Chapter 3: Determination of Forward and Future Prices 3.1 Investment Asset vs. Consumption Asset Investment asset: asset held for investment purposes (stocks and bonds) We can use arbitrage arguments to determine forward prices from its spot price Consumption asset: asset held primarily for consumption (copper, oil) 3.2 Short Selling Short sale of stocks: sell stocks you don’t own An investor instructs his broker to short 500 IBM shares: the broker borrows shares from another client and selling them in the market If the broker runs out of shares, the investor has to close out its position April: short 500 shares IBM at $120 a share May: dividend of $1 a share is paid to all shareholders => The investor has to pay $500 to the broker July: the position of the investor is closed out/ buys back the shares at $100 a share What is the profit of the investor? 3.4 Assumptions and Notation - Market Participants no transaction costs same tax rate on all net trading profit borrow and lend money against the same interest rate take advantage of arbitrage opportunities Notation - T: time until delivery - S0: price of an asset today - F0 forward or future price - r: risk free rate of interest, with continuous compounding 3.5 Forward rate for an investment asset (provide no income: zero coupon bonds or non-dividend paying stocks) Example: 3.5.1 Risk free rate: 5% Current stock price: S0 = $40 What is the forward price in three months? Forward rate: F0 = S0 .e0.05*3/12 = $40.50 F0 = S0 .erT (3.5) If the forward price is $ 39 - short one share - invest the proceeds at the risk free rate - take a long position in a futures contract In three month time: Proceeds grow to 40 .e0.05*3/12 = $40.50 Take delivery of the share Close out the short position Net gain: $40.50 - $39 = $1.50 3.6 Known income (coupon bearing bonds or dividend paying stocks) Example: Coupon bearing bond ($40 in 6 months time and $40 in one year, just before the end of the year) S0 = $900 Six months risk free interest rate: 9 % One year risk free interest rate: 10 % I (investment income/ present value): I = 40 . e -0.09 . 6/12 + 40 . e-0.10 . 1 = 74.433 F0 = (S0 – I) .erT (3.6) F0 = (900 – 74.433) e 0.10 .1 = $912.39 3.7 Known yield (this means that the income is known when expressed as a percent of the asset price at the time the income is paid) F0 = S0 .e (r-q) T (3.7) 3.8 Valuing Forward Contracts Delivery date in T years, r is the risk free rate F0 : current forward price for a contract, that was negotiated some time ago K: delivery price in the contract f: value of a long forward contract today A general result: f = (F0 – K) .e-rT See Example: 3.5.1 T: 3 months Risk free rate: 5% S0 = $40 F0 = S0 .erT = $40.50 (= K: delivery price in the contract) What is the value of a long forward contract one month later when the stock price is $42? F0 = S0 .erT = $42 . e0.05 *2/12 = $42.35 1 month later: f = (42.35 – 40.50) .e-0.05* 2/12 = $1.83 3.9 Are forward prices and futures prices equal? Empirical research: A number of studies found significant differences between forward and future prices It seems likely that these observed differences are due to: - transaction costs - taxes - treatment of margins 3.10 Stock index futures A stock index tracks changes in the hypothetical portfolio of stocks The weight of a stock equals the proportion of the portfolio invested in the stock Future prices of stock indices A stock index can be regarded as the price of an investment asset that pays dividends The investment asset is the portfolio of the stocks underlying the index and the dividends are the dividends that would be received by the holder of the portfolio F0 = S0 .e (r-q) T (3.7) 3.11 Forward and future contracts on currencies Definition: S0 and F0 : spot or forward price in dollars of one unit of the foreign currency (like the euro, the British Pound or the Japanese Yen) The relation between S0 and F0 F0 = S0 .e (r-rf) T (3.13) The well known interest rate parity relationship (courses international economics 1 and international economics 2) Example: S0 = 1.22 USD per euro r = 0.0375 rf = 0.02 T = ½ year F0 = S0 .e (r-rf) T = 1.2307 Is it possible for a big financial institution (lend and borrow money at the risk free rate in Europe or the United States) to make a profit if: a) F = 1.24 USD per euro b) F = 1.22 USD per euro Show how profits can be made! 3.12 Futures on commodities Storage costs: We have seen: F0 = (S0 – I) .erT (3.6) Where: I: present value of investment income Storage costs can be seen as negative income: F0 = (S0 + U) .erT (3.15) If storage costs are seen as providing a negative yield then (3.15) becomes (3.16): F0 = S0 .e(r+u)T (3.16) Convenience yield: (y) We do not necessarily have equality in equations (3.15) and (3.16) because users of a consumption commodity may feel that ownership of a physical commodity provides benefits that are not obtained by holders of future contracts. The crude oil in inventory (in the presence of hurricanes like Katrina or Rita) may be valuable to keep a production process running and perhaps profiting from temporary shortages In this case: F0 .eyT= (S0 + U) .erT or F0.eyT = S0 .e(r+u)T => F0 = S0 .e(r+u-y)T (3.21) 3.13 Cost of carry Cost of carry (c): storage costs plus the interest that is paid to finance the asset less the income earned on the asset For a non dividend paying stock: c = r For a stock index: c = r – q For a currency: c = r – rf For a commodity with storage costs: c = r + u For an investment asset F0 = S0 .ecT (3.22) For a consumption asset F0 = S0 .e(c-y)T (3.23) y: the convenience yield (3.15 Future prices and the expected future spot price) To be discussed after knowledge of the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) The CAPM tells you all about Risk and Return.