WAR IN IRAQ: THE IMPLICATIONS OF WAR ON THE US ECONOMY Economic Concepts Final Project MBAM 592.11 Fall 2004, Session A Mike Bennett Angela Copeland Sarah Todnem Professor David Smith Monday, October 18, 2004 Table of Contents I. Introduction………………………………………………………3 II. Short Term Effects of War……………………………………….4 III. Long Term Effects of War……………………………………….6 IV. Conclusions……………………………………………………….8 V. Sources.......................................................................................10 2 I. Introduction The obvious justifications for going to war with Iraq are increasing national security by decreasing the perceived terrorist threat and removing from power a dictator guilty of many human rights violations. However, the not so obvious rationale for invading Iraq may have a lot to do with gaining political leverage over the rich oil deposits there. However, there are many costs associated with war that need to be considered when performing a cost-benefit analysis. Below is a table which shows the costs of wars throughout U.S. History, shown in 2002 dollars. Also included is a table of the component costs of the War in Iraq, depicting the increased cost of prolonged occupation paired with the increased cost of the technology used in war. War Conflict Costs (Billions) Revolutionary War Civil War World War I World War II Vietnam First Gulf War $2.20 $62.00 $190.60 $2,896.30 $494.30 $76.10 Per Capita Cost $447 $1,686 $2,489 $20,388 $2,204 $306 Costs as a % of GDP 63 104 24 130 12 1 Table 1: Historical Cost of War 3 Currently, the U.S. Government spends $10 – 15M per hour for a bomber run, $1M for each Tomahawk Missile launch, $3M per day for aircraft carrier deployment, and $21K each to upgrade bombs to include satellite guidance. II. Short-term Effects of the War Many people feel that war will help the economy by boosting production and creating more jobs. As we will see, going to war does provide many benefits to a country, especially one in an economic downturn. However, these benefits are primarily seen in the short run. Going to war increases GDP in the short run. Governments increase spending in order to provide the troops and equipment necessary for participating in a war. In the past year, the US government has increased government spending by over 25%. However, economic well-being is falsely inflated. The Government gets the funds to provide for this spending by: raising taxes, decreasing spending in other areas, and increasing its debt. The government has a budget constraint like everything else. The figure below demonstrates that as the government increases military spending, there is less money to fund social programs. (These programs help build important factors of productivity such as physical and human capital). In a time of war, total government spending increases, shifting the budget constraint outward. At the same time, the 4 government is less willing to trade military for social spending, indicating that they shift up along the curve. Figure 1: Government Budget Constraint The government currently estimates that a short-term war with Iraq will cost from $60-90B, with a long-term estimate of $600B. However, economists generally see these costs as too narrowly-defined and estimate that the real cost of the war will be $100200B, or $2,000B in the long-term. Therefore that is at least $100B that will be funneled to military spending as opposed to social programs that would build human and physical capital for future productivity. 5 In the short term, unemployment is also positively affected. The increase in government spending leads to an increase in production that will increase the number of civilian jobs available in manufacturing and related sectors such defense contracting. The war will also increase demand for soldiers, seamen, and airmen. The increased demand for military personnel will create job openings in private sectors as they are vacated by reservists being activated as well. Therefore, the unemployment rate will drop as more jobs become available in both government and private sectors. III. Long-term Effects of the War From the short-term perspective, war seems to be a good thing for the economy. However, in the long term, many of the benefits will cause economic problems. As earlier noted, the government raises taxes, increases debt, and decreases spending in other areas to generate the funds needed to go to war. Increasing taxes puts a strain on consumers, causing them to spend less. This lack of spending is reflected as decreased consumption in overall GDP. Increasing the debt of the government means that the government goes into the private loan market and buys up a good portion of the loans. This action causes inflation, decreasing the value of the American dollar. Thus people are unable to spend as much as they once did. Also the lack of spending in other areas leads to deficiencies in human and physical capital, causing productivity growth slowdown. Taking into account all these drawbacks to government spending on war, it is estimated that GDP could be up to 2% below baseline for 2005 – 2009 because of the 6 war. Conversely, many hope that an added economic benefit of the war will be increased oil supply and increased stability in the Middle East. These goals are valid, but ultimately, war will not bring about large-scale changes in the foreseeable future due to outside forces such as OPEC and the larger political climate of the world. Figure 2: Oil Production’s Effect of Supply and Demand Figure 2 demonstrates that during the War in Iraq, the decreased oil supply creates an increase in the price of oil. After the war, the hope is that the supply of oil will increase, decreasing the cost of oil. 7 War is not a long-term solution to unemployment. When the war is over, the additional production caused by the large increase in government spending will cease when the supplies used in the war have been replenished to pre-war levels. Additionally, the raised taxes over time place pressure on the consumers, causing decreased consumption. This decrease will also lead to production cuts and higher unemployment. IV. Conclusions The broken window fallacy describes a situation in which a vandal throws a brick through a shop window. The owner then must spend money to replace the window. In the end, the fallacy suggests that the vandal is a public benefactor because he stimulated spending in the society, causing a trickledown effect that improves the economic well being of a society. What the fallacy fails to account for is the fact that without the vandal, the shop keeper would have had both his window and his money. He would have invested his money elsewhere were the window not broken, while preserving the capital of the window. The broken window fallacy is an antic-dote that explains the economic shortcomings of war. Going to war claiming that it will benefit the economy is 8 much like throwing the brick, assuming that it will stimulate spending. The war ties up funds that could be expended in a more productive fashion, while destroying some of the existing capital of a society. Therefore, going to war will not benefit the economy in the long run. As we have seen, war does show some short-term benefits in GDP and unemployment due to increased government purchases that stimulate production. However, in the long-term, the government’s war spending takes funds away from more productive spending, while also destroying important physical and human capital. War may seem to benefit the economy, but these benefits are extremely short lived and the overall effect is negative. 9 V. Sources “Calculating the consequences”, The Economist, November 28,2002. McKibbin and Stoeckel, “The Economic Costs of a War in Iraq”, Brookings Institution and Centre for International Economics, March 7, 2003. Francis, David. “War’s certainty: a big price tag”, The Christian Science Monitor. Thurow, Lester. “Economics of the War in Iraq”, Commonwealth Magazine, April 2003. “Bush’s War Economy”, The Progressive, December 2003. Moffett, Mike. “Are Wars Good for the Economy?”, Economics.About.com 10