OPEN UNIVERSITY OF TANZANIA Direct Line: +255 22 2668820 General Line +255 22 2668992 Ext. 142 Fax: 255-22-2668759 E-mail: dfstes@out.ac.tz Kawawa Road P.O. Box 23409 Dar es Salaam, Tanzania http://www.out.ac.tz FACULTY OF SCIENCE TECHNOLOGY AND ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES DEPARTMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL STUDIES OEV 210 ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICS Extended Course Outline BY NGARUKO D.D.P (PhD) Centre for Economics and Community Economic Development The Open University of Tanzania 2009 i TABLE OF CONTENTS TABLE OF CONTENTS ............................................................................................................ i ABSTRACT ............................................................................................................................ vii COURSE DESCRIPTION ...................................................................................................... viii LECTURE ONE ........................................................................................................................ 1 INTRODUCTION TO ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICS...................................................... 1 1.1. What is Environmental Economics?.............................................................................. 1 1.2 Why do we use economics in environmental policy? ........................................................ 1 1.3 Why Study Environmental Economics? ......................................................................... 2 1.4 Key questions for environmental economics .................................................................. 2 1.5 Introduction to the theory of economics ............................................................................ 3 1.5.1 Definition of Economics ............................................................................................ 3 1.5.2 Microeconomics and Macroeconomics ...................................................................... 3 1.5.3 The Problem of Scarcity and Choice .......................................................................... 4 1.5.4 Choice and Opportunity Cost ..................................................................................... 5 1.5.5 Functions of Economic Systems................................................................................. 5 LECTURE TWO........................................................................................................................ 8 THE THEORY OF DEMAND................................................................................................... 8 2.1 Introduction ...................................................................................................................... 8 2.2 Demand Theory................................................................................................................ 8 2.2.1 Determinants of Quantity Demanded ......................................................................... 8 2.2.2 Demand Function....................................................................................................... 9 2.2.3 Demand Schedule ...................................................................................................... 9 2.2.4 Demand Curve......................................................................................................... 10 2.2.5 Market Demand ....................................................................................................... 10 2.3 Factors leading to the violation of the law of demand ..................................................... 12 2.4 Change in Quantity Demanded and Change in Demand ................................................. 12 2.5 Types of Demand ........................................................................................................... 13 LECTURE THREE .................................................................................................................. 15 THE THEORY OF SUPPLY AND EQUILIBRIUM PRICE.................................................... 15 3.1 Introduction .................................................................................................................... 15 3.2 Determinants of Quantity Supplied ................................................................................. 15 3.3 Supply Function ............................................................................................................. 16 3.4 Market Supply ................................................................................................................ 16 3.4.1 Supply Schedule ...................................................................................................... 17 3.4.2 Supply Curve ........................................................................................................... 17 3.4.3 Changes in Quantity Supplied and Change in Supply ............................................... 18 3.5 Price Determination and Market Equilibrium................................................................. 18 3.6 Changes in equilibrium price .......................................................................................... 19 LECTURE FOUR .................................................................................................................... 21 ELASTICITY OF DEMAND AND SUPPLY .......................................................................... 21 4.1 Introductions .................................................................................................................. 21 4.2 Elasticity of Demand ...................................................................................................... 21 4.2.1 Price Elasticity of Demand (η)................................................................................. 21 4.2.2 How to Interpret Price Elasticity of Demand ............................................................ 22 ii 4.2.3 Determinants of Price Elasticity of Demand............................................................. 23 4.2.4 Income Elasticity of Demand (ηY ) ......................................................................... 24 2.2.5 Interpretation of Income Elasticity of Demand ......................................................... 24 4.2.6 Importance of Income elasticity of Demand ............................................................. 25 4.2.7 Cross Elasticity of Demand (ηC) ............................................................................. 25 4.2.8 Interpretation of Cross Elasticity of Demand............................................................ 26 4.3 Elasticity of Supply (ε) ................................................................................................... 26 4.3.1 Interpretation of Price Elasticity of Supply............................................................... 26 4.3.2 Determinants of Price Elasticity of Supply............................................................... 27 4.3.3 Point Elasticity and Arc Elasticity............................................................................ 28 LECTURE FIVE...................................................................................................................... 30 FUNDAMENTAL ECONOMIC CONCEPTS FOR ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY ANALYSIS ................................................................................................................................................. 30 5.1 Introduction ................................................................................................................. 30 5.2 Marginal analysis ........................................................................................................... 30 5.3 Sunk costs ..................................................................................................................... 31 5.4 Opportunity costs ........................................................................................................... 31 5.5 Scarcity: The Key Problem in Economics ....................................................................... 31 5.6 Positive Economics Vs Normative Economics................................................................ 31 5.7 Models of Scarcity: The Key Problem in Economics ................................................... 32 5.7.1 Malthus Model: because land is fixed, scarcity is inevitable..................................... 32 5.7.2 IPAT : Devised by biologist Paul Ehrlich in 1971 .................................................... 32 5.7.3 Doomsday Models: computer models that predicted severe shortages of resources .. 32 5.7.4 Lomborg Model: pessimistic predictions get more attention than reality .................. 33 LECTURE SIX ........................................................................................................................ 34 MARKET STRUCTURES....................................................................................................... 34 6.1 Introduction .................................................................................................................... 34 6.2 Perfect competition......................................................................................................... 34 6.2.1 Advantages of Perfect Competition.......................................................................... 35 6.2.2 Disadvantages of Perfect Competition...................................................................... 35 6.3 Monopoly....................................................................................................................... 35 6.3.1 Factors leading to Monopoly.................................................................................... 