The Financial Crisis and Corporate Governance Reform I. Introduction In the wake of the recent financial crisis, the Obama administration has declared regulatory reform of the nation’s financial system among its top priorities. Calls for increased regulation in response to an economic crisis are nothing new. Examples of previous crises leading to regulatory responses are many. For example, the Foreign Corrupt Practices Act of 1977 followed the SEC’s exposure of corporate bribery in foreign countries, and the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 (SOX) followed accounting scandals at Enron, WorldCom and others.1 The primary challenge of this current round of regulatory reform will be to establish a more effective means of financial oversight without so restricting the flexibility and efficiency of the financial system that economic growth is stifled. In order to achieve that necessary balance, any proposed regulations must be critically evaluated to ensure they effectively remedy specific problems uncovered by the crisis with minimal intrusive effect on economic growth and the financial system. The initial response to the current financial crisis was necessarily centered on restoring viability to corporations large enough to pose systemic risks to the national economy.2 The Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) provided massive government bailouts to large companies such as Bank of America, AIG and Citigroup in an effort to restore confidence and liquidity in the financial system.3 The overall effectiveness and 1 Foreign Corrupt Practices Act, 15 U.S.C. §78dd (1977); Sarbanes-Oxley Act, 15 U.S.C.§7201 (2002). 2 Emergency Economic Stabilization Act, Pub. L. No. 110-343 (2008). 3 Kiel, Paul, Show Me the TARP Money, ProPublica, Feb. 9, 2009, http://bailout.propublica.org/main/list/index. efficiency of TARP is subject to debate, but the result was to leave the federal government with a substantial interest in many large corporations within the financial system.4 Given the vast resources employed by the federal government to deal with the exigent circumstances created by the financial crisis, proposed legislation thus far has understandably been focused on establishing the authority and procedures for a federal systemic risk regulator.5 This as yet unspecified agency would be charged with oversight responsibilities for corporations deemed large enough to pose a threat to the economy as a whole.6 One aspect of this oversight would involve federal takeovers of failed systemic risk corporations based on the FDIC model for taking smaller failed banks into receivership.7 In summary, the basic thrust of these initial reform efforts has been primarily aimed at creating a more viable, unified regulatory structure for dealing with corporations posing systemic risks, and for establishing an organized takeover process should the failure of such a corporation occur. A second prong of the Obama administration’s reform effort, and one that has been getting significantly more attention lately, has focused on identifying potential corporate governance reforms that would serve to prevent corporations from repeating the mistakes that led to the current crisis. Specifically, the administration has sought to understand why executives and boards at so many major financial institutions failed to appropriately gauge risk and adhere to sound long-term risk management strategies. Not Nothwehr, Erin, U. of Iowa Ctr. For Int’l Fin. and Dev.,Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008 (Dec. 2008), http://www.uiowa.edu/ifdebook/issues/bailouts/eesa.shtml. 5 H.R. 1754, 111th Cong. (2009). 6 Id. 7 Id. 4 surprisingly, the conclusions drawn from this analysis implicate several factors that contributed to the failure to assess risk, but they can be broadly categorized as involving breakdowns in corporate governance. Accordingly, proposed solutions from the administration and from commentators have offered a broad array of measures aimed at improving corporate evaluations and awareness of risk. The focus of this essay is to examine proposed reforms in the area of corporate governance, and to evaluate whether such reforms might serve to prevent future crises without being so intrusive as to hamper growth. Broadly stated, governance reform goals include: (1) Bringing greater transparency to corporate risk management. (2) Increasing the accountability of the board to shareholders. (3) Aligning compensation of top executives with long-term corporate performance. (4) Improving risk awareness at the board level. (5) Improving the procedures for internal evaluation of risk. II. Origins of the Current Financial Crisis: The US Housing Market In order to evaluate whether proposed solutions to lacking corporate governance standards are likely to achieve these goals, it is important to first understand how breakdowns in risk management and analysis contributed to the current financial crisis. Where did these bad risks originate? How did so many major financial institutions fail to accurately perceive the risks they were taking? An examination of activities in the US housing market over the past decade is helpful. The sustained rise in housing prices leading up to the current financial crisis fostered the perception that real estate was