this system, hundreds of thousands of local government-run ever-normal granaries were established all over the empire. Local governments were to purchase grains from the market to stock the granaries when grain price was low, and sold the grains back to the market at submarket price when there was an unusual hike in rice price. If the stock in local granaries was not sufficient in lowering local rice price, granary storages in other areas would be mobilized under the coordination of higher-level officials (Will and Wong 1991; 7 Will 1990; Rowe 2001: 155-185). What we can see was a market economy contained by the strong, regulative hand of the imperial state. At times when the routine regulatory apparatuses were insufficient in protecting people’s livelihoods, the government would also resort to extraordinary means to check the free operation of the market. It is what we shall soon turn to. Popular Resistances and Gentry’s Strategies of Class Reproduction The Changing Political Economy and Pattern of Social Unrest The contours of the processes of commercialization, population growth and state centralization in China’s long eighteenth century were not totally congruent. While the empire’s commerce and population grew uninterruptedly from the late seventeenth up to the early nineteenth century, the aggressive expansion of state power lasted only between the 1680s and 1760s, and began to level off thereafter. The centralization of the Qing regime between the 1680s and the 1750s was largely driven by the fiscal and logistic necessity arising from the Qing’s prolonged military campaign in Central Asia. This effort ended up in the success of the Qianlong campaign of 1755-60 that incorporated today’s Xinjiang area. After the campaign, the constant urge of military mobilization was gone, and the conservative notion of “sustaining the prosperity and preserving the peace” (ciying baotai) became the central goal of the regime. Also, with the tax quota frozen at the 1713 level, the real income of the government dropped when inflation picked up. When government spending on payroll and public projects shrank in real terms, underpaid officials began to resort to bribery to maintain their luxurious ways of live, and local governments at the brink of bankruptcy were urged to appropriate unsanctioned surtaxes to pay for their bills (Guo 1996: 14-15; Kuhn and Mann 1978: 119-30; Zelin 1984). Local tax bullies reemerged and the competition for resources between the central and local government intensified. It is noted that in the 1770s onward, government’s capacity in regulating the grain market via the granary system decreased precipitously and the officials gradually adopted a hand-off policy toward the market (Will 1990: 289-301; Wong 1991: 75-92). The falling state power vis-à-vis the society was aggravated by the ever expanding size of the population and increasing complexity of the Chinese society Accordingly, we can partition the long eighteenth century into the epoch of 1683-1760 and that of 1761-1820. While the first epoch was characterized by the simultaneous growth of state power, commerce and population, the second was characterized by the falling capacity of the central government amid the incessant growth of commerce and 8 population. Figure 3 below roughly shows the general trend of unrest level in eighteenth-century China. Two peaks of unrest are clearly seen at the 1740s and the 1790s, corresponding to the two epochs. The compositions of unrest in the two peaks are different. The one in 1740s was mainly made up of localized conflicts including actions directed at the state (such as protests asking for government food relief) and class conflicts (such as food riots). Most events in the peak of the 1790s were large-scale armed uprisings, usually organized by heterodox religious sects. 50 Figure 3. Mentions of Unrest Events, 1645-1795 45 40 Localized Conf lict s Armed Uprising Armed Uprising (XGZ) 35 Mentions 30 25 20 15 10 5 1792 1785 1778 1771 1764 1757 1750 1743 1736 1729 1722 1715 1708 1701 1694 1687 1680 1673 1666 1659 1652 1645 0 Year Source: KYQ and XGZ In the first epoch, with the presence of a hegemonic and paternalist state and with the expanding agrarian frontiers capable of absorbing the dislocated and landless population, many of the unrest were well contained and remained to be localized and brief. In the second epoch, however, the frontier zones had been filled up and could no longer serve as the “safety valve” of the empire, and the state capacity had dropped to the point where the recalcitrant and ever-expanding subaltern class could survive government suppression and launched large-scale, sustained uprisings. Below, we shall see how the class reproduction strategy of the gentry elite was shaped by the different dynamics of unrest and different state responses to it in the two epochs. The 1740s: Food Riots and the Double Pressures on the Gentry-Merchants The 1740s was a decade of empire-wide food shortage. Hikes of rice price were widely reported in different parts of the empire (Quan 1996e; Rowe 2001: 179-83). It is debatable whether the price hike was caused by population growth – the 1740s was the decade when the rate of population expansion was the highest (45% over the decade) (Lin 1989: 299) – or by the rapid increase in silver supply of the empire (Quan 1996a). But the pike was unmistakable. A natural response of the gentry-merchants to a local food crisis was to stockpile their grains and to sell it to the market bit by bit to maximize their profits, or to ship the rice to other regions with even higher prices. On the other hand, 9 the poor, who had neither financial nor institutional means to cope with a sudden rise in the cost of living, often answered the profit-maximizing activities of the merchants by storming grain storehouses, forcing the merchants to sell their goods at lower prices, or stopping them from exporting their rice through setting up barricades or looting commercial rice boats. Events of food riots were documented in virtually all regions of the empire, from Hubei to Guangdong, from Jiangsu to Guizhou (CSUE; Wong 1982). These food crises and food riots were not specific to China, but were widely documented in other early modern societies (Tilly 1975; Rudé 1964: Ch. 1, 2, 7; Thompson 1991: Ch. 4; Walthall 1986; Vlastos 1986; Ikegami and Tilly 1994; White 1995). What was particular about the food crises in China was how the Qing government handled them. From the vantage point of the imperial state, the most ideal way of alleviating a food crisis was to mobilize the granary system and transported the stocks from rice-abundant area to localities in crises. But in the 1740s, particularly