The Standard Trade Model • Ricardian model: – production possibilities determined by the allocation of labor between sectors. – comparative advantage but no distribution of income. • Heckscher-Ohlin model: – multiple factors of production; – differences in resources drive trade patterns; – trade can affect the distribution of income. • Standard trade model: – bring several features into one framework: – difference in production possibility frontier give rise to trade; – production possibility determine a country’s relative supply; – world equilibrium is determined by world relative supply and demand that lies between national relative supply schedules. • Standard trade model. More flexible to analyze several important issues: – trade effect on industrial structure; – world price effects on national production, consumption and welfare; impact of tariffs and other trade policies on the domestic country; – impact of growth on welfare; • Standard trade model is built on 4 relationship: 1. the relationship between the production possibility frontier and the relative supply curve; 2. the relationship between relative prices and relative demand; 3. the determination of world equilibrium by world relative supply and world relative demand; 4. the effect of the terms of trade—the price of a country’s exports divided by the price of its imports— on a nation’s welfare. • Important concept: the term of trade (TOT) TOT = Export Price Import Price – TOT changes have an impact on industrial structure, consumption and welfare; – Old debate on the TOT of developing countries – Prebish-Singer thesis: TOT between primary products and manufactured goods tends to deteriorate over time. Æ countries that export primary products (developing countries) would be able to import less and less for a given level of exports; Æ developing economies should not focus on producing primary products but should instead promote the development of manufacturing industry. 1 Important concept: the term of trade (TOT) 1960 2000 Developed country 117 110 Developing country 45 75 Oil producers 21 80 Deterioration of the TOT in developed countries vs better TOT for oil exporters UNCTAD: TOT 1980 base = 100 – A particular aspect of the TOT deterioration: EU Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) – Impact of the CAP on developing countries, that have large agricultural sector – WTO negotiation and “collapse” in Cancun • Production possibilities and relative supply V = PC QC + PF QF ⇔ QF = Each country’s production possibility frontier is a smooth curve like that illustrated by TT. V ⎛ PC ⎞ − ⎜ ⎟QC PF ⎜⎝ PF ⎟⎠ A market economy maximizes the value of output, V, at given market prices PC QC + PF QF The economy will produce the highest value of output it can, which can be achieved by producing at point Q, where TT is just tangent to an isovalue line. Suppose PC PF were to rise. The isovalue lines will be steeper than before – the highest isovalue line the economy could reach before the change in PC PF is shown as VV1; – the highest line after the price change is VV1; – the point at which the economy produces shifts from Q1 to Q². A rise in the relative price of cloth leads the economy to produce more cloth and less food. The relative supply of cloth will therefore rise when the relative price of cloth rises. 2 • Relative prices and demand – Autarky equilibrium : QA=DA and QM=DM; the value of consumption equals the value of its production: V = PC QC + PF QF = PC DC + PF DF – Production and consumption MUST lie on the same isovalue line. – Production already defined (see last slide) – Consumption? consumption decisions may be represented as if they were based on the tastes of a single representative individual. The tastes of an individual can be represented graphically by a series of indifference curves. Indifference Curve Food Production An indifference curve traces a set of combinations of cloth (C) and food (F) consumption that leave the individual equally well off. Properties of indifference curves: 1. downward sloping: If an individual is offered less F, then to be made equally well off she must be given more C. 2. The farther up and to the right an indifference curve lies, the higher the level of welfare to which it corresponds: on individual will prefer more of both goods to less. 3. Each indifference curve gets flatter as we move to the right: The more C and the less F an individual consumes, the more valuable a unit of F is at the margin compared with a unit of C, so more C will have to be provided to compensate for any further reduction in F. Free Trade: The economy produces more cloth than it consumes and therefore exports cloth; correspondingly, it consumes more food than it produces and therefore imports food. Equilibrium in Autarky Cloth Production Food Production The economy produces at point Q, where the production possibility frontier is tangent to the highest possible isovalue line. D Food imports It consumes at point D, where that isovalue line is tangent to the highest possible indifference curve. Q=D Q Cloth exports Cloth Production 3 Effects of a rise in the relative price of cloth Slope of the isovalue lines is equal to minus the relative price of cloth PC PF , so when that relative price rises all isovalue lines become steeper. D1’ In particular, the maximum value line rotates from VV1 to VV². – production shifts from Q1 to Q2; – consumption shifts from D1 to D2. two effects: – income effect: the relative price of cloth rises, country imports more food for any given volume of exports; – substitution effect: change in relative prices leads to a shift along the indifference curve, toward food and away from cloth. Welfare effect of a rise in the relative price of cloth A country that initially exports cloth is made better off (see shift from D1 to D2). A country that initially exports food is made worse off (see shift from D2 to D1). Case of developing countries: – change of industrial structure in favor of manufacturing (where they do not have any comparative advantage); – income redistribution towards manufacturing workers (and not workers in the agricultural sector.); – margin reduction and exit of small enterprises. A rise in the terms of trade increases a country’s welfare, while a decline in the terms of trade reduces its welfare. International equilibrium within the RS and RD framework The higher PC PF is the larger the world supply of cloth relative to food (RS) and the lower the world demand for cloth relative to food (RD). Equilibrium relative price (here, (PC PF )equi) is determined by the intersection of the world relative supply and demand equi curves. ⎛ PC ⎞ The world relative supply curve (RS) is upward sloping because an increase in PC PF leads both countries to produce more cloth and less food. ⎜⎜ ⎟⎟ ⎝ PF ⎠ The world relative demand curve (RD) is downward sloping because an increase in PC PF leads both countries to shift their consumption mix away from cloth toward food. The intersection of the curves (point 1) determines the equilibrium relative price 4 International equilibrium within offer curves framework At the relative price corresponding to the slope of the line from the origin, Home makes the offer to trade QC-DC units of cloth for DF-QF units of food. Offer curve: tracing out how Home’s offer varies as PC PF changes. Same for Foreign (see below) International equilibrium within offer curves framework Equilibrium : QC − DC = DC* − QC* and DF − QF = QF* − DF* Foreign’s offer curve shows how that country’s desired imports of cloth and exports of food vary with the relative price. At the equilibrium point E the relative price of cloth is equal to the slope of OE. Home’s exports of cloth, which equal Foreign’s imports, are OX. Foreign’s exports of food, which equal Home’s imports, are OY. • Economic growth and term of trade Growth is biased when it shifts production possibilities out more toward one good than toward another. In both cases, the production possibility frontier shifts out from TT1 to TT². In case (a) this shift is biased toward cloth, in case (b) toward food. 5 • TOT, distortion and Immiserizing growth – Is growth good or bad for the domestic country? This depends on the bias of the growth. Export biased growth is good for the domestic country because it increases its term of trade; – if a country growth results in an increased desired to trade, growth leads to a deterioration of country’s TOT unless ROW is growing at the same rate or faster; – is the deterioration in the TOT so severe that the country is made worth off? Immiserizing growth (Bhagwati, 1958); A special case: immiserizing growth: large country with monopoly power Assume a technical improvement in cloth and shift from TT1 to TT². – At the initial price W1, country wan to trade more, supplying more export and demanding more import of food; – this cause the TOT to deteriorate (the relative price of cloth fall) – this deterioration is so large that welfare reduces from D1 to D²; New consumption and new production sets; This seems to be paradoxical but since the country has a monopoly power in trade, it has an impact on the TOT. When a country has a monopoly power, free trade is not the optimal policy Food Production D1 D2 W2 W1 TT1 TT2 Cloth Production Growth within the relative supply framework Growth biased toward cloth shifts the RS curve to the right (panel a), while growth biased toward food shifts it to the left (panel b) – Export-biased growth tends to worsen a growing country’s terms of trade, to the benefit of the rest of the world; – import-biased growth tends to improve a growing country’s terms of trade at the rest of the world’s expense. 6 Example: Has the Growth of Newly Industrializing Countries Hurt Advanced Nations? Average Annual Percent Changes in Terms of Trade Growth in the rest of the world can hurt the domestic country if it takes place in sectors that compete with domestic’s exports. (Samuelson, 2004: If China becomes sufficiently good at producing goods it currently imports, comparative advantage disappears and the US loses the gains from trade.) 