Regional inequality in China

advertisement
Progress in Human Geography 23,1 (1999) pp. 49–59
Regional inequality in China
Yehua Dennis Wei
Department of Geography, University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee, Milwaukee, WI
523201, USA
Abstract: Regional inequality is one of the major subjects of research on China, and is a major
concern to the Chinese government. This article reviews the copious research on regional
inequality in China. It is proposed that recent research has significantly improved our understanding of regional inequality but that problems still exist. It is also argued that multiscale
studies and investigations of the various mechanisms that affect inequality will further improve
future research findings.
Key words: China, regional development, regional inequality.
I
Introduction
Regional inequality is an important aspect of academic inquiry and is one of the major
concerns facing governments as it may threaten national unity and social stability. The
trends and forces underlying regional inequality have been the subject of heated
debates (e.g., Myrdal, 1957; Borts and Stein, 1964; Williamson, 1965; Friedmann, 1966;
Coats et al., 1977; Alonso, 1980; Smith, 1984; Amos, 1990; Barrow and Sala-I-Martin,
1995). The issue is of particular importance to those developing countries that inherited
regional imbalances as a result of colonialism, and to the so-called ‘Marxist-Leninist’
states (Sidaway and Simon, 1990) that demanded as a point of ideology a reduction in
regional inequality (these will hereafter be referred to for the sake of simplicity as
socialist countries; for definitions of socialist countries, see Forbes and Thrift, 1987;
Sidaway and Simon, 1990). The questions of whether regional inequality was in fact
reduced in socialist countries and of whether economic reforms have in effect
intensified regional inequality have attracted considerable attention (e.g., Koropeckyj,
1972; Fuchs and Demko, 1979; Forbes and Thrift, 1987; Liebowitz, 1987; Ozornoy, 1991;
Smith, 1996). (For Marxist perspectives on regional inequality under socialism, see Peet,
1980.)
Several articles have reviewed the research on regional inequality in the former USSR
and eastern Europe (Fuchs and Demko, 1979; Bahry and Nechemias, 1981; Turnock,
1984; Schiffer, 1985) and the urban geography of China (Ma and Noble, 1986; Pannell,
© Arnold 1999
0309–1325(99)PH225RA
50
Regional inequality in China
1990; Yeung and Zhou, 1991; Ronnas and Sjoberg, 1993; Wei, 1995a; Yan 1995). However,
it is surprising there has so far been no evaluation of the debate over Chinese regional
inequality. This debate started in the 1970s (the Lardy–Donnithorne debate) and, since
the 1980s, it has received renewed interest as China’s reformers and conservatives have
battled over the pace and scope of economic reforms. This article reviews research on
regional inequality in China with a particular focus on regional income/economic
inequality. No attempt is made to review research on regional inequalities in social
services, on urban inequality and on rural inequality.
II
China’s regional inequality under Mao
Regional inequality has been an important issue in China since the establishment of the
People’s Republic of China (PRC) in 1949, mainly as a result of its role in debates
concerning the nature of socialism, central control and local autonomy, and resource
allocation among the regions (Bo, 1993; Fan, 1995a; Wei, 1997). When the PRC was
established, Chairman Mao Zedong and the Chinese Communist Party engaged
themselves with the problems of poverty and the substantial coastal–interior
imbalances in China. Influenced by socialist ideology and egalitarian ideas, Mao tried
to develop the backward inland areas and to reduce regional inequality. Indeed, the
appropriate allocation of resources to the regions has since become an important part of
China’s national planning (Wei, 1993a), and was one of the major components of
China’s First Five-Year-Plan (FYP) (1953–57). The interaction between the coast and the
interior was one of the ‘ten great relationships’ proposed by Mao (1956). In this he
stressed developing the interior without, at the same time, neglecting the coastal region.
Researchers generally agree that some effort was expended to develop economically
lagging regions but there is disagreement over the extent and consequences of this.