in the years 1743 and 1748, the granary system was overloaded with too many crises all over the empire. The government then resorted to squeezing the gentry-merchants. The Qianlong emperor repeatedly reminded the bureaucracy that local food crises were always exalted and sometimes caused by “wicked merchants” (jianshang), or those “rich but not benevolent” (weifu buren) people, who deliberately stockpiled grains and pushed up rice price. Hence, one of the best ways to cope with a food crisis was to urge local merchants to sell their stocks at prices lower than the market price. But it had to be done in the way that would not stir up popular contentions against the rich (QSL-QL juan 193: 13-4, 273: 26-8; see also Rowe 2001: 180-81). While at some places local officials carried out the emperor’s will well and solved local food crisis smoothly (see Rowe 2001: 167-83), in many other places local food crises deteriorated into escalating unrest. A case in point was the food riots of Suzhou – the largest and wealthiest city in the Lower Yangzi Delta – in 1748. The scale of the disorder was perhaps the largest the city witnessed in the eighteenth century. In 1747, in response to the escalating rice price and imminent social unrest, the provincial governor of Jiangsu pressed the gentry-merchants in Suzhou to sell their rice at low prices. For fear of government punishment, the gentry sold out most of their stocks in a panic. In the next year, after another bad harvest in the adjacent areas, rice price upshot even more steeply. Most private stocks in the city had already gone because of the panic sell-off in the previous year. Large-scale riots in the city and several other locations in the vicinity followed suit. Besides the seizure of food, the rioters also requested the comeback of a trusted and respected ex-local official who was believed to be more capable of managing the crisis. Rice wholesalers were looted and local government offices stormed. The resolves of the local government to restore law and order by physical force only messed up the situation further. The arrest of a popular figure identified as the ringleader unleashed 10 other rounds of protests and riots demanding the release of the arrested. The angry citizens were pacified only after the central government gave in to the protesters’ demands and let the beloved ex-official go back to the area and handle the situation (QSL-QL juan 314: 25-6, 314: 31-3, 316: 4-8). Another case was the salt riot in the mid-Yangzi commercial city of Hankou in 1740. To alleviate an occasional pike of salt price in Hubei province, the provincial governor encouraged the salt merchants in Hankou, the richest city in the province, to export its salt to the regions with the highest prices. When the salt price in Hankou soared subsequently, a riot in the city broke out. Major salt houses were encircled and smashed by thousands of angry citizens. The merchants were held hostage and they were forced to sell their salt locally. Despite the scale of disorder, no suppression or arrest was reported after the incident. The rioters were only seen by Qianlong as “stupid people” (yumin) who “did not have the patience to wait for the handling of the situation by officials” (bu jingting banli). The local officials were told to patiently explain to the angry citizens to make them “content with their lots” (gean benfen). Also, local officials should urge the merchants to sell their salt fairly, so that both the merchants and the people could get a fair deal (liangde qiping). After a lengthy investigation of the event in the central government, the provincial governor of Hubei, who encouraged the Hankou merchants to sell their salt to other regions in the first place, was demoted as he was identified as the person responsible for causing the price hike and the riots (QSL-QL juan 117:7, 117: 20-21, 118: 6-7, 120: 28, 122: 16-7, 123: 57). The cases of Suzhou in 1748 and Hankou in 1740 – the two wealthiest cities in the empire – were emblematic of the pattern of unrest and government’s response to it in the first half of the eighteenth century. In these two cases and many other similar cases, the poor attacking the rich were not punished severely, while the rich and the officials in charge were to be blamed. Time and again, the emperor compared both the “wicked merchants” (jianshang) who “turned a blind eye to their neighbors’ sufferings” (moshi xiangmin kunku) and the “contentious people” (diaomin) who “have the intention to rob” (cun rangduo zi xin) to disobedient children who needed education and discipline by their parents – i.e. the imperial state (QSL-QL juan 185: 6-9, 193: 13-4, 273: 26-9, 291: 17-9). Viewed in this light, it is well probable that in the emperor’s eyes, the “wicked merchants” were elder brothers who tormented the younger ones, and the practice of the government to press them to sell their commodities cheap was like parents disciplining a bullying son. Besides violent direct actions directed at the merchants, organized protests calling for government’s food relief were another type of popular responses to food crises. This type of action was usually initiated by local gentry and was most frequently found in the Lower Yangzi Delta, where the hegemony of the local gentry was the strongest. The typical 11 scenario was that certain members of the local gentry class wrote and distributed polemical posters and pamphlets to call the commoners for action. The repertoires of protests included market strikes (bashi, shutdown of local markets by peddlers and merchants), rallying in front of or even storming local government offices, composing and circulating popular songs ridiculing local officials, etc. (e.g. QSL-QL juan 173: 6-7, 287: 17). For example, in 1742, when the Gaoyou, Baoying and Huian prefectures of Jiangsu were hit by a flood and the government was accused of being slow at delivering food relief, local gentries in the prefecture cities called for market strikes and organized protests in which local people protested by holding statues of local gods (which were often used to symbolize alternative, popular justice challenging the legitimacy of local officials Wu 2000) in front of local government offices. One of the organizers was found to come from an extremely prestigious lineage in the region and to be a close relative of one of the grant secretariats in the central government (QSL-QL juan 173: 6-7). This incident caught serious attention of the emperor, who sent a special agent to the area to pacify the local populace and investigate the event. The gentry instigators were persecuted rigorously, the local official in charge of moral education was demoted, and the grand secretariat