The Optimal Design of a Fiscal Union∗ Mikhail Dmitriev†and Jonathan Hoddenbagh‡ First Draft: December 2012 This Version: November 2015 We study cooperative and non-cooperative fiscal policy in a multi-country model where asset markets are segmented and countries face terms of trade externalities. We show that the optimal form of fiscal cooperation, or fiscal union, is defined by the Armington elasticity of substitution between goods from different countries. We prove that members of a fiscal union should: (1) harmonize tax rates when the Armington elasticity is low in order to ameliorate terms of trade externalities; and (2) send fiscal transfers across countries when the Armington elasticity is high in order to improve risk-sharing. For standard calibrations, the welfare gains from tax harmonization are as high as 0.3% of permanent consumption for countries both inside and outside of a currency union. The welfare gains from fiscal transfers are close to zero for countries outside of a currency union, but rise to between 0.5% (France) and 3.6% (Greece) of permanent consumption for countries inside a currency union. Keywords: Fiscal union; Currency union; Monetary union; Optimal fiscal policy. JEL Classification Numbers: E50, F41, F42. ∗ We thank Fabio Ghironi, Eyal Dvir, Peter Ireland and Susanto Basu for advice and encouragement at each stage of this project. We also thank Ryan Chahrour, Sanjay Chugh, Christophe Chamley, David Schumacher, Raúl Razo-Garcia, Laura Bottazzi, and Pedro Gete for helpful comments, as well as seminar participants at the Bank of Canada, the Bank for International Settlements, Boston College, the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Florida State University, Johns Hopkins SAIS, the Paris School of Economics, Simon Fraser, the University of Adelaide, the University of Hawaii, Villanova, the BC/BU Green Line Macro Meeting, the Canadian Economic Association, the Northern Finance Association and the Western Economic Association. Any errors are our own. † Florida State. Email: mdmitriev@fsu.edu. Web: http://www.mikhaildmitriev.org ‡ Johns Hopkins. Email: hoddenbagh@jhu.edu. Web: https://www2.bc.edu/jonathan-hoddenbagh/ 1 Introduction “Over the longer-term it would be natural to reflect further on whether we have done enough in the euro area to preserve at all times the ability to use fiscal policy counter-cyclically. But it is also clear that. . . this could only take place in the context of a decisive step towards closer Fiscal Union.” — Mario Draghi, President of the ECB, Nov. 27, 2014 “Cross-border risk-sharing through the financial system has slid backwards. Europe’s leaders do not currently foresee fiscal union as part of monetary union. Such timidity has costs.” — Mark Carney, Governor of the Bank of England, Jan. 28, 2015 Currency unions are typically federations comprised of a common central bank, a centralized fiscal authority and a subset of regional fiscal authorities. The euro area stands in stark contrast: a currency union with no centralized fiscal authority or fiscal union (Bordo et al (2011)). While the European Central Bank conducts monetary policy for the euro area as a whole, fiscal policy is largely carried out by self-interested national authorities. In addition, financial markets in the euro area play much less of an insurance role than in other federations, primarily due to lower cross-border ownership of assets. While federations like the U.S., Canada and Germany smooth over 80 percent of the impact of local shocks through a combination of fiscal transfers and financial market integration, the euro area only insures half that amount (IMF (2013)). The relative paucity of cross-border risk-sharing in the euro area combined with the selfinterested behavior of national fiscal authorities has prompted much debate about the need for a fiscal union between member states. Although the concept of a fiscal union has received a great deal of attention in policy circles, there is still considerable uncertainty about how to design such a union. The literature has typically studied this question in an environment of perfect cross-country risk-sharing, where full consumption insurance is provided by internationally complete asset markets or by terms of trade movements, and where national fiscal authorities are not self-interested but cooperative.1 However, the challenge facing the euro area is a direct consequence of these features missing from the literature: too little cross-country risk-sharing and too much self-interest on the part of national fiscal authorities. To address this gap in the literature and the policy realm, we study the optimal design of a fiscal union in an open economy model where cross-country risk-sharing is imperfect and fiscal authorities are self-interested. Self-interested national fiscal authorities use fiscal policy to tilt the terms of trade in their favor, giving rise to terms of trade externalities — a crucial component of the present crisis in the euro area that has yet to be addressed in the literature. 1 See for example Beetsma and Jensen (2005), Gali and Monacelli (2008), Ferrero (2009) and Farhi and Werning (2012). 2 We examine the interplay of nominal rigidities with imperfect risk-sharing and terms of trade externalities and find that the negative welfare impact of these distortions is highly sensitive to the elasticity of substitution between goods produced in different countries. As such, we find that the magnitude of this elasticity — the Armington elasticity — governs the optimal design of a fiscal union. When the Armington elasticity is equal to one, a common assumption in the literature following Cole and Obstfeld (1991), terms of trade movements provide complete international risk-sharing through offsetting income and substitution effects, even in financial autarky. Under this assumption, there is no need for a fiscal union to improve international risk-sharing. At the same time, when goods are imperfect substitutes countries are exposed to a relatively high degree of monopoly power at the export level. Self-interested domestic fiscal policymakers use this monopoly power to impose a large markup on their exports, giving rise to a large terms of trade externality. The optimal fiscal union forces domestic fiscal policymakers to internalize this externality and prevents countries from manipulating their terms of trade. We find that when the elasticity is close to one countries should cooperate in setting steady state domestic income tax rates to ameliorate large terms of trade externalities — what we call a tax union. As the Armington elasticity increases and domestic goods become more substitutable with foreign goods, the degree of international risk-sharing provided by terms of trade movements declines, as does each country’s monopoly power, thereby reducing the gains from a tax union. On the other hand, there is now an increasingly important role for a fiscal union to improve international risk-sharing. In a currency union with rigid wages, a one percent decline in productivity will raise marginal costs and prices by one percent, and the substitution from domestic goods to foreign goods will be exactly proportional to the Armington elasticity. For example, if the Armington elasticity is five a negative one percent productivity shock causes demand for the home good to drop by five percent. The welfare loss from a negative productivity shock thus increases in the Armington elasticity. This expenditure switching channel is severely dampened under a flexible exchange rate, where prices are stabilized by exchange rate depreciation resulting from expansionary monetary policy after a negative productivity shock, regardless of the value of the elasticity parameter. In a currency union where the common central bank is unable to offset asymmetric shocks, countries should organize a contingent cross-country transfer scheme to provide international risk-sharing — what we call a transfer union — to compensate for the decline in aggregate demand. We compute the welfare gains from a fiscal union for a wide range of elasticities, including country-specific estimates for European countries from Corbo and Osbat (2013) and Imbs and Méjean (2010).2 For standard calibrations, the welfare gains from a tax union are as high as 2 Using highly disaggregated data, Eaton and Kortum (2002) estimate the elasticity to be 9.28, Broda and Weinstein (2006) find an unweighted median of 3.1 and mean of 12.6, while Romalis finds a range of 4 to 13. Imbs and Méjean (2015) find a mean of 6.7 with a standard deviaion of 4.9, and a median of 5.1. Lai and 3 0.3% of permanent consumption for countries both inside of and outside of currency unions. The welfare gains from a transfer union are negligible for countries outside of a currency union (0.01% of permanent consumption), but rise to between 0.5% (France) and 3.6% (Greece) for countries inside a currency union with incomplete markets, and rise even higher when countries are cut off from international financial markets.3 The gains from a transfer union are significantly larger within a currency union because a single monetary policy cannot adequately offset the negative impact of asymmetric shocks across countries, leading to large gaps in risk sharing. In addition to studying optimal fiscal policy, we show that labor mobility can facilitate international risk-sharing and alleviate the negative impact of wage rigidity as workers move from depressed regions to boom regions. Although labor mobility is enshrined as one of the four pillars of the European Union, mobility remains quite low within the euro area (see Fig 2). Forming a fiscal union is thus far more important for the euro area than for other federal currency unions where labor mobility is relatively high and financial markets are more integrated, like the U.S. and Canada. These other federations are much better suited to withstand asymmetric shocks across regions than the euro area. Our closed-form model requires two simplifying assumptions: complete openness in consumption for all economies in the model as well as one period in advance nominal rigidities. We relax both of these assumptions in Section 7 and evaluate the welfare gains from a fiscal union in a model with consumption home bias and Calvo wage rigidities. As in the closed-form case, we solve the extended model under non-unitary elasticity so that financial market structure matters. In the extended model, we consider incomplete markets with cross-border trade in safe government bonds (incomplete risk-sharing) as well as financial autarky. In this setup, we find that home bias increases the welfare gains from a transfer union, while home bias decreases the welfare gains from a tax union. We also find that Calvo rigidities do not change our results, yielding similar welfare consequences as one period in advance rigidities. We focus on the closed-form model for the first half of the paper as it generates analytically tractable and intuitive results, and then shift to the extended model. Trefler (2002) estimate a range between 5 and 8. More recently, Simonovska and Waugh (2011) find a range between 3.38 and 5.42, while Feenstra, Obstfeld and Russ (2012) find a median estimate of the elasticity between foreign countries of 3.1 for the U.S. In a survey of the literature on elasticity estimates, Anderson and Van Wincoop (2004) conclude a range of five to ten is reasonable. Ruhl (2008) explains why the international macro and trade literatures have quite different estimates of the Armington elasticity. Corsetti, Dedola and Leduc (2008) estimate low values of the trade elasticity for the United States. Bussière et al (2013) show that trade elasticities can vary over the business cycle because of changes in the composition of demand. 3 These gains are larger than Lucas’ (2003) estimates of the welfare cost of business cycle fluctuations (0.05% of permanent consumption), which we replicate in a flexible wage environment. 4 How We Differ From The Literature We contribute to the existing literature in three important ways. First, we consider noncooperative equilibria between self-interested fiscal authorities in a currency union, capturing the current policy environment in the euro area. Second, we relax the assumption of perfect risksharing via complete markets or unitary elasticity. Third, we analyze the welfare implications of a tax union and of labor mobility. Our ability to tackle these issues is driven by our novel global closed-form solution that does not restrict the Armington elasticity to one. This provides a tractable framework to analyze optimal policy and enables us to accurately compare welfare across a variety of risk-sharing regimes, which is not possible under unitary elasticity. Early non-microfounded contributions on the conduct of optimal monetary and fiscal policy among interdependent economies include Canzoneri and Henderson (1990) and Eichengreen and Ghironi (2002). Another strand of the literature focuses on the division of seignorage within a currency union. Sims (1999) and Bottazzi and Manasse (2002) examine the interaction between monetary and fiscal policy when seignorage is distributed by a common central bank. We abstract from the role of seignorage and focus on the potential for fiscal policy cooperation to improve welfare. Bottazzi and Manasse (2005) also examine the role of information asymmetry on the conduct of monetary policy within a currency union. Benigno and De Paoli (2010) study the ability of a small open economy with a flexible exchange rate to exploit terms of trade externalities using fiscal policy. Beetsma and Jensen (2005), Gali and Monacelli (2008) and Ferrero (2009) focus primarily on the case of cooperative policy in a currency union with internationally complete asset markets. These papers show that monetary policy should stabilize inflation at the union level and that cooperative fiscal policy in the form of government spending has a country-specific stabilization role. Evers (2012) takes a more quantitative approach and estimates the welfare gains from a variety of “transfer rules”, in essence running a horse race between different types of fiscal regimes within a currency union. Farhi and Werning (2012) study cooperative fiscal policy in a transfer scheme under unitary elasticity, where full international risk sharing is provided via terms of trade movements. They demonstrate that even when private asset markets are complete internationally, there is a role for contingent cross-country transfers to provide consumption insurance because the government can internalize the aggregate demand externality which households and firms do not take into account. We differ from Farhi and Werning (2012) by focusing on non-unitary elasticity where private risk-sharing is incomplete, and by quantifying the welfare gains from a transfer union using elasticities calibrated from the data. The welfare gains from a transfer union under unitary elasticity are extremely small (0.01%) relative to the gains using elasticities calibrated from the data (1-3% under incomplete markets). 