an extremely low-risk investment.8 This belief in turn led to a relaxation of standards for issuers of home mortgage loans. This relaxation of standards manifested itself primarily in the dramatic increase in the availability of subprime mortgages.9 Prior to 2000, the issuance of subprime mortgages was an extremely small percentage of total mortgage originations; however, by 2006 nearly half of all mortgage originations were of the subprime variety.10 These subprime mortgages were issued with adjustable rates that generally included a low “teaser rate” to induce borrowers, but reset to higher rates after the first two or three years of the loan.11 Further, many of these subprime loans did not require a down payments or income verification for borrowers.12 Indeed, the most excessive mortgages did not even require the borrower to pay the full amount of interest due during the initial loan period.13 Instead, the excess interest was simply added to the principle of the loan. Issuers justified these subprime mortgages on the belief that housing prices would continue to increase substantially and indefinitely, and that the increased value of the properties would be sufficient to enable borrowers to refinance at a reasonable fixed rate before the adjustable rates reset.14 Furthermore, these subprime loans enabled a large new group of eligible borrowers to participate in the housing market. The influx of new 8 The Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight index of house prices showed increases in every quarter from 1991 through the third quarter of 2007. 9 Martin Neil Baily, Robert E. Litan & Matthew S. Johnson, The Origins of the Financial Crisis, Brookings Institution, Initiative on Bus. & Pub. Pol’y, 14 (Nov. 2008), http://www.brookings.edu/papers/2008/11_orgins_crisis_baily_litan.aspx 10 Id. 11 Id. at 17. 12 Id. 13 Id. at 18. 14 Id. at 17. borrowers, along with sustained low interest rates, served to increase housing demand and also further inflated housing prices.15 In this way, the sustained, rather modest housing growth of the 1990s became the over-heated housing bubble of the 2000s. The incentive to issue subprime loans was further enhanced by the ability of the issuers to transfer the risks associated with them.16 Government sponsored enterprises Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, along with private sector commercial and investment banks, spread the high risks associated with subprime loans throughout the financial system by means of packaging the loans into mortgaged backed securities (MBS) and collateralized debt obligations (CDOs).17 These institutions then sold their newly created securities to investors of all varieties. CDO and MBS issuers were able to market their products to a broad spectrum of investors by allocating the rights to the cash flows from these mortgage-backed investment products into “tranches,” or risk classes.18 The CDO & MBS issuers were then able to convince the credit rating agencies to assign their highest ratings to the securities in the most senior tranch.19 The high return offered by these securities, combined with the high ratings assigned to them by credit rating agencies, made them extremely attractive investments. These factors, combined with a period of sustained low interest rates and lax federal regulation, led many financial institutions to borrow more and more money (increase their leverage) to finance their investment in mortgaged-related assets.20 15 Id. at 18. Id. at 20. 17 Id. at 22-23. 18 Id. at 25. 19 Id. at 25. 20 Id. at 29. 16 Further compounding the problem, insurance companies, investment banks and others began selling “credit default swaps” (CDS) which allowed investors to essentially bet against the risks represented by CDOs.21 These CDS transactions occurred in the Over the Counter (OTC) derivatives market, and were not subject to standardization or oversight from any regulatory body. As a result, no one knew the specific terms of these CDS contracts except the two parties involved, and there existed no public knowledge as to the volume of CDS transactions an institution had made. Even more importantly, since there was no regulation of the CDS market, there were no minimum capital requirements for the selling institutions. The management of many CDS issuers, most notably AIG, so believed their own sales pitch regarding the safety the top tranches of mortgaged-backed securities, that they did not find it necessary to reserve significant capital in the event that the loans underlying the CDO & MBS products went into default.22 Thus, in 2007, when the crisis arose and the value of these mortgaged-backed assets was finally called into question, there were woefully insufficient reserves available to make payment on CDS obligations. The holders of CDOs suddenly found them near worthless, and the CDS issuers were unable to honor their contracts. The result was the freezing of capital markets and catastrophe of the current crisis. In retrospect, it is not difficult to understand why subprime borrowers, banks, and other investors borrowed money on the prospect that the US housing market would 21 Cox, Christopher, Chairman, U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission. Testimony Concerning Turmoil in U.S. Credit Markets: Recent Actions Regarding Government Sponsored Entities, Investment Banks and Other Financial Institutions. Before the Senate Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, Sept. 23, 2008. 