involved was purged (QSL-QL juan 173: 6-7, 185: 6-8, 185: 9). The suppressions of gentry-led mobilization were invariably more brutal than the suppression of the riots of the poor, for any alliance between the gentry and the popular classes was perceived to be grave threats to the imperial rule. The gentry-leaders were often executed upon arrest. The Qianlong emperor was puzzled why the local elites, who were surely not to be affected by food crises, would be so enthusiastic in organizing such protest actions (QSL-QL juan 173: 67, 316: 19-20). But if we take into account the ferocity of food riots and pressure that local officials put on the gentry during a food crisis, the gentry’s initiative in organizing protest actions was not puzzling at all. Directing the anger of the poor to the state was the best thing the gentry could do (if they were capable of doing so) to protect themselves from the violence form below and to preempt the government’s pressure on them. However, given the relentless response of the government, the risk of organizing local protests was enormous on the part of the gentry-leaders. Hence, this kind of protest was not as frequently seen as food riots. The food crises, food riots, and the government management of them in the 1740s showed that though the imperial government was prone to rely on the market and merchants to enhance the wealth of the empire and the livelihoods of its subjects in ordinary times, the gentry-merchants were squeezed from above (through the paternalist discipline of the imperial state) and from below (through popular contentions) whenever the livelihoods of ordinary people were disrupted by the vicissitudes of the market. Gentry-merchants hardly had the chance to transgress the 12 constraints put on them by the paternalist state and the “moral economy of the crowd” (cf. Thompson 1991). Their profitmaximizing activities were well contained. The 1790s: Millenarian Uprisings and Militarization of the Gentry Elites As a result of the commercialization process and population expansion, a substantial portion of the peasantry experienced downward mobility thorough the eighteenth century. For the per capita acreage of cultivable land was decreasing, poor peasants working on small plots of land were increasingly exposed to the risk of bankruptcy at times of bad harvests that would force them to sell their land in the market for food. In the early eighteenth century, the enlarging population of landless peasants was effectively absorbed by the agrarian frontiers such as Sichuan and Taiwan (Entenmann 1982; Shepherd 1993). However, by the mid-eighteenth century, most fertile lands in the frontiers had been filled up. The landless migrants were left with the choices of settling in the infertile highland or participating in the nonagrarian sectors by becoming peddlers, miners, or boatmen on commercial ships (Kuhn and Mann 1978; Kuhn 1970: 39; Leong 1997). This marginal population was extremely vulnerable to the vicissitudes of nature (if they were cultivators in the ecologically fragile area) and market (if they worked in the commercial sector). They were excluded from the safety net of the lineage-based social organizations, and were beyond the reach of the imperial public order grounded on the baojia system. This uprooted population was far more susceptible to the calling of heterodox religious sects – in which they could found social support and spiritual comfort – than the appeals of the Confucianist orthodoxy. The growing population of this subaltern class and the falling capacity of the state in maintaining social order led to the exponential growth of sectarian activities toward the end of the eighteenth century. Most heterodox religious sects in early modern China were dominated by the tradition of the White Lotus religion, the origins of which could be traced as far back as to circa 1100 C. E.. It represented a merging of the religious traditions of Taoism, Buddhism and Manichaeanism. The core of the religion was the idea about the cycling of kalpas (jie), a classical Sanskrit term meaning immensely long periods of time between successive transformations of the world. The followers of the religion worshipped the Eternal Venerable Mother (wusheng naomu), the supreme deity controlling the cycle of kalpas. Each kalpa was governed by a particular Buddha, and the present kalpa was governed by the historical Shakyamuni Buddha. When the current kapla ended, the material world would be destroyed by horrific famines and diseases. Then the Venerable Mother would send the Maitreya Buddha (lile fo) to earth and initiate a new kalpa. Followers of the religion were told to practice vegetarianism and led an ascetic way of life so that they could attain 13 salvation and would be brought back to the womb of the Venerable Mother during the catastrophic kalpic transition (Harrell and Perry 1982: 290-1; Yu 1987a; Ownby 1999; Overmyer 1976, 1981, 1985). The White Lotus religion spread rapidly in China among the lower classes in the early modern period. Independent and competing sects worshipping the Venerable Mother ramified (Gaustad 2000). Many of these sects were entrepreneurial and their leaders used sectarian activities for personal gains. They attracted people by demonstrating their magical power of exorcising illnesses, and told the followers that their chance of salvation during the kalpic transition increased with their contribution to the sects. Many sectarian leaders got rich by exploiting their followers’ faith (Qin and Zhang 1999: 296). There were also sects which lived on organized banditry or showed a rebellious character. Notably, the White Lotus religion was appropriated by many rebels as an ideology to call for action. In those cases, the content of the religion mutated with a utopian twist. It came to prophesize that during the imminent kalpic transition, the Maitreya Buddha would be reincarnated and his followers should aid his work of cleaning the world of corruption to earn their salvation. The new kalpa would be the dawn of an egalitarian world in which there would be no distinction between men and women, rich and poor, old and young (Harrell and Perry 1982: 290-1; Yu 1987a). There was some sort of wealth redistribution within the sects, as wealthy members were expected to contribute more, and their donations were used to help poorer members (Entenmann 1982: 192). The guru-disciple hierarchy within the sects overturned other Confucianist social hierarchy such as that between men and women. Women (particularly widows) were frequently found among the prominent leaders in sectarian uprisings (Yu 1987b; Liu 1988: 788-93). The first major outbreak of large scale uprising with a White