36 6.3.2 Examples of Monopolies in Tanzania (as of 2004) ................................................... 36 6.3.3 Advantages of Monopoly ......................................................................................... 37 6.3.4 Disadvantages of Monopoly..................................................................................... 37 6.3.5 Measures to Control Monopoly................................................................................ 37 6.4 Price Discrimination under Monopoly ............................................................................ 38 6.4.1 Advantages of Price Discrimination ......................................................................... 38 6.5 Monopolistic competition ............................................................................................... 39 6.5.1 Advantages of Monopolistic Competition ................................................................ 39 6.5.2 Disadvantages of Monopolistic Competition ............................................................ 39 6.6 Oligopoly ....................................................................................................................... 39 6.6.1 Examples of Oligopolies in Tanzania:...................................................................... 40 LECTURE SEVEN .................................................................................................................. 41 MARKET FAILURES FOR ENVIRONMENTAL RESOURCES ........................................... 41 7.1 Introduction .................................................................................................................... 41 7.2 The Invisible Hand ...................................................................................................... 41 7.3 Categories (Causes) of market failures............................................................................ 42 iii 7.3.1 Common property resources are one category of market failure. .............................. 42 7.3.2 Externalities are another class of market failure ....................................................... 44 7.3.3 Public Commodities................................................................................................. 46 7.3.4 Excess Market power (monopoly and oligopoly)..................................................... 47 7.3.5 Lack of markets ....................................................................................................... 48 7.3.6 Distortions in capital markets................................................................................... 49 7.3.7 Imperfect Information ............................................................................................ 49 LECTURE EIGHT................................................................................................................... 51 VALUING ENVIRONMENTAL BENEFITS.......................................................................... 51 8.1 Introduction .................................................................................................................... 51 8.2 Concepts of the value of a life......................................................................................... 51 8.3 Revealed Preference Approaches (RPA) ..................................................................... 52 8.3.1 Aversion Costs....................................................................................................... 53 8.3.2 Travel Cost Method .............................................................................................. 53 8.3.3 Hedonic Pricing Techniques .................................................................................... 54 8.4 Stated Preference Approaches (SPA): Contingent Valuation........................................... 54 LECTURE NINE ..................................................................................................................... 56 COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS OF ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY........................................... 56 9.1 Introduction to Cost-Benefit Analysis (CBA)............................................................... 56 9.2 Steps to cost-benefit analysis .................................................................................... 56 9.3 Dealing with Uncertainty................................................................................................ 56 9.4 Discounting methods ...................................................................................................... 59 9.4.1 Discount rate, r ........................................................................................................ 59 9.4.2 Social discount rate.................................................................................................. 60 9.5 Concepts of Cost.......................................................................................................... 61 9.5.1 Important concerns on how costs will be conceptualized.......................................... 61 9.5.2 Broad categories of costs ......................................................................................... 61 9.5.3 Estimating Costs ...................................................................................................... 62 9.5.4 How Accurate are Cost Estimates?........................................................................... 63 LECTURE TEN....................................................................................................................... 65 NATIONAL INCOME............................................................................................................. 65 10.1 Introduction .................................................................................................................. 65 10.2 National Income Accounting ........................................................................................ 65 10.3 Uses of National Income accounts ................................................................................ 65 10.4 Measurement of national Product.................................................................................. 66 10.5 Expenditure Approach to GNP ..................................................................................... 67 10.6 Income Approach to GNP............................................................................................. 68 10.7 Other Social Accounts .................................................................................................. 69 10.8 GNP, Expenditure and National Income ....................................................................... 69 LECTURE ELEVEN ............................................................................................................... 73 ECONOMIC GROWTH AND THE ENVIRONMENT ........................................................... 73 11.1 Introduction ............................................................................................................... 73 11.2 The fundamental issues of environment in GDP............................................................ 73 11.3 How Does the Environment Affect the Economy ....................................................... 74 11.4 Income and the Environment: Case study of the environment in East Asia.................... 75 11.4.1 History of Japan’s environmental policy ................................................................ 75 11.4.2 History of environmental policy in South Korea..................................................... 76 iv 11.4.3 History of environmental policy in China............................................................... 76 11.4.4 Convergence of environmental policy .................................................................... 76 11.4.5 Differences ............................................................................................................ 76 11.5 The Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC) .................................................................... 77 11.5.1 Theoretical requirements for EKC.......................................................................... 78 11.5.2 Implications of the EKC......................................................................................... 79 LECTURE TWELVE .............................................................................................................. 80 THE ENVIRONMENT IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES ....................................................... 80 12.1 Introduction .................................................................................................................. 80 12.2 Causes of environmental problems in developing countries .......................................... 81 12.3 Access to clean water in LDCs...................................................................................... 81 12.4 Air pollution in LDCs ................................................................................................... 82 12.5 Timber and deforestation in LDCs ................................................................................ 82 12.5.1 Reasons why deforestation is a problem................................................................. 83 12.6 Resource management .................................................................................................. 84 12.7 Agriculture in LDCs ..................................................................................................... 84 12.7.1 Costs of increased agricultural productivity............................................................ 85 12.7.2 Can biotechnology be a solution?........................................................................... 85 LECTURE THIRTEEN ........................................................................................................... 