5 2 The Model in Closed-Form We consider a continuum of small open economies represented by the unit interval, as popularized in the literature by Gali and Monacelli (2005, 2008). Our model is based on Dmitriev and Hoddenbagh (2013), although here we consider wage rigidity rather than price rigidity and extend the closed-form solution for flexible exchange rates to the case of a currency union. Each economy consists of a representative household and a representative firm. All countries are identical ex-ante: they have the same preferences, technology, and wage-setting. Ex-post, economies will differ depending on the realization of their technology shock. Households are immobile across countries, however goods can move freely across borders. Each economy produces one final good, over which it exercises a degree of monopoly power. This is crucially important: countries are able to manipulate their terms of trade even though they are measure zero. As in Corsetti and Pesenti (2001, 2005) and Obstfeld and Rogoff (2000, 2002), we use one-period-in-advance wage setting to introduce nominal rigidities. Workers set next period’s nominal wages, in terms of domestic currency, prior to next-period’s production and consumption decisions. Given this preset wage, workers supply as much labor as demanded by firms. We lay out a general framework below, and then hone in on the specific case of complete markets and financial autarky. To avoid additional notation, we ignore time subindices unless absolutely necessary. When time subindices are absent, we are implicitly referring to period t. Production Each economy i produces a final good, which requires technology, Zi , and aggregated labor, Ni . We assume that technology is independent across time and across countries. We need not impose any particular distributional requirement on technology at this point. The production function of each economy will be: Yi = Zi Ni . (1) Households, indexed by h, each have monopoly power over their differentiated labor input, which will lead to a markup on wages. A perfectly competitive, representative final goods producer aggregates differentiated labor inputs from households in CES fashion into a final good for export. Production of the representative final goods firm in a specific country is: Z Ni = 1 Ni (h) ε−1 ε ε ε−1 dh , 0 where ε is the elasticity of substitution between different types of labor, and µε = ε ε−1 is the markup on labor. The aggregate labor cost index, W , defined as the minimum cost to produce one unit of out1 R 1−ε 1 1−ε put, will be a function of the nominal wage for household h, W (h): Wi = 0 Wi (h) dh . 6 Cost minimization by the firm leads to demand for labor from household h: Ni (h) = Wi (h) Wi −ε Ni . In the open economy, monopoly power is exercised at both the household and the country level: at the household level because of differentiated labor, and at the country level because each economy produces a unique good. We show in Section 3 that optimizing non-cooperative policymakers will remove the household markup on labor but will introduce a terms of trade markup through the income tax rate. Just to be clear, firms have no monopoly power and are perfectly competitive. Households In each economy, there is a household, h, with lifetime expected utility Et−1 (∞ X βk k=0 1−σ Cit+k (h) 1−σ 1+ϕ −χ Nit+k (h) 1+ϕ ) (2) where β < 1 is the household discount factor, C(h) is the consumption basket or index, N (h) is household labor effort (think of this as hours worked). Households face a general budget constraint that nests both complete markets and financial autarky; we will discuss the differences between the two in subsequent sections. For now, it is sufficient to simply write out the most general form of the budget constraint: Cit (h) = (1 − τi ) Wit (h) Pit (h) Nit (h) + Dit (h) + Tit (h) + Γit (h). (3) The distortionary tax rate on household labor income in country i is denoted by τi , while Γit is a domestic lump-sum tax rebate to households. T refers to lump-sum cross-country transfers. In the absence of a fiscal union, these cross-country transfers will equal zero (T = 0). Net taxes equal zero in the model, as any amount of government revenue is rebated lump-sum to households. The consumer price index corresponds to Pit , while the nominal wage is Wit . Dit denotes state-contingent portfolio payments expressed in real consumption units, and the following equation holds in all possible states in all periods: 1 Z Dit Pit = Eijt Bijt dj, 0 where Bijt is a state-contingent payment in currency j Eijt is the exchange rate in units of currency i per one unit of currency j; an increase in Eijt signals a depreciation of currency i relative to currency j. In a currency union, Eijt = 1 for all i, j, t. When international asset markets are complete, households perform all cross-border trades in contingent claims in period 7 0, insuring against all possible states in all future periods. The transverality condition simply states that all period 0 transactions must be balanced: payment for claims issued must equal payment for claims received. The transversality condition for complete markets is: E0 (∞ X ) β t Cit−σ Dit = 0, (4) t=0 while in financial autarky Dit = 0. Intuitively, the transversality condition stipulates that the present discounted value of future earnings should be equal to the present discounted value of future consumption flows. Under complete markets, consumers choose a state contingent plan for consumption, labor supply and portfolio holdings in period 0. Consumption and Price Indices Households in each country consume a basket of imported goods. This consumption basket is an aggregate of all of the varieties produced by different countries. The consumption basket for a representative small open economy i, which is common across countries, is defined as follows: Z 1 γ−1 γ γ γ−1 cij dj Ci = (5) 0 where lower case cij is the consumption by country i of the final good produced by country j, and γ is the elasticity of substitution between domestic and foreign goods (the Armington elasticity). Because there is no home bias in consumption, countries will export all of the output of their unique variety, and import varieties from other countries to assemble the consumption basket. Prices are defined as follows: lower case pij denotes the price in country i (in currency i) of the unique final good produced in country j, while upper case Pi is the aggregate consumer price index in country i. Given the above consumption index, the consumer price index will be 1 R 1−γ 1 Pi = 0 p1−γ dj . Demand by country i for the unique variety produced by country j is: ij cij = pij Pi −γ Ci . (6) We assume that producer currency pricing (PCP) holds, and that the law of one price (LOP) holds, so that the price of the same good is equal across countries when converted into a common currency. We define the nominal bilateral exchange rate between countries i and j, Eij , as units of currency i per one unit of currency j. LOP requires that pij = Eij pjj . Given LOP and identical preferences across countries, PPP also holds for all i, j country pairs: Pi = Eij Pj . The terms of trade for country j, defined as the home currency price of exports over the home currency price of imports, is denoted T OTj = pjj /Pj . 8 Take country i’s demand for country j’s unique variety (6), and using LOP and PPP, solve for world demand for country j’s unique variety: Z 1 Z 1 cij di = Yj = 0 0 pij Pi −γ Ci di LOP+PPP = pjj Pj −γ Z 1 Ci di = T OTj−γ Cw . (7) 0 where Cw is defined as the average world consumption across all i economies, Cw = R1 0 Ci di. Using goods market clearing and the fact that technology Zit is identically and independently distributed across time and consumption baskets are identical across countries, we can rewrite average world consumption as: 1 Z Cwt = γ−1 γ γ γ−1 Yit . (8) 0 Labor Market Clearing Households maximize (2) subject to (3). The first order condition for labor gives the labor supply condition (which is the optimal preset wage): Wit = χµε 1 − τi Et−1 Nit1+ϕ n −σ o . C N Et−1 itPit it The representative firm in country i maximizes profit by choosing the appropriate amount of aggregate labor, leading to the familiar labor demand condition equating the real wage at time t (Wit /pit ) with the marginal product of labor (Zit ). To obtain the labor market clearing condition, set labor demand equal to labor supply, and use the fact that the wage is preset at time t − 1 and that demand for unique variety is (7):4 1= χµε 1−τ Et−1 Nit1+ϕ . γ−1 1 γ γ −σ Et−1 Cit Yit Cwt (9) Taking the expectations operator out of (9) yields the flexible wage equilibrium. Complete Markets In complete markets, agents in each economy have access to a full set of domestic and foreign state-contingent assets. Households in all countries will maximize (2), choosing consumption, leisure, money holdings, and a complete set of state-contingent nominal bonds, subject to (3). 4 A more general labor market clearing condition, which holds for both producer currency pricing and local currency pricing is: n o 1+ϕ E N t−1 it χµε n o. 1= pit −σ 1−τ E t−1 Cit Yit Pit 9 Complete markets and PPP imply the following risk-sharing condition: −σ Cjt Cit−σ = −σ −σ Cit+1 Cjt+1 ∀i, j (10) which states that the ratio of the marginal utility of consumption at time t and t + 1 must be equal across all countries. Importantly, this condition does not imply that consumption is equal across countries. Consumption in country i will depend on the initial asset position, fiscal and monetary policy, the distribution of country-specific shocks, the covariance of global and local shocks, and other factors.5 When (4), (9), and (10) hold, consumption in country i can be expressed as a function of world consumption: Cit = Et−1 −σ β s Yit+s Cwt+s T OTit+s P Cwt . 1−σ Et−1 β s Cwt+s P (11) This defines the optimal consumption allocation for country i in complete markets.6 Using the fact that Zit is independent across time and across countries, and wages are preset, (11) is equivalent to γ−1 Cit = Cw Et−1 Yit γ . 1 γ (12) Financial Autarky The aggregate resource constraint under financial autarky specifies that the nominal value of output in the home country (exports) must equal the nominal of consumption in the home country (imports). That is, trade in goods must be balanced. In a model with cross-border lending, bonds would also show up in this condition, but in financial autarky they are obviously absent. The primary departure from complete markets lies in the household and economy-wide budget constraint (i.e. the trade balance), where spending on imports must equal export revenues: Pi Ci = pii Yi . Substituting world demand for the unique variety (7) into the trade balance condition, one can show that demand for country i’s good in financial autarky will be: 1 γ−1 Cit = Cwγ Yit γ . (13) Thus, in complete markets consumption is equal to expected domestic output expressed in consumption baskets; in autarky consumption is equal to realized domestic output expressed 5 A policy change in economy i may lead to a change in consumption. For example, monetary policy affects the covariance between home production and world consumption, which in turn influences home consumption, even in complete markets. Fiscal policy can tax consumption and cause a lower level of consumption in the long-run relative to the rest of the world. In spite of this, it is still possible to characterize an optimal consumption plan that is robust to changes in monetary and fiscal policy. 6 Details are found in the appendix of Dmitriev and Hoddenbagh (2013). 10 in consumption baskets. 3 Non-Cooperative Policy In order to study the benefits of international policy cooperation, we must first understand the non-cooperative Nash equilibrium. What outcomes naturally arise when policymakers do not cooperate? Our goal in this section is to illuminate the various distortions that are present in the non-cooperative Nash equilibrium, and to compare and contrast with the global social planner equilibrium defined in Appendix A. We can then pinpoint specific areas of policy cooperation that ameliorate welfare decreasing distortions, leading us to the optimal design of a fiscal union. We begin with the Nash equilibrium under flexible exchange rates and then move to the case of a currency union. Flexible Exchange Rates When exchange rates are flexible, each country has its own central bank and its own fiscal authority. Before any shocks are realized, national fiscal authorities declare non state-contingent taxes, and then national central banks declare monetary policy for all states of the world. With this knowledge in hand, households lay out a state-contingent plan for consumption and labor as well asset holdings when markets are complete. After that, shocks hit the economy. A detailed timeline is provided in Figure 1. Without loss of generality, we assume a cashless limiting economy.7 Central banks set monetary policy in each period by optimally choosing the amount of labor. Although central banks optimize by choosing labor instead of money or an interest rate, the three are equivalent in this model.8 We can write down an interest rate rule that gives the exact same allocation. Domestic fiscal authorities choose the optimal labor tax rate τi . The objective function for non-cooperative domestic policymakers will be max max Et−1 Nit τi Cit1−σ Nit1+ϕ −χ 1−σ 1+ϕ , (14) where the fiscal authority acts first and chooses τi and the central bank then chooses Nit . We first examine the Nash equilibrium for non-cooperative policymakers when international asset markets are complete. Policymakers in complete markets will maximize their objective function subject to production (1), aggregate world consumption (8) and labor market clearing (9) and goods market clearing (12) constraints. Proposition 1 Flexible Exchange Rates + Complete Markets When international asset markets are complete and exchange rates are flexible, non-cooperative policymakers will 7 8 Benigno and Benigno (2003) describe a cashless-limiting economy in detail in their appendix, pp.756-758. We demonstrate the equivalence in Appendix F of Dmitriev and Hoddenbagh (2013). 11 maximize (14) subject to (1), (8), (9), and (12). The solution under commitment for noncooperative policymakers in complete markets is: Ci = Ni = 1 χµγ 1 χµγ 1 σ+ϕ Z 1 (γ−1)(1+ϕ) 1+γϕ Zi 1+γϕ (γ−1)(σ+ϕ) di , (15a) 0 1 σ+ϕ Z 1 (γ−1)(1+ϕ) 1+γϕ Zi 1−γσ (γ−1)(σ+ϕ) di γ−1 Zi1+γϕ . (15b) 0 It is optimal for non-cooperative central banks under commitment to mimic the flexible wage allocation. The optimal tax rate for non-cooperative fiscal authorities is τi = 1 − µε . µγ Proof See Appendix B. The above allocation replicates the global social planner allocation with the addition of a terms of trade markup, µγ = γ , γ−1 that lowers consumption and output. It is optimal for central banks to mimic the flexible wage allocation through a policy of price stability.9 Optimizing fiscal authorities internalize the negative welfare impact of the domestic markup on differentiated labor inputs (µε ), and thus choose an income tax rate that cancels out the labor markup. However, fiscal authorities also want to use their country-level monopoly power. Because each country in the continuum is measure zero, policymakers do not internalize the impact of charging a higher markup for their export good on the welfare of other countries. This leads fiscal authorities to set an income tax rate which reduces hours worked and restricts production, τi = 1− µµγε , so that exports from each country are subject to a terms of trade markup (µγ ). The terms of trade externality leads to lower welfare outcomes because households in each country must pay a higher price on each import good in the consumption basket. Even though asset markets are complete, the non-cooperative allocation under flexible exchange rates yields lower welfare than the global social planner allocation due to the imposition of the terms of trade markup. The need for some sort of international fiscal cooperation that would force domestic fiscal authorities to internalize this externality is clear. Now that we’ve examined the complete markets equilibrium when exchange rates are flexible, we turn our attention to the case of financial autarky. The objective function in financial autarky will be identical to the complete markets case. Domestic fiscal authorities will first choose the optimal tax rate, and then central banks will set the optimal monetary policy by choosing labor. However, there is a slight difference in the constraints faced by policymakers in complete markets and financial autarky. In complete markets, home consumption is a function of expected output (12), while in autarky home consumption is a function of actual output (13). All other constraints are identical in complete markets and financial autarky. 