22 James B. Kelleher, Buffett’s “time bomb” goes off on Wall Street, Reuters, Sept. 18, 2008. http://www.reuters.com/article/newsOne/idUSN1837154020080918 continue to escalate in value. So long as asset prices were rising, it seemed like an excellent opportunity for consumers to live beyond their means, and for institutional investors to maximize return. The more troubling aspect of the crisis is how each institution involved in the securitization of mortgages failed to understand and appreciate the real risks involved in the underlying assets they issued, held and traded. At no time did the mortgage originators, loan servicers, MBS and CDO issuers, credit rating agencies, CDS sellers, or any of the holders of mortgaged backed securities question the fundamental soundness of these assets and the transparently unsustainable loans underlying these mortgages. III. Failures of Risk Management: Corporate Governance Problems As the financial crisis has illustrated, too often corporate boards at financial institutions were either insufficiently aware of risk or greatly underestimated the risks associated with mortgage-backed assets. Several factors have been identified as contributing to this problem. 1. Over-reliance on mathematical models of risk assessment The use of mathematical models for assessing risk has steadily increased in recent decades, but the technical assumptions underpinning these models are too often faulty or no longer reflective of current market realities.23 Further, even when executives did not trust the accuracy of the technical models, too often the importance of having numerical support often became more important than the actual accuracy of the numbers themselves. 23 Avinash Persaud, Why Bank Risk Models Failed, Vox, Apr. 4, 1999. http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/1029 2. Lack of formal structure for risk analysis Many boards at US financial institutions did not have independent committees for assessing risk.24 Instead many of these institutions assigned risk assessment responsibilities to audit committees already overloaded with compliance activities.25 Even where risk committees were present, members often had no significant experience or training in risk management.26 Further, at many financial institutions there was no Chief Risk Officer (CRO) with board membership.27 Having a CRO present to keep the board regularly informed of corporate risk exposure and risk profile is one way to maintain a high profile for corporate risk management strategies. 3. Failure to transmit risk information through effective channels Due in significant part to the lack of formalized structure for risk analysis; accurate information about risk exposure was not conveyed to the board in a timely or effective manner. This was especially true in financial institutions, such as Bank of America, where one person held the position of chairman of the board and CEO.28 CEO bonuses were commonly linked to short-term stock performance, thus giving CEOs incentive to take high risks in search of high return, even at the expense of long-term 24 For example, Bear Stearns did not establish a risk committee until shortly before it failed. 25 KPMG, Audit committees put risk management at the top of their agendas, June 16, 2008, http://www.kpmg.co.uk/news/detail.cfm?pr=3120 26 Francesco Guerrera & Peter Thal Larson, Gone by the board? Why bank directors did not spot credit risks, Financial Times, June 25, 2008, http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/6e66fe18-42e8-11dd-81d0-0000779fd2ac.html 27 Grant Kirkpatrick, The Corporate Governance Lessons from the Financial Crisis, OECD Steering Group on Corporate Governance, 20, Feb. 11, 2009. 28 Kenneth Lewis was ousted as board chairman of Bank of America on April 29, 2009, but remains as CEO of the company. performance.29 Also, corporations without CROs or independent risk committees provided insufficient structure for risk managers to express potential concerns. 4. Failure to fully appreciate the risk information that was received. The composition of boards was another problem. Directors with little or no experience in the technical aspects of risk management populated many boards. Further, many boards had non-officer directors lacking serious experience in the financial industry.30 Examples include John Deutch, former head of the CIA and current professor of physical chemistry, who sat on Citigroup’s audit and risk management committees, and Tommy Franks, the retired top US Army General, who sits on the audit committee at Bank of America. Without sufficient risk management expertise at the board and committee levels, there can be no meaningful independent analysis of the overall risk profile. 5. Compensation of corporate officers too closely aligned with short-term performance. Another corporate governance matter with direct effects on risk management is the issue of executive compensation. Compensation packages for corporate officers in the US have been heavily weighted toward bonus payments for immediate performance as well as payment in the form of equity.31 This compensation structure often creates a conflict of interest for corporate managers where their personal remuneration interests are in contrast to the long-term interests of the corporations. The existence of these conflicts significantly increases the incentive for executives to take outsized long-term risks in 29 Kirkpatrick, supra at 12-13. Guerrera & Larson, supra. 