87 SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT ......................................................................................... 87 13.1 Introduction .................................................................................................................. 87 13.2 Definition of environmentally sustainable development .............................................. 87 13.3 Neoclassical vs. ecological economics .......................................................................... 88 13.4 How to Incorporate the Environment in Economic Analysis ...................................... 89 13.5 How should Green GDP be measured? ......................................................................... 90 13.5.1 Principles to measuring green GDP........................................................................ 90 13.6 Will Sustainable Development Occur in Market Economies?..................................... 91 13.7 Audits for resource-rich countries ................................................................................. 93 LECTURE FOURTEEN .......................................................................................................... 94 INTERNATIONAL TRADE, TRADE AGGREEMENTS AND THE ENVIRONMENT ........ 94 14.1 Introduction .................................................................................................................. 94 14.2 Critical Reasons for International Trade........................................................................ 94 14.3 Theories explaining basis for international trade ........................................................... 96 14.3.1 Mercantilism......................................................................................................... 96 14.3.2 Absolute Advantage Principle ................................................................................ 96 14.3.3 The Law of Comparative Advantage...................................................................... 97 14.4 Criticisms of the Law of Comparative Advantage ......................................................... 98 14.5 Pollution Haven Hypothesis.......................................................................................... 99 14.6 International Agreements: GATT.................................................................................102 14.7 Climate Change and International Agreements ............................................................103 14.8 Lessons for design of global agreement .......................................................................104 14.9 The Montreal Protocol .................................................................................................104 LECTURE FIFTEEN ..............................................................................................................106 EXHAUSTIBLE RESOURCES..............................................................................................106 15.1 Introduction .................................................................................................................106 15.2 Quantification of exhaustible reserve resources............................................................106 15.3 Principles for understanding exhaustible resource problems.........................................107 v 15.3.1 Arbitrage Principle................................................................................................107 15.3.2 Exhaustion principle .............................................................................................107 15.4 Government taxation on exhaustible resources.............................................................109 15.5 Exploration and extraction rights .................................................................................110 15.6 Prices of exhaustible resources over time.....................................................................110 15.7 Optimal Extraction of an Exhaustible Resource .........................................................111 15.8 The Costs of Extraction ...............................................................................................111 15.9 Marginal user cost (MUC) ...........................................................................................112 15.10 Changes in the marginal extraction cost .....................................................................113 vi ABSTRACT This study material covers syllabus for the course OEV 210, Environmental Economics, for the second year students pursuing BSc. in Environmental Sciences programme offered at the Open University of Tanzania. The study material is written to introduce students to the basic elements of environmental economics. The course is all about the contribution of that economics can make to our understanding of environmental problems in the 21st century. Students should note that almost all standard textbooks of environmental economics are tailored towards economics students studying environmental economics course. The books assume that students reading must have had prior knowledge of economics. This study material is intended for students who do not posses prior knowledge of economics although it could also be useful to undergraduate economics students taking environmental economics course as an optional course. As such there is very little theorization and formal conceptualization of economic concepts, and where necessary, the concepts are presented in a style easy to grasp by the students. This study material is divided into fifteen lectures. Lecture one covers the introduction to environmental economics. Chapter two to chapter four covers theories of demand, supply and elasticity which in many cases are referred to as price theory. Lecture five introduces some fundamental concepts of economics relevant for environmental policy analysis. The theory of market structures and market failures in relation to utilization of environmental resources are covered in lectures six and seven respectively. The concepts of valuation of environmental aspects and cost benefit analysis of environmental policy are presented in respectively, chapters eight and nine. Chapter ten covers the concepts of national income from the environmental economics point of view. Economic growth and its relationship with the environment are explained in chapter eleven whereas in chapter twelve the environment is viewed from the developing countries point of view. International trade and trade agreements with impact on the global environment are covered in chapter fourteen and the lastly, chapter fifteen covers all about theories governing exhaustible/depletable resources from the economics perspective. Where possible review questions and activities are posed at the end of each lecture or in between lectures. Again, the questions vary greatly in extent but they have been prepared to grasp the intended lecture objectives. Students should ensure that they try all the questions as they help to find out what a student understands from what he/she doesn’t. The list of reference materials and suggested sections of the particular references is also provided for students to only concentrate on the intended learning outcomes. However students are advised to read extensively to widen up their understanding of the course. Internet is one of the main sources of the contents included in this study material. Thus some examples may need recasting to suit our local situations. if students find some sections in the book are containing insufficient coverage for the intended learning outcomes, they are advised to refer to the recommended textbooks and also search on the internet for additional notes. A few web links have been indicated but there many more. vii COURSE DESCRIPTION Course Weight: Pre-Requisite: 2 Units NONE Course Rationale Management of natural resources relies on an understanding of how markets work but also how they fail. In this course students will be introduced to key economic theories and concepts such as the law of demand & supply, market competition and economic efficiency, and the market failure paradigm. The students will also be introduced to approaches and techniques used to analyse environmental aspects such as environmental policy and decision making, environmental and sustainable development as well as such aspects as cost-benefit analysis, cost-effectiveness analysis and multi-criteria analysis. Learning Outcomes After completion of the course, students are expected to explain: • The fundamentals of economic theory with reference to the use and management environmental aspects • Economic techniques that can be applied to support business and policy decisions about the conservation and management of the environment , • Internal and external costs, market approaches to environmental resource management and cost-benefit analysis. • Sustainable economic growth and development and implications on environmental resources at national and global levels Mode of Assessment Timed test Final examination 30% 70% KEY REFERENCE BOOKS, READING MATERIALS AND INTERNET SOURCES Lecture Title Lecture One: Introduction Environmental Economics Lecture Two: The Theory of Demand Lecture Three: The Theory of Supply Lecture Four: Elasticity of Demand and Supply Lecture Five: Fundamental Economic Concepts for Environmental Policy Analysis Lecture Six: Market Structures Lecture Seven: Market Failures for Environmental Resources Lecture Eight: Valuing Environmental Benefits Recommended Textbooks and other reference materials 1. Tietenberg Tom (1998) Chapters 1 & 12 2. David Pearce and Turner Kerry (1990) Chapter 1 3. Perman Roger, Mar Yue et al (1999) Chapter 1 4. Burningham David and Davies John (2004) Chapters 1&2 5. Internet sources 1. Samuelson P.A. and Nordhaus (1992) 2. Any introduction to economics textbook 