9 In a related paper (Dmitriev and Hoddenbagh 2013), we prove that mimicking the flexible price allocation is a dominant strategy for small open economy central banks. This result is robust to changes in elasticity between domestic and foreign goods, the degree of cooperation between policymakers in different countries, and the degree of financial integration across countries. 12 Proposition 2 Flexible Exchange Rates + Financial Autarky Non-cooperative policymakers in financial autarky will maximize (14) subject to (1), (8), (9), and (13). The solution under commitment for non-cooperative policymakers in financial autarky is: Ci = Ni = 1 χµγ 1 χµγ 1 σ+ϕ Z 1 (γ−1)(1+ϕ) 1−σ+γ(σ+ϕ) Zi (1+ϕ) (γ−1)(σ+ϕ) (γ−1)(1+ϕ) 1−σ+γ(σ+ϕ) Zi di , (16a) Zi1−σ+γ(ϕ+σ) . (16b) 0 1 σ+ϕ Z 1 (γ−1)(1+ϕ) 1−σ+γ(σ+ϕ) Zi (1−σ) (γ−1)(σ+ϕ) di (γ−1)(1−σ) 0 It is optimal for non-cooperative central banks to mimic the flexible wage allocation. The optimal tax rate for non-cooperative fiscal authorities is τi = 1 − µε . µγ Proof See Appendix B. As in complete markets, central banks find it optimal to mimic the flexible wage equilibrium through a policy of price stability in financial autarky. On the fiscal side, policymakers again eliminate the domestic markup µε , but impose a terms of trade markup on their unique export good µγ via the steady state income tax rate. Financial autarky removes cross-country consumption insurance, as households no longer have the ability to trade in international contingent claims. This can be seen most clearly in (16a), where equilibrium consumption is a function of idiosyncratic productivity, Zi , and will fluctuate with country-specific shocks to technology. Currency Union Within a currency union, a single central bank sets monetary policy for the union as a whole. Countries no longer control their domestic monetary policy as they do when exchange rates are flexible. In the presence of aggregate shocks, the union-wide central bank will stabilize inflation at the union level, a result shown in Gali and Monacelli (2008). However, for tractability we assume no aggregate shocks, only asymmetric country-specific shocks. With only one policy instrument, the union-wide central bank cannot eliminate wage rigidity at the country level in the presence of asymmetric shocks. As a result, the union-wide central bank does nothing in our model. None of our results change if we add aggregate shocks: these shocks would simply be counteracted by the union-wide central bank. In a currency union each country retains control over it’s own fiscal policy. The objective function for non-cooperative fiscal policymakers in a currency union is: max Et−1 τi Cit1−σ N 1+ϕ − χ it 1−σ 1+ϕ (17) The constraints faced by policymakers within a currency union are identical to those faced by policymakers under flexible exchange rates, with the addition of a fifth constraint unique to 13 currency unions. Thus, relative to the optimization problem under flexible exchange rates, we add one constraint and subtract one FOC. Plugging our expression for the real wage (pii = Wi ) Zi into the demand for country i’s good (7) yields: Wit Pit Yit = −γ {z | A Cw Zitγ = AZitγ } (18) where A is a constant. (18) is the additional constraint faced by the policymaker in a currency union. Proposition 3 Currency Union + Complete Markets Non-cooperative policymakers in a currency union will maximize (17) subject to (1), (8), (9), (12), and (18). The solution under commitment for non-cooperative policymakers within a currency union in complete markets is: Ci = Cw = Ni = 1 χµγ 1 χµγ 1 σ+ϕ 1 σ+ϕ 1 σ+ϕ γ(1+ϕ) γ−1 R , 1 (γ−1)(1+ϕ) di Z i 0 R1 Ziγ−1 di 0 1 σ+ϕ γ(1−σ) γ−1 R Ziγ−1 . 1 (γ−1)(1+ϕ) di Zi 0 (19a) R1 Ziγ−1 di 0 (19b) The resulting equilibrium allocation does not replicate the flexible wage equilibrium. The optimal tax rate for non-cooperative fiscal authorities is τi = 1 − µε . µγ Proof See Appendix C. Within a currency union, the inability of the union-wide central bank to alleviate asymmetric shocks across countries leads to the presence of wage rigidity in the optimal allocation. In addition, non-cooperative fiscal authorities exploit their country-level monopoly power and impose a terms of trade markup via income tax policy. We thus see the presence of two distortions in the equilibrium allocation: wage rigidity and a terms of trade markup. As in the flexible exchange rate allocation, there is no idiosyncratic technology risk in consumption under complete markets, so consumption will be equalized across countries in equilibrium. However, welfare will be lower when wages are rigid than when they are flexible, as one can notice by comparing the above allocation with the Pareto efficient allocation (see Section 6 for details). Proposition 4 Currency Union + Financial Autarky In financial autarky, non-cooperative policymakers in a currency union will maximize (17) subject to (1), (8), (9), (13) and (18). 14 The optimal allocation in financial autarky given by a non-contingent policymaker in a currency union is: Ci = Ni = 1 χµγ 1 χµγ 1 σ+ϕ R 1 σ+ϕ 1 0 R 1 0 Ziγ−1 di R1 (γ−1)(1+ϕ) Zi di 0 R (γ−1)(1−σ) Zi di 1 0 (γ−1)(1−σ) Zi di R 1 0 Ziγ−1 di R1 (γ−1)(1+ϕ) Zi di 0 1 σ+ϕ 1+ϕ γ−1 Ziγ−1 , (20a) Ziγ−1 . (20b) 1 σ+ϕ 1−σ γ−1 The resulting equilibrium allocation does not replicate the flexible wage allocation. The optimal tax rate for non-cooperative fiscal authorities is τi = 1 − µε . µγ Proof See Appendix C. In the autarky Nash equilibrium described in Proposition 4, members of a currency union face three welfare decreasing distortions: wage rigidity resulting from the absence of country-specific monetary policy; idiosyncratic consumption risk, caused by lack of access to international financial markets; and a terms of trade markup, imposed by non-cooperative fiscal authorities in other countries. The potential for cooperative measures to ameliorate these distortions is evident, and will be the focus of Section 4. Contingent Tax Policy We also consider the role of contingent tax policy in Appendix D. We show that contingent tax policy within a currency union can play the same role as monetary policy outside of a currency union, eliminating nominal rigidities and mimicking the flexible-wage allocation. While the ability of contingent taxes to eliminate nominal rigidities has been shown in other closed and open economy studies, we are the first to show that the distortionary impact of wage rigidity and hence the importance of contingent tax adjustments is increasing in the Armington elasticity.10 Our analysis is also the first to demonstrate that international policy cooperation is not necessary to eliminate the distortionary impact of wage rigidity: non-cooperative contingent fiscal policy is all that is required. Empirical evidence from Vegh and Vuletin (2015) shows that tax policy in industrial countries is acyclical. In line with this evidence, we assume that tax policy is non-contingent for the remainder of the paper. 10 Two related papers, Adao, Correia and Teles (2009) and Farhi, Gopinath and Itskhoki (2011), show that a set of state-contingent taxes can mimic the flexible price equilibrium. A non-exhaustive list of other papers demonstrating the importance of contingent fiscal policy includes Chugh (2006), Chugh and Ghironi (2015), Correia et al (2013), Kersting (2013), Lewis and Cardoso-Costa (2015), Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2004) and Siu (2004). 15 4 Cooperative Policy in a Fiscal Union In this section we analyze fiscal policy cooperation. Although the concept of fiscal cooperation may be quite broad, we focus here on two specific types — a tax union and a transfer union. In a tax union, fiscal policymakers in each country cooperatively set steady state income tax rates to maximize the welfare of the union as a whole. A tax union may be viewed as a cross-country agreement on income tax setting between domestic fiscal authorities, or as a set of tax rates chosen by a supranational (or federal) fiscal authority. In a transfer union, fiscal policymakers in each country arrange contingent cross-country transfers to maximize the welfare of the union as a whole. The transfer scheme may derive from an agreement between national fiscal authorities or from a supranational (or federal) fiscal authority. Four different types of fiscal policy cooperation are possible: a combined tax and transfer union; a tax union with no transfer union; a transfer union with no tax union; and no tax nor transfer union.11 The objective functions for the various types of fiscal union are written below. Cit1−σ Nit1+ϕ max max Et−1 −χ di Nit ∀τi 1−σ 1+ϕ 0 1−σ Z 1 Nit1+ϕ Cit max −χ Et−1 di ∀τi 1−σ 1+ϕ 0 Z 1 (21a) (21b) Objective functions (21a) and (21b) refer to a tax union outside of and within a currency union, respectively. Here, the fiscal authorities in each country jointly maximize the welfare of all countries in the union by choosing the same steady state income tax rate. 1−σ Nit1+ϕ Cit −χ di max max max Et−1 τi Nit ∀Tit 1−σ 1+ϕ 0 1−σ Z 1 Cit Nit1+ϕ max max Et−1 −χ di τi ∀Tit 1−σ 1+ϕ 0 Z 1 (21c) (21d) Objective functions (21c) and (21d) refer to a transfer union outside of and within a currency union, respectively. Here, a supranational (or federal) fiscal body optimally chooses crosscountry transfers in order to maximize union-wide welfare. Nit1+ϕ Cit1−σ −χ di max max Et−1 Nit ∀τi ,Tit 0 1−σ 1+ϕ 1−σ Z 1 Cit Nit1+ϕ max Et−1 −χ di ∀τi ,Tit 0 1−σ 1+ϕ Z 11 1 (21e) (21f) Because our focus is on the optimal design of a fiscal union, we ignore the implications of monetary policy cooperation. With one common central bank, monetary cooperation within a currency union is not possible. In another paper (Dmitriev and Hoddenbagh (2013)), we show that in a continuum of small open economies monetary cooperation yields no welfare gains, as non-cooperative and cooperative equilibria exactly coincide. 16 Finally, (21e) and (21f) refer to a tax and transfer union outside of and within a currency union, respectively. Here, countries not only agree on income tax rates, but also agree to send contingent cash transfers across countries. Proposition 5 Tax Unions Policymakers in a tax union will internalize the impact of their income tax rate on all union members. As a result, a tax union will remove the incentive for policymakers to manipulate their terms of trade. The optimal tax rate in a tax union is τi = 1 − µε , which will remove the markup on domestic production in each country, µε , while preventing the imposition of a terms of trade markup on exports, µγ , from all equilibrium allocations. Proof See Appendix E. A tax union forces domestic fiscal authorities to internalize the impact of their terms of trade externality on union wide welfare. As a result, policymakers will not impose a terms of trade markup on the export of their country’s unique good in a tax union. This improves welfare for the entire union as well as for each individual country, particularly for low values of elasticity when countries have a high degree of monopoly power. The distortive impact of the terms of trade externality increases as the degree of substitutability decreases, which will become clear in Section 6 when we calculate the welfare gains from a tax union. In other words, the benefits of a tax union are increasing in the degree of country-level monopoly power. Members of a transfer union agree to send contingent cash transfers across countries in order to insure against idiosyncratic consumption risk. In complete markets the presence of crosscountry transfers will alter the goods market clearing constraint, so that (12) is replaced by the following two conditions: γ−1 Cit = Cwt Et−1 Yit γ + Tit , 1 γ (22) In financial autarky the presence of cross-country transfers will alter the goods market clearing constraint, so that (13) is replaced by the following two conditions: γ−1 1 γ Cit = Cwt Yit γ + Tit . (23) Note that the sum of all cross-country transfers must add up to zero in both complete markets R1 and in financial autarky: 0 Tit di = 0. Proposition 6 Transfer Unions Policymakers in a transfer union agree to send contingent cash transfers across countries in order to insure against idiosyncratic consumption risk. The equilibrium allocation within a transfer union will be identical with the equilibrium allocation under complete markets. As a result, transfer unions are redundant when international asset 17 markets are complete or when substitutability is one, but yield large welfare gains when markets are incomplete. Proof See Appendix F. As Proposition 6 states, a transfer union guarantees complete cross-country consumption insurance and thus replicates the effect of complete markets.12 The welfare benefits of a transfer union are increasing in the Armington elasticity: as goods become closer substitutes, the natural risk-sharing role played by the terms of trade begins to disappear. This will be seen more clearly in Section 6 when we calculate the welfare gains from a transfer union. It is also possible to have a tax and a transfer union. If countries agree to both, they will enjoy complete risk-sharing and eliminate the distortive impact of the terms of trade externality. Proposition 5 and 6 show that a tax union, a transfer union or a combination of the two will move countries toward the Pareto efficient allocation. Proposition 7 Pareto Optimum The Pareto efficient allocation is achieved through a combination of: (1) independent monetary policy outside of a currency union or contingent fiscal policy within a currency union; (2) internationally complete asset markets or a transfer union; and (3) a tax union. Proof (1) eliminates the distortionary impact of wage rigidity, (2) provides cross-country risk-sharing, and (3) prevents terms of trade manipulation. Any combination of (1), (2) and (3), for example a tax and transfer union whose members control their own monetary policy outside of a currency union, will yield the Pareto efficient allocation. Although each of these ingredients is necessary to achieve the Pareto efficient allocation, the relative importance of these ingredients is highly sensitive to the elasticity of substitution between products from different countries. In Section 6, we show that the optimal design of a fiscal union, and the emphasis given to a tax versus a transfer union, will depend on the value of the elasticity parameter. 5 Labor Mobility If deeper fiscal integration is not possible, what should governments do? One possibility, heralding back to James Meade (1957), is to pursue policies that increase labor mobility. Discussing the creation of a common currency area in Western Europe, Meade argued that without the free movement of goods, capital and labor, the idea was doomed to failure. We demonstrate the benefits of labor mobility in a rigorous microfounded setup using using our analytical closed-form model. 12 When we introduce home bias in consumption to the model in Section 7, we see that a transfer union actually improves upon the complete markets allocation. This matches the results of Farhi and Werning (2013), who show that generically private risk sharing is inefficient in the presence of consumption home bias because of an aggregate demand externality. 