Most maintain that regional inequality declined as a result of the implementation of distributive policies, especially inter-regional resource transfers to interior regions through
centralized fiscal and investment systems (Lardy, 1975; 1978; 1980; Paine, 1981; Wu,
1987; Guo, 1988; Pannell, 1988; Yang, 1990). For example, Lardy (1975; 1978; 1980)
maintains that central control over financial resources and income redistribution among
the regions reduced regional inequality. In contrast, Donnithorne (1972; 1976) argues
that Mao’s policy of decentralization and self-reliance produced regional autarky and a
‘cellular economy’ that weakened the effectiveness of resource transfers and, as a result,
regional inequality continued to be pronounced for a long period of time. The
Lardy–Donnithorne debate represents two theoretical perspectives on China that have
evolved to the present day: the totalitarian approach and the fragmentation approach.
Others have argued that Chinese regional inequality persisted or even increased under
Mao as a result largely of regional autarky and localism, poor returns of interior
investment and an unfair price structure (Cole, 1987; Kueh, 1989; Cannon, 1990; Tsui,
1991; Yang, 1991a; Wei and Ma, 1996; Wei, 1997). Wei (1998a) shows that regional
inequality in industrial output declined during the 1950s but that it still persisted for
the next one-and-a-half decades.
With the availability of newly released regional statistics, publications in the 1990s
significantly improved our previous fragmented understandings of regional inequality.
These publications have provided overwhelming evidence to support the persistence or
Yehua Dennis Wei
51
widening of regional inequality under Mao. First, China’s coastal region possesses
better physical and human resources for development than does the interior and, historically, Chinese regional development has been extremely uneven – created partially
as a result of the penetration of colonial forces after the 1840s. Secondly, the need for
urban-centered industrialization and a national defense system limited the resources
that were available for the development of poor areas (Cannon, 1990; Jian et al., 1996;
Wei and Ma, 1996; Zhou, 1996; Ma and Wei, 1997). Thirdly, inefficiency in interior
investment has contributed significantly to the persistence of regional inequality. A
large amount of the capital that was invested in the interior was for defense purposes
under the ‘third front’ (san xian) program, which tied up great amounts of investment
and yielded poor economic results (Naughton, 1988; Linge and Forbes, 1990; Wei,
1995b; Ma and Wei, 1997). Fourthly, decentralization policies in the late 1950s and early
1970s facilitated, to a certain extent, localism, and they improved the economies of
coastal provinces. In the early 1970s, China’s development policy was reorientated
more toward the coastal region as a consequence of China gradually opening its door
to the outside world. Lastly, China, as other socialist countries (Kornai, 1992), was
troubled by political turmoil, social unrest and economic mismanagement. The interior
did not have the resources and favorable macroconditions for economic growth. In
short, the legacy of history, an uneven geographic distribution of resources, an
emphasis on industrialization and national defense, decentralization and policy
changes, and political and social unrest, have all contributed to the persistence of
regional inequality in China.
Some of the early writings on inequality were based on propaganda produced by the
Chinese government, and hence were unaware of what had really happened in China.
Publications since the 1980s, and especially since the 1990s, have used more reliable
data, so researchers are now able to investigate the issue of regional development more
critically and carefully. However, as is discussed in the next section, problems in
methodology have also contributed to differing views on inequality.
III
Regional inequality in post-Mao China
Since the launch of the economic reforms in 1978, China’s dominant development
policies have changed from being ones based on self-reliance to open-door policies and
policies of comparative advantages. Following the ‘ladder-step theory’ (tidu lilun) – a
Chinese version of the growth pole and inverted-U theories – the government
encouraged certain regions to ‘get rich quick’. It also emphasized the development of
coastal regions (Yang, 1991b; Fan, 1997; Wei, 1997). Hence China’s reform policies in the
1980s were very favorable to some coastal areas of the country.
After a short period of stagnation following the Tiananmen incident in 1989, the
1990s witnessed the implementation of bolder reforms aimed toward transforming
China into a socialist market economy. During the 1990s, some regions of China (particularly some coastal areas such as southern Jiangsu) recorded dramatic growth while
some interior areas were lagging far behind. Millions of rural workers migrated to
coastal cities in pursuit of employment, which generated considerable concern about
migration and urbanization policies and their impact. Regional ‘resource wars’ erupted
in many localities, in which regions used illegal administrative and military measures
52
Regional inequality in China
to protect their local markets and to restrict inter-regional resource flows (Wademan,
1995). Bargaining between central and local government over resource allocation and
development policies became extremely intense as a consequence of China’s poorer
areas considering themselves to be less favored by central government (Wong, 1991;
Wei, 1996). These problems – intensified by inflation and corruption – prompted many
to consider regional inequality a root cause of China’s regional problems and hence an
important issue in government policy (Fan, 1997; Wei, 1997). The Ninth FYP
(1996–2000) sees polarization as a serious threat to China’s prosperity, stability and
unity; it has therefore made reducing regional inequality a top policy priority.