31 Kirkpatrick, supra at 13. 30 exchange for immediate high returns. By inflating the short-term stock price at the expense of long-term corporate performance, executives are able to sell their equity interests for immediate personal gain. Therefore, even if officers were to conclude that mortgaged back securities and CDOs were not sustainable investments over the long term, it was in their own personal financial interest to ignore these risks in exchange for the maximizing immediate returns these investments offered. 6. Compensation of lower-level managers too closely aligned with shortterm performance. Similar to the compensation of executives, investment banks offered bonuses at the sales and trading levels that were heavily weighted toward short-term performance and insufficiently tied to longer-term objectives.32 Moreover, while potential losses incurred with risk-taking would be borne solely by the institution, bonuses rewarding short-term success were unlimited in size. This compensation structure encouraged sales people and traders to focus excessively on immediate returns. 7. Lower prestige and status of risk managers relative to traders Additionally, there is significant anecdotal evidence that financial institutions frequently disfavored risk managers in comparison with their counterpart traders. An SEC report detailed how risk managers and traders at Bear Sterns were placed within close proximity to one another, suggesting strongly that the risk managers were not acting independently of influence from their trading counterparts.33 Additionally, there are 32 Id. at 12. Securities and Exchange Commission, SEC’s oversight of Bear Stearns and Related Entitites: The Consolidated Supervised Entity Program, Report No. 446-A, Sept. 25, 2008. 33 examples of bank management having little regard for risk managers while aggressively pursuing the expansion of its mortgage business.34 IV. Guiding Principles and Goals for Governance Reform In addressing the problems exposed by the financial crisis, the most immediate goal of governance reforms should be to restore trust and confidence in the financial system. To earn that trust, reforms must be targeted to achieve greater transparency within financial institutions. Further, the public at large must be convinced that reform measures are being taken for the benefit of “main street” businesses and not merely to benefit corporate tycoons and politicians. Additionally, corporate governance reform should foster the long-term goal of creating stability in financial institutions, and creating more robust risk management systems. This includes enhancing the formal mechanisms for analyzing risk, increasing awareness of risk factors within the corporate culture, increasing accountability for irresponsible risk taking, and reducing incentives to take excessive risks. With these goals in mind, reform efforts must strike a careful balance between more innovative, lightly regulated financial markets subject to instability and secure, heavily regulated markets that may stifle economic growth. While there is widespread agreement that a more effective regime of corporate governance is needed in the US, there is substantial debate over the extent of reform necessary to achieve that goal. Increasing the effort and expense of compliance with regulatory mandates places a drag 34 Caroline Binham, HBOS Whistleblower Says Bank Ignored Alerts on Sales (Update 2), Bloomberg.com, Feb. 27, 2009, http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=206011020&sid=a.pGKHXuQwEU&refer=u k. on growth and tends to stifle innovation. Accordingly, reaction to the current crisis must be carefully considered and appropriately targeted in order to avoid the negative consequences associated with over-regulation. Also, if the response to this crisis places too great a regulatory burden on US companies, those companies are likely to seek to relocate to foreign markets offering lighter regulatory restrictions. It is therefore critical that reform measures minimize unnecessary regulatory hurdles, while effectively confronting the corporate governance problems exposed by the economic crisis. V. Potential Measures for Improving Corporate Governance In the wake of the crisis, several specific recommendations have been made in regard to improving corporate governance standards. These recommendations can be broadly categorized although there is some overlap between categories. 