18 We assume perfect labor mobility, such that workers within a household can reallocate immediately without any costs after learning the realization of technology shocks. Workers send transfers to their family members. Disutility from labor results from the total number of hours worked in the household. Wages are set one period in advance by firms, and firms have rational expectations about worker’s reallocation. Nominal wages will equalize across countries in the currency union since consumption baskets are identical across countries. However, producer price indices (PPI) will be higher in the countries with smaller production and productivity. As a result, the real wage defined using the consumer price index (CPI) will be identical across the currency union, while real wages defined using the PPI will differ across countries. When labor is mobile, non-cooperative policymakers in a currency union in financial autarky maximize the familiar objective function, but face a new set of constraints (found in Appendix G). As each economy in the currency union is hit with idiosyncratic shocks, labor will move from low demand recession countries to high demand boom countries. The movement of workers across borders equalizes real wages across countries and thereby acts as a natural shock absorber, enabling efficient adjustment of the economy without any policy actions taken by monetary or fiscal authorities. Proposition 8 Labor Mobility Labor mobility will eliminate two distortions: wage rigidity and the lack of risk-sharing in financial autarky. The resulting equilibrium allocations yield higher welfare than the flexible wage allocations in complete markets and financial autarky. When labor can move freely across borders, the solution under commitment for non-cooperative policymakers outside of or within a currency union, in complete markets or financial autarky, is: Ci = Ni = 1 χµγ 1 χµγ 1 σ+ϕ Z 1 Ziγ−1 di 1+ϕ (σ+ϕ)(γ−1) (24a) 0 1 σ+ϕ Z 1 Ziγ−1 di 1+ϕ−γ(σ+ϕ) (γ−1)(σ+ϕ) Ziγ−1 . (24b) 0 The optimal tax rate for non-cooperative fiscal authorities is τi = 1 − µε . µγ Proof See Appendix G. Labor mobility achieves three goals from a policy perspective. First, households whose members can move across countries without any restrictions diversify their source of income, which provides cross-country risk-sharing even in the absence of internationally complete asset markets. Second, shifting labor hours across countries generates labor risk-sharing, so that hours worked do not fluctuate with country-specific shocks. Third, the stabilizing influence of labor mobility on both consumption and labor eliminates the distortionary impact of wage rigidity. So the fixed wage allocation under labor mobility will mimic the flexible wage allocation. Al- 19 though the distortive effect of the terms of trade externality remains so there is still a need for a tax union, the benefits of labor mobility are potentially massive and ease the burden on fiscal policy greatly. We quantify these gains in Sections 6 and 7. Legally, labor mobility is enshrined as one of the four pillars of economic integration within the European Union. EU citizens are free to migrate to any other EU country to seek employment (Kahanec 2012, Zimmermann 2005). Workers are also free to move across state borders in the U.S., as well as provincial borders in Canada and state borders in Australia. Despite similar legal guarantees for labor mobility, the data show that labor mobility is much higher within the U.S., Canada and Australia than within the EU. Figure 2 plots the extent of labor mobility across countries in the EU as well as across U.S. states, Canadian provinces, and Australian states and territories. Over and above regulatory and legal barriers to mobility, language seems to rule: linguistic and cultural differences across countries make emigration much more difficult. For example, notice the high degree of labor mobility within unilingual currency unions (Australia and the U.S.), the slightly lower degree of labor mobility in a bilingual currency union (Canada), and the much lower degree of labor mobility in a multilingual currency union (euro area). One can see the importance of language most clearly by focusing on the much higher degree of mobility within EU countries (0.95%) where languages are uniform than across EU countries (0.29%) where they differ, as well as the the high mobility across Canada as a whole (0.98%) versus the low degree of mobility between French-speaking Quebec and the English-speaking provinces (0.39%). These data reinforce the notion that labor mobility is vital to the sound functioning of a currency union. High mobility in the US, Australia and Canada dampens the distortionary impact of internal wage rigidity, lowers unemployment and improves risk-sharing. On the other hand, low mobility in the EU leads to high unemployment and overvalued wages in areas that are hit by large negative shocks. But the main takeaway is surely this: achieving a fiscal union within the euro area may prove politically difficult, but the lack of labor mobility within the euro area suggests an even stronger need for a fiscal union. 6 Welfare Analysis in the Closed-Form Model We now analyze the welfare gains resulting from the introduction of a tax union, a transfer union as well as labor mobility. The advantage of the closed-form solution is most apparent here: rather than approximating a quadratic welfare function around a particular steady state, we can calculate welfare explicitly at any steady state, whether distorted or otherwise. This is particularly important when we focus on the welfare gains from a tax union, which eliminates the terms of trade markup from the steady state allocation. In a log-linear model, comparing welfare between the tax union and no tax union cases is infeasible because of the different steady states. 20 Our calibration for the closed-form model at quarterly frequency follows standard benchmarks from the literature and is reported in Table 1. In our welfare analysis, we allow the Armington elasticity to vary while fixing the other parameters of the model. Expected Utilities Below we calculate the log of expected utility for five allocations: flexible exchange rates with complete risk-sharing (25a); flexible exchange rates in financial autarky (25c); currency union in complete markets (25b); currency union in financial autarky (25d); and labor mobility (25e).13 We ignore the constant terms and focus only on the exponents of Z. Details on how we compute welfare analytically for each allocation are found in Appendix H. We assume technology is lognormally distributed in all countries, log(Zi ) ∼ N (0, σZ2 ), and is independent across time and across countries. log E {Uflex complete } = log E {Ufixed complete } = log E {Uflex autarky } = log E {Ufixed autarky } = log E {Ulabor mobility } = (γ − 1)(1 − σ)(1 + ϕ)2 2 σZ (1 + γϕ)(σ + ϕ) (γ − 1)(1 − σ)(1 + ϕ)(1 + ϕ − γϕ) 2 σZ (σ + ϕ) (γ − 1)(1 − σ)(1 + ϕ)2 [1 + ϕ + (γ − 1)(1 − σ)(σ + ϕ)] 2 σZ (σ + ϕ)[1 − σ + γ(σ + ϕ)]2 (γ − 1)(1 − σ)(1 + ϕ) [1 − (γ − 1)(σ + ϕ)] 2 σZ σ+ϕ (γ − 1)(1 + ϕ) 2 σZ σ+ϕ (25a) (25b) (25c) (25d) (25e) Using these expected utilities, it is straightforward to show that: (1) improved risk-sharing always has positive welfare consequences, (2) flexible exchange rates always have positive welfare consequences, and (3) the gains from improved risk-sharing are always higher within a currency union than outside of one.14 We also see that under unitary elasticity the expected utility for all policy coalitions is identical. Recall that unitary elasticity leads to complete risksharing and eliminates wage rigidity via movements in the terms of trade. This explains in part why the literature has found very small gains from international policy cooperation: the common assumption of unitary elasticity precludes gains from cooperation because terms of trade movements provide cross-country risk-sharing and negate the influence of nominal rigidities.15 13 Allocations that eliminate wage rigidity (via flexible exchange rates or contingent fiscal policy) are denoted by f lex, while those that do not are denoted by f ixed (i.e. currency unions). We assume that there is no contingent fiscal policy in the currency union allocations, so that wages are rigid. Similarly, allocations with complete international risk-sharing (via complete markets or a transfer union) are denoted by complete, while autarky allocations with no risk-sharing are denoted by autarky. 14 See Appendix H equations (H.2a) – (H.2d) for calculation of explicit welfare differences. 15 Papers which employ unitary elasticity include Corsetti and Pesenti (2001, 2005), Obstfeld and Rogoff (2000, 2002), and Farhi and Werning (2012). 21 Tax Union First, we compare the welfare of a country in a tax union with the welfare of a country outside of a tax union, assuming the two countries are identical in all other respects.16 The log difference in expected utility between a country inside a tax union and a country outside of a tax union is: log E {Utax union } − log E {Uno tax union } = 1−σ σ+ϕ log µγ = 1−σ σ+ϕ log γ γ−1 . (26) Equation (26) shows that the welfare gains from a tax union are decreasing in the elasticity γ, the degree of substitutability between products across countries. As goods become closer substitutes, country level monopoly power falls and the distortionary impact of the terms of trade externality decreases due to the declining markup on exports. In the limit, as γ → ∞ and goods become perfect substitutes, the terms of trade markup will go to zero, and a tax union will be unnecessary. On the other hand, as the Armington elasticity decreases, countries gain a higher degree of monopoly power over their export good and thus increase their terms of trade markup µγ . In the limit, as γ → 1, the terms of trade markup approaches infinity and the benefits of a tax union dwarf the gains from other policy measures. Figure 3 illustrates the importance of a tax union for low values of the Armington elasticity and plots the loss in consumption from the terms of trade distortion relative to the Armington elasticity. The figure makes it clear that as γ → 1, a tax union becomes imperative. In the absence of a tax union, optimizing non-cooperative fiscal authorities charge extremely large markups on their export good, leading to a dismal equilibrium for all countries. Noncooperative fiscal policy inflicts extremely large welfare losses on other countries under low Armington elasticity. It is important reemphasize that the benefits of a tax union are steady state benefits because the terms of trade markup is itself a steady state markup. Business cycle fluctuations and shocks have no bearing on the welfare gains from a tax union. As the gains from a tax union are a steady state phenomenon they cannot be analyzed in a log-linear model. Transfer Union, Flexible Wages and Labor Mobility We now turn to the welfare gains achieved through improved risk-sharing (via a transfer union or deeper financial integration), the elimination of wage rigidity (via optimal monetary policy outside of a currency union or contingent fiscal policy within a currency union) and labor mobility. In what follows, we assume the presence of a tax union, which removes the constant terms of trade markup. Figure 4 plots the consumption in each allocation as a percentage of the Pareto optimum. The negative impact of the wage rigidity distortion dominates the negative impact of financial 16 They differ only in the fact that one country faces a terms of trade markup in it’s steady state allocation (the country outside of a tax union) and the other does not (the country within a tax union). 22 autarky, as both fixed wage allocations perform quite poorly relative to the flexible wage allocations, particularly as the degree of substitutability increases. The relative similarity of all flexible wage allocations (Flex Complete, Flex Autarky, and Labor Mobility) is quite striking. Even in financial autarky, flexible wages enable households to stabilize consumption with small movements in their labor hours. The benefit of consumption risk-sharing is thus very small when wages are flexible. The gains from flexible wages approach 2% of permanent consumption under complete risk-sharing and 4% of permanent consumption under financial autarky for γ = 10. On the other hand, the welfare gains from perfect risk-sharing via a transfer union or complete markets equal 2% of permanent consumption within a currency union when γ = 10. Are countries better off in a currency union? One of the arguments in support of a currency union, advanced by Mundell (1961, 1973) among others, is that the formation of such a union leads to deeper financial integration and improves cross-country risk-sharing. Using this logic, we conduct a thought experiment on the potential benefits of a currency union. We compare the welfare of a country outside a currency union in financial autarky with a member of a currency union in complete markets. Is a country better off with a flexible exchange rate and no risk-sharing, or in a currency union with perfect risk-sharing?17 For plausible calibrations, welfare is higher in the former. When households are completely risk neutral (σ = 0), they always prefer to be outside of a currency union in financial autarky. As households become more risk averse, they may prefer a country that is a member of a currency union with full risk-sharing. But even in the limit, as σ → ∞, households prefer a currency union only if γ ∈ 1, 1+2ϕ . For standard calibrations of ϕ ϕ, this means households will prefer a currency union when γ is between 1 and 2. So there is a very small range of γ for which extremely risk averse households are better off in a currency union in complete markets than outside of one in financial autarky. Even under extreme risk aversion, deeper financial integration is not worth the loss of independent monetary policy. Why is welfare higher under flexible exchange rates and financial autarky? Assume country i is a member of a currency union and is hit with a negative productivity shock. Wage rigidity will force its producers to charge a higher price to stay afloat. With a flexible exchange rate, the higher domestic price would be offset by a depreciated currency, but in a currency union this effect is absent. Given the higher price, consumers in country i and in other countries will switch to cheaper substitutes. If the elasticity of substitution is very high, demand for country i0 s good will collapse, and country i will produce almost nothing. If markets within the currency union are complete or a transfer union is in place, consumption must be equal across countries. However, only a few countries will produce any output, and households in those few countries will have to work long hours to supply goods for the whole currency union. As a 17 The answer depends on the degree of risk aversion as defined by σ, the inverse Frisch elasticity of labor supply ϕ, as well as the Armington elasticity γ. Details are found in Appendix I. Here we focus on the intuition. 23 result, average consumption and welfare will fall. This effect is exacerbated as goods become closer substitutes. In the limit, when goods are perfect substitutes (γ = ∞) and shocks are asymmetric, only one country in the currency union will produce any output, and consumption and welfare will equal zero for all countries in the union. On the other hand, when substitutability is close to one, the welfare losses from wage rigidity and the gains from risk-sharing go to zero. Terms of trade movements will provide risk-sharing and insulate economies from the negative impact of asymmetric productivity shocks and nominal rigidities. In this case, a country will be indifferent between remaining outside a currency union in financial autarky and joining a currency union with full risk-sharing. In reality of course, membership in a currency union does not guarantee perfect risk-sharing through access to complete markets, nor does lack of membership in a currency union prevent countries from accessing international financial markets. Whether countries enjoy some degree of cross-border risk-sharing seems to be largely unrelated to their membership in a currency union, although it is true that the introduction of the euro led to an increase in cross-border lending within the euro area, as well as an initial convergence of borrowing rates within the union. However, from a theoretical standpoint it is hard to argue that the potential risk-sharing benefits of a currency union outweigh the loss of independent monetary policy. 