1. Samuelson P.A. and Nordhaus (1992) 2. Any introduction to economics textbook 1. Samuelson P.A. and Nordhaus (1992) 2. Any introduction to economics textbook 1. Samuelson P.A. and Nordhaus (1992) 2. Any introduction to economics textbook 3. Tietenberg Tom (1998) Various Chapter sections 4. Internet sources 1. Samuelson P.A. and Nordhaus (1992) 2. Any introduction to economics textbook 3. Internet sources 1. Perman Roger, Mar Yue et al (1999) Chapter 6 2. Burningham David and Davies John (2004) Chapters 3 3. Internet sources 1. Tietenberg Tom (1998) Capter 4 2. Perman Roger, Mar Yue et al (1999) Chapters 14 & 15 3. Burningham David and Davies John (2004) Chapters5 4. Internet sources viii Lecture Nine: Cost-Benefit Analysis of Environmental Policy Lecture Ten: National Income Lecture Eleven: Economic Growth and the Environment Lecture Twelve: The Environment in Developing Countries Lecture Thirteen: Sustainable Development Lecture Fourteen: Free Trade, Trade Agreements and the Environment Lecture Fifteen: Exhaustible Resources 1. Tietenberg Tom (1998) Capter 4 2. Perman Roger, Mar Yue et al (1999) Chapter 14 3. Burningham David and Davies John (2004) Chapter 6 4. Internet sources 1. Samuelson P.A. and Nordhaus (1992) 2. Any introduction to economics textbook 2. David Pearce and Turner Kerry (1990) Chapter 2 3. Burningham David and Davies John (2004) Chapters 1&2 4. Internet sources 1. Tietenberg Tom (1998) Chapter 19 2. David Pearce and Turner Kerry (1990) Chapters 3 & 20 3. Perman Roger, Mar Yue et al (1999) Chapters 2 & 16 4. Burningham David and Davies John (2004) Chapters 4, 7 &8 5. Internet sources 1. Tietenberg Tom (1998) Chapters 8-10, & 19-21 2. David Pearce and Turner Kerry (1990) Chapters 20 & 22 3. Perman Roger, Mar Yue et al (1999) Chapters 2 & 10 4. Burningham David and Davies John (2004) Chapters 4, 7, 8 & 9 5. Internet sources 1. Tietenberg Tom (1998) Chapters 19 & 20 2. David Pearce and Turner Kerry (1990) Chapters 3, 20 & 22 3. Perman Roger, Mar Yue et al (1999) Chapters 2 & 4 4. Burningham David and Davies John (2004) Chapters 4, 7, 8 &9 5. Internet sources 1. Tietenberg Tom (1998) Chapters 19 & 20 2. David Pearce and Turner Kerry (1990) Chapters 3, 20 & 22 3. Perman Roger, Mar Yue et al (1999) Chapter 13 4. Burningham David and Davies John (2004) Chapters 4, 7, 8 &9 5. Internet sources 1. Tietenberg Tom (1998) Chapters 7 2. David Pearce and Turner Kerry (1990) Chapters 16-19 3. Perman Roger, Mar Yue et al (1999) Chapters 8 & 9 4. Internet sources LIST OF RECOMMENDED REFERENCES 1. Burningham David and Davies John (2004) Studies in Economics and Business: Environmental Economics. 3rd Ed Heinemann UK 2. David Pearce and Turner Kerry (1990) Economics of Natural Resources and the Environment. The John Hopkins University Press, GB 3. Perman Roger, Mar Yue et al (1999) Natural Resource and Environmental Economics. 2nd Ed Prentice Hall England 4. Samuelson P.A. and Nordhaus (1992) Economics. McGraw Hill 5. Tietenberg Tom (1998) Environmental Economics and Policy. 2nd Ed Addison-Wesley Educational Publishers Inc.England 6. Example of internet sources http://classes.maxwell.syr.edu/ppa777/envilect.html www.varsitynotes.com/economics/environment_economics.html www.colorado.edu/Economics/money/4545/4545lnts.html ix LECTURE ONE INTRODUCTION TO ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICS 1.1. What is Environmental Economics? Economics is the study of the allocation of scarce resources. Note that the theories of economics can be applied to any scarce resource, not just traditional commodities. Economics is not simply about profits or money. It applies anywhere constraints are faced, so that choices must be made. Environmental and natural resource economics is the application of the principles of economics to the study of how environmental and natural resources are developed and managed. Natural resources refer to resources provided by nature that can be divided into increasingly smaller units and allocated at the margin. Environmental resources are all those resources provided by nature that are indivisible. Natural resources serve as inputs to the economic system. Environmental resources are affected by the system (e.g. pollution). At the end of this lecture you are expected to be able to: 1. Define and explain justification for studying environmental economics 2. Define economics and explain its importance 3. Differentiate between microeconomics and macroeconomics 4. Explain the problem of scarce resources and opportunity cost 5. Explain the basic functions of any economic system 1.2 Why do we use economics in environmental policy? The main reason is that in our society the environment has become a scarce resource. Since economics is about how to tackle scarce resources, it can often be useful when dealing with environmental problems. One way of using economics is to ensure that the costs and the benefits of environmental measures are well balanced. Although it is difficult to estimate costs and benefits, there is an increasing demand that this is done before new environmental policy is decided on a European level. With the use of market-based instruments, environmental goals can sometimes be reached more efficiently than with traditional command and control regulations. Economic and environmental objectives are often perceived as being contradictory. It is believed that a choice must be made between one and the other and that both cannot be achieved concurrently. 1 1.3 Why Study Environmental Economics? In general, prices reflect the relative scarcity of goods. However, in environmental economics, markets, and thus prices, often do not exist. The following aspects of environmental and natural resource economics make it unique: • Market failures - When market failures exist, government intervention may be appropriate. • Dynamics - The decision to consume a good today typically does not affect the ability to consume it tomorrow. However, the decision to use natural resources today does affect what will be available tomorrow. • Irreversibility - Damage to natural resources has long-term effects. This is not as large a problem for normal consumer goods. Thus an interdisciplinary understanding of the environment, political science, etc. is necessary to be a good environmental economist. 1.4 Key questions for environmental economics a) Market failure - Typically, externalities are a problem hence need for various appropriate types of remedies. For example, imperfect competition leads to regulated utilities. b) Difficult to forge best type of intervention- The problem in environmental economics is often that there is no market for environmental resources. Thus, one option is to create a market. However, economists realize that this is not always the best solution. c) How to evaluate environmental programs is critical - Ideally, we need to know what level of environmental protection is desired. Economists focus on decisions at the margin: equating marginal costs and marginal benefits. The choice is not between clean air and dirty air, but rather between levels of pollution. Note that this requires placing a value on environmental protection. However, this valuation is complicated by the lack of market prices for environmental goods. d) Efficiency versus equity - We need to remember that even when an efficient solution occurs, it might not be desirable. The fundamental theorem of welfare economics says nothing about the distribution of resources in an efficient solution. Equity issues are also important. Policymakers need to consider how various groups will be impacted. This can be complicated in environmental economics. For example, how should the welfare of future generations be weighed when making global warming policy? 2 1.5 Introduction to the theory of economics In this lecture, students are introduced to aspects that make economics one of the most distinctive and interesting social science fields of study. The functions of economic systems as well as importance of economics are also highlighted. 1.5.1 Definition of Economics Economics is a social science which deals with the study of how people allocate their limited/scarce resources to satisfy endless human wants. There are basically three key points for us to note in this definition: (a) Economics is a social science concerned with human behaviour. (b) It deals with allocation of scarce resources which include land, labour, capital and management/entrepreneurship. (c) It is concerned with satisfaction on human wants which are endless, and this involves the problem of choice among alternatives. Since resources are scarce in relation to their demand, the study of economics has become a major discipline over the past three centuries. The question of how resources should be allocated for production of different products and different time and between private and public uses are some basic economic problems which give rise to the study of economics. Economics as a science has many branches. Some of the branches are classified as “Economic Theories” whereas others are referred to as “Applied Economics”. In general Economic Theories can be grouped into microeconomics and macroeconomics, whereas Applied Economics comprises environmental economics, industrial economics, development economics, agricultural economics, health economics, etc. 1.5.2 Microeconomics and Macroeconomics It is appropriate at this point to distinguish between microeconomics and macroeconomics. Microeconomics is derived from a Greek word “Mikros” meaning “small”. Thus microeconomics is concerned with economics of small units such as individual farmers, individual households, individual households, food processors, individual commercial bank etc. The process of price determination and the process of profit maximisation by individual farmers is part of the study of microeconomics. Macroeconomics, on the other hand, deals with the study of economic aggregates. The word macroeconomics comes from the Greek word “Makros” which means “large”. Therefore macroeconomics focuses on the national or the aggregate economy. It covers national income and employment, general price level, international trade theory, government budgets, public finance etc. 3 Note that despite the contrast between microeconomics and macroeconomics, there is no conflict between the two branches of economic theory. This is so because the economy of the aggregate is nothing, but a summation of individual units that make the aggregate economy. Microeconomics deals with allocation of resources among individual economic units such as farmers, food processors, and household members or consumers whereas Macroeconomics focuses on broad aspects of the aggregate economy such as Gross Domestic Product (GDP), money and banking, inflation, balance of payments and policy issues. 