1. Increasing disclosure requirements One of the bedrock principles of open markets is that participants should have full and fair disclosure to all relevant information underlying their investment decisions. This disclosure is essential to instilling confidence and trust in the market, but also must be checked by the need for corporations to protect sensitive information. Efforts to increase disclosure requirements have centered on two types: (1) disclosure to regulators, and (2) disclosure to the investing public. Mandating disclosure to regulators is intended to keep federal agencies informed about activity that is currently unregulated, such as the OTC derivatives market which led to much of the current economic turmoil. Disclosure of sensitive trading information to regulators would have the advantage of secrecy. Corporations could share strategic information vital to assessing systemic risk, such as their positions in the OTC derivative market and the extent of their leverage. However, it is unclear whether regulators would have the capacity and sustained resolve to make effective use of this information once the immediacy of the moment has passed. It is noteworthy that, even under the current regulatory scheme, national banking regulators had access to sufficient information to determine that many banks were over invested in mortgage-backed securities, yet the OCC performed no better than the banks themselves in identifying and averting the underlying risks associated with many bank’s extensive involvement in this area.35 Disclosure requirements to the public could take several forms. First, a corporation could include basic information about its risk profile, formal risk management structure and the risk management credentials of its directors in annual reports to shareholders. While having to provide this information is likely to force corporations to pay more attention to risk, it is unclear that general information on such a complex topic would be of significant benefit to investors. Further, making shareholder reports longer and more complex runs the risk that average investors will not take the time to actually read them. Alternatively, information about aggregate positions in unregulated OTC derivative markets could be disclosed to the investing public through an information clearinghouse. This type of disclosure would preserve institution-specific strategic information while allowing investors and regulators access to information relevant to 35 L. Gordon Crovitz, Derivatives and the Wisdom of Crowds: Smart reform yields more information, not more regulation, Wall Street Journal, May 18, 2009, http://online.wsj.com/article/SB124260235584228407.html determining the presence of systemic risks in OTC markets. Further, making this type of information broadly available could assist the accuracy of forecasts on topics like interest rates, corporate credit risk, and foreign exchange movements.36 Thus an informed market would operate more efficiently and with greater awareness of potential risks. Finally, a consumer protection measure could be taken by requiring mortgage issuers to include plain language statements to consumers about loan terms and conditions, particularly in regard to subprime mortgages. Creating an additional disclosure form might make subprime borrowers more cognizant of the long-term risks associated with these mortgages. Including an additional boilerplate form for borrowers to sign probably would not make a substantial impact, but implementing this type of disclosure requirement would be relatively simple and inexpensive. 2. Requiring formalized risk management structure A further possible measure to strengthen corporate governance is simply requiring corporations to maintain a more formalized structure for analyzing risk. Several proposals have been made to achieve more robust internal mechanisms for assessing risk: SOX mandated the presence of at least one financial expert on corporate boards. A similar measure could be adopted for a risk management expert. Requiring the chairman of the board to be an independent director – the rationale being that CEO’s are more inclined to take outsized risks while boards should exercise independent oversight of risk management. Recently, shareholders of Bank of America voted to enact such a division after widespread dissatisfaction with management’s performance. 36 Id. Requiring risk committees to have a minimum level of risk management sophistication. Similar to having a risk management expert on the board, risk committees could be required to have a threshold number of members with experience and expertise in the field of risk management. The explicit separation of risk and audit committee functions. Requiring corporations to establish a risk committee separate and apart from the audit committee would allow greater focus on risk management issues, and decrease the likelihood that audit committees will simply be too overwhelmed with compliance issues to effectively analyze risk levels. Mandated frequency of risk committee meetings. Having an expertly staffed risk committee is of little value if that committee fails to meet often enough to be effective. For example, Lehman Brothers had an independent risk committee in place prior to the financial crisis, but it only met twice in both 2006 and 2007.37 Therefore, a minimum requirement might be for the risk committee to meet at least quarterly. 