Lotus outlook was in the mid-fourteenth century, when heterodox sects in the South declared in the midst of plagues and famines that the Maitreya Buddha had come and people in search of salvation should take up their arms and overthrow the Mongols. The Red Turban Army to which Zhu Yuanzhang, the founder of the Ming dynasty, belonged was one of the rebel groups inspired by the White Lotus religion. After the establishment of the Ming dynasty in 1368, White Lotus sects were persecuted inexorably, for the new emperor was well aware of the rebellious potential of the religion. But towards the mid-seventeenth century when the imperial government was weakening, White Lotus sects revived and fueled a number of major rebellions contributing to the final collapse of the Ming. The White Lotus religion was suppressed once again after the consolidation of the Qing dynasty. But the Qing government was never able to root out sectarian activities, which turned into underground operation. Over the eighteenth 14 century, White Lotus sects proliferated with the growth of the subaltern class (Harrell and Perry 297-301). Countless semi-secret vegetarian halls were established as gathering places of the believers. In 1746, a White Lotus sect know as Dacheng in Sichuan was found to be preparing for an armed uprising (KYQ 640-47). The rebellion aborted as the rebels’ plan to storm the major cities in the regions was unveiled before it materialized. The followers of the sects were found to be mostly migrants from other provinces (QSL-QL: 242: 30, 245: 10, 249: 31-2, 251.6, 265: 11-2, 265: 37-8, 267: 31). The leader of the aborted rebellion was a woman who preached that the Maitreya Buddha was coming to rule the world very soon, and the faithful should join the rebellion and they would be assigned official posts in the millenarian kingdom of the future (QSL-QL 271: 18-9, 271: 21-2). According to the confessions of the arrested members, the followers of the sect spread all over the empire, and were active in Yunnan, Guizhou, Jiangsu, Jiangxi, Hubei, Hunan, Shanxi and even Zhili. An empire-wide witch-hunting of co-conspirators and crackdown of Buddhist vegetarian halls ensued. Notwithstanding the assiduous crackdown of heterodox sects after 1746, religious uprisings erupted one after the other in the latter half of the eighteenth century (KYQ: 648-734). In 1748, amid the empire-wide food crisis, an armed rebellion organized by another White Lotus sect broke out in the Jianning prefecture of Fujian at the empire’s southeast coast. The leaders of the rebellion claimed that the Maitreya Buddha would arrive in the prefecture capital soon, and his follower should conquer the city to prepare for his coming (QSL-QL 309: 38-44). The call for action was echoed by thousands of hungry Hakka migrants residing in the highland areas (QSL-QL 317: 29-30). When the rebel army marched with the banners of “urging the rich to aid the poor” (quanfu jipin) and “exercising justice according to the Heavenly Will” (titian xingdao), participants of the uprisings felt free to loot grain storages and property of the rich along the way (QSL-QL juan 309: 4-5, 309: 8-9, 309: 38-44, 312: 12-3). Other major uprisings with the tint of White Lotus religion included the uprising of the Clear Water sect in Shandong in 1774 (KYQ 746-771; Naquin 1981) and the uprising of the Fujian migrants in Taiwan in 1787 (Ownby 1996: 55-81, Appendix; KYQ: 772-818). Though the Qing government was able to suppress these rebellions without many difficulties, the outbreaks showed a general trend of increasing scale and duration. The Dacheng rebellion in 1746 never materialized, the Fujian uprising in 1748 lasted a few weeks, the Shandong uprising in 1774 lasted a few months, and the Taiwan uprising in 1787 lasted nearly a year. This trend can be seen as a reflection of the falling capacity of the state in maintaining social order as well as the growing size and despair of the subaltern class. Of course, the largest and most disruptive uprising of all was the White Lotus rebellion of 1796-1805. 15 From 1792 on, rumors about the imminent end of the kalpa and arrival of the Maitreya Buddha were spreading in the White Lotus sects active in western Hubei. It was anticipated that on the 10th day of the 3rd month of 1796, “a black whirlwind would rise and blow all day and all night, killing countless people, and leaving mountains of bones and oceans of blood.” The sect leaders told their followers to save themselves by participating in a general uprising to overthrow the Manchus (Naquin 1981: 155; KYQ: 863). The rumors triggered a spiral of sect activism and government suppression in the mountainous border areas of the Shaanxi, Sichuan and Hubei provinces. These areas were densely populated by poor migrants from central China who failed to find any decent piece of land in the overcrowded Sichuan lowland. These migrants hardly made ends meet by relying on the infertile lands in the highland, and many of them chose to become outlaws living on banditry or were recruited by religious sects (Kuhn 1970: 39; Goldstone 1991: 394-99). In the few years leading up to 1796, intensification of government arrest further radicalized the sect members, who believed that they would be arrested anyway. They were found looting lowland villages for food, which was then stocked for the preparation of the uprising (QZQ: 1-164; KYQ: 861-8). According to confessions of the arrested members, they were attracted by the call for action because the sect leaders promised that participants of the uprisings would be rewarded with small plots of land or official titles in the forthcoming Maitreya kingdom (QZQ: 10; KYQ: 862-3). When the general uprising broke out in spring 1796, it was immediately joined by a substantial number of nonsect members who were identified by the Qing authority as “perverse and lawless people” (wulai bufazi tu) including shack people (pengmin), salt smugglers, pirate coin makers and bandits (KYQ: 825). The rebellion persisted for nearly 10 years and cost the Qing regime more financial resources to put it down than any other military campaign in the eighteenth century. Other than the large population of the starving migrants in the ecologically fragile Shaanxi-Sichuan-Hubei border, the other reason for the sustainability of the rebellion was the guerilla tactics employed by the rebels. Participants of the uprising were organized into small and highly mobile bands supported and informed by the surrounding populace. Their practice of hit and run made the relatively immobile banner armies – the elite force of the Qing military establishment – stationed in walled cities impotent (Kuhn 1970: 40). When the imperial