7 Welfare Analysis in the Extended Model In this section we relax some earlier simplifying assumptions and conduct welfare analysis in a model with home bias, Calvo wage rigidities and incomplete markets. The model presented here, which we refer to as the “Extended Model,” is identical in all other respects to the closed-form model described in Section 2 and is laid out in detail in Appendix J. Calibration As in the closed-form model, we calibrate the extended model at quarterly frequency. All parameter values are found in Table 1. The elasticity of substitution between home and foreign products is defined by η, while the elasticity of substitution between the goods of different countries remains γ. The relative weight of these goods in the consumption basket is defined by the degree of home bias, 1−α. When α = 0, households only consume domestic goods, while when α = 1, the economy is fully open and households will consume a basket made up entirely of imports from all other countries in the world. The strength of wage rigidity is defined by θW , the fraction of households who are able to reset wages in each period. We consider three primary settings for Calvo wage rigidity: flexible wages (θW = 0), low wage rigidity (θW = 0.75) which implies that the average household resets wages once every four quarters, and high wage rigidity θW = 0.87 which implies that the average household resets wages every two years.18 18 We take θW = 0.75 as a conservative estimate of wage rigidity from Basu, Barattieri and Gottschalk (2014), who find strong empirical evidence for θW in the range of 0.75 and 0.8 using U.S. micro data. Even 24 Tax Union First, we analyze the welfare gains from a tax union by comparing the difference in steady state consumption between a set of countries outside of a tax union with those inside a tax union. We set η = 4 to match the average elasticity between home and foreign goods for the euro area countries from Table 4. Figure 5 plots the loss in permanent consumption from the terms of trade externality as a function of openness and the Armington elasticity. The distortionary impact of the terms of trade markup is increasing in both openness and the Armington elasticity. One can see this by examining the optimal non-cooperative income tax rate in the extended γ−1+(1−α)η model, τi = 1 − µε γ−(1−α)(1−η) , which we derive in Appendix K. This tax rate is increasing in openness and both elasticities, η and γ. As the degree of home bias increases, self-interested fiscal authorities find it less desirable to impose a large markup on their export good. Why? Because the same good makes up an increasingly significant portion of the home consumption basket. A tradeoff is thus introduced between exploiting the terms of trade and driving up the price of the home good for domestic consumers. This is a result of the law of one price: if the fiscal authority taxes workers in order to reduce supply and increase the price of its unique final good, households in all countries will suffer but home households will suffer more because the home good makes up (1-α) fraction of the consumption basket. In contrast, when economies are completely open, home households consume measure zero of their domestic good, and the non-cooperative fiscal authority is no longer concerned about reducing home welfare through the terms of trade markup. As we saw earlier in the closed-form version of the model, the optimal income tax rate converges to τi = 1 − γ γ−1 when economies are completely open. Within a tax union, the optimal tax rate remains τi = 1 − µε . Why does the welfare loss from the terms of trade externality increase in the degree of openness? When an economy is more open, imports make up a larger portion of the consumption basket. These imports are subject to a terms of trade markup. As a result, the more a country needs to import, the greater the negative welfare impact of the terms of trade externality. In addition, as goods become less substitutable (as the Armington elasticity decreases), fiscal authorities have an incentive to impose larger terms of trade markups on their exports through income tax setting. Country-level monopoly power is thus increasing in both openness and the Armington elasticity. θW = 0.87 is a relatively conservative parameterization given recent estimates by Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2012). They find very strong downward wage rigidity in a number of countries in Europe from 2008-2011, including Greece, Portugal and Spain. Although wages are more flexible in the upward direction, our focus here is on the negative effect of downward wage rigidity and the large welfare losses that accrue in a currency union under this scenario. Cacciatore, Ghironi and Fiori (2015) show that labor market reforms which reduce downward wage rigidity in a monetary union provide large welfare gains. 25 Transfer Union Next, we calculate the welfare losses from business cycle fluctuations in financial autarky and incomplete markets. We follow Lucas (2003) and estimate the utility from a deterministic consumption path and a risky consumption path with the same mean. We then calculate the amount of consumption necessary to make a risk averse household indifferent between the deterministic and risky consumption streams. In what follows we assume that there is no steady state terms of trade markup. Figure 6 plots the loss in permanent consumption from business cycle fluctuations in financial autarky for high wage rigidity (θW = 0.87). Figure 6 shows that home bias lowers welfare for every value of the Armington elasticity. In other words, home bias exacerbates the negative welfare impact of wage rigidity in the absence of risk-sharing. Our closed-form model thus provides a lower bound estimate of the welfare benefits of a transfer union under financial autarky. The losses in permanent consumption in financial autarky in a currency union are as high as 16% when economies are completely open (α = 1) and 17% under full home bias (α → 0). The Armington elasticity is far more important than consumption home bias in determining welfare losses: the losses in permanent consumption can be as low as 0% for low elasticity (γ = 1) and as high as 17% for high elasticity (γ = 10). Why does home bias increase the welfare losses from business cycle fluctuations in financial autarky? Consider the following thought experiment. Assume that wages are completely rigid, that α = 0.01 so that 1% of consumption always goes to imports and the remainder goes towards home goods, and that home and foreign consumption baskets are perfect complements. Under financial autarky in a currency union, the cash value of imports must equal the cash value of exports. Therefore, total consumption is equal to the value of exports multiplied by 100. Also, when the home and foreign consumption baskets are perfect complements, fluctuations in total household consumption are equal to fluctuations in export revenues. This effect is only strengthened when home and foreign goods are imperfect complements or substitutes. A negative shock that raises the price of the home good will lead domestic households to substitute home goods for foreign goods in their consumption basket, increasing the share of imports in total consumption. But in financial autarky the value of imports must equal the value of exports, and exports are now uncompetitive on the world market due to the rise in price caused by the negative shock. As a result, total home consumption must fall. Figure 7 plots the loss in permanent consumption from business cycle fluctuations in incomplete markets. The ability to trade bonds greatly improves welfare for countries in a currency union who are exposed to asymmetric shocks. Different from financial autarky, an increase in home bias improves the ability of countries to stabilize business cycles when markets are incomplete. If a country is completely open, bonds allow households to stabilize consumption but not hours worked, because exports become uncompetitive following a negative technology shock 26 and wages are rigid. When home bias increases, stabilization of both consumption and hours worked is possible, because firms supply goods mainly to the home market. In contrast, under financial autarky more home bias is bad for welfare because consumption is never stabilized. As a robustness check, we plot the loss in permanent consumption from business cycle fluctuations for varying levels of Calvo wage rigidity in Figure 8. We set consumption home bias equal to the euro area average of 65% (i.e. (1 − α) = 0.65). Again, we see that it is not only wage rigidity that leads to large welfare losses, but the combination of wage rigidity and a high Armington elasticity. Simply put, when a country in a currency union produces exports that are easily substitutable, the welfare consequences are dramatic. When wages are quite rigid, as the evidence in Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2011) suggests for some European countries, the losses in permanent consumption are small for low values of elasticity, but approach 80% for high values of elasticity. Even for conservative estimates of wage rigidity, the losses in permanent consumption are quite large when the Armington elasticity is high. Overall our closed-form results are robust to the inclusion of consumption home bias, incomplete markets and Calvo rigidities. The Armington elasticity remains an essential parameter in the optimal design of a fiscal union. A tax union is more important when exports are imperfect substitutes, while a transfer union is more important when exports are close substitutes. We find that consumption home bias increases the need for a transfer union in financial autarky, as the losses from incomplete risk-sharing rise with 1 − α. On the other hand, home bias reduces the need for a tax union, as monopoly power at the export level declines when domestic goods make up a larger percentage of the domestic consumption basket. In the limit, when countries only consume domestic goods, there are no terms of trade externalities. In addition, home bias strengthens the distortionary impact of wage rigidity, raising the importance of contingent fiscal policy or labor mobility within a currency union. Our welfare analysis also demonstrates that under the commonly assumed Cole-Obstfeld calibration, which sets σ = η = γ = 1, the welfare losses from business cycle fluctuations, and thus the gains from a transfer union, are extremely small. We nest the Cole-Obstfeld calibration as a special case here, and show that the the distortionary impact of imperfect risk-sharing and wage rigidity is much larger as the Armington elasticity moves away from unity and goods become more substitutable. Welfare Losses for Country-Specific Elasticity Estimates In Table 2 we examine the steady state losses arising from terms of trade externalities for particular countries in Europe using the elasticity estimates calculated by Corbo and Osbat (2013) and Imbs and Méjean (2010). These are two of the only papers to estimate the aggregate elasticity of substitution between home and foreign products (η) and the aggregate elasticity of substitution between the products of different countries (γ). Most trade papers focus only on sector-specific estimates. We find that more open countries with low elasticities (e.g. the Czech Republic and the Netherlands) gain the most from the presence of a tax union. 27 Next, we compute the welfare losses for a number of European countries under financial autarky, incomplete markets, complete markets and the optimal transfer union resulting from 1% technology shocks. We consider three different values for Calvo wage rigidity in our computations: high wage rigidity (θW = 0.87), low wage rigidity (θW = 0.75) and flexible wages (θW = 0). Table 3 reports the loss in permanent consumption for the country-specific elasticity estimates of Corbo and Osbat (2013), while Table 4 reports the results for the countryspecific elasticity estimates of Imbs and Méjean (2010). The results are particularly striking for countries in financial autarky, where the losses are as high as 7.22% (Greece). Access to a non-contingent bond for households significantly improves welfare, as permanent consumption losses drop to a range of 1.19% (Slovakia) to 2.88% (Austria) under high wage rigidity. Moving from incomplete markets to complete markets yields a smaller welfare gain of between 0.5 to 2 percent of permanent consumption for most countries in the sample. A transfer union is the most efficient allocation, as losses range from 0% (Italy) to 0.56% (Czech Republic). In Table 5 we compute the welfare losses in incomplete markets resulting from productivity shocks calibrated to match the volatility and autocorrelation of output in the data. The autocorrelation of HP-filtered output (ρY ) in the data is approximately 0.9998. We conservatively set ρZ = 0.99 for our simulations which implies ρY = 0.99 in the model; if we increase ρZ , the welfare losses also increase. The volatility of productivity shocks (σZ,1 , σZ,2 ) are calibrated to match the volatilities of HP-filtered output (σY,1 , σY,2 ). We conduct welfare analysis for two scenarios. In Scenario 1 we take the volatility of output (σY,1 ) from HP-filtered GDP data for each country with no adjustments and calibrate productivity shocks (σZ,1 ) to match the output volatilities from the data. In Scenario 2 we compute the volatility of output (σY,2 ) from HP-filtered GDP data for each country after subtracting euro area GDP in order to construct a valid measure of asymmetric productivity shocks. We then calibrate the volatility of asymmetric productivity shocks (σZ,2 ) to match the volatility of asymmetric output in the data (σY,2 ). The volatility of output resulting from asymmetric shocks (σY,2 ) is roughly half of the overall volatility of output for each country (σY,1 ). Scenario 1 may be thought of as a set of upper bound estimates and Scenario 2 as a set of lower bound estimates of empirically plausible welfare losses resulting from the absence of perfect cross-country risk sharing in a monetary union, where a common central bank cannot respond to asymmetric shocks across countries. The countries with the largest to gain from a transfer union are the smaller “periphery” countries, including Greece, Hungary, the Czech Republic, Portugal and Slovakia. Our results on the welfare gains of a transfer union over and above the complete markets allocation match the findings of Farhi and Werning (2013), who demonstrate that the privately optimal allocation under complete markets is inefficient and can be improved upon by government intervention in the form of fiscal transfers between countries. Here we go one step further and explicitly quantify the welfare gains from a transfer union. These results confirm that the 28 potential gains from international fiscal cooperation are economically significant for a number of countries in the euro area, but particularly for countries that lose access to international financial markets and have high trade elasticities. Greece is a prime example of both. 8 Conclusion We provide a unique perspective on the welfare gains that would result from the construction of a fiscal union in the euro area. We derive a novel, global, closed-form solution for an open economy model in which currency union members face limited cross-country risk-sharing, selfinterested fiscal authorities and wage rigidity. Our novel closed-form solution allows us to examine the optimal structure of a fiscal union and analytically calculate the exact welfare gains that would result from a fiscal union for a wide range of scenarios. We confirm our analytical findings in a larger model that incorporates consumption home bias and Calvo wage rigidities. In our analytical framework we prove that the optimal design of a fiscal union depends crucially on the Armington elasticity, which defines the degree of substitutability between the products of different countries. When substitutability is low (around one), risk-sharing occurs naturally via terms of trade movements so that a transfer union is unnecessary. Terms of trade externalities are large however, and optimal policy will implement a tax union to prevent terms of trade manipulation. The welfare gains from a tax union can be as high as one percent of permanent consumption for standard calibrations. When substitutability is high (above one), risk-sharing no longer occurs naturally via terms of trade movements. If financial markets do not provide cross-country risk-sharing, there is a role for a transfer union to provide insurance against idiosyncratic shocks. The relative importance of a transfer union increases as goods become more substitutable. The welfare gains from a transfer union are negligible outside of a currency union, but are significant for countries inside the euro area. The euro area, a currency union with self-interested fiscal authorities, low cross-border risksharing and low labor mobility, would benefit immensely from a fiscal union between member states. Although it may be difficult to achieve, our findings suggest that the preservation of the currency union depends on it. 29 References [1] Adao, B., Correia, I., and Teles, P. On the relevance of exchange rate regimes for stabilization policy. Journal of Economic Theory 144, 4 (July 2009), 1468–1488. [2] Anderson, J. E., and van Wincoop, E. Trade costs. Journal of Economic Literature 42, 3 (September 2004), 691–751. [3] Armington, P. A theory of demand for products distinguished by place of production. International Monetary Fund Staff Papers 16 (1969), 159–176. [4] Balta, N., and Delgado, J. Home bias and market integration in the eu. CESifo Economic Studies 55, 1 (2009), 110–144. [5] Barattieri, A., Basu, S., and Gottschalk, P. Some Evidence on the Importance of Sticky Wages. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 6, 1 (January 2014), 70–101. [6] Beetsma, R. M., and Jensen, H. Monetary and fiscal policy interactions in a microfounded model of a monetary union. Journal of International Economics 67, 2 (December 2005), 320–352. [7] Benigno, G., and De Paoli, B. On the international dimension of fiscal policy. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 42, 8 (December 2010), 1523–1542. [8] Bordo, M. D., Jonung, L., and Markiewicz, A. A Fiscal Union for the Euro: Some Lessons from History . CESifo Economic Studies 59, 3 (September 2013), 449–488. [9] Bottazzi, L., and Manasse, P. Credibility and seigniorage in a common currency area. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 34, 4 (November 2002), 1034–46. [10] Bottazzi, L., and Manasse, P. Asymmetric Information and Monetary Policy in Common Currency Areas. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 37, 4 (August 2005), 603–21. [11] Bussière, M., Callegari, G., Ghironi, F., Sestieri, G., and Yamano, N. Estimating Trade Elasticities: Demand Composition and the Trade Collapse of 2008-2009. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 5, 3 (July 2013), 118–51. [12] Cacciatore, M., Fiori, G., and Ghironi, F. Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a Monetary Union. Journal of International Economics (2015). [13] Canzoneri, M. B., and Henderson, D. W. Monetary Policy in Interdependent Economies: A Game-Theoretic Approach, vol. 1 of MIT Press Books. The MIT Press, 1991. 30 [14] Cardoso-Costa, J.-M., and Lewis, V. Fiscal Policy and Inflation in a Monetary Union. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2676549 (2015). [15] Chugh, S. Optimal fiscal and monetary policy with sticky wages and sticky prices. Review of Economic Dynamics 9 (2006), 683–714. [16] Chugh, S. K., and Ghironi, F. Optimal Fiscal Policy with Endogenous Product Variety. CEPR Discussion Papers 10674, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers, June 2015. [17] Cole, H. L., and Obstfeld, M. Commodity trade and international risk sharing : How much do financial markets matter? Journal of Monetary Economics 28, 1 (August 1991), 3–24. [18] Corbo, V., and Osbat, C. Trade adjustment in the european union - a structural estimation approach. Working Paper Series 1535, European Central Bank, Apr. 2013. [19] Correia, I., Farhi, E., Nicolini, J. P., and Teles, P. Unconventional fiscal policy at the zero bound. American Economic Review 103, 4 (June 2013), 1172–1211. [20] Corsetti, G., Dedola, L., and Leduc, S. International Risk Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks. Review of Economic Studies 75, 2 (2008), 443–473. [21] Corsetti, G., and Pesenti, P. Welfare and macroeconomic interdependence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 116, 2 (May 2001), 421–445. [22] Corsetti, G., and Pesenti, P. International dimensions of optimal monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 52, 2 (March 2005), 281–305. [23] Dmitriev, Economies. M., and Hoddenbagh, Available at J. SSRN: Price Stability in Small Open http://ssrn.com/abstract=2249552 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2249552 (2013). [24] Eaton, J., and Kortum, S. Technology, geography, and trade. Econometrica 70, 5 (September 2002), 1741–1779. [25] Eichengreen, B., and Ghironi, F. Transatlantic trade-offs in the age of balanced budgets and european monetary union. Open Economies Review 13, 4 (October 2002), 381–411. [26] Evers, M. P. Federal fiscal transfer rules in monetary unions. European Economic Review 56, 3 (2012), 507–525. [27] Farhi, E., Gopinath, G., and Itskhoki, O. Fiscal Devaluations. NBER Working Papers 17662, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, Dec. 2011. 31 [28] Feenstra, R., Obstfeld, M., and Russ, K. In search of the armington elasticity. 2012. [29] Ferrero, A. Fiscal and monetary rules for a currency union. Journal of International Economics 77, 1 (February 2009), 1–10. [30] Gali, J., and Monacelli, T. Optimal monetary and fiscal policy in a currency union. Journal of International Economics 76, 1 (September 2008), 116–132. [31] Galı́, J., and Monacelli, T. Monetary policy and exchange rate volatility in a small open economy. Review of Economic Studies 72, 3 (07 2005), 707–734. [32] Imbs, J., and Méjean, I. Trade Elasticities: A Final Report for the European Commission. European Economy - Economic Papers 432, Directorate General Economic and Financial Affairs (DG ECFIN), European Commission, Dec. 2010. [33] Imbs, J., and Méjean, I. Elasticity Optimism. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 7, 3 (July 2015), 43–83. [34] IMF. Toward a Fiscal Union for the Euro Area. IMF Staff Discussion Note SDN/13/09, International Monetary Theory, 2013. [35] Kahanec, M. Labor mobility in an enlarged european union. IZA Discussion Papers 6485, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Apr. 2012. [36] Kersting, E. K. Fiscal Stabilization With Partial Exchange Rate Pass-Through. Economic Inquiry 51, 1 (01 2013), 348–367. [37] Lai, H., and Trefler, D. The gains from trade with monopolistic competition: Specification, estimation, and mis-specification. NBER Working Papers 9169, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, Sept. 2002. [38] Lucas, R. Macroeconomic priorities. American Economic Review 93, 1 (March 2003), 1–14. [39] Meade, J. E. The balance-of-payments problems of a european free-trade area. The Economic Journal 67, 267 (1957), pp. 379–396. [40] Mundell, R. A plan for a european currency. In The Economics Of Common Currencies, H. Johnson and A. Swoboda, Eds. Allen and Unwin, 1973. [41] Mundell, R. A. A theory of optimum currency areas. The American Economic Review 51, 4 (1961), pp. 657–665. 32 [42] Obstfeld, M., and Rogoff, K. New directions for stochastic open economy models. Journal of International Economics 50, 1 (February 2000), 117–153. [43] Obstfeld, M., and Rogoff, K. Global implications of self-oriented national monetary rules. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, 2 (May 2002), 503–535. [44] Romalis, J. NAFTA’s and CUSFTA’s Impact on International Trade. The Review of Economics and Statistics 89, 3 (August 2007), 416–435. [45] Ruhl, K. J. The international elasticity puzzle. Tech. rep., 2008. [46] Schmitt-Grohé, S., and Uribe, M. Optimal fiscal and monetary policy under sticky prices. Journal of Economic Theory 114, 2 (February 2004), 198–230. [47] Schmitt-Grohé, S., and Uribe, M. Pegs, downward wage rigidity, and unemployment: The role of financial structure. NBER Working Papers 18223, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, July 2012. [48] Simonovska, I., and Waugh, M. E. The elasticity of trade: Estimates and evidence. NBER Working Papers 16796, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, Feb. 2011. [49] Sims, C. The Precarious Fiscal Foundations of EMU. Netherlands Central Bank Staff Report. Available at http://ideas.repec.org/p/dnb/staffs/34.html (1999). [50] Siu, H. E. Optimal fiscal and monetary policy with sticky prices. Journal of Monetary Economics 51, 3 (April 2004), 575–607. [51] Vegh, C. A., and Vuletin, G. How Is Tax Policy Conducted over the Business Cycle? American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 7, 3 (August 2015), 327–70. [52] Werning, I., and Farhi, E. Fiscal unions. NBER Working Papers 18280, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, Aug. 2012. [53] Zimmermann, K. European labour mobility: Challenges and potentials. De Economist 153, 4 (December 2005), 425–450. 33 Table 1: Parameter Value σ 2 ϕ 3 χ 1 ε 6 θW Varies β 0.99 γ Varies α Varies η 1 ρZ 0.95 σZ 0.01 Calibration of the Closed-Form and Extended Models Description Risk aversion parameter Inverse labor supply elasticity (Gali and Monacelli (2005, 2008)) Following Gali and Monacelli (2005, 2008) Elasticity between different types of labor Calvo parameter for wage rigidity Household discount factor Armington elasticity Openness in extended model Elasticity between home and foreign goods in extended model Persistence of technology shock in extended model Standard deviation of technology Table 2: Losses in Permanent Consumption from Terms of Trade Externalities Austria Czech Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Hungary Italy Netherlands Portugal Slovakia Spain Sweden UK European Avg α 0.55 0.70 0.40 0.32 0.31 0.34 0.35 0.49 0.22 0.62 0.41 0.30 0.30 0.42 0.37 0.35 Corbo & Osbat (2013) η γ Loss in percent 4.5 3.8 0.114 3.4 3.8 0.273 3.3 3.4 0.075 3.5 3.4 0.041 3.7 3.8 0.031 3.7 4.3 0.033 2.9 4.1 0.045 3.3 4.2 0.090 3.2 3.2 0.021 3.5 3.5 0.218 3.3 3.9 0.065 3.7 3.9 0.028 3.4 3.2 0.040 4.2 4.5 0.046 2.9 3.0 0.084 3.5 3.7 0.046 Imbs and Méjean (2010) η γ Loss in percent 1.9 3.9 0.180 3.5 3.1 3.5 4.8 2.4 3.9 3.4 3.5 3.8 4.2 3.1 3.8 0.042 0.041 0.041 0.029 0.186 0.014 3.6 3.2 3.5 3.2 3.2 3.3 4.9 2.7 4.4 4.0 3.6 3.8 0.044 0.051 0.025 0.067 0.060 0.046 Openness (α) is taken from Balta and Delgado (2013). The elasticity of substitution between home and foreign products (η) and the elasticity of substitution between the products of different countries (γ) for European countries is taken from Imbs and Méjean (2010). 34 Table 3: Losses in Permanent Consumption for Country-Specific Elasticity Estimates of Corbo & Osbat (2013) Parameters 35 Austria Czech Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Hungary Italy Netherlands Portugal Slovakia Spain Sweden UK Europ. Avg α 0.55 0.70 0.40 0.32 0.31 0.34 0.35 0.49 0.22 0.62 0.41 0.30 0.30 0.42 0.37 0.35 η 4.5 3.4 3.3 3.5 3.7 3.7 2.9 3.3 3.2 3.5 3.3 3.7 3.4 4.2 2.9 3.5 γ 3.8 3.8 3.4 3.4 3.8 4.3 4.1 4.2 3.2 3.5 3.9 3.9 3.2 4.5 3.0 3.7 High Wage Rigidity (θW = 0.87) Fin. Incomp. Complete Transfer Autarky Markets Markets Union 6.05 2.88 2.09 0.37 5.13 2.86 2.21 0.56 5.48 1.88 1.08 0.06 5.83 1.64 0.81 0.02 6.38 1.82 0.95 0.03 6.75 2.18 1.27 0.07 6.06 1.90 1.06 0.04 6.06 2.62 1.80 0.23 5.67 1.01 0.30 0.00 5.07 2.55 1.85 0.34 5.97 2.18 1.34 0.10 6.50 1.81 0.93 0.03 5.61 1.44 0.65 0.01 6.97 2.77 1.87 0.21 4.84 1.45 0.71 0.02 6.05 1.90 1.05 0.05 Low Wage Rigidity (θW = 0.75) Fin. Incomp. Complete Transfer Autarky Markets Markets Union 2.76 1.41 1.08 0.33 2.40 1.41 1.13 0.47 2.54 0.94 0.58 0.06 2.68 0.82 0.44 0.02 2.88 0.91 0.51 0.03 3.02 1.08 0.68 0.07 2.76 0.95 0.57 0.04 2.76 1.29 0.94 0.21 2.61 0.51 0.17 0.00 2.38 1.26 0.96 0.30 2.73 1.08 0.71 0.09 2.92 0.90 0.50 0.02 2.59 0.72 0.35 0.01 3.09 1.36 0.97 0.20 2.29 0.73 0.39 0.02 2.76 0.95 0.56 0.04 Flex Wages (θW = 0) Fin. Incomp. Autarky Markets 0.032 0.011 0.029 0.010 0.033 0.014 0.034 0.016 0.035 0.016 0.035 0.015 0.035 0.015 0.033 0.013 0.036 0.019 0.029 0.010 0.034 0.014 0.035 0.016 0.035 0.017 0.034 0.013 0.033 0.015 0.034 0.015 We compute the welfare losses in percent from a one percent technology shock (σZ = 0.01, ρZ = 0.95). We follow Lucas (2003) and estimate the utility from a deterministic consumption path and a risky consumption path with the same mean. We then calculate the amount of consumption necessary to make a risk averse household indifferent between the deterministic and risky consumption streams. The result is the loss in permanent consumption in percentage points for four scenarios: autarky, incomplete markets, complete markets, and a transfer union. There is no steady state terms of trade markup here. Openness (α) is taken from Balta and Delgado (2009). The elasticity of substitution between home and foreign products (η) and the elasticity of substitution between the products of different countries (γ) for European countries is taken from Table 4 and 5 of Corbo and Osbat (2013). Table 4: Losses in Permanent Consumption for Country-Specific Elasticity Estimates of Imbs and Méjean (2010) Parameters 36 Austria Finland France Germany Greece Hungary Italy Portugal Slovakia Spain Sweden UK European Avg α 0.55 0.32 0.31 0.34 0.35 0.49 0.22 0.41 0.30 0.30 0.42 0.37 0.35 η 1.9 3.5 3.1 3.5 4.8 2.4 3.9 3.6 3.2 3.5 3.2 3.2 3.3 γ 3.9 3.4 3.5 3.8 4.2 3.1 3.8 4.9 2.7 4.4 4.0 3.6 3.8 High Wage Rigidity (θW = 0.87) Fin. Incomp. Complete Transfer Autarky Markets Markets Union 4.94 2.21 1.50 0.18 5.81 1.63 0.81 0.02 5.70 1.53 0.72 0.01 6.19 1.91 1.05 0.04 7.22 2.48 1.53 0.12 4.32 1.66 0.98 0.07 6.71 1.36 0.52 0.00 6.99 2.73 1.82 0.19 4.99 1.19 0.47 0.00 6.80 1.95 1.04 0.03 6.01 2.25 1.41 0.11 5.65 1.82 1.00 0.04 6.05 1.90 1.05 0.05 Low Wage Rigidity (θW = 0.75) Fin. Incomp. Complete Transfer Autarky Markets Markets Union 2.33 1.10 0.79 0.16 2.67 0.81 0.44 0.02 2.63 0.76 0.39 0.01 2.81 0.95 0.56 0.04 3.18 1.22 0.80 0.11 2.08 0.84 0.53 0.06 3.00 0.68 0.29 0.00 3.10 1.33 0.95 0.18 2.35 0.60 0.26 0.00 3.03 0.97 0.56 0.03 2.74 1.11 0.74 0.11 2.61 0.91 0.54 0.04 2.76 0.95 0.56 0.04 Flex Wages (θW = 0) Fin. Incomp. Autarky Markets 0.031 0.012 0.034 0.016 0.035 0.016 0.035 0.015 0.035 0.015 0.030 0.013 0.036 0.019 0.035 0.014 0.034 0.017 0.036 0.016 0.034 0.014 0.034 0.015 0.034 0.015 We compute the welfare losses in percent from a one percent technology shock (σZ = 0.01, ρZ = 0.95). We follow Lucas (2003) and estimate the utility from a deterministic consumption path and a risky consumption path with the same mean. We then calculate the amount of consumption necessary to make a risk averse household indifferent between the deterministic and risky consumption streams. The result is the loss in permanent consumption in percentage points for four scenarios: autarky, incomplete markets, complete markets, and a transfer union. There is no steady state terms of trade markup here. Openness (α) is taken from Balta and Delgado (2013). The elasticity of substitution between home and foreign products (η) and the elasticity of substitution between the products of different countries (γ) for European countries is taken from Imbs and Méjean (2010). Table 5: Losses in Permanent Consumption in Incomplete Markets from Productivity Shocks Calibrated to the Data 37 Austria Czech Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Hungary Italy Netherlands Portugal Slovakia Spain Sweden UK European Avg α 0.55 0.70 0.40 0.32 0.31 0.34 0.35 0.49 0.22 0.62 0.41 0.30 0.30 0.42 0.37 0.35 Data σY,1 0.013 0.019 0.015 0.021 0.010 0.017 0.024 0.017 0.014 0.013 0.013 0.023 0.012 0.019 0.014 0.013 σY,2 0.005 0.010 0.007 0.010 