3. Compensation issues One issue getting a great deal of attention in the wake of the financial crisis is the compensation of executives. The public and legislators have been incensed recently over bonuses paid out of TARP funds to current and former AIG executives.38 There has also been a more general dissatisfaction with steadily rising executive compensation over the past two decades. Further, as previously discussed, the structure of executive 37 Kirkpatrick, supra at 19. See, e.g., Liam Pleven, Serena Ng, and Sudeep Reddy, AIG Faces Growing Wrath Over Payouts, Wall Street Journal, Mar. 16, 2009, http://online.wsj.com/article/SB123715965204435363.html. 38 compensation in the US has been heavily weighted toward bonuses and equity interests that encouraged executives to focus on short-term performance. Since 2007, the SEC has mandated that corporations file Compensation Disclosure and Analysis (CD&A) reports. These disclosure reports were an initial attempt at reigning in compensation packages for corporate executives, but mere disclosure has proved ineffective because it does not limit the specific types of compensation that led to excessive risk-taking. Current efforts to reform compensation structures have focused on more closely aligning the personal financial interests of executives with the long-term performance of the corporations they manage. Specifically, many financial institutions are reducing bonuses for immediate increases in stock price in favor of higher base salaries. For example, in the past month, Morgan Stanley and UBS have more than doubled the base pay for executives while greatly reducing available bonuses.39 This shift away from bonuses for short-term performance is likely to be supported by regulatory efforts when Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner’s proposed overhaul of executive compensation is announced in the coming weeks. While Geithner has opposed putting absolute caps on compensation, he has called for “very, very substantial change” in the regulation of executive pay.40 One such regulatory change advocated by Mr. Geithner is the introduction of “say on pay” requirements, which would allow shareholders an up-or-down vote on executive 39 Elizabeth Hester, Morgan Stanley to Boost Executive Salaries as Bonuses Decline (Correct), Bloomberg.com, May 23, 2009, http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=20601087&sid=aoz7URVpwVro 40 Rich Miller, Geithner Calls for “Very Substantial” Change in Wall Street Pay, Bloomberg.com, May 22, 2009, http://bloomberg.com/apps/news ?pid=20601087&sid=aCwz3Hlyo9sg compensation packages.41 While Geithner has not suggested that these votes would be binding, they do give shareholders a voice in the area of executive compensation and presumably would increase accountability for compensation committee directors. Similar to compensation structure reforms, several US companies have voluntarily implemented “say on pay” policies in the past year.42 4. Proxy access and the “Shareholders Bill of Rights” A further means of addressing corporate governance issues includes proposals to make boards more responsive, and more accountable, to shareholders. The SEC plans to introduce rule amendments that would greatly increase shareholders ability to include their own nominated directors on company proxy ballots.43 Under the existing proxy rules, shareholders who wish to challenge the slate of directors offered by the board must resort to sending their own proxy materials to shareholders – an extremely expensive process. Under the proposed new rules, shareholders satisfying a minimum threshold ownership of voting securities would be entitled to include their candidate (or multiple candidates, up to 25 percent of the board – whichever is greater) with company proxy materials.44 These minimum ownership thresholds would be set according to the size of the corporation, and are proposed as follows45: One percent ownership in voting securities of a “large accelerated filer” (a company with a worldwide market value of at least $700M). 41 Id. Aflac, TIAA-CREF & Verizon are examples. 43 See Security and Exchange Commission, SEC Votes to Propose Rule Amendments to Facilitate Rights of Shareholders to Nominate Directors, press release 2009-116, May 20, 2009. 44 Id. 45 Id. 42 Three percent ownership in voting securities of an “accelerated filer” (a company with a worldwide market value between $75M and $700M). Five percent ownership in voting securities of a “non-accelerated filer” (a company with a worldwide market value of less than $75M). Additionally, under the proposed changes, shareholders would be allowed to aggregate holdings for purposes of meeting these threshold requirements; however, there would be additional requirements to be met before a shareholder could gain access to company proxy materials. These requirements are46: Shareholder would be required to have held their shares for at least one year. Shareholders would have to sign a statement of intent to continue holding their shares until the annual meeting at which directors are elected Shareholders would be required to certify that they are not holding their stock for the purpose of changing control of the company, or to gain more than minority representation on the board of directors. As an additional measure the current rule allowing companies to block shareholder proposals related to the election of directors would be sharply narrowed. Under the proposed changes, qualifying shareholders could submit shareholder proposals concerning a company’s nominating procedures or nomination disclosure provisions. A qualified shareholder for purposes of this measure would