government realized that the war against the rebels was in a deadlock and the bannermen were unreliable in suppressing the revolt, it changed its strategy and began to encourage the local gentry in the unrest area to organize local militias under the nominal supervision of local officials. It was to stamp out any possible foothold that the rebels could find in the vast rural space separating walled cities (Kuhn 1970: 41-50). Though this strategy turned out to be 16 effective and accounted for the final dissolution of the rebellion, it opened the Pandora Box of political and military decentralization of the empire. After crushing the powers of semi-autonomous warlords in the 1670s and 1680s, the Manchu state was ever eager to monopolize the means of violence. Militarization of local elite was a taboo in the dynasty. Though scattered local militias existed under the tacit approval of the government for the sake of suppressing smaller-scale rebellions, especially in the frontier areas where the imperial presence was relatively weak, they were never formally recognized nor encouraged by the state (such as the Miao rebellions in the 1730s and 1740s e.g. QSL-QL juan 3: 27, 57: 21; Naquin 1981: 150). In the aftermath of the White Lotus Rebellion, the capacity of the state continued to decline. Declining state capacity and the deflationary depression caused by the opium trade and massive silver outflow led to the ramification of rural disorder. Banditry, sectarian activities, rent and tax resistances mushroomed in both economically advanced and backward regions (e.g. Perry 1980: 48-95; Bernhardt 1992: 43-83). The rescinding constraint from the state and enlarging threat from below enabled as well as urged the local gentry to shore up their policing and military functions. Local military networks spanning from provincial elites to gentry and ruffians at the county level emerged all over the empire (Kuhn 1970: 41-50; McCord 1990; Perry 2002: 31-39; Wakeman 1966). Local militias were usually financed by the private wealth of gentry leaders as well as special taxes extracted from agricultural production and mercantile activities in the communities concerned. Financial resources of militias at lower geographical level were funneled to higher level military organizations (such as provincial armies that emerged in the mid-nineteenth century) (Kuhn 1970: 87-92). Local government officials who were anxious to extract unsanctioned surtaxes to cope with the deteriorating fiscal condition of the state, as well as landlords who found increasingly difficult in collecting rents given the peasants hardships, allied with the local militias and relied on them for tax and rent collection. Local officials, landlords and gentry gradually converged into a strata of local despots who were later characterized by the twentieth-century revolutionaries as “local bullies and evil gentry” (tuhao leshen). Their coercive and extractive activities led to a general decline in agricultural productivity and further increase in social unrest (Wakeman 1975: 21-23; Polanchek 1975: 220-2; 226-8 246; Perry 1980: 86-7; Bernhardt 1992: 80). The result was a vicious circle of escalating social unrest and elite militarization over the nineteenth century. While it is noted that “religious rebellions crowded the records of every decade after the middle of the eighteenth century” (Yang 1961: 219) right to the collapse of the Qing empire, the pace of elite militarization redoubled after the Taiping 17 Rebellion of 1851-1864, when the first professional provincial army virtually autonomous from the command of Beijing was established in Hunan for the suppression of the rebels. This vicious circle threw China in disarray and made it incapable of coping with the challenge of imperialist powers, hence paving the way for the final disintegration of the Qing empire and the protracted civil war that followed. Conclusion In early modern northwestern Europe, a section of the aristocracy transformed themselves into capitalists and became the locomotives of Europe’s “transition to capitalism.” This elite transformation was facilitated by the particular habitus in which the aristocratic elites were embedded. The continuous decline in seigniorial income after the fifteenthcentury crisis of feudalism, in conjunction with the escalating interstate competition for mobile capital after the collapse of the medieval system of rule, induced a section of the aristocracy to engage in commercial activities and exchanged its financial power for the protection from the absolutist states (Wallerstein 1974, 1989; Arrighi 1994). At the same time, the “new periphery” of the Americas served as an ever expanding outlet for Europe’s subaltern class displaced by the boom and burst of the commercializing economy. Resources imported from the New World prevented the living standards of the poor from falling too much during the era of primitive accumulation, hence contributing to the relative stability and lack of large-scale peasant revolts in northwestern Europe as compared to other world-empires in turmoil towards the end of the eighteenth century (for the disappearance of large-scale revolt in eighteenth-century Europe, see Rudé 1964: 20 and Bercé 1987: 183-96; for the contribution of New World Resources to Europe’s stability, see Pomeranz 2000: 82-4; 282-4; for North America as a destination of mass migration at times of economic distress in Europe, see Bailyn 1986). Aided by the state from above and shielded from large-scale revolt from below, the embourgeoisement of the aristocracy went unfettered in the core zones of Europe. By contrast, the particular habitus of the gentry elites in eighteenth-century China led them to embark on different paths of class reproduction. In most of the eighteenth century, the paternalist Manchu state was harsh on the gentry-merchants. The imperial authority was anxious to keep the mercantile elites at bay and at times joined the rioting mass to check their profit-maximizing activities. Given the state’s paternalist regulation of the market and the availability of other means of class reproduction (such as participating in the imperial examination and performing bureaucratic services), it was unwise for the gentry lineages to throw too much resource into the accumulation of capital. The full-scale embourgeoisement of the gentry class was forestalled, and the transition from a market economy to capitalism in China was therefore arrested. 