Researchers disagree once more over whether regional inequality has intensified and
over the forces that have contributed to the change in regional inequality in post-Mao
China. Some maintain that economic reforms, especially coastal development strategies
and open-door policies, have stimulated the growth of coastal provinces and have
intensified regional inequality (Lakshmanan and Hua, 1987; Wu, 1987; Aguignier, 1988;
Kueh, 1989; Cannon, 1990; Yang, 1990; 1991a; Kato, 1992; Keresford and McFarlane,
1995; Chai, 1996). Government policy that favors the coast has often been blamed for
the rise of regional gaps and conflicts. Researchers have argued that more resources
should be committed to the development of the poorer interior regions to reduce
regional inequality.
However, not all authors have embraced the notion that regional inequality has
widened in the post-Mao period. They argue instead that regional inequality has
actually declined since the initiation of economic reforms, mainly as a result of
diffusion, inter-regional resource transfer and rural industrialization (Pannell, 1988;
Denny, 1991; Lyons, 1991; Tsui, 1991; Huo, 1994; Chen and Fleisher, 1996; Jian et al.,
1996). Denny (1991), for example, argues that economic reforms and trickle-down
effects have stimulated the rapid growth of the poorer regions (his account of the
diffusion of foreign investment to the interior, however, is overstated). The reduction of
interprovincial inequality, however, is mainly due to the declining status of China’s
traditional industrial bases (especially Shanghai and Liaoning) and the emergence of
the coastal provinces of Guangdong, Fujian, Zhejiang, Jiangsu and Shandong (Fan,
1995a; Wei and Ma, 1996; Wei, 1997; 1998a).
This debate is also intense in the Chinese literature. Influenced by the growth pole
and inverted-U theories, some consider that widening regional gaps are inevitable
because China should pursue the goal of economic efficiency, and that diffusion would
facilitate the development of poorer regions and would reduce regional inequality (Lu,
1991; Wei, 1992). These ideas were largely reflected in China’s official view of regional
development in the 1980s. Some researchers have shown a trend toward regional
convergence (Liu et al., 1994; Yang, 1994); others argue that economic reforms have not
intensified regional inequality but have generated economic prosperity and opportunities for all; they defend uneven development policies and argue for the continuation of
coast-orientated development (Yang, 1992). Still others suggest there has been a
dramatic increase in regional inequality and they argue for a shift of policy emphasis
from the coast to the interior (Chen et al., 1993; Hu and Kang, 1995). This view had some
impact on China’s regional policy in the mid-1990s, as reflected in the Ninth FYP
(1995–2000). But what roles the government will play in regional development and how
many resources will be committed to developing the interior remain questions to be
answered.
Yehua Dennis Wei
53
Empirical studies of regional inequality have long been troubled by problems of
methodology. First, regional inequality is sensitive to geographical scale (Gore, 1984).
The well-known modified areal unit problem points to the fact that regional analysis
depends on geographical scale. Regional inequality may increase at one scale but may
decrease at another. In other words, different geographical scales of observation may
lead to controversial findings. Secondly, the methods adopted to measure regional
inequality also affect the findings. Absolute measures (e.g., standard deviation) and
relative measures (e.g., coefficient of variation, the Gini index) often lead to dramatically different results. Lastly, regional inequalities in income, industrial production and
social services may differ greatly. These problems are well documented but they still
trouble researchers.