have held stock worth $2,000 in 46 Id. market value, or one percent whichever is less, for a period of one year prior to submitting the proposal.47 Should the proposed changes to proxy access become law, the consequences to effective risk management are difficult to gauge. Making it easier to vote out board members will increase the board responsiveness to minority shareholder interests; however, it is not clear that minority shareholder interests are necessary in line with longterm performance of the company. As has occurred with executives given equity interests as compensation, the enhanced influence of shareholders may result in policies that pump up the immediate stock price by pursuing high returns at the expense of elevated risks. The one-year holding period requirement may serve to alleviate some shareholder shortsightedness, as those capable of nominating directors will presumably be invested in the company for the long term; however, once qualified to nominate directors, the incentive for immediate return will be similar to that of executives with an equity interest. Another concern with greater proxy access, and the resulting increase in contested elections, is the corresponding increase in influence among proxy advisory services such at RiskMetrics, Glass Lewis and Proxy Governance. There is concern that these services may succumb to the same conflicts of interests that have recently tarnished the credibility of the Credit Rating Agencies.48 Perhaps increased SEC scrutiny of proxy advisor practices could quell such dangers, but currently the possibility of proxy advisor conflicts remains a potential downside to increased advisor influence. 47 Id. See, e.g., Interview by Metropolitan Corporate Counsel with Cary I. Klafter, Vice President, Legal and Corporate Affairs and Corporate Secretary, Intel Corporation (May 4, 2009), http://www.metrocorpcounsel.com/current.php?artType=view&EntryNo=9673. 48 On the other hand, a recent study by the Investor Responsibility Research Center Institute shows that companies in which minority shareholder interests (usually hedge funds) won a seat on the board substantially outperformed peers in both the short and long terms.49 Indeed, according to the study, those companies with greater minority representation performed better than those with more modest representation.50 An even more dramatic effort to strengthen the power of shareholders has been proposed by Senator Chuck Schumer. Under his recently introduced legislation, called the “Shareholder Bill of Rights Act of 2009”, Schumer seeks a federal mandate on many of the potential remedies discussed above, including: (1) increased minority proxy access, (2) an independent chair of the board, (3) “say on pay” for shareholders, and (4) the establishment of a risk committee.51 In addition, Schumer’s bill would require that every board member be re-elected annually, thereby eliminating “staggered boards.”52 Also, Schumer’s bill would require that board members in uncontested elections receive a majority of all available votes or be forced to immediately resign.53 These proposals again raise the question of whether a board beholden to shareholder interests is actually less likely to pursue short-term gains in favor of longterm growth. Institutional investors, the ones most likely to benefit from increased shareholder power, did not fare well in the recent crisis in terms of assessing the overall risk of their investments. Additionally, federalizing corporate governance to the extent proposed by Schumer would likely result in the courts determining complex issues of 49 Chris Cernich, Scott Fenn, Michael Anderson, & Shirley Westcott, Effectiveness of Hybrid Boards, Investor Responsibility Research Center Institute, 38 (May 2009). 50 Id. 51 S. Res. 1074, 111th Cong. (2009) 52 Id. 53 Id. pre-emption, as these new regulations would effectively usurp much of what has traditionally been governed under state corporate law. 5. Independent certification of risk management systems. One additional possibility for enhancing corporate risk management is requiring independent certification of corporate risk management systems. Such a measure would subject risk management systems to the same type of outside analysis and review that SOX brought to corporate accounting. While requiring independent verification of adequate risk procedures would surely strengthen corporate awareness of risk, a significant drawback is the substantial expense involved in obtaining outside certifications. Due to these costs, and the resulting negative effects on growth at a time when economic stimulation is a top priority, requiring independent certification has not received seriously attention by the administration. However, if excessive risk taking continues to be a problem beyond the current round of reforms, certification is likely to receive more substantial consideration. VI. Striking a Balance: How Far Should Governance Reforms Go? In considering the broad range of potential responses to the current problems with corporate governance in the US, a threshold consideration is determining to what extent these reforms should be implemented at the federal level. Matters of corporate governance have traditionally been determined under state corporate laws, and courts have held