0.005 0.006 0.024 0.010 0.004 0.005 0.011 0.014 0.007 0.009 0.008 0.000 η 4.5 3.4 3.3 3.5 3.7 3.7 2.9 3.3 3.2 3.5 3.3 3.7 3.4 4.2 2.9 3.5 Corbo & γ σZ,1 3.8 0.010 3.8 0.015 3.4 0.013 3.4 0.018 3.8 0.008 4.3 0.014 4.1 0.020 4.2 0.013 3.2 0.012 3.5 0.010 3.9 0.010 3.9 0.019 3.2 0.010 4.5 0.014 3.0 0.011 3.7 0.010 Osbat Losses 1.087 2.065 1.318 2.500 0.576 1.790 3.393 1.767 0.954 0.987 1.006 3.020 0.848 2.168 0.936 0.978 (2013) σZ,2 0.004 0.007 0.006 0.008 0.004 0.005 0.020 0.008 0.003 0.004 0.009 0.012 0.006 0.007 0.006 0.000 Losses 0.147 0.514 0.291 0.562 0.142 0.207 3.340 0.629 0.079 0.141 0.750 1.200 0.291 0.505 0.299 0.000 η 1.9 Imbs & Méjean (2010) γ σZ,1 Losses σZ,2 Losses 3.9 0.011 0.982 0.004 0.132 3.5 3.1 3.5 4.8 2.4 3.9 3.4 3.5 3.8 4.2 3.1 3.8 0.018 0.008 0.014 0.019 0.014 0.011 2.502 0.542 1.722 3.681 1.458 1.050 0.008 0.004 0.005 0.019 0.008 0.003 0.561 0.133 0.198 3.633 0.521 0.087 3.6 3.2 3.5 3.2 3.2 3.3 4.9 2.7 4.4 4.0 3.6 3.8 0.010 0.019 0.010 0.015 0.011 0.011 1.081 2.600 0.941 2.016 1.030 0.982 0.009 0.012 0.006 0.007 0.006 0.000 0.811 1.033 0.323 0.470 0.326 0.000 Here we compute the welfare losses in incomplete markets resulting from productivity shocks calibrated to match the volatility and autocorrelation of output in the data. The autocorrelation of HP-filtered output (ρZ ) in the data is approximately 0.9998, so we set ρZ = 0.99 for the simulations above. The volatility of productivity shocks (σZ,1 , σZ,2 ) are calibrated to match the volatilities of HP-filtered output (σY,1 , σY,2 ). In Scenario 1 we take the volatility of output (σY,1 ) from HP-filtered GDP data for each country with no adjustments and calibrate productivity shocks (σZ,1 ) to match the output volatilities from the data. In Scenario 2 we compute the volatility of output (σY,2 ) from HP-filtered GDP data for each country after subtracting euro area GDP in order to construct a valid measure of asymmetric productivity shocks. We then calibrate the volatility of asymmetric productivity shocks (σZ,2 ) to match the volatility of asymmetric output in the data (σY,2 ). We follow Lucas (2003) and estimate the utility from a deterministic consumption path and a risky consumption path with the same mean. We then calculate the amount of consumption necessary to make a risk averse household indifferent between the deterministic and risky consumption streams: the result is the losses in permanent consumption in percentage points. There is no steady state terms of trade markup here. Openness (α) is taken from Balta and Delgado (2009). The elasticity of substitution between home and foreign products (η) and the elasticity of substitution between the products of different countries (γ) for European countries is taken from Corbo and Osbat (2013) and from Imbs and Méjean (2010). Figure 1: Model Timeline -1 0 1 Policymaker declares fiscal and monetary policy Household makes state-contingent plan Period 1 shocks are realized t 2, 3, ..., t-1 Period t shocks are realized Figure 2: Annual Cross-Border Mobility, % of Population (2010) EU27: across countries Canada: between Quebec and 9 other provinces/territories EU15: across regions within countries Canada: across 10 provinces/territories US: across 4 main regions Australia: across 8 states/territories US: across 50 states 0 1 2 3 Source: OECD. This figure plots the percentage of the population that moved across national borders (for the EU27), or across regions within the same country (all others). 38 Figure 3: Welfare Losses From Terms of Trade Externalities in the Closed-Form Model Consumption as % of Pareto Optimum 100 98 96 94 Flex Complete Fixed Complete Flex Autarky Fixed Autarky Labor Mobility 92 90 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Armington Elasticity (γ) 8 9 10 Consumption as % of Pareto Optimum Figure 4: Welfare Losses from Business Cycle Fluctuations in the Closed-Form Model 100 99 98 97 Flex Complete Fixed Complete Flex Autarky Fixed Autarky Labor Mobility 96 95 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 Armington Elasticity (γ) 39 16 18 20 Losses In Permanent Consumption Figure 5: Welfare Losses from Terms of Trade Externalities 10 8 6 4 2 0 1 0.7 2 0.6 0.5 3 γ 0.4 α 4 0.3 Losses In Permanent Consumption Figure 6: Welfare Losses from Business Cycle Fluctuations in Financial Autarky 20 15 10 5 0 10 8 1 6 4 2 Armington Elasticity (γ) 0 0 40 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Openness (α) Losses In Permanent Consumption Figure 7: Welfare Losses from Business Cycle Fluctuations in Incomplete Markets 8 6 4 2 0 10 8 1 6 4 2 0 0 Armington Elasticity (γ) 0.4 0.2 0.6 0.8 Openness (α) Losses In Permanent Consumption Figure 8: Welfare Losses from Business Cycle Fluctuations in Financial Autarky for Different Levels of Wage Rigidity 10 8 6 4 2 0 10 8 0.95 6 0.9 4 0.85 2 Armington Elasticity (γ) 0.8 00.75 Calvo Wage Rigidity (θW ) 41 For Online Publication: Technical Appendix A Global Social Planner We begin by describing the maximization problem faced by a benevolent global social planner who has complete control over the monetary and fiscal policies of each country. Since the economies in our model are identical ex-ante, the global social planner will maximize a weighted utility function over all i countries, Z 1 1−σ Ni1+ϕ Ci −χ di, (A.1) 1−σ (1 + ϕ) 0 subject to the consumption basket and the aggregate resource constraint: Z Ci = 1 γ−1 γ γ γ−1 cij dj , Z 1 Yi =Ni Zi = cji dj. (A.2) 0 (A.3) 0 Proposition 9 The global social planner will maximize (A.1), subject to (A.2) and (A.3). The solution to the global social planner problem is: 1 σ+ϕ 1+ϕ 1 Ci = Zwσ+ϕ , χ 1 σ+ϕ (1−γσ)(1+ϕ) γ−1 1 Ni = Zw(1+γϕ)(σ+ϕ) Zi1+γϕ , χ 1+γϕ Z 1 (γ−1)(1+ϕ) (γ−1)(1+ϕ) 1+γϕ Zi Zw = di . (A.4a) (A.4b) (A.4c) 0 Proof See Appendix C in Dmitriev and Hoddenbagh (2013). The global social planner solution characterizes the Pareto efficient allocation. From (A.4a), we see that domestic consumption depends on average world technology Zw , which is a constant because technology shocks are identically and independently distributed. Consumption is thus stabilized at the country level, insuring risk averse households from consumption risk. On the other hand, (A.4b) shows that labor will fluctuate with technology shocks, increasing in booms and decreasing in recessions. There are no distortions in the efficient allocation: wage ridigity, incomplete risk-sharing, and the terms of trade externality are absent. The efficient allocation provides a natural benchmark to evaluate different policy regimes. In Sections 3 and 4 we look closely at optimal monetary and fiscal policy in non-cooperative and cooperative settings and see what conditions are necessary to replicate the Pareto efficient allocation outside of and within a currency union. In Section 5 we study the effect of labor mobility and see if it can replicate the Pareto efficient allocation. B Proof of Proposition 1 and 2: Flexible Exchange Rate Allocations Non-cooperative central banks will maximize their objective function (14) subject to (1), (8), (9) and (12) in complete markets and (1), (8), (9), and (13) in financial autarky. The Lagrangian 42 for the non-cooperative and cooperative cases is: 1−σ 1+ϕ Et−1 Nit1+ϕ Et−1 Cit1−σ χµε −χ + λi Et−1 Cit − Et−1 Nit L= 1−σ 1+ϕ 1 − τi γ−1 γ−1 γ−1 γ−1 1 1 γ γ Using Cit = Cwt Et−1 Nit γ Zit γ for complete markets, or Cit = Cwt Nit γ Zit γ for financial autarky, we can take the first order condition with respect to Nit .19 The FOC will be identical in both cases. γ−1 1 γ γ − 1 Yit γ Cwt µ 1 1+ϕ ∂L ε −σ −χ 1+λ = Cit (1 + λi (1 − σ)) (1 + ϕ) N =0 ∂Nit γ Nit 1 − τi Nit it In equilibrium, this equals: 1=χ | ε (1+ϕ) 1 + λi µ1−τ i λi (1−σ)(γ−1) 1+ γ {z ! Nit1+ϕ γ−1 γ Cit−σ Yit 1 γ . (B.1) Cwt } Constant This equation holds in both complete markets and financial autarky, and differs from the flexible price equilibrium only by the constant term. However, subject to labor market clearing, this constant will coincide with the flexible price equilibrium. The flexible wage equilibrium in complete markets and financial autarky is found by taking expectations out of the labor market clearing condition (9) and substituting in goods market clearing (12): 1= χµε 1 − τi 1+ϕγ γ Yit 1 . (B.2) γ Zit1+ϕ Cit−σ Cwt For complete markets, we can express output as a function of technology and a constant term γ(1+ϕ) 1+γϕ by substituting (12) into (B.2): Yit = Ai Zit . (We can do the same for exercise for autarky by substituting (13) into (B.2), but leave that to the reader). Using this expression for output, consumption in complete markets in country i can be expressed as (γ−1)(1+ϕ) γ−1 1 γ γ Cit = Ai Cwt Et−1 Zit 1+γϕ . (B.3) Now substitute (B.3) back into the flexible price equilibrium (B.2) σ (γ−1)σ (γ−1)(1+ϕ) σ 1+ϕγ −1 χµε γ γ 1= Cwt Ai Et−1 Zit 1+γϕ Ai γ Cwtγ , 1 − τi 19 (B.4) Remember that we are optimizing given the fact that state st is realized. Expectations in our context thus refer to a summation over P all possible states multiplied by the probability of each state occuring. For 1−σ example, Et−1 {Cit } = st Ci1−σ (st )Pr(st ). 43 and rearrange and solve for Ai : " Ai = 1 − τi χµε γ (γ−1)(1+ϕ) 1+γϕ 1−σ Et−1 Zit Cwt 1 −σγ # 1−σ+γ(ϕ+σ) . (B.5) Now, substitute the solution (B.5) into (B.3): " Cit = Using the fact that Cwt = χµε 1 − τi R1 0 1−γ 1 (γ−1)(1+ϕ) 1+γϕ # 1−σ+γ(ϕ+σ) ϕ+1 Cwt Et−1 Zit 1+γϕ . Cit di = Cit in equilibrium, and setting Zw = R1 0 (B.6) (γ−1)(1+ϕ) 1+γϕ Zit 1+γϕ (γ−1)(1+ϕ) di , integrate (B.6) over all i and solve for consumption for country i in complete markets: Cit = 1 − τi χµε 1 σ+ϕ 1+ϕ Zwσ+ϕ . (B.7) Solving for labor and output using (B.7) is a straightforward exercise. The solution to the central bank’s problem in complete markets and financial autarky for cooperative and noncooperative equilibria coincides exactly with the flexible wage allocation. Non-cooperative fiscal authorities will set a labor tax rate of τi = 1 − µµγε , introducing a terms of trade markup to exploit their country-level monopoly power. C Proof of Proposition 3 and 4: Currency Union Allocations Non-cooperative policymakers in a currency union in complete markets will maximize (17) by choosing a non state contingent income tax rate, subject to (1), (8), (9), (12), and (18). From (18) we can compute labor using Yit = Zit Nit : Nit = AZitγ−1 . (C.1) Given the above, consumption will be Z Cit = Cwt = A Zitγ−1 di γ γ−1 . (C.2) Using labor market clearing (9), and substituting in Yit , Cit , Nit expressed as functions of A and Zit from above, we find: R 1 (γ−1)(1+ϕ) A1+ϕ 0 Zit di χµε 1= (C.3) γ(1−σ) R 1 (γ−1) 1 − τi γ−1 A1−σ 0 Zit di Now we can solve for A: A= χµε 1 − τi −1 Z σ+ϕ 1 (γ−1)(1+ϕ) Zit 0 −1 Z σ+ϕ di 0 44 1 Zitγ−1 di γ (1−σ) γ−1 σ+ϕ . (C.4) Given this solution for the constant A, one can solve for Cit and Nit by substituting A into the expressions above, resulting in (19a) for Cit and (19b) for Nit . The same exercise in financial autarky will yield (20a) for Cit and (20b) for Nit . D Contingent Tax Policy Up to this point we have assumed that tax policy is non-contingent, so that fiscal authorities can only set a constant income tax rate. If we allow fiscal policymakers to adjust tax rates over the business cycle, the objective function under flexible exchange rates is 1−σ Nit1+ϕ Cit −χ , (D.1) max max Et−1 τit Nit 1−σ 1+ϕ and within a currency union is max Et−1 τit N 1+ϕ Cit1−σ − χ it 1−σ 1+ϕ . (D.2) As we showed in Proposition 1 and 2, when exchange rates are flexible national central banks will mimic the flexible wage allocation and a constant labor tax rate will be optimal for both contingent and non-contingent fiscal policymakers. The role of fiscal policy under flexible exchange rates is simply to ameliorate the monopolistic markup on differentiated labor inputs and impose a terms of trade markup in the non-cooperative case. In other words, contingent fiscal policy is redundant when exchange rates are flexible because national central banks adjust monetary policy over the business cycle to counteract wage rigidity. In contrast, the role of fiscal policy in a currency union is twofold: to impose a terms of trade markup, but also to eliminate wage rigidity at the national level resulting from asymmetric shocks. Optimal contingent fiscal policy within a currency union will not set a constant tax rate. Within a currency union the union-wide central bank has only one policy instrument at its disposal and cannot offset the effect of asymmetric shocks across countries. Contingent national fiscal policy can fill the void, setting domestic tax rates in each period to remove domestic wage rigidity and mimic the flexible wage equilibrium. One already begins to see that fiscal policy is more important within a currency union than outside of one. Given that contingent fiscal policy is only necessary in a currency union, we ignore flexible exchange rate allocations in Proposition 10. Proposition 10 Contingent Fiscal Policy Contingent non-cooperative policymakers within a currency union will maximize (D.2), subject to (9), (12), (1), (8), and (18) in complete markets and subject to (9), (1), (8), (13) and (18) in autarky. The optimal allocation will exactly coincide with (15a) in complete markets and (16a) in autarky, replicating the flexible wage allocation with a terms of trade markup. Proof We now assume that fiscal policymakers can choose their income tax rate in each period. In both complete markets and financial autarky, the fiscal authority in country i will maximize utility in each period, choosing the optimal contingent labor tax τit , given the realization of Zit in that period. To solve for the optimal allocation, follow the exact same steps as in Appendix C, but use τit as the policy instrument rather than Nit . The optimal allocations will remove the wage rigidity distortion and mimic the flexible exchange rate allocations, given by (15a) in complete markets and (16a) in financial autarky. 