1.5.3 The Problem of Scarcity and Choice The problem of scarcity and choice is fundamental to the study of economics. Resources which are also known as the factors of production or inputs are usually needed for the production of goods and services to satisfy human wants or ends. These include natural resources such as land, minerals, forest wildlife, etc; human resources such as labour, capital and management or entrepreneurship. Most resources are limited in supply, and usually they are scarce, because their demand per unit time far outstrips supply. Any good that is scarce is called an “economic good”. Since most resources are scarce, it means they can also meet a small fraction of people’s demand for these resources. If resources are abundant and can meet all people’s demand, there is no problem hence no need to study economics. However most resources are scarce because they are limited in supply in relation to their demand. The problem of scarcity, therefore, arises because of inadequate resource to produce goods and services for all human wants. Given the above situation, we have to make a choice as to what needs are to be met, what goods and services are to be produced; and what goods should not be produced; whose wants are to be satisfied, and whose wants should not be satisfied. Since resources are limited, they must be managed rationally among many competing uses for which they are required. The question of optimum resource allocation is, therefore, a major problem that must be addressed by various economic units such as households, producers, government and the entire nation. All societies face this problem of resource scarcity and choice. In general we can however say that resource allocation within any society depends on the type of the economic system in existence. For instance in a market economy like that of USA and Japan, the price mechanism 4 plays a major role in rationing goods and services. Price helps in determining what goods and services to produce and in what quantities. In a centrally planned economy like that of the former Soviet Union (USSR), the central government plays a major role in rationing goods and services among the various units in the society. Under a mixed economic system like Tanzania and most Sub Saharan economies, both price and government play major roles in resource allocation. 1.5.4 Choice and Opportunity Cost The economic term for expressing costs in terms of foregone alternative is the “opportunity cost”. For example, if a newly recruited company’s economist earns a monthly salary of TShs 5 million, and he is interested in buying a car, a music system and a house plot from his month’s salary. Given his limited monthly income, he cannot satisfy all his wants and, therefore, has to decide which want has to be satisfied and which to be postponed. In order to decide on which choice, he has to arrange his wants in order of importance i.e. according to his “scale of preference” from the most important going down to the least important one. Let us assume that the scale according to his preference is house plot, car, music system etc. From the above ranking, he is likely to choose to buy a house plot and forego the car and the music system. Thus, if he decides to buy the house plot, the opportunity cost of the house plot is the car, which is the next best choice he decides not to buy. The sacrificing or foregoing of one choice in order to attain another is called “principle of opportunity cost”. Therefore the opportunity cost concept in economics can be defined as the cost of foregone best alternative in the process of decision-making. It should be noted that opportunity cost arises in a decision making process and it is due to the fact that resources are limited and human wants are endless and therefore, a choice has to be made among competing wants. The concept of opportunity costs related not only to individuals, farmers and industrialists, but also to businesses, governments as well as other agencies involved in decision-making. 1.5.5 Functions of Economic Systems There are basically three types of economic systems; the open market economic systems, centrally planned economic systems, and the mix of the two i.e. mixed economic systems. In every economic system there are three basic functions which are to be performed i.e. production, distribution, and present and future consumption. Let us look at each one. 5 (a) Production The production, in any economic system, centres on three basic principles, i.e. • What goods and services to produce • How to produce these goods and services • For whom to produce The question of what to produce is determined by the resources which the society has. There are many alternative commodities that a producer can produce but since resources are always limited, producer must choose among alternative commodities. Decision has to base on the expected income from the products and on the available resource. For instance, a producer may decide to choose production of cash crops instead of milk production depending on their relative profitability. Just as there are many possible products to produce, there are many ways of producing them. The question of how to produce is purely a technical and technological one. It concerns the way the resources (or factors of production) can be combined to yield maximum output at least cost of production. So choice of products is not independent of the choice of production method since a cost of production is influenced by production method. The question of “for whom to produce” is dependent on tastes and preference of individuals in the society. Such tastes and preferences dictate the type of goods and services to produce. However, these tastes and preferences must be backed up by the individual income or the purchasing power of the consumers. (b) Distribution The problem of distributing goods and services among members of the society depends on the political economic philosophy of the respective government. For instance, a socialist government aims at equitable distribution of wealth while capitalist government may not pursue this function. Thus, whether a nation’s wealth is distributed evenly or concentrated in few hands, is determined by the political economic philosophy of the government. (c) Present and future consumption Determining the present and future consumption and saving is another function which most economies have to perform. Since savings increase a nation’s investment, and this determines the growth rate of the nation’s economy, this is a major function performed in any society. However, the decision about how much to consume and how much to save depends on the political 6 economic philosophy of the respective government. For example under a free market economic system, this depends on market forces, whereas in centrally planned economic system, the government usually makes the decision. ? REVIEW QUESTIONS 1. Giving examples, write short notes on the following concepts as used in Economics: Scarcity and choice. Opportunity cost, Economic goods, and Public goods 2. Discuss the main functions of an economic system. 7 LECTURE TWO THE THEORY OF DEMAND 2.1 Introduction This lecture introduces students to the basic principles of demand theory. It is through the study of this theory that markets can be studied, understood and market prices estimated. The understanding of this lecture is a pre-requisite for the mastery of the other lectures in this course. By the end of this lecture, you should be able to: 1. Define and explain demand and its determinants 2. Explain the law of demand and its application in economics. 3. Derive demand schedule and demand curves 4. Explain factors leading to the violation of the law of demand 5. Distinguish between change in demand and changes in quantity demanded 2.2 Demand Theory Demand is the desire backed by the ability and willingness to have the commodity desired. The actual buying of commodities is called Effective Demand. Quantity demanded refers to the amount of commodity which buyers are willing and are able to purchase in the market at various prices per given period of time. Quantity actually demanded implies that a commodity is available in the market. 2.2.1 Determinants of Quantity Demanded (a) Price of the Commodity - Consumers will buy more the commodity if its price falls because of mainly two reasons. First, they leave substitutes and buy more of the cheaper commodity and secondly, more consumers join the market to buy the cheaper commodity. On the other hand, when prices rise, quantity demanded of the commodity falls. (b) Prices of other Commodities - These may lower or raise the quantity demanded of a commodity or leave it constant. There are mainly two types of other commodities. First, the substitutes where two commodities may meet the same demand e.g. maize and sorghum. Increase in the price of substitutes increases quantity demanded of the commodity and vice-versa. Second, the complements where commodities are jointly demanded e.g. bread and butter. Increase in price of complements decrease quantity demanded of a commodity and vice-versa. 