The cost of taxes Lecture 7 – academic year 2014/15 Introduction to Economics Fabio Landini The cost of taxes • Past classes: a tax on a good affects its price and quantity exchanged. • Moreover: buyers and sellers share in the tax burden in different ways. • The objective of this lecture is to answer the following question: what are the effects of a tax on the welfare of market participants? 2 Market equilibrium and allocative efficiency • A free market produces the quantity of goods that maximizes the total welfare(= consumer surplus + producer surplus). • When an allocation of resources maximizes the total welfare, we say that such allocation is economically efficient. 3 The costs of imposing taxes • When the government imposes a tax on a particular good, the equilibrium quantity of that good diminishes and its price increases. • The size of the market for that particular good decreases. • Therefore: in a perfectly competitive market, taxes have a cost in terms of diminished welfare experienced by individuals. 4 Market equilibrium in presence of a tax Price Consumer Price Tax levy (T x Q) Value of the tax (T) Supply Producer price Quantity sold (Q) 0 Q.ty with Q.ty without the tax the tax Demand Quantity 5 The costs of imposing taxes • The tax introduces a mark-up between the price paid by the consumer and the price earned by the producer. • The cost of the tax for consumers and producers exceeds the tax levy (earned by the government), generating a net loss. • The net loss is the reduction in total welfare caused by the introduction of a tax. 6 Consumer surplus: from A+B+C to A Price Price paid by consumer = PB Tax levy: from none to B+D Supply A B Total surplus (social welfare): from A+B+C+D+E+F to A+B+D+F C Price without tax = P1 E D Price earned by producer = PS Producer surplus: from D+E+F to F Net loss of social welfare: C+E F Demand 0 Q2 Q1 Quantity 7 Net loss: an example • At the current price of 0.50 € per unit, the quantity sold is 1.000 units. 8 Net loss: an example Price Supply 0.50 demand 0 1000 Quantity 9 Net loss: an example • The government introduces a tax of 0.20 € on the production of each unit of the good. The producers “collect” the tax and then they pay it back to the government. • Let’s assume the tax burden is shared equally – Consumers and producers pay 0.10 € each. – Remember: taxes are not necessarily paid only by those who are supposed to pay the government (previous lessons). • The higher price for consumers and the smaller price for producers translates into a smaller quantity that is exchanged in the market. 10 Net loss: an example Price Supply 0.60 0.50 0.40 Demand 0 800 1000 11 Quantity Net loss: an example • The tax impair both consumers and producers, so that the quantity exchanged diminishes of 200 units(= 1.000 - 800). • The area of the triangle included between the demand curve and the supply curve and delimited by the quantity exchanged is a measure of the net loss. • Example: = (0.10 x 200)/2 + (0.10 x 200)/2 = 20 €. • Tax levy= (0.60 - 0.40) x 800 = 160 12 Net loss: an example Price Tax levy = 160 Supply 0.60 Net loss of social welfare = 20 0.50 0.40 Decrease in Demand quantity = 200 0 800 1000 13 Quantity Effects of taxes • Taxes -> loss of welfare – They induce the market participants (producers and consumers) to change their behaviour. • Prices (PD, PS) change makes some some exchanges not profitable any more. – Higher price induces consumers to purchase less. – Lower price induces producers to produce less. • The size of the market reduces and becomes smaller than the optimal level. 14 Price Loss of exchange benefits P B Price without tax Supply Value of the tax P S Cost of supplier Value for consumer 0 Q2 Q1 Decrease in quantity due to the tax Demand Quantity 15 Why the net loss? • Even if the tax levy is redistributed entirely to producers and consumers, the fiscal revenue is not sufficient to compensate for the reduction in the volume of exchange due to the tax. 16 How big is the net loss? Theory • The size of the net loss depends on Q* caused by T. • At the same time: Q* depends on the price elasticity of demand and supply. – If price elasticity, then net loss. – If price elasticity, then net loss. 17 Effects of taxes and elasticity of supply (a) Inelastic supply Price (b) Elastic supply Price If the supply is elastic, the net loss is large Supply Value of the tax If the supply is inelastic, the net loss is small . Value of the tax Demand 0 Quantity Supply Demand 0 Quantity 18 Effects of taxes and elasticity of supply (c) Inelastic