that federal agencies may not enforce governance requirements without specific authorization from Congress.54 The first significant federal legislation in the area of governance came in 2002 with the passage of SOX. While some commentators maintain that all governance regulation is best handled at the state level, federal regulation in this area appears certain to increase in the near term. These new measures will effectively raise the floor for governance regulation, and allow states to adjust their own specific requirement upwards from the federal minimums. Given that the federal standards will be minimums, with states able to enact more stringent measures, Congress should proceed cautiously when placing new governance requirements on corporations. By showing restraint in enacting reforms, Congress can avoid the negative growth effects of over-regulation while ensuring that benefits of diverse solutions to corporate governance problems continue to accrue at the state level. A second threshold issue is how federal governance reforms can be tailored to target only those companies that pose significant threats to the financial system. By limiting the application of mandated federal reforms to only large companies, the most troubling risk management problems revealed by the current crisis can be effectively targeted without placing potentially heavy burdens of compliance on smaller companies that do not significantly threaten the financial system. Of course, tailoring reforms according to company size necessarily involves issues of line drawing. One possible place to draw the line for proposed reforms such as the establishment of a risk committee, having an independent chairperson, and “say on 54 See, e.g., Bus. Roundtable v. S.E.C., 905 F.2d 406, 412 (D.C. Cir. 1990); Sante Fe Industries, Inc. v. Green, 430 U.S. 462, 477-478 (1977). pay” measures is at the “large accelerated filer” designation already used by the SEC. Exempting smaller companies will allow them more flexibility and fewer compliance issues, while still safeguarding the financial system from excessive risk taking by large institutions. With federal governance reforms appropriately targeted, the first goal should be to restore trust in the financial system. In order to restore trust, greater disclosure and transparency is needed, particularly in the unregulated OTC derivatives market – where CDSs were negotiated and traded. Mandating public disclosure of aggregate OTC market information through a clearinghouse would be a positive step in increase awareness of systemic risks arising from the OTC derivatives market. With greater certainty established, public trust of the financial system will increase. As a further means of restoring public trust, and of creating more effective risk management systems, measures should be taken to ensure that a robust risk management structure exists at every large US corporation. Mandating the presence of a risk committee, separate from the audit committee, would be an uncomplicated yet positive step in that direction. An additional requirement that the risk committee have at least one person with significant risk management credentials would also be prudent. Requiring this basic level of internal structure should present only a small hurdle for large companies, as most have already stepped up their risk management structure in the wake of the crisis.55 On the issue of executive compensation, giving shareholders a non-binding “say on pay” would help to ensure that greater attention is paid to compensation packages both 55 Enterprise Risk Management Symposium, Survey of Actuaries and Corporate Risk Experts, May 11, 2009. in quantity and in type. Establishing this additional check on pay should help prevent incentives to take excessive risk for short-term returns. Further measures on remuneration, such as hard caps on executive pay or foreclosing certain types of remuneration, lack flexibility and could unduly restrain US companies in global competition for top executive talent. Finally, the argument that increasing board accountability, through increased proxy access and more frequent elections, will improve risk management is unconvincing without credible evidence that shareholders are better suited to judge risk than the boards themselves. Indeed, by shortening election cycles and increasing contested elections the pressure on board members to encourage shortsighted, immediate return only intensifies. For this reason, measures that substantially alter the balance of power between boards and shareholders should not be included in the federal floor for corporate governance standards. Rather, states engaged in a “race to the top” for shareholder rights would be a more appropriate testing ground for these measures. VII. Conclusion Federal reform of corporate governance regulation is a critical part of the Obama administration’s effort to overhaul regulation of the financial system. In enacting these reforms, the administration must appropriately target new requirements in order to restore confidence and achieve stability without hampering economic growth. In order to achieve this balance, regulation should be focused on increasing risk awareness and decrease incentives to assume imprudent risks in return for higher short-term returns.