The discourse surrounding China’s regional inequality suffers from methodological
problems. First, the scale of observation has created much confusion as the patterns of
change in the nation’s macrogeographical regions (coastal versus interior regions, or
eastern, central and western regions) are different from those in the provinces (Wei and
Ma, 1996). Secondly, the lack of reliable time-series regional data on social and
economic development is perhaps the most important factor contributing to the diverse
findings. Publications before the mid-1990s used only very limited data – even those of
Lyons (1991) and Tsui (1991). These studies showed systematically and for the first time
the trend of regional inequality in China from the 1950s to the 1980s, but their
conclusions are difficult to compare because of data constraints and differences in geographical units. Thirdly, fewer studies have been undertaken to explain the forces
responsible for regional inequality (Tang et al., 1993; Wei and Fan, 1997). Some progress
has been made in understanding the politics of central control and local autonomy (for
a review of China’s central–local relations, see Goodman, 1989; Chung, 1995), local
state corporatism (e.g., Oi, 1992), market transition and income distribution (e.g., Nee,
1989) and foreign direct investment (e.g., Leung, 1993), but this has not been incorporated sufficiently into research on regional inequality. Lastly, the implications of
analyses are often misinterpreted, due largely to a limited understanding of regional
development theories and the difference in geographical scale. Policy options are often
based on findings from one geographical scale, which may not be applicable to other
scales.
IV
Multiscale approaches and multi-mechanisms: a new direction
The studies published in the mid-1990s used more comprehensive data than those
published previously, and adopted a multiscale approach to improving our understanding of China’s regional inequality. Inequality at the inter-regional scale across
China’s eastern, central and western regions differs from inequality at the interprovincial scale across the provinces. Analysts and the Chinese government have used
both these scales, but only a few researchers are sensitive to the issue of geographical
scale and have hence differentiated among the patterns that emerge when using
different scales (e.g., Fan, 1995a; Wei and Ma, 1996; Zhao, 1996; Wei, 1993b; 1997; 1998a).
It has been found that inter-regional inequality rose during both Mao’s era and the
reform period; interprovincial inequality, however, rose under Mao but declined during
the period of reform. As in east European countries (Smith, 1996), a complex mosaic of
54
Regional inequality in China
regional development has emerged, and scale seems to be an important feature when
considering regional inequality in China.
Economic reforms, particularly coastal development strategies and open-door
policies, have contributed to the rapid growth of the coastal region while the interior
has lagged behind. The rapid growth, in particular, of the coastal provinces of
Guangdong, Jiangsu, Zhejiang, Fujian and Shandong has contributed greatly to the
development of the coast as a whole. These provinces have been favored by state policy
and global investors; local initiatives and favorable local conditions have also
contributed to their dramatic growth (Wei, 1997). Global, state and local forces, rather
than state policy alone, have influenced the changing inequality in the regions of China.
In addition, the growth rates of the traditionally richest provinces (including
Shanghai, Beijing and Liaoning) that found favor under Mao’s industrialization policy
were among the lowest during much of the reform period. This is largely the result of
strict central control, the late opening up of China to foreign investment, the dominance
of state-owned enterprises and an overburdened urban infrastructure (Tian, 1996; Wei,
1998b). The slow growth of these provinces has also led to a decline of interprovincial
inequality in post-Mao China. Thus, regional inequality in post-Mao China cannot be
described simply as either convergence or divergence; it is related to geographical scale.
In addition, the trend in regional inequality for the last four and half decades shows no
clear divergent, convergent, inverted-U or cyclical patterns.
Three major geographical scales have been adopted for the analysis of China: interregional, interprovincial and intraprovincial. The inter-regional and interprovincial
scales are the most important to many researchers and government organizations as
these are the focus of regional problems and government policies. But substantial
inequalities also exist within the provinces, and hence the level of analysis at an
intraprovincial scale improves our understanding of the detailed local processes that
shape uneven development (Fan, 1995a; Wei and Fan, 1997). In other words, a
multiscale approach is fundamental when studying regional inequality in China, and
we should not exaggerate or ignore the significance of any one dimension of inequality
(Wei, 1997).
Within a specific province, inter-regional and intercounty inequalities differ
dramatically. While researchers have focused on intercounty inequality, the patterns
of change among countries also vary significantly. Fan (1995a) shows that, between
1982 and 1990, intercounty inequality increased enormously in Guangdong,
remained about the same in Fujian and declined in Zhejiang, Anhui and Hunan. She
attributes the increase in Guangdong to preferential government policies and foreign
investment.