18 Beginning at the end of the eighteenth century, the capacity of the paternalist state declined and the lid put on the expansion of local elites’ power was lifted. Meanwhile, the population expansion and tightening land-man ratio in eighteenth-century China, together with the lack of any ecological frontier comparable to the size of the Americas, created a large and formidable subaltern class that gave rise to a general breakdown of social order and successive large-scale millenarian uprisings in particular. Freed from the political constraints from above and threatened by the subaltern class from below, the gentry elites took on a peculiar path of class survival and reproduction through militarization, which caused further increase in popular resentment and revolts. Capitalist enterprises did emerge in mid-nineteenth-century China as a response to the “challenge from the West.” But the nascent capitalist transition was countervailed by the transition of China’s socio-political system into a sort of feudal order characterized by crumbling central authority and expansion of local military-predatory networks. The militarization of local elite continued well into the twentieth century when many local despots developed or were integrated into warlord regimes under the sponsorship of imperialist powers. These military-predatory elites were exactly the “semi-feudal, semi-colonial” class which fettered the growth of China’s “national bourgeois” according to Mao Zedong’s famous analysis of China’s social formation in the early twentieth century. The post-imperial chaos of China was ended not by any “bourgeois revolution” but by a Communist-led agrarian revolution. Students of China’s Communism notice that the Chinese revolution was grounded on the rich tradition of peasant war in late imperial China, and the socialist state that the revolution sought to construct turned out to be not so far away from the Qing state in terms of its paternalism and authoritarianism. Viewed in this light, the paternalist and utopian religious ideologies originating in eighteenth-century China not only arrested China’s transition to capitalism in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, but also turned China into an epicenter of anti-systemic movements in the twentieth century. But it is another story. References Primary Sources CSUE: Ho-fung Hung. Catalog of Social Unrest Events in Early Qing China, 1645-1795. (in progress) KYQ: Zhongguo renmin daxue qingshi yanjiusuo danganshi; zhongguo zhengzhi zhidushi jiaoyanshi eds. 1979. Kongyongqian shiqi chengxiang renmin fankang douzheng ziliao. (Materials on urban and rural resistance and struggles in the Kangxi, Yongzheng, and Qianlong reigns). Beijing: Zhonghua shuju. QSL-QL: Da Qing gaozong chun (qianlong) huangdi shilu. Taibei: Taiwan huawen shuju. 19 QZQ: Zhongguo shehui kexue yuan lishi yanjiusuo Qingshi shi, ziliao shi, eds. 1981. Qing Zhongqi wu sheng bailian jiao qiyi ziliao (Materials on the Mid-Qing Five Province White Lotus Uprising) 5 vol. Suzhou: Jiangsu renmin chubanshe. XGZ: Xie Guozhen. 1956. Qingchu nongmin qiyi ziliao jilu. (Selected materials on peasant uprisings in early Qing). Shanghai: Xinzhishi chubanshe. Secondary Sources Abu-Lughod, Janet L 1989. Before European Hegemony: The World System A.D. 1250-1350. New York: Oxford UP. Arrighi, Giovanni. 1994. The Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power, and the Origins of Our Times. London: Verso. Arrighi, Giovanni and Ho-fung Hung 2002. “Historical Capitalism, East and West.” Paper presented at the ASA Annual Conference 2002, Chicago. Atwell, William S. 1998. “Ming China and the Emerging World Economy. C. 1470-1650,” Twitchett and Mote, eds., The Cambridge History of China Vol. 8, 2, The Ming Dynasty, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 376-416. Bailyn, Bernard. 1986. Voyages to the West: A Passage in the Peopling of America on the Eve of the Revolution. New York: Knopf. Bartlett Beatrice S. 1991. Monarchs and Ministers: The Grand Council in Mid-Ch’ing China, 1723-1820. Berkeley: University of California Press. Bercé, Yves-Marie 1987. Revolt and Revolution in Early Modern Europe: An Essay on the History of Political Violence. New York: St. Martin’s Press. Bernhardt, Kathryn 1992. Rents, Taxes, and Peasant Resistance: The Lower Yangzi Region, 1840-1950. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Bernstein, Thomas. 2000. “Instability in Rural China.” David Shambaugh ed. Is China Unstable? Armonk: M. E. Sharpe. Bourdieu, Pierre. 1990. The Logic of Practice. Cambridge, UK: Polity Press. Braudel, Fernand 1977. Afterthoughts on Material Civilization and Capitalism. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Braudel, Fernand 1992. Civilization and Capitalism 15th - 18th Century 3 Vols. Berkeley: University of California Press. Buoye, Thomas, M. 2000. Manslaughter, Markets, and Moral Economy: Violent Disputes over Property Rights in Eighteenth-Century China. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Brook, Timothy. 1990. “Family Continuity and Cultural Hegemony: The Gentry of Ningbo, 1368-1911.” Joseph W. Esherick & Mary Backus Rankin eds. Chinese Local Elites and Patterns of Dominance. Berkeley: University of California Press. 27-50. Chao Zhongchen (1993). “Wanming baiyin daliang liuru ji qi yingxiang,” (The Massive Inflow of Silver in Late Ming and its Influences) Shixue yuekan, 1993, 1, 33-39. Chase-Dunn, Christopher & Thomas Hall 1997. Rise and Demise: Comparing World-Systems. Boulder: Westview Press. Elvin, Mark 1973. The Pattern of the Chinese Past. Stanford: Stanford UP. ------- 1998. “The Environmental Legacy of Imperial China.” The China Quarterly. No. 156: 733-56. 20 Entenmann, Robert Eric. 1982. Migration and Settlement in Sichuan, 1644-1796. Unpublished dissertation, Harvard University. Fan I-chun 1992. Long-Distance Trade and Market Integration in the Ming-Ch’ing Period, 1400-1850. Ph. D dissertation, Stanford University. Fan Jinmin 1998. Mingqing Jiangnan shangyede fazhan (The Development of Commerce in Jiangnan in the Ming-Qing Period). Nanjing: Nanjing daxue chubanshe. Frank, Andre Gunder (1998). ReORIENT: Global Economy in the Age of Asia. Berkeley: University of Californial Press. Gao Wangling 1995. Shiba shiji Zhongguode jingji fazhan he zhengfu zhengce. (Economic Development and Government Policies in Eighteenth-Century China) Beijing: Zhonggu shehui kexue chubanshe. Gaustad, Blaine. 2000. “Prophets and Pretenders: Inter-sect Competition in Qianlong China,” Late Imperial China. 21 (1): 1-40. Goldstone, Jack A. 1991. Rebellion and Revolution in the Early Modern World, Berkeley & LA: University of California Press. ------- 2000. “The Rise of the West or Not? A Revision to Socio-Economic History.” Sociological Theory. 18(2): 175-94. Guo Chengkang. 1996. “Zhongguo shiba shijide wujia wenti yu zhengfu duice,” (The Price Question in 18th Century China and the Government's Remedies) Qingshi yanjiu, 1996, 1, 8-19. Harrell, Stevan and Elizabeth J. Perry. 