8 (c) Income - For normal goods, the rise in income is expected to lead to the increase in quantity demanded of such commodities. For inferior goods, as consumer's income increases, the quantity demanded of such commodities falls because consumers opt for those which are more expensive and inferior good look too cheap for them. For necessities, quantity demanded remains the same after certain level even if consumer’s income increases e.g. salt, foodstuffs etc. (d) Tastes and Preference - These depend on habit, age, sex, education, time, religion etc. The quantity demanded may increase when the favourable to the commodity and vice-versa. Tastes and preferences may be permanent or temporary. For example, the temporary favourable taste is increase in meat consumption on Christmas. (e) Sociological factors - These include education, marital status, age etc. 2.2.2 Demand Function The technical relationship between quantity demanded and the determinants of the quantity demanded of a given commodity is termed as Demand Function. This is summarised as follows; given other factors constant: QTY = f(P0, P1 ....... Pn-1, Y, T/P, E) Where QTY = Quantity demanded of commodity Y, P0 = Price of commodity Y, P1...Pn-1 = Price of other commodities, Y = Income, T/P = Taste and Preference and E = Sociological and other factors. 2.2.3 Demand Schedule It is the numerical representation of quantity demanded at various price levels of a given commodity. Example: Table 1 Potato's Demand Schedule Price per kg (TShs) Quantity demanded (Kg) 50 2 30 10 10 30 5 50 Individual household demand schedule differs from market demand schedule in that the earlier shows the quantity demanded by one household only at various prices whereas the later shows the total demand of a commodity by all households in the market of a commodity. 9 2.2.4 Demand Curve It is the graphical representation of the demand schedule. It is drawn on the assumption that the higher the price, the lower the quantity demanded, other things being constant. Price D P1 P0 0 D Q0 Q1 Fig. 2.1 Demand Curve Quantity Figure 2.1 shows that as price increases e.g. from P0 to P1 the quantity demanded decreases from Q1 to Q0. As with demand schedule, the demand curves can be drawn for individual household i.e. individual household Demand Curve as well as for all the households in the market of a commodity i.e. Market Demand Curve. The demand curve slopes downwards from left to right. This demonstrates the Law of Demand, which states that, “given other factors constant, the higher the price, the lower the quantity demanded and vice-versa”. 2.2.5 Market Demand This is referred to as the total demand of a commodity by all households in the market of that particular commodity. Individual household demand differs from market demand in that the earlier is the demand of a commodity by one household only. There are many factors affecting market demand depending on the market conditions and availability of the commodity. However common ones include price of the commodity, price of all other commodities, total household income, income distribution among households i.e. high demand when income is equally distributed among household but less demand if income is owned by few households, population size and composition, tastes and preference, government policies etc. Give a description of the shape of the market demand curve in relation to that of an individual. Draw them to illustrate their shapes. The existence of the Law of Demand is due to the following factors: 10 (a) The Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility - This law assumes that as one consumes more of a certain commodity after a certain level, the satisfaction derived from additional units of that commodity (Marginal Utility) reduces/diminishes. So as the consumer purchases more a commodity, the marginal utility reduces. The consumer can continue doing so if only the commodity is given free. It should be noted that the price of a commodity depends on its Marginal Utility of the last unit consumed rather than total utility (total satisfaction). (b) Income Changes - As the price rises, the real income of consumers decrease i.e consumers can't purchase more units of the commodity with the same money income. The reverse is also true. Real income measures the purchasing power of a household's money income whereas money income is a measure of income in terms of money e.g. shillings, dollars, pounds etc. (c) Substitution Effect - If the prices of the substitute commodities remain constant, consumers will purchase more of a commodity if its price falls and purchase less of the substitutes and vice-versa. (d) The Price Effect - When the price of a commodity falls consumers buy more of it because of the income and substitution effects. When the price falls, even the poor can purchase the commodity hence increasing demand. (e) Different uses of certain commodities- When a price of a commodity whose uses are many are high, consumers use it for important purposes only and when prices falls, consumers use them even for luxurious purposes. (f) Presence of low-income groups - These can only afford to purchase a commodity at low prices and buy less when prices increase. With rich groups the Law of Demand cannot hold because these can afford to purchase the same amount of commodity at any price. Other than price-demand curve and price-demand law discussed before, there are other demand curves such as: (a) Income-demand curves - Relationship between quantities demanded and changes in income. (b) Cross-Demand Curves - Relationship between quantities demanded and changes in prices of substitute commodities. (c) Abnormal Demand Curves - These are also called Regressive Demand Curves. These are price-demand curves which violate the Demand Law. 11 2.3 Factors leading to the violation of the law of demand (a) Luxurious goods - These are termed as articles of ostentation. They are demanded to maintain one's status such that if their prices rise, people buy more of them e.g. gold rings. When prices rise the demand goes high. (b) Price expectations - When prices are expected to rise, consumers will buy more of a commodity as price increase in order to avoid effects of further expected price increase. On the other hand, sellers also increase prices following the increased demand. (c) Giffen Commodities - These commodities take large portion of one’s income in such a way that if their prices increase, one tends to purchase more of them and less when prices fall. If the prices of such commodities increase, the consumer buys less of the Geffen commodities and buys more the commodities previously foregone. However this is so much popular with poor people. (d) Ignorance effect - Some commodities may be of high value due to their high prices, package, labels etc. So as the price rise the quantity also may increase. (e) Effects of a depression period - This is a period of low prices, low incomes, low purchasing power and low economic activity. During this period demand is also low. Discuss the essence of the argument that “The law of demand does not exist if other factors (other than price) are not held constant”. 2.4 Change in Quantity Demanded and Change in Demand Change in quantity demanded differs from Change in Demand in that the earlier refers to the increase or decrease in the amount of the purchased commodity in the market due to changes in price, given other factors constant. On the other hand Change in Demand refers to an increase or decrease in quantity demanded at constant prices brought about by changes in other factors influencing demand 12 Price D1 D2 P1 D1 D2 0 Q1 Q2 Quantity Fig. 2.2 Change in Quantity Demanded Vs Change in Demand Figure 2.2 shows that at P1 quantity demanded can increase or decrease due to changes in other determinants of quantity demanded. Increase in demand is shown by shift of the demand curve to the right from D1 to D2 where the quantity increases from Q1 to Q2 at the same price, P1. 2.5 Types of Demand These are also called interrelated demand, which is the situation where demand for one commodity affects the demand for another commodity positively or negatively. This interrelated demand denotes 5 types of demand: (a) Joint/Complementary Demand - Demand for commodities which are used together such that increased demand for one increases demand for the other e.g butter and bread, sugar and tea leaves etc. (b) Competitive Demand - Demand for commodities which serve almost the same purpose so that the increase in demand for one of them reduces demand for the other e.g beans and peas. (c) Derived Demand - Demand for the commodity not for its own sake but as a result of Demand for another. For instance, the demand for factors of production is derived from demand for commodities they are going to produce. (d) Composite Demand - Demand for commodities which serve several uses such that their total demand is got by adding up quantity demanded of them by those several uses. E.g cotton is demanded for making clothes, animal feeds, threads etc. (e) Independent Demand - Demand for a commodity does not affect and is not affected by demand for another commodity. However commodities are rare to find. 13 ? REVIEW QUESTIONS 1. What is the difference between an increase in demand and an increase in the quantity demanded? 2. What is the difference between a change in demand and a change in quantity demanded? 