Among China’s provinces, Jiangsu has attracted considerable attention. Rozelle
(1994) has found that rural intercounty inequality increased between 1984 and 1989,
while Fan (1995b) – based on all county-level units – argues that intercounty inequality
declined between 1982 and 1990 and that township and village enterprises (as major
forces of regional development) have contributed to the trend of balanced
development. Studies by Wei (1997) and Wei and Fan (1997) show that intercounty
inequality (based on all county-level units) declined during the post-Mao period, while
the north–south divide in Jiangsu has been intensified. They argue that the interplay of
the three dominant forces – state policy, foreign investment and local initiative – is
critical to an understanding of regional inequality in Jiangsu. In short, multiscale and
Yehua Dennis Wei
55
multi-mechanism approaches can improve our understanding of the complexity of
regional inequality in provincial China.
The multi-mechanism approach may have captured the fundamental features of the
Chinese transitional economy (Wei, 1997; Wei and Fan, 1997). Since the launch of
reforms in 1978, China has experienced profound changes: while the state still plays an
important role, its control of the nation’s economy and its capacity to control the
nation’s economy have been steadily declining. Meanwhile, specific localities and
global investors have emerged as important agents in shaping China’s regional
development as a consequence of global restructuring and China’s economic reforms
(which emphasize decentralization, marketization and globalization – an open-door
policy). The three dominant agents – the central state, the locality and the global
investor – act simultaneously and interactively to shape regional inequality. This
conceptual framework seems to be in line with recent geographical research that has
identified the world economy, the nation-state and specific localities as critical to geographical inquiry (Brown, 1991; Taylor, 1993; Agnew and Corbridge, 1995). Wei (1997)
argues that this framework can be extended to the study of regional inequality in other
transition economies that are similarly undergoing processes of decentralization, marketization and globalization, and it may also prove to be useful for other developing
countries that are experiencing similar processes.
V
Conclusion
Regional inequality has been a major concern of the Chinese government and is an
important issue for academic inquiry. Earlier research on Mao’s China was largely
based on fragmented and unreliable data. With the opening up of China to the outside
world and the availability of regional statistics, researchers are now equipped with
better data sources. Recent efforts have significantly improved our understanding of
China’s regional inequality, although problems with methodology have thrown doubt
on some of the findings. Multiscale and multi-mechanism approaches may also
improve our understanding of regional inequality in China.
Economic reforms and dramatic changes in China have provided researchers with
further opportunities for study. China’s importance in geographical inquiry will rise
even further now that China and the Asia-Pacific region are playing an increasingly
important role in the global economy. Research on China’s regional inequality tends to
be empirically orientated, and more efforts should be made (including those by
systematic geographers) to develop theories that will improve our understanding of
China’s regional development. Moreover, China’s experience with regional
development can be used to test theories, and it can also provide some useful reference
points for other developing countries and transition economies. Comparative studies of
China with economies such as these (e.g., Russia and India) are needed in order to
improve our understanding of how globalization, the nation-state and local initiatives
shape the dynamics of regional inequality.
Future research should analyze further the impact of economic reforms, international investment and trade, as well as local states and agents, in shaping China’s regional
development. As investment is a particularly important factor of the Chinese
government’s production and investment policy, more work is needed to identify
56
Regional inequality in China
investment processes and patterns. China is also experiencing a transition from state
socialism to market socialism in which markets and nonstate enterprises are playing an
emerging role. The impact of liberalization and ownership transformation on regional
inequality also merits further investigation. While recent research has greatly improved
our understanding of regional income inequality, inequalities in consumption,
education and healthcare have attracted much less attention. Moreover, China’s
provinces differ greatly, and substantial inequality exists between them. More attention
should be paid to the crucial discrepancies experienced in these diverse regions
(Solinger, 1996), although intraprovincial data are often limited. Last but not least, the
policy implications of research should be welcomed.
Acknowledgements
I would like to thank Larry Ma, Cindy Fan and the anonymous referees for constructive
comments on this article.
References
Agnew, J. and Corbridge, S. 1995: Mastering
space. New York: Routledge.