demand (d) Elastic demand Price Supply Value of the tax Price If the demand is inelastic, the net Value of the tax loss is small Demand 0 Quantity 0 Supply Demand If the demand is elastic, the net loss is large Quantity 19 How big is the net loss? Discussion • While it is easy to compute the value of taxes, it is not that easy to evaluate the net loss caused by the taxes. • Example: tax on labour: • For some workers the supply of labour is inelastic: – 40 years-old head of household wants to work full time, independently of the wage. – In this case, a tax on labour causes a relatively small net loss 20 How big is the net loss? Discussion • For other types of workers the supply is elastic. – Women, elderly people, students: react positively to monetary incentives. – In these cases, a tax on labour causes a relatively large net loss (smaller productivity, illegal work, early retirement). • In general: there are different opinions on the elasticity of labour supply. 21 State and the economy The debate on the net loss is not (only) an academic discussion. Different opinions on the elasticity and its effects often derive from different visions concerning the role of the State in the economy The tax on labour represent a large part of the tax levy in advanced countries. When people talk bout reducing such taxes, the question is: – Do we want to reduce taxes and public services? – Or do we want higher taxes and more public services? The answer depend on how we think the role of the State in the allocation of resources. 22 Net loss and fiscal revenue Following an increase in taxes, the fiscal revenue rapidly increases up to a maximum and, then, it diminishes. 23 Net loss and fiscal revenue Small tax Price Supply Net loss PB Fiscal revenue PS Demand 0 Q2Q1 Quantity 24 Net loss and fiscal revenue Medium tax Price Supply Net loss PB Fiscal revenue PS Demand 0 Q2 Q1 Quantity 25 Net loss and fiscal revenue Large tax Price Supply PB Net loss Demand PS 0 Q2 Q1 Quantity 26 Net loss (a) Net loss 0 Value of the tax Fiscal revenue (b) Revenue (Laffer’s curve) 0 Value of the tax 27 The theory of Laffer’s curve … Main idea: when taxes are too high they discourage production. • In the case of labour: if the tax on income is too high, it discourage the supply of work. • Smaller taxes create incentives to work more, increasing social welfare and fiscal revenue. Hence: it is better to reduce taxes! 28 …and the empirical evidence In the 1980 , Reagan (USA president) implemented a policy aimed at reducing taxes. However, the fiscal revenue decreased rather than increasing In the period 1980-84, disposable income: +4%, fiscal revenue: -9% Fiscal deficit. 29 …and the empirical evidence What does this result tell us? • The idea of Laffer can be correct if applied to tax payers subject to high tax rates. In the period 1980-84 the fiscal revenue produced by high income tax payers increased (more work, smaller evasion…) • The idea of Laffer can be correct if applied to countries with high tax rates. In Sweden during the 1980s the tax rate on high incomes was about the 80%, while in the USA was much smaller . 30 The debate… But then why there are countries with high tax rates and countries with low tax rates? It depends on how one evaluates the elasticity of some economic curves. In reality it is really complex to determine the real value of elasticity, and this creates a lack of consensus on this issues. Much depends on the preferences of citizens/voters… 31 The debate… In some countries (northern Europe), high tax rates are accepted because they create more resources to be redistributed through public services. This, in their view, compensate parts of the net loss. In other countries (USA), low tax rates and little redistribution are preferred because it is generally believed that poverty is not the result of unlucky events but rather the consequence of individual actions. Therefore the social expenditure is unfair (beyond a certain limit) and it does not compensate the net loss. 32 Conclusion • The reduction in the consumer surplus and producer surplus caused by taxes exceeds the the increase in fiscal revenue obtained by the public administration. Therefore, taxes produce a net loss. • The higher the tax rate, the higher the net loss. • The fiscal revenue first increase with the value of the tax; then, as the tax rate increases, the fiscal revenue starts to diminish following the reduction in the size of the market. • When the tax rate is very high, this can justify a tax cut so as to reduce the net loss. 33