3. Given below is the demand schedule for a 500 mls tin of soda in Dar es Salaam city observed in a nightclub. Construct the demand curve Price per 500mls soda tin (Tshs) 1000 700 650 600 550 500 450 400 Quantity of soda tins purchased per night 00 50 90 100 110 120 130 140 14 LECTURE THREE THE THEORY OF SUPPLY AND EQUILIBRIUM PRICE 3.1 Introduction Supply refers to the amount of a commodity producers are willing to bring to the market at various prices within a given period of time. Quantity supplied is the amount producers would like to sell but not how much they actually sell (quantity actually supplied). By the end of this lecture you should be able to: 1. Define supply and explain factors affecting supply of goods and services 2. Determine equilibrium price and quantity in a market 3. Differentiate between changes in quantity supplied and change in supply 4. Explain and determine price determination and market equilibrium 3.2 Determinants of Quantity Supplied The analysis of the influence of each of the factors assumes that other factors remain constant. (a) Price of the Commodity - At high prices the commodities become more profitable to produce and sell hence the Law of Supply, which states that ‘the higher the price, the higher the quantity supplied.' (b) Price of other Commodities - When prices of competing commodities increase, then it becomes more profitable to produce and sell these competing commodities thereby decreasing supply of the commodity and vice-versa e.g. when price of beans falls, farmers shift to peas production which fetch high prices and profits. On the other hand when two commodities are produced together, the increase in price of one causes an increase in supply of the other e.g. increased beef price causes increased beef price cattle production thereby increasing supply of hides. (c) Goals of the firm - Supply is usually expected to be high if the goal of the producer is sales maximisation i.e. when the goal is profit maximisation, supply can be low because producers would want to supply less and sell at high prices. (d) Government policy - This may be in form of taxation, subsidization and other legislations (fiscal policies). High taxation leads to high costs of production which eventually leads to low quantity supplied. On the other hand, subsidization lowers costs of production thereby increasing quantity supplied of a commodity. 15 (e) Degree of Freedom of entry of firms in production determines quantity supplied in that if there is freedom (perfect competition), the supply is likely to increase because suppliers can't restrict supply so as to sell at high prices. Under monopolistic is a dictator of quantity supplied and would like to sell small amounts at high prices. (f) Gestation period refers to the production period or maturity period. When gestation is short (for industrial products), the supply becomes easy to increase in the shortest possible time. For agricultural production, the gestation period is usually long, thereby restricting quick supply e.g palm oil supply cannot be increased in a very short period because it takes some years before the crop matures. (g) Non-pecuriary means (non-monetary). Therefore changes in non-pecuriary advantages of work such as improved working incentives may lead to increased production hence supply whereas the reverse is true for non-pecuriary disadvantage of work e.g. power working conditions, increasing risks etc. (h) Climate (Weather) - If weather e.g. rain, wind, sunshine etc are favourable to production is likely to increase given other factors constant. Weather factors have much influence especially on the supply of agricultural products. (i) State of technology - Efficient technology leads to expanded volume of supply and reverse is true for inefficient technology of production. (j) Demand - High demand for a commodity calls for increased supply of the commodity whereas low demand leads to low supply. (k) Non-economic factors include political situation in the nation. Political stability encourages increased production and thereby supply. 3.3 Supply Function It is the statement showing the technical relationship between quantity supplied and the major determinants of quantity supplied of a given commodity. QSY = f(P0, P1 .......Pn-1, F1 .... Fn, G, T, E). Where Qsy = Quantity supplied of commodity y, P0 = Price of commodity Y, P1 ....Pn-1 = Price of other commodities, F1 .... Fn = Factors of production, G = Goals of producer, T = Technology and E = Other factors (error term) 3.4 Market Supply Market supply refers to total supply of a commodity by all suppliers in the market of that particular market. Individual producer supply differs from market supply in that individual producer supply 16 producer supply is concerned with a supply by only one supplier/producer whereas market supply refers to total supply by all suppliers of a certain commodity in a given market and place. 3.4.1 Supply Schedule It is the numerical representation showing the amount of a commodity brought to the market at various prices per period of time. Example of a rice supply schedule is illustrated below. Table 2 Supply schedule for rice Price per kg (TShs) Quantity supplied per period of time (Kg) 5 100 10 250 15 350 20 450 The supply schedule can be an individual supply schedule or market supply schedule. 3.4.2 Supply Curve It is the graphical representation of the supply schedule. Normally the supply curve slopes upwards from left to right indicating that the higher the price, the higher the quantity supplied, other factors being constant. This notifies the Law of Supply. Price S P2 P1 0 Q1 Fig. 3.1 Supply Curve Q2 Quantity Supplied When prices increase from P1 to P2 quantity supplied increases from Q1 to Q2. The supply curve can be a curve or a straight line and it is not necessary that it passes through the origin. Individual Supply Curves can be used to derive the Market Supply Curve. Therefore the Market Supply curve is the horizontal summation of the supply curves by all the individual suppliers of the commodity. 17 Using graphs describe the differences in shapes between the individual and market supply curves. 3.4.3 Changes in Quantity Supplied and Change in Supply Change in quantity supplied occurs where there is a change in price of a commodity when other determinants of quantity supplied are assumed to be constant. It is illustrated by the movement of supply along the same supply curve. Change in supply refers to the change in quantity supplied of commodity which arises from changes in determinants of quantity supplied at constant price. It is illustrated by shift of the supply curve upwards or downwards. Price S1 S2 P1 0 Q1 Q2 Quantity supplied Fig. 3.2 Change in Quantity supplied Vs Change in supply At P1, quantity supplied can increase or decrease due to changes in other determinants other than price. Increase in supply is demonstrated by shift of supply curve from S1 to S2 i.e. from left to right where quantity supplied increase from Q1 to Q2. Decrease in demand is shown by the shift of the supply curve to the left i.e. from S1 to S2 where quantity supplied decreases from Q1 to Q3 at constant price, P1. Each determinant can cause increase or decrease of quantity supplied. 3.5 Price Determination and Market Equilibrium In our discussion of supply and demand concepts we made reference several times to “price” without mentioning how this market price or “equilibrium price” is determined. This is the primary focus of this section. In the process of buying and selling, a lot of bargaining takes place between buyers and sellers. The bargaining continues until both parties agree about the quantity and the price. It is only when the quantity demanded is equal to the quantity supplied that actual purchase takes place. The price of which the supply and demand are equal is called the market price or “equilibrium price”. 18 As a means of enhancing our understanding of how that equilibrium price is determined let us consider the hypothetical supply and demand schedules for rice in Mbeya market as presented in the table below. From the schedules we can observe that the equilibrium is established at TSh. 25,000 per 100 kg bag. At this price quantity supplied is equal to quantity demanded. Table 3 Supply and Demand schedules for rice in Mbeya market Price of rice (TShs per 100kg bag) 5,000 10,000 15,000 25,000 35,000 40,000 Quantity of supply (100kg bag) 1 3 6 9 12 15 Quantity demanded (100kg bag) 24 19 15 9 4 1 We can plot figures in the above table to reveal the supply and demand curves as shown in Figure 3.3. It can be observed that the equilibrium price is TS. 25,000 per 100kg bag and the equilibrium quantity is 9 bags each weighing 100kg. Price (TShs) 50,000- D S 25,000- 5,000- S D 0 1 9 15 Quantity in 100kg bags Fig. 3.3 Market equilibrium price and quantity 3.6 Changes in equilibrium price Usually equilibrium can be disturbed and the disturbance can be in form of price distortion which can be examined under two scenarios. First, the case of shortages and second the case of market surplus. (i) Case of supply shortages - This occurs when the demand outstrips supply and example can be illustrated from the example in table 3 and fig 3.3. Suppose the government decides to set the price of rice at TShs.10,000 per bag, the demand for rice far outstrips the supply and since the 19 consumers demand is not met we have a situation of excess demand or supply shortages. Under such a situation, sellers of rice would raise their prices and this will reduce demand until the equilibrium is established at TShs. 25,000 per bag. (ii) Case of market surplus - This is a situation where the quantity supplied in the market would be greater than quantity demanded by consumers, leading to excess supply or market surplus. Following the market surplus, sellers would reduce their prices in order to reduce the market surplus. This is illustrated by a situation where a price is set that is higher than the equilibrium price. In our rice example, suppose the price is set at TShs. 35,000 per bag, consumers will demand less than supplied until the unless the price is lowered. The reduction in price will induce consumers to demand more. The decrease in price will continue until an equilibrium price is reached i.e. TShs 25,000 per bag where demand and supply are equal. You should note that only the equilibrium price of Tshs 25,000 per bag is the stable equilibrium price, as a price higher or lower than the equilibrium price will create a market surplus which will set forces in motion to bring back the price to equilibrium level. It should be noted that changes in equilibrium price can also be brought about by shifts of supply or demand curves. For example a shift in demand curve can bring a new equilibrium level. ? REVIEW QUESTIONS 1. How is the equilibrium price of the commodity determined? 