Aguignier, P. 1988: Regional disparities since
1978. In Feuchtwang, S., Hussain, A. and
Pairault, T., editors, Transforming China’s
economy in the eighties. Vol. 2, Boulder, CO:
Westview Press, 93–106.
Alonso, W. 1980: Five bell shapes in
development. Papers of the Regional Science
Association 45, 5–16.
Amos, O.M. Jr 1990: Growth pole cycles. Review
of Regional Studies 20, 37–48.
Bahry, D. and Nechemias, C. 1981: Half full or
half empty? The debate over Soviet regional
inequality. Slavic Review 40, 366–83.
Barro, R. and Sala-I-Martin, X. 1995: Economic
growth. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Beresford, M. and McFarlane, B. 1995: Regional
inequality and regionalism in Vietnam and
China. Journal of Contemporary Asia 25, 50–72.
Bo, Y. 1993: Ruogang zhongda juace yu shijian de
huigu (Reflections of some important decisions and
events). Beijing: Central School of the Chinese
Communist Party Press.
Borts, G.H. and Stein, J.L. 1964: Economic growth
in a free market. New York: Columbia University
Press.
Brown, L.A. 1991: Place, migration and development
in the third world. New York: Routledge.
Cannon, T. 1990: Regions. In Cannon, T. and
Jenkins, A., editors, The geography of con-
temporary China, London: Routledge, 28–60.
Chai, J. 1996: Divergent development and
regional income gap in China. Journal of
Contemporary Asia 26, 46–58.
Chen, J. and Fleisher , B.M. 1996: Regional
income inequality and economic growth in
China. Journal of Comparative Economics 22,
141–64.
Chen, W ., Wu, C. and Zhang, W . 1993:
Characters and trends of China’s regional
economic inequality. Jingji dili (Economic
Geography) 13, 16–21.
Chung, J.H. 1995: Studies of central-provincial
relations in the People’s Republic of China.
China Quarterly 142, 487–508.
Coates, B.E., Johnston, R.J. and Knox, P.L. 1977:
Geography and inequality. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Cole, J.P. 1987: Regional inequalities in the
People’s Republic of China. Fijdschrift voor
Economische en Sociale Geografie 78, 2011–13.
Denny, D.L. 1991: Regional economic differences
during the decade of reform. In Joint Economic
Committee, Congress of the United States,
editor, China’s economic dilemmas in the 1990s,
Washington, DC: US Government Printing
Office, 186–208.
Donnithorne, A. 1972: China’s cellular economy.
China Quarterly 52, 605–19.
––––– 1976: Centralization and decentralization in
China’s fiscal management. China Quarterly 66,
328–54.
Yehua Dennis Wei
Fan, C.C. 1995a: Of belts and ladders: state policy
and uneven regional development in post-Mao
China. Annals of the Association of American
Geographers 85, 421–49.
––––– 1995b: Development from above, below
and outside: spatial impacts of China’s
economic reforms in Jiangsu and Guangdong
provinces. Chinese Environment and Development
61, 85–116.
––––– 1997: Uneven development and beyond.
International Journal of Urban and Regional
Research 21, 620–39.
Forbes, D. and Thrift, N. 1987: The socialist third
world. New York: Blackwell.
Friedmann, J. 1966: Regional development policy.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Fuchs, R.J. and Demko, G.J. 1979: Geographic
inequality under socialism. Annals of the
Association of American Geographers 69,
304–18.
Goodman, D.S.G. 1989: Political perspectives. In
Goodman, D.S.G., editor, China’s regional
development, London: Routledge, 20–37.
Gore, C. 1984: Regions in question. New York:
Methuen.
Guo, W . 1988: The transformation of China’s
regional policy. Development Policy Review 6,
29–50.
Hu, A. and Kang, X. 1995: Zhongguo diqu chayi
baogao (Report on regional inequality in China).
Shenyang: Liaoning People’s Press.
Huo, S. 1994: Regional inequality variations and
central government policy, 1978–1988. In Hao,
J. and Lin, Z., editors, Changing central–local
relations in China, Boulder, CO: Westview Press,
182–206.
Jian, T., Sachs, F.D. and Warner, A.M. 1996:
Trends in regional inequality in China. China
Economic Review 7, 1–21.