1982. “Syncretic Sects in Chinese Society.” Modern China. 8(3): 283-304. Ho Ping-ti. 1959. Studies on the Population of China, 1368-1953. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press. Huang, Philip C. C. 1985. The Peasant Economy and Social Change in North China. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Hung Ho-fung 2001. “Imperial China and Capitalist Europe in the Eighteenth-Century Global Economy.” Review (Fernand Braudel Center) XXIV (4): 473-513. Ikegami, Eiko & Charles Tilly 1994. “State Formation and Contention in Japan and France,” in James L. McClain, John M. Merriman and Ugawa Kaoru. eds. Edo and Paris: Urban Life and the State in the Early Modern Era, Ithaca and London, Cornell University Press. Jing Junjian. 1982. “Hierarchy in the Qing Dynasty.” Social Sciences in China: A Quarterly Journal. Vol. 3, No. 1. 15692. Kishimoto-Nakayama Mio 1984. “The Kangxi Depression and Early Qing Local Markets,” Modern China, 10, 2, 226-56. Kuhn, Philip A. 1970. Rebellion and Its Enemies in Late Imperial China: Militarization and Social Structure, 1796-1864. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. -------- 1990. Soulstealers: The Chinese Sorcery Scare of 1768. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. Kuhn, Philip & Susan Mann 1978. “Dynastic Decline and the Roots of Rebellion,” in John K. Fairbank, ed., The Cambridge History of China, Vol. 10, London and New York: Cambridge University Press, 107-62. Lachman. 2000. Capitalist in spite of Themselves: Elite Conflict and Economic Transition in Early Modern Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 21 Leong, Sow-theng. 1997. Migration and Ethnicity in Chinese History: Hakkas, Pengmin, and Their Neighbors. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Li Bozhong 1986. “Mingqing Jiangnan yu waidi jingji lianxide jiaqiang ji qi dui Jiangnan jingji fazhan de yingxiang,” (The Strengthening of Economic Ties Between Jiangnan and Other Provinces, and its Influences on the Economic Development of Jiangnan) Zhongguo jingjishi yanjiu, 1986, 2, 117-134. Li Bozhong 1999. “Zhongguo quanguo shichangde xingcheng, 1500-1840,” (The Formation of National Market in China, 1500-1840) Qinghua daxue xuebao, 1999, 4, 48-54. (keynote speech to the “Eighth Annual World History Association International Congress,” Victoria, June 27, 1999.) Lin Manhong (1989). “Shijie jingji yu jindai zhongguo nongye: Qingren Wang Zuhui yiduan Qianlong liangjia jishu zi jiexi,” (The World Economy and Modern Chinese Agriculture: an Analysis of a Writing of Wang zuhui on the Qianlong Rice Price). Zhongyang yanjiuyuan jindaishi yanjiusuo Jindai Zhongguo nongcun jingji shi lunwenji. (Symposium on the Rural Economy of Modern China) Taipei: Academia Sinica, 291-235. Lin Manhong 1991. “Two Social Theories Revealed: Statecraft Controversies Over China’s Monetary Crisis, 1808-1854,” Late Imperial China, 12,2, 1-35. Liu Kwang-ching. 1988. “Cong dangan shiliao kan 1796 Hubei sheng bailian jiao qiyide zongjiao yinsu” (The Religious Factor in the 1796 White Lotus Uprising in Hubei as Seen in Archival Sources). Diyi lishi dangan guan ed. Ming Qing dangan yu lishi yanjiu. Beijing: Zhonghua Shuju. 776-815. Liu, Paul K. C. and Kuo-shu Hwang. 1979. “Population Change and Economic Development in Mainland China since 1400.” Hon Chi-ming and Yu Zong-shai. Eds. Proceedings of the Conference on Modern Chinese Economic History. Nankang: The Institute of Economics, Academia Sinica. 61-93. Marks, Robert B. 1991. “Rice Prices, Food Supply, and Market Structure in Eighteenth-Century South China,” Late Imperial China, 12, 2, 64-116. ------ 1996. “Commercialization without Capitalism: Processes of Environmental Change in South China, 1550-1850,” Environmental History, 1, 1, 56-82. McCord, Edward A. 1990. “Local Military Power and Elite Formation: The Liu Family of Xingyi County, Guizhou.” Joseph W. Esherick & Mary Backus Rankin eds. Chinese Local Elites and Patterns of Dominance. Berkeley: University of California Press. 162-90. ------ 1993. The Power of the Gun: The Emergence of Modern Chinese Warlordism. Berkeley: University of California Press. Naquin, Susan & Evelyn S. Rawski 1987. Chinese Society in the Eighteenth Century. New Haven: Yale University Press. Naquin, Susan. 1981. Shantung Rebellion: The Wang Lun Uprising of 1774. New Haven: Yale University Press. Ownby, David. 1996. Brotherhoods and Secret Societies in Early and Mid-Qing China: The Formation of a Tradition. ----------. 1999. “Chinese Millenarian Traditions: The Formative Age,” American Historical Review. 104 (5). Overmyer, Daniel. 1981. “Alternatives: Popular Religious Sects in Chinese Society,” Modern China 7(2). Perkins, Dwight H. 1969. Agricultural Development in China, 1368-1968. Chicago: Aldine Publishing Co.. Perry, Elizabeth 1980. Rebels and Revolutionaries in North China, 1845-1945. Stanford: Stanford University Press. 22 -------- 2002. “Predators and Protectors: Strategies of Peasant Survival.” Elizabeth J. Perry. Challenging the Mandate of Heaven: Social Protest and State Power in China. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe. 3-46. Polacheck, James. 1975. “Gentry Hegemony: Soochow in the T’ung-chih Restoration.” Frederic Wakeman Jr. and Carolyn Grant eds. Conflict and Control in Late Imperial China. Berkeley: University of California Press. Polanyi, Karl. 1944. The Great Transformation: the Political and Economic Origins of Our Time. Boston: Beacon Press Pomeranz, Kenneth. 2000. The great divergence : Europe, China, and the Making of the Modern World Economy. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. Qin Baoqi and Zhang Yan. 1999. Shiba shijide Zhongguoyu shijie: shehui juan (China and the World in the Eighteenth Century: Society). Shenyang: Liaohai chubanshe. Quan Hansheng 1987. Mingqing jingjishi yanjiu (Studies of the Economic History of Ming and Qing). Taipei: Lianjing chubanshe. Quan Hansheng 1996a. “Meizhou baiyin yu shiba shiji Zhongguo wujia gemingde guanxi,” (The Relation between American Silver and the 18th Century Price Revolution in China) in Quan Hansheng, Zhongguo jingjishi luncong. (Essays on Chinese Economic History) Taipei: Hedao chubanshe, 475-508. Quan Hansheng 1996b. “Mingqing jian Meizhou baiyinde shuru Zhongguo,” (The Inflow of American Silver to China in Ming and Qing) in Quan Hansheng, Zhongguo jingjishi luncong. (Essays on Chinese Economic History) Taipei: Hedao chubanshe, 435-50. Quan Hansheng 1996c. “Qing Yongzheng nianjian (1723-35) de mijia,” (The Rice Price in the Reign of Yongzheng (1723-35)) in Quan Hansheng, Zhongguo jingjishi luncong. (Essays on Chinese Economic History) Taipei: Hedao chubanshe, 547-66. Quan Hansheng 1996d. “Qing zhongye yiqian Jiangzhe mijiade biandong qushi,” (The Trend of the Change of Rice Price in Jiangsu and Zheijiang before Mid Qing) in Quan Hansheng, Zhongguo jingjishi luncong. (Essays on Chinese Economic History) Taipei: Hedao chubanshe. Taipei: Hedao chubanshe, 509-16. Quan Hansheng 1996e. “Qianlong shisanniande migui wenti.” (The Quesiton of High Price Rice in 1748). Quan Hansheng. Zhongguo jingjishi luncong (Essays on Chinese Economic History). Taipei: Hedao chubanshe. 