45 The optimal contingent labor tax within a currency union will be equal to τit = 1 − µit . The realized markup µit is defined by M P Lit = µit · M RSit , where M P Lit = Zit is the marginal product of labor and M RSit is the marginal rate of substitution. A positive productivity shock increases M P Lit , but since wages remain fixed, there will be a rise in demand for labor. The rise in demand for labor will induce households to work more hours and cause an even larger increase in M RSit . As a result, the markup will be countercylical and the optimal contingent labor tax will be procyclical: taxes will increase when productivity shocks are positive and decline when productivity shocks are negative. Note that international policy cooperation is not necessary to eliminate the distortionary impact of wage rigidity: non-cooperative contingent fiscal policy is all that is required. For the remainder of the paper, we will assume that fiscal policy is non-contingent. However, keep in mind that contingent fiscal policy within a currency union can play the same role as monetary policy outside of a currency union, eliminating nominal rigidities and mimicking the flexiblewage allocation. While the ability of contingent fiscal policy to eliminate nominal rigidities has been shown in other closed and open economy studies, we are the first to emphasize that the distortionary impact of wage rigidity and hence the importance of contingent fiscal policy is increasing in the Armington elasticity γ. E Proof of Proposition 5: Tax Union Under flexible exchange rates, policymakers in a tax union will maximize (21a) if they are not in a transfer union or (21e) if they are in a transfer union. In a currency union, policymakers in a tax union will maximize (21b) if they are not in a transfer union or (21f) if they are in a transfer union. Policymakers face the constraints outlined in Propositions 1 (flexible exchange rates and complete markets), 2 (flexible exchange rates and financial autarky), 3 (currency union and complete markets) or 4 (currency union and financial autarky), respectively. In the non-cooperative case, policymakers do not internalize the impact of their tax rate on other countries. As a result, non-cooperative policymakers set τi to eliminate the markup on domestic intermediates, µε , but also introduce a terms of trade markup, µγ , to take advantage of the monopoly power they exercise over their unique export good. The solution to the noncooperative problem is τi = 1 − µµγε . In a tax union policymakers do internalize the impact of their tax rate on other countries. The solution to the cooperative problem defines the optimal tax rate within a tax union: τi = 1−µε . The optimal tax rate in a tax union eliminates the markup on domestic intermediate goods without imposing a terms of trade markup. F Proof of Proposition 6: Transfer Union In a transfer union, policymakers agree to send contingent cash payments across countries. Under flexible exchange rates, policymakers in a transfer union will maximize (21c) if they are not in a tax union or (21e) if they are in a tax union. In a currency union, policymakers in a transfer union will maximize (21d) if they are not in a tax union or (21f) if they are in a tax union. Policymakers face the constraints outlined in Propositions 1 (flexible exchange rates and complete markets), 2 (flexible exchange rates and financial autarky), 3 (currency union and complete markets) or 4 (currency union and financial autarky), respectively. Because the transfers are state contingent, countries jointly agree on a state contingent plan to insure households against idiosyncratic consumption risk resulting from asymmetric shocks. Outside 46 of a tax union, the solution to the transfer union optimization problem under flexible exchange rates will replicate the complete markets allocation detailed in Proposition 1. Outside of a tax union, the solution to the optimization problem in a currency union will replicate the complete markets allocation detailed in Proposition 3. Within a tax union, the solution to the transfer union optimization problem under flexible exchange rates will replicate the complete markets allocation detailed in Proposition 1 without a terms of trade markup. Within a tax union, the solution to the optimization problem in a currency union will replicate the complete markets allocation detailed in Proposition 3 without a terms of trade markup. G Proof of Proposition 8: Labor Mobility In the presence of labor mobility, non-cooperative policymakers in a currency union in financial autarky will face the following problem max τi N 1+ϕ C 1−σ −χ 1−σ 1+ϕ (G.1) s.t. W N (h) = CP γ Z 1 γ−1 γ−1 γ cj dj C= (G.2a) (G.2b) 0 W = Zj pj 1 Z 1 1−γ 1−γ P = pj dj (G.2c) (G.2d) 0 cj = Zj Nj Z 1 Nj (h)dj N (h) = Z 0 1 Nj = Nj (h) ε−1 ε (G.2e) (G.2f) ε ε−1 (G.2g) dj 0 where W is equalized across countries because of labor mobility. As each economy in the currency union is hit with idiosyncratic shocks, labor will shift from low demand bust countries to high demand boom countries. FOCs: p −γ j C (G.3) cj = P W χµε = CσN ϕ (G.4) P 1 − τi To solve for the optimal allocation, begin with (G.2d) Z P = 0 1 p1−γ dj j 1 1−γ Z = 0 1 W Zj 1 ! 1−γ 1−γ 47 dj Z =W 0 1 Zjγ−1 dj 1 1−γ and solve for the real wage Z W = P 1 Zjγ−1 dj 1 γ−1 . (G.5) 0 Now substitute this expression for the real wage into (G.2a): W C = N (h) = N (h) P 1 Z Zjγ−1 dj 1 γ−1 1 Z Z Nj (h)dj = 0 0 1 Zjγ−1 dj 1 γ−1 . 0 Take (G.3) and substitute in the expression for the real wage from (G.2c): !γ p −γ Z j j cj = C= W C, P P (G.6) and then substitute cj = Zj Nj in G.6 Nj = W P −γ Zjγ−1 C. (G.7) Integrating Nj over j will yield Z 1 Nj dj = N = C 0 W P −γ Z 1 Z Zjγ−1 dj =C 1 Zjγ−1 dj 1 − γ−1 . (G.8) 0 0 Using (G.4), we can substitute in our expression for N from (G.8) and our expression for W/P from (G.5): W = P Z 1 Zjγ−1 dj 1 γ−1 = 0 χµε 1 − τi C σ N ϕ. Solving for C, we find: C= 1 − τi χµε 1 σ+ϕ Z 1 Zjγ−1 dj 1+ϕ (σ+ϕ)(γ−1) . (G.9) 0 To solve for Nj simply substitute (G.9) into (G.7): Nj = 1 − τi χµε 1 σ+ϕ Z 1 Zjγ−1 dj 1+ϕ−γ(σ+ϕ) (γ−1)(σ+ϕ) Zjγ−1 . (G.10) 0 As we’ve mentioned a number of times, the optimal tax rate outside of a tax union in the decentralized Nash equilibrium will be τi = 1 − µµγε . When labor can move freely across borders, the equilibrium allocation outside of a tax union 48 will be: Ci = Ni = 1 χµγ 1 χµγ 1 Z σ+ϕ 1 Ziγ−1 di 1+ϕ (σ+ϕ)(γ−1) 0 1 σ+ϕ Z 1 Zjγ−1 dj 1+ϕ−γ(σ+ϕ) (γ−1)(σ+ϕ) Zjγ−1 . 0 This allocation holds under flexible exchange rates and within a currency union, in both complete markets and financial autarky. H Welfare Derivations Below, we outline the steps necessary to derive the expected utility functions contained in Section 6 of the paper. Here we only conduct the exercise for flexible exchange rates in complete markets, but following the steps presented here will also yield the expected utility functions for the other allocations. 1+γϕ 1 Z 1 (γ−1)(1+ϕ) (γ−1)(σ+ϕ) 1 − τi σ+ϕ Zi 1+γϕ di Cf lex,complete = χµε 0 n o 1 1 − τi E {Uf lex,complete } = − E Cf1−σ lex,complete 1 − σ µε (1 + ϕ) 1−σ Z 1 (γ−1)(1+ϕ) (1+γϕ)(1−σ) σ+ϕ (γ−1)(σ+ϕ) 1 1 − τi 1 − τi Z 1+γϕ di = E − 0 i 1 − σ µε (1 + ϕ) χµε For normative analysis, we assume that technology is log-normally distributed and is independent across time and across countries: log Zit ∼ N (0, σZ2 ). The expectation above can then be rewritten as: Z 1 (γ−1)(1+ϕ) (1+γϕ)(1−σ) (γ−1)(σ+ϕ) (γ−1)(1+ϕ) 2 (1+γϕ)(1−σ) 2 E Zi 1+γϕ di = e[ 1+γϕ ] (γ−1)(σ+ϕ) σZ 0 =e (γ−1)(1+ϕ)2 (1−σ) 2 σZ (1+γϕ)(σ+ϕ) . Now, we insert this expression back into the original equation and get: 1 − τi 1 − E {Uf lex,complete } = 1 − σ µε (1 + ϕ) 1 − τi χµε 1−σ σ+ϕ e (γ−1)(1+ϕ)2 (1−σ) 2 σZ (1+γϕ)(σ+ϕ) . Taking logarithms, we can rewrite the log of expected utility as: 1 1 − τi 1−σ 1 − τi (γ − 1)(1 + ϕ)2 (1 − σ) 2 − + log + σZ . log E {Uf lex,complete } = log 1 − σ µε (1 + ϕ) σ+ϕ χµε (1 + γϕ)(σ + ϕ) (H.1) Calculating the expected utility for the other coalitions simply requires that one follow the steps outlined here. Notice that when we calculate welfare differences between allocations, the first and second terms on the right hand side of equation (H.1) will cancel out, leaving only the 49 difference between the remaining term on the right hand side. Using the expected utilities from (25a) – (25d), and the fact that any constant terms will cancel out when subtracted from each other, we calculate the welfare differences for four scenarios: (1) complete markets vs. autarky for flexible wages; (2) complete markets vs. autarky for fixed wages; (3) flexible vs. fixed wages for complete markets; and (4) flexible vs. fixed wages for autarky. When comparing welfare across different allocations, it is important to keep in mind that as risk-aversion decreases, (i.e. as σ → 1), the welfare differences expressed in logarithms also decrease but the absolute values of utility increase. In other words, when risk aversion is low, the welfare differences shown in (H.2a) – (H.2d) will shrink, but this does not mean that the welfare differences are decreasing in absolute value. σ(γ − 1)2 (1 − σ)(1 + ϕ)2 σ 2 (H.2a) (σ + ϕ)(1 + γϕ)[1 − σ + γ(σ + ϕ)] Z σ(γ − 1)2 (1 − σ)(1 + ϕ) 2 log E {Uf ixed,complete } − log E {Uf ixed,autarky } = σZ (H.2b) σ+ϕ γϕ2 (γ − 1)2 (1 − σ)(1 + ϕ) 2 log E {Uf lex,complete } − log E {Uf ixed,complete } = σZ (H.2c) (1 + γϕ)(σ + ϕ) (γ − 1)2 (1 − σ)(1 + ϕ)[γ(σ + ϕ) − σ] 2 log E {Uf lex,autarky } − log E {Uf ixed,autarky } = σZ 1 + γ(σ + ϕ) − σ (H.2d) log E {Uf lex,complete } − log E {Uf lex,autarky } = I Are countries better off in a currency union? A country with a flexible exchange rate and no risk-sharing is better off than a country in a currency union with perfect risk-sharing whenever (1 + ϕ) [1 + ϕ + (γ − 1)(1 − σ)(σ + ϕ)] − (1 + ϕ − γϕ) [1 − σ + γ(σ + ϕ)]2 ≥ 0, (I.1) which can be rewritten in cubic form as ( h i γ − 1 ϕ(σ + ϕ)2 (γ − 1)2 + (γ − 1) 2ϕ(σ + ϕ)(1 + ϕ) − (σ + ϕ)2 ) + ϕ(1 + ϕ)2 + (1 − σ)(1 + ϕ)(σ + ϕ) − 2(σ + ϕ)(1 + ϕ) The roots to this cubic equation are: 2 2 3√ σ +2σ ϕ−ϕ2 +2σϕ2 −(σ+ϕ) 2 σ+ϕ+4σϕ+4σϕ2 2(σ 2 ϕ+2σϕ2 +ϕ2 ) 1 γ= 3√ σ2 +2σ2 ϕ−ϕ2 +2σϕ2 +(σ+ϕ) 2 σ+ϕ+4σϕ+4σϕ2 ≥ 0. (I.2) (I.3) 2(σ 2 ϕ+2σϕ2 +ϕ2 ) where the first root is less than one, and the third root is greater than one. When γ is less than one or greater than the third root expressed in (I.3), a country will be better off outside of a currency union in financial autarky than as a member of a currency union in complete markets. In the limiting case as households become completely risk neutral (σ → 0), the roots of (I.2) 50 will be −1 0 γ= 1 (I.4) while in the opposite limiting case, as households become extremely risk averse (σ → ∞), the roots of (I.2) will be 0 1 (I.5) γ= 1+2ϕ ϕ Internationally traded goods are perfect complements as γ approaches zero and perfect substitutes as γ approaches infinity, so γ must be non-negative. We can safely ignore any negative roots and focus only on positive roots. There is a very small window for which countries are better off as members of a currency union than as non-members. In a standard calibration with σ = 2 and ϕ = 3, countries are better off as members of a currency union only when 1 ≤ γ ≤ 1.12. For all other values of γ outside this narrow range, households prefer to be outside of a currency union in financial autarky. J Extended Model with Home Bias and Calvo Wage Rigidity In each country i, the consumption basket consists of home (CitH ) and foreign (CitF ) goods, i η h η−1 η−1 η−1 1 1 Cit = (1 − α) η (CitH ) η + α η (CitF ) η (J.1) where CitF and CitH are defined as CitF Z = F (Cijt ) γ−1 γ γ γ−1 dj and CitH Z = ε ε−1 ε−1 (CitH (h)) ε dh . (J.2) F Cijt denotes consumption by households in country i of the variety produced by country j, while CitH (h) denotes consumption by households in country i of the domestic variety produced by intermediate firm h. The elasticity of substitution between home and foreign products is defined by η, while the elasticity of substitution between the goods of different countries remains γ. The relative weight of these goods in the consumption basket is defined by the degree of home bias, 1 − α. When α = 0, home bias is complete and households only consume domestic goods. In the opposite extreme, when α = 1, the economy is fully open and households will consume a basket made up entirely of imports from all other countries in the world. Similarly the price index will consist of goods prices of both home and foreign products: h i 1 H 1−η F 1−η 1−η Pit = (1 − α)(Pit ) + α(Pit ) . 51 (J.3) Relative demand for home and foreign products is given by CitH = (1 − α) CitF =α PitH Pit −η PitF Pit −η Cit , (J.4) Cit , (J.5) where CitF and CitH are defined as CitF CitH Z = Z = F (Cijt ) γ−1 γ γ γ−1 dj , (J.6) . (J.7) −1 −1 (CitH (h)) dh F denotes consumption by households in country i of the variety produced by country j. Cijt H Cit (h) denotes consumption by households in country i of the domestic variety produced by intermediate firm h. Production in each country i and the demand for country i0 s goods are given by: Yit = Zit Nit (J.8) Yit = CitH + PitH /PitF −γ CtH∗ (J.9) where CtH∗ represents foreign consumption of the home good. The formula for consumption depends on whether we have complete markets, incomplete markets, financial autarky or financial autarky with a transfer union. Correspondingly: nP o PH,it F σ1 t β Yit P F E0 Pt it Cit = (J.10a) σ−1 P t Pit σ Pt E0 β PF it Yit PH,it − Bit + Bit−1 (1 + iit−1 ) Pt Yit PH,it Cit = Pt Yit PH,it Tit Cit = + Pt Pit Calvo wage setting can be expressed as Cit = 1−ε Wt1−ε = (1 − θW )W̃t1−ε + θW Wt−1 (J.10b) (J.10c) (J.10d) (J.11) where Wt is the actual wage, W̃ is the optimal reset wage and θW is the fraction of households 52 who are able to reset wages in each period. The equations describing Calvo wage setting are: VW,t = Nt1+ϕ + βθW Et VW,t+1 Nt ṼW,t = Ct−σ + βθW ṼW,t+1 Pt VW,t ε W̃ = χ ε − 1 ṼW,t 1−ε Wt1−ε = (1 − θW )W̃t1−ε + θW Wt−1 (J.12) (J.13) (J.14) (J.15) There is a nominal government bond that pays in units of the import basket CF for incomplete markets. Households will maximize utility from (2) subject to the following budget constraint: Wit (h) Bit−1 (h) Bit (h) Cit (h) + = (1 − τi ) Nit (h) + Dit (h) + Tit (h) + Γit (h) + (1 + it−1 ) . Pit Pit (h) Pit (J.16) The domestic interest rate it equals the world interest rate plus a country specific interest rate premium p() that is strictly increasing in the amount of debt Bt : it = i∗ + p(Bt ). (J.17) Financial autarky is the case for which p goes to infinity. The interest rate premium is necessary to ensure stationarity. To compute welfare under financial autarky, incomplete markets, complete markets and a transfer union, we solve a second-order approximation of the model for each country assuming that the home country is a small open economy and that the rest of the union is in the steady state. In this case the calibration of parameters for other members of the union has no effect. The correct specification yields the ergodic mean for the rest of the union. We compute the ergodic mean (assuming that the rest of the union has an identical calibration to the small open economy, but faces asymmetric shocks) and find that it has no effect on allocation or welfare analysis. Indeed, since shocks are asymmetric and positive shocks cancel out negative shocks across the union, it does not matter whether the rest of the union is at rest or experiences asymmetric shocks. This is also true if we consider two economies rather than a continuum of small open economies. The computation of the ergodic mean remains unaffected as positive shocks for the rest of the union would cancel out with negative shocks for the home country, and the welfare results should be robust in that respect. To compute welfare for the optimal transfer union we numerically search over the optimal transfers as a function of technology shocks and then estimate the ergodic mean for welfare using second order perturbation methods. K Non-cooperative Tax Policy in the Extended Model In this section we solve for the optimal steady state income tax rate for non-cooperative fiscal authorities in the extended model with home bias. Because the optimal income tax rate is a steady state object, we will drop all time subscripts in this section. Using the demand equation from (J.4) and the fact that C = Y P H /P , we can write C H = (1 − α)C 1−η Y η . 53 (K.1) We can also rearrange the price index (J.3) to get η−1 PH P PH +α−1=α PF η−1 . (K.2) Substitute C/Y = P H /P into (K.2) and rearrange so that 1 PH (C/Y )η−1 + α − 1 η−1 . = PF α (K.3) Now we plug this expression into the demand equation for home products (J.9): Y = (1 − α)C 1−η (C/Y )η−1 + α − 1 Y + α η −γ η−1 C H∗ (K.4) Using the implicit function theorem, we define C = f (Y )=(K.4), so that the non-cooperative policymaker’s objective function becomes max Y f (Y )1−σ Y 1+ϕ −χ . 1−σ 1+ϕ (K.5) The policymaker’s first order conditions with respect to Y are f 0 (Y )f (Y )−σ − χY ϕ = 0 (K.6) where we’ve used Y = N because we are in steady state, and C = f (Y ). From the implicit function theorem, we know that f 0 (Y ) = −gY /gC , where g(C, Y ) = −Y + (1 − α)C 1−η C η−1 Y 1−η + α − 1 Y + α η −γ η−1 C H∗ . (K.7) Solving for gC gives −γ η−1 1−η η−1 −1 γ C Y + α − 1 −η η C H∗ C η−2 Y 1−η . gC = (1 − η)(1 − α)C Y − α α (K.8) In steady state, we know that αC = αY = C H∗ , so that gC = (1 − η)(1 − α) − γ. Similarly, we solve for gY : gY = −1 + (1 − α)ηC 1−η Y η−1 −γ −1 γ C η−1 Y 1−η + α − 1 η−1 + C H∗ C η−1 Y −η , α α (K.9) which becomes gY = −1 + (1 − α)η + γ in steady state. Using these two simplified expressions for gC and gY , we can rewrite the FOC from (K.6): f 0 (Y )f (Y )−σ − χY ϕ = − gY −σ 1 − (1 − α)η − γ −σ C − χY ϕ = Y − χY ϕ = 0. gC (1 − η)(1 − α) − γ 54 (K.10) Using the implicit function theorem and solving for steady state Y yields: Y = 1 − τi χµε 1 σ+ϕ 1 − σ+ϕ 1 γ − 1 + (1 − α)η = χ γ − (1 − α)(1 − η) (K.11) γ−1+(1−α)η where the optimal tax rate for non-cooperative fiscal authorities is τi = 1 − µε γ−(1−α)(1−η) . As in the closed-form model, the optimal tax rate in a tax union will be τi = 1 − µε . 55