Kato, H. 1992: Regional development in the
reform period. In Garnaut, R., Liu, G., editors,
Economic reform and internationalization,
London: Allen & Unwin, 116–36.
Kornai, J. 1992: The socialist system. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Koropeckyj, I.S. 1972: Equalization of regional
development in socialist countries. Economic
Development and Cultural Change 21, 68–86.
Kueh, Y.Y. 1989: The Maoist legacy and China’s
new industrialization strategy. China Quarterly
119, 420–47.
Lakshmanan, T.R. and Hua, C. 1987: Regional
57
disparities in China. International Regional
Science Review 11, 97–104.
Lardy, N.R. 1975: Centralization and decentralization in China’s fiscal management. China
Quarterly 61, 23–60.
––––– 1978: Economic growth and distribution in
China. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
––––– 1980: Regional growth and income distribution in China. In Dernberger, R.F., editor,
China’s development experience in comparative
perspective,
Cambridge,
MA:
Harvard
University Press, 153–90.
Leung, C.K. 1993: Personal contacts, subcontracting linkages, and development in the
Hong Kong–Zhujiang Delta region. Annals of
the Association of American Geographers 83,
272–302.
Liebowitz, R.D. 1987: Soviet investment strategy.
Annals of the Association of American Geographers
77, 396–407.
Linge, G.J.R. and Forbes, D.K. 1990: The space
economy of China. In Linge, G.J.R. and Forbes,
D.K., editors, China’s spatial economy, New York:
Oxford University Press, 35–58.
Liu, X., Li, Q. and Hsueh, T. 1994: Zhongguo diqu
jingji fazhan yanjiu (China’s regional economic
development studies). Beijing: Chinese Statistics
Press.
Lu, D. 1991: Geography and regional
development studies. Dili kexue (Geographical
Science) 3, 197–205.
Lyons, T.P. 1991: Interprovincial disparities in
China. Economic Development and Cultural
Change 39, 471–506.
Ma, L.J.C. and Noble, A.G. 1986: Chinese cities.
Urban Geography 7, 279–90.
Ma, L.J.C. and Wei, Y. 1997: Determinants of state
investment in China, 1953–1990. Tijdschrift voor
Economische en Sociale Geografie 88, 211–25.
Mao, Z. 1956: On the ten great relationships.
In Selected works of Mao Tsetung. Vol. 5
(1977), Beijing: Foreign Language Publishers,
61–83.
Myrdal, G. 1957: Economic theory and underdeveloped regions. London: Duckworth.
Naughton, B. 1988: The third front. China
Quarterly 155, 351–86.
Nee, V. 1989: A theory of market transition.
American Sociological Review 54, 267–82.
Oi, J.C. 1992: Fiscal reform and economic
foundations of local state corporatism in China.
World Politics 45, 99–126.
Ozornoy, G.L. 1991: Some issues of regional
58
Regional inequality in China
inequality in the USSR under Gorbachev.
Regional Studies 25, 381–93.
Paine, S. 1981: Spatial aspects of Chinese
development. Journal of Development Studies 17,
132–95.
Pannell, C.W . 1988: Regional shifts in China’s
industrial output. Professional Geographer 40,
19–32.
––––– 1990: China’s urban geography. Progress in
Human Geography 14, 214–36.
Peet, R. 1980: Commentary on ‘geographic
inequality under socialism’. Annals of the
Association of American Geographers 70, 280–86.
Rozelle, S. 1994: Rural industrialization and
increasing inequality. Journal of Comparative
Economics 19, 362–91.
Ronnas, P. and Sjoberg, O. 1993: Urbanization,
central planning and Tolley’s model of urban
growth. Geoforum 24, 193–204.
Schiffer, J.R. 1985: Interpretations of the issue of
‘inequality’ in Soviet regional policy debates.
International Journal of Urban and Regional
Research 9, 508–32.
Sidaway, J.D. and Simon, D. 1990: Spatial
policies and uneven development in the
‘Marxist-Leninist’ states of the third world. In
Simon, D., editor, Third world regional
development, London: Paul Chapman, 24–38.