19861995 19962005 Advanced Countries 0.8 -0.4 Developing Asia -0.1 -1.1 if this is true, we should see large negative numbers for the terms of trade of advanced countries and large positive numbers for the terms of trade of the new competitors. Group mainly dominated by China The percentage real income effect of a change in the terms of trade is approximately equal to the percent change in the terms of trade, multiplied by the share of imports in income. Example: China (growth ~ 8% in 2005) 4 effects on the term of trade: – positive: productivity in the import sectors of the industrialized countries Æ reduction of import price; – positive: low consumption, high investment rate (40%) Æ High Chinese demand of machinery and equipment Æ increase in relative prices of machinery and equipment Æ TOT improvement (Germany, for example) – negative: increase of importation of oil and raw material Æ price of oil increase Æ improvement of TOT of oil exporters (developing countries) Æ deterioration of TOT of developed and developing countries that compete with Chinese consumers; – negative: increase of the productivity of chinese exports in in sectors that compete with domestic’s exports Æ deterioration of TOT (Samuelson’s argument). • International transfer of income – Keynes vs Ohlin regarding the Germany’s transfer payment after WWI. Keynes argue that transfer to the allies would worsen Germany’s TOT because Germany would have to make its exports cheaper relative to its imports; – Asian countries before and after 1998. Before: large capital flow recipient (~ transfer). After: large outward transfer. Thus, current account surplus and capital account deficit. Export prices decreases by 23% in Indonesia, 29% in South-Korea, 35% in Thailand… – according to Keynes, this should lead to a large deterioration of the TOT effect. – the transfer problem in Asia was masked by other forces (price of oil, yen/US $ … ) 7 Effect of a transfer on the TOT Home makes a transfer of some of its income to Foreign. – Home’s income is reduced, and it must reduce its expenditure. – Foreign increases its expenditure. This shift in the national division of world spending may lead to a shift in world relative demand and thus affect the terms of trade. The shift in the RD curve (if it occurs) is the only effect of a transfer of income. The RS curve does not shift. 2 cases: – If the two countries allocate their change in spending in the same proportions Æ world equilibrium does not change; – If not, there is a terms of trade effect; the direction of the effect will depend on the difference in Home and Foreign spending patterns. Assume that Home has a higher marginal propensity to spend on cloth than Foreign. Then Æ move from RD1 to RD². • Tariffs and export subsidies – Import tariffs are taxes levied on import while export subsidies are payments given to exporters; – tariffs and export subsidies is that they create a difference between prices at which goods are traded on the world market and their prices within a country; – direct effect of a tariff: imported goods are more expensive inside a country than they are outside; – direct effect of an export subsidy: more profitable to sell abroad than at home unless the price at home is higher, so such a subsidy raises the price of exported goods inside a country; – price changes caused by tariffs and subsidies change both relative supply and relative demand Æ shift in the TOT of the country imposing the policy change and in the TOT of the rest of the world. Effect of a tariff on the TOT Assume home impose an ad-valorem tariff on imports of food Æ domestic relative price of cloth is lower than the world relative price – At any given world relative price of cloth, then, Home producers face a lower relative cloth price and therefore produce less cloth and more food. At the same time, Home consumers shift their consumption toward cloth and away from food. – Relative supply of cloth fall while the relative demand for cloth rise (from RD1 to RD²); – World relative price of cloth rises and thus Home’s terms of trade improve at Foreign’s expense. Impact depends clearly on the size of the country that imposes tariffs. 8 Effect of an export subsidy on the TOT An export subsidy’s effects are the reverse of those of a tariff. Relative supply of cloth rises, while relative demand falls. Home’s terms of trade decline as the relative price of cloth falls from (PC PF )1 to (PC PF )2 . A Home export subsidy worsens Home’s terms of trade and improves Foreign’s. TOT effect: distribution of income BETWEEN countries – Tariff effect on Home’s welfare – TOT improvement benefits Home; – But imposes costs by distorting production and consumption incentives within Home’s economy. TOT gains will outweigh the losses from distortion only as long as the tariff is not too large.Æ optimal tariffs for large country (makes no sense for small countries) – export subsidy never make sense (political economy): – Foreign’s TOT improve at Home’s expense, leaving it clearly better off. – Home loses from TOT deterioration and from the distorting effects of its policy. TOT effect: distribution of income WITHIN countries – Trade policies: strong effects on income distribution because of factor immobility and differences in the factor intensity of different industries. – Tariff direct effect: increase in the domestic relative price of the imported good; – Export subsidy direct effect: increase in the domestic relative price of the exported good. – Indirect effect on TOT: A tariff might improve a country’s TOT so much that even after the tariff rate is added, the domestic relative price of the import good falls. Similarly, an export subsidy might worsen the terms of trade so much that the domestic relative price of the export good falls 9