547-66. Rowe, William T. 1998. “Domestic Interregional Trade in Eighteenth-century China,” in Leonard Blusse and Gaastra Femme, eds., On the Eighteenth Century as a Category of Asian History: Van Leur in Retrospect. Aldershot: Ashgate Press, 173-192. ------- 1992. “Success Stories: Lineage and Elite Status in Hanyang County, Hubei, c. 1368-1949.” Joseph W. Esherick & Mary Backus Rankin eds. Chinese Local Elites and Patterns of Dominance. Berkeley: University of California Press. 51-81.. ------- 2000. “Social Stability and Social Change” in The Cambridge History of China, Early Ch’ing, Book Manuscript. ------- 2001. Saving the World: Cheng Hongmu and Elite Consciousness in Eighteenth-Century China. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Rudé, George. 1964. The Crowd in History – A Study of Popular Disturbances in France and England, 1730-1848. New York: John Wiley & Sons. Shepherd, John 1993. Statecraft and Political Economy on the Taiwan Frontier, 1600-1800. Stanford: Stanford University Press. 23 Swidler, Ann. 1986. “Culture in Action: Symbols and Strategies.” American Sociological Review. 51 (2). 273-86. Tarrow, Sidney 1992. “Mentalities, Political Cultures, and Collective Action Frames: Constructing Meanings through Action.” Aldon D. Morris & Carol McClurg Mueller eds. Frontiers in Social Movement Theory. New Haven, Yale University Press. 174-204. Thompson, E. P.. 1991. “The Moral Economy of the English Crowd in the Eighteenth Century,” E. P. Thompson Customs in Common. London: Penguin. 185-258. Tilly, Charles. 1975. “Food Supply and Public Order in Modern Europe.” Charles Tilly ed. The Formation of National States in Western Europe. Princeton: Princeton University Press. 380-455. Vlastos, Stephen. 1986. Peasant Protest and Uprising in Tokugawa Japan. Berkeley: University of California Press. von Glahn, Richard 1996. Fountain of Fortune: Money and Monetary Policy in China, 1000 to 1700. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press. Wakeman, Frederic, Jr. 1966. Strangers at the Gate: Social Disorder in South China, 1839-1861. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1966. ------- 1975. “The Evolution of Local Control in Late Imperial China.” Frederic Wakeman, Jr. and Carolyn Grant. Conflict and Control in Late Imperial China. Berkeley: University of California Press. 1-25. ------- 1985. The Great Enterprise: The Manchu Reconstruction of Imperial Order in Seventeenth-Century China. Berkeley: University of California Press. Wallerstein, Immanuel 1974. The Modern World-System I: Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins of the European WorldEconomy in the Sixteenth Century. New York: Academic Press. ------ 1989. The Modern World-System III: The Second Era of Great Expansion of the Capitalist World-Ecomony, 17301840s. New York: Academic Press. Walthall, Anne. 1986. Peasant Uprising in Japan. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. -------. 1994. “Edo Riots.” James L. McClain et al eds. Edo and Paris: Urban Life and the State in the Early Modern Era. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Wang, Yeh-chien. 1973. Land Taxation in Imperial China, 1750-1911. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. ------- 1980. “The Secular Trend of Prices during the Ch’ing Period, 1644-1911,” in Yu Zongxian et al, eds., Zhongguo jingji fazhanshi lunwenji. Taipei: Lianjing chubanshe, 1541-77. ------- 1992. “Secular Trends of Rice Prices in the Yangzi Delta, 1638-1935.” Thomas G. Rawski and Lillian M. Li eds. Chinese History in Economic Perspective. Berkeley: University of California Press.35-68. White, James W. 1995. Ikki: Social Conflict and Political Protest in Early Modern Japan. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Will, Pierre-Etienne. 1990. Bureaucracy and Famine in Eighteenth-Century China. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Will, Pierre-Etienne and Bin R. Wong. 1991. Nourish the People: The State Civilian Granary System in China, 16501850. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Wong, Bin R. 1982. “Food Riots in the Qing Dynasty” Journal of Asian Studies. 41: 4: 767-88. 24 --------. 1997. China Transformed: Historical Change and the Limits of European Experience. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Wu Chengming. 1983. Zhongguo zibanzhuyi yu guoneishichang. (Chinese Capitalism and National Market) Beijing: Zhongguo Shehui Kexue Chubanshe. Wu Jen-shu. 2000. “Festival, Cult and Protest – The City God Cult and the Collective Protests of Urban People in Ming and Qing Times.” Journal of Acadmia Sinica (Institute of Modern History). No. 34. Dec. 149-210. Xiao Qing 1987. Zhongguo gudai jinrong sixiang shi (A History of Ancient Chinese Monetary Thoughts). Taipei: Shangwu yinshuguan. Xu Tan 1999. “Qingdai qianqi shangpin liutong gejude bianhua,” (The Change in the Pattern of Commodity Circulation in Early Qing) Qingshi yanjiu, 1999, 3, 1-13. Yang, C. K. 1961. Religion in Chinese Society: A Study of Contemporary Social Functions of Religion and Some of their Historical Factors. Berkeley: University California Press. ----------. 1975. “Some Preliminary Statistical Patterns of Mass Actions in Nineteenth-Century China.” Frederic Wakeman Jr. and Carolyn Grant eds. Conflict and Control in Late Imperial China. Berkeley: University of California Press. 174-210. Yu Songqing. 1987a. “Ming Qing bailian jiao yanjiu” (Research on the White Lotus Teachings of the Ming and Qing Dynasties. Yu Songqing Ming Qing Bailian Jiao Yanjiu Chengdu: Sichuan renmin chubanshe. 1-116. ---------- 1987b. “Ming Qing shiqi mimi zongjiao zhongde nuxing” (Women in the Secret Societies during the Ming-Qing period). Yu Songqing. Ming Qing Bailian Jiao Yanjiu. Chengdu: Sichuan renmin chubanshe. 295-311. Zelin, Madeleine 1984. The Magistrate’s Tael: Rationalizing Fiscal Reform in Eighteenth-Century Ch’ing China. Berkerley: California University Press. Zheng Yongchang 1994. Mingmo Qingchu yingui qianjian xianxiang yu xiangguan zhengzhi jingji sixiang. (The “Expensive Silver and Cheap Copper” Phenomenon in Late Ming and Early Qing, and the related Political Economic Thoughts) Taipei: Guoli taiwan shifan daxue lishi yanjiu suo. 25