Smith, A. 1996: From convergence to fragmentation: uneven regional development, industrial
restructuring, and the ‘transition to capitalism’
in Slovakia. Environment and Planning A 28,
136–56.
Smith, N. 1984: Uneven development. London:
Blackwell.
Solinger , D.J. 1996: Despite decentralization.
China Quarterly 145, 1–34.
Tang, W., Chu, D. and Fan, C.C. 1993: Economic
reform and regional development in China in
the 21st century. In Yeung, Y.M., editor, Pacific
Asia in the 21st century, Hong Kong: Chinese
University Press, 105–33.
Taylor, P.J. 1993: Political geography. Harlow:
Longman.
Tian, G. 1996: Shanghai’s role in the economic
development of China. Westport, CT: Praeger.
Tsui, K.Y. 1991: China’s regional inequality,
1952–1985. Journal of Comparative Economics 15,
1–21.
Turnock, D. 1984: Postwar studies on the human
geography of eastern Europe. Progress in
Human Geography 8, 315–46.
Wademan, A.H. 1995: Bamboo walls and brick
ramparts. PhD dissertation, Department of
Political Science, University of California at Los
Angeles.
Wei, H. 1992: The change of regional income
inequality in China. Jingji yanjiu (Economic
Research) 4, 61–65.
Wei, Y. 1993a: Regional development studies in
China: major subjects and recent progress. Jingji
dili (Economic Geography) 13, 1–7.
––––– 1993b: Changing patterns of regional
inequalities in China, 1952–90. MA thesis,
Department of Geography, University of
Akron.
––––– 1995a: Chinese cities: a review and a
research agenda. Asian Geographer 14, 1–13.
––––– 1995b: Spatial and temporal variations of
the relationship between state investment and
industrial output in China. Tijdschrift voor
Economische en Sociale Geografie 86, 129–36.
––––– 1996: Fiscal systems and uneven regional
development in China, 1978–1991. Geoforum 27,
329–44.
––––– 1997: Patterns of regional inequality in
China: globalization, the state, and localities.
PhD dissertation, Department of Geography,
University of California at Los Angeles.
––––– 1998a: Regional inequality of industrial
output in China, 1952 to 1990. Geografiska
Annaler B 80, 1–15.
––––– 1998b: Economic reforms and regional
development in coastal China. Journal of
Contemporary Asia (in press).
Wei, Y. and Fan, C.C. 1997: Intraprovincial
inequality in China: a case study of Jiangsu.
Paper presented at the annual meeting of the
Association of American Geographers, Fort
Worth, Texas, 1–5 April.
Wei, Y. and Ma, L.J.C. 1996: Changing patterns of
spatial inequality in China. Third World
Planning Review 18, 177–91.
Williamson, J.G. 1965: Regional inequality and
the process of national development. Economic
Development and Cultural Change 13, 3–83.
Wong, C.P.W . 1991: Central–local relations in an
era of fiscal decline. China Quarterly 128,
691–715.
Wu, C.T. 1987: Chinese socialism and uneven
development. In Forbes, D. and Thrift, N.,
editors, The socialist third world, New York:
Blackwell, 53–97.
Yan, X. 1995: Chinese urban geography since the
late 1970s. Urban Geography 16, 469–92.
Yang, D. 1990: Patterns of China’s regional
development strategy. China Quarterly 122,
230–57.
Yehua Dennis Wei
––––– 1991a: Reforms, resources, and regional
cleavages. Issues and Studies 27, 43–69.
––––– 1991b: China adjusts to the world economy.
Pacific Affairs 64, 42–64.
Yang, K. 1994: The change of regional economic
inequality in China. Jingji yanjiu (Economic
Research) 12, 28–33.
Yang, W. 1992: An empirical analysis of the
change of regional income inequality. Jingji
yanjiu (Economic Research) 1, 70–74.
59
Yeung, Y.M. and Zhou, Y. 1991: Human
geography in China. Progress in Human
Geography 15, 373–94.
Zhao, X. 1996: Spatial disparities and economic
development in China, 1953–92. Development
and Change 27, 131–63.
Zhou, Q. 1996: Interprovincial resource transfers
in China, 1952–90. International Journal of Urban
and Regional Research 20, 571–86.
Download