2. Using appropriate diagrams illustrate the concepts of excess demand and the concepts of excess supply 3 Given below are supply and demand data for a farmer’s bags of maize Price per bag Quantity supplied Quantity demanded (000’ Shs) (bags) (bags) 3 100 500 4 200 400 5 300 300 6 400 200 7 500 100 (a) What is the equilibrium price and quantity? Illustrate using supply and demand curves (b) How many bags of maize will be produced if the government sets a price support at Shs 6 per bag? How many bags will the government have to purchase at Shs 6? 20 LECTURE FOUR ELASTICITY OF DEMAND AND SUPPLY 4.1 Introductions Elasticity is the degree of responsiveness of dependent variables to independent variables. Dependent variables may be quantity demanded or supplied while independent variables are factors which influence the demand or supply. Due to this categorisation there are two main types of elasticity i.e. elasticity of demand and elasticity of supply. By the end of this lecture you should be able to: 1. Calculate and interpret price, income and cross elasticities of demand for and supply of goods and services 2. Discuss various determinants of elasticity of demand and supply 4.2 Elasticity of Demand Elasticity of Demand is the degree of responsiveness of quantity demanded to factors which influence the quantity demanded namely price, income and prices of other commodities. Therefore there are 3 types of elasticity of demand i.e. price elasticity of demand, income elasticity of demand and cross elasticity of demand. 4.2.1 Price Elasticity of Demand (η η) It is the measure of the degree of responsiveness of quantity demanded to changes in the commodity's price. It can be expressed as follows: η = Percentage Change in quantity demanded or Percentage Change in price ∆Q • P ∆P Q where ∆Q = Change in quantity demanded of a commodity, ∆P = Change in price of the commodity, P = Original price of the commodity and Q = Original quantity demanded of the commodity. 21 P 10 A ∆P 5 B ∆Q 0 3 5 Fig. 4.1 Price Elasticity of demand from A to B Q From figure 4.1; ∆P = 10 – 5 = 5, ∆Q = 3 - 5 = -2 units, P = 10/-and Q = 3 Thus; ηd = -2/ 5 x 10/3 = -1.3 The elasticity does not have units and it is expressed in absolute values i.e. it is always positive. The negative sign which can appear indicates the negative slope of the demand curve i.e. downward sloping. Elasticity ranges from zero to infinity. 4.2.2 How to Interpret Price Elasticity of Demand (a) Perfectly or completely inelastic - This is when price elasticity of demand is zero i.e quantity demanded does not respond to change in price at all e.g. demand for cigarettes. (b) Inelastic - This occurs when the price elasticity of demand is greater than zero but less than one i.e. 0< η <1. This implies that quantity demanded changes by smaller percentages than the price. (c) Elastic - When the price elasticity of demand is greater than one but less than infinity i.e. 1<η<∞. This implies that change in quantity demanded is greater than that in prices. (d) Unit Elasticity - This occurs when the price elasticity of demand equals one. This leads to a rectangular hyperbola demand curve i.e. η = 1. (e) Perfect elastic - Occurs when the price elasticity of demand is equal to infinity. This means that buyers are prepared to buy all they can at or below the same price and none at all even at slightly higher prices. 22 It should be clear that if elasticity of demand is calculated at various points along the same demand curve, the elasticity varies from zero to infinity. This implies that the slope of the Demand Curve may be the same at all points whereas the elasticity of demand varies at various points. This is explained by the fact that the slope depends on the absolute changes in Price and Quantity demanded whereas elasticity of demand depends on the percentage changes of Price and of quantity demanded. 4.2.3 Determinants of Price Elasticity of Demand (a) Availability of Substitutes - If a commodity has many substitutes its demand would tend to be price elastic i.e. when its prices increases, consumer shift to substitutes immediately. When it has no substitutes or few, its demand would tend to be price inelastic i.e its price increases, the quantity demanded remains more and less the same because consumers have to purchase it as they have no substitute to shift to. (b) Degree of necessity - The price elasticity of demand for necessities tends to be inelastic because they are indispensable. For example, ever if the price of salt increase, consumers will buy almost the same quantity since most of them can't do without salt. Dispensable commodities such as luxuries have high price elasticity of Demand, because when their prices increase, consumers leave then since they can do without them. (c) Joint (Complementary) demands - When goods are used together (complementary), their demand is inelastic because the demand for one may not reduce even if the price of other increases so long as people still demand the second commodity e.g price of bread and demand for butter. (d) Cost of the Commodity - If a commodity takes a small fraction of the consumer's income, its demand tends to be inelastic e.g a match box. On the other hand, when the commodity takes a larger portion of the consumer's income, its demand tends to be price elastic since the increase in price can easily be felt. (e) Consumer's income - Price elasticity of demand for a commodity tends to be high when there are many poor people. When the price increase, they leave the commodity or buy less of it. When there are many rich people, price elasticity of demand tends to be very low because they can afford to buy the same at any price. (f) Price Stability - If there are price instabilities or expectations of price increases, demand tends to be price inelastic. As the price increases, consumers keep on buying almost the same quantity because they expect the prices to rise in the future. In such circumstances, they can even buy more of the commodity as its price increases. 23 (g) Durability of the Commodity - Durable commodities like cars, radios, refrigerators, milking machines etc have low price elasticity of demand, because even if the price of such commodities falls, one may not demand for another one when he already has one. Agricultural products which are easy to store e.g grains have a high elasticity of demand i.e when their prices fall consumers buy more and store then for future use. Demand for perishables e.g milk is inelastic because when the price falls, consumers may not buy more because they cannot manage to store them for a long time. (h) Alternative Uses of the Commodity - When a commodity has several uses, its demand tends to be price elastic. When its price increases, consumers use less of it for only important purposes. (i) Demand for the commodity whose use can be postponed its demand tends to be more elastic, for instance when prices of building materials increase, people can postpone purchasing them until some future date. When a commodity has an immediate use, its demand tends to be price inelastic. 4.2.4 Income Elasticity of Demand (η ηY ) This is the measure of the degree of responsiveness of quantity demanded to changes in consumer incomes i.e. ηY = Percentage Change in quantity demanded Percentage Change in consumer's income = ∆Q⁄Q x 100 ∆Y⁄Y x 100 = ∆Q⁄ ∆Y x Y⁄ Q Where ∆Q = Change in quantity demanded of a commodity ∆Y = Change in income of the consumer Y = Original consumers’ income Q = Original quantity demanded of the commodity 2.2.5 Interpretation of Income Elasticity of Demand (a) Income elastic - This occurs when the income elasticity is greater than one i.e quantity demanded changes more proportionately than change in incomes, keeping other factors affecting demand constant. This means that a slight increase in the money income of the consumer, leads to a very large increase in quantity demanded. Whereas the slight decrease in consumers income leads to a drastic decrease in quantity demanded. 24 (b) Income inelastic - This occurs when income elasticity of demand is less than 1 but greater than zero (0<ηY<1). This means that slight the increase in quantity demanded. (c) For inferior commodities, the income elasticity of demand is negative i.e. when incomes increase, people buy the commodity in fewer quantities. (d) When the income elasticity of demand is zero, it means that the commodity is a necessity; as quantity demanded remains constant e.g. demand for salt. (e) Normal goods have positive income elasticity of demand since their demand increases as incomes increase. It should be noted that a commodity can be a normal good, necessity or an inferior good depending on the income level of the household. The consumer may buy more of the commodity as his income increases (for a normal good). Later the consumer buys the same amount even if his income increases (for necessity good). Finally he/she can start purchasing less of the commodity (inferior commodity) and consuming more of the more expensive commodities as his income increases. 4.2.6 Importance of Income elasticity of Demand (a) It is important in distinguishing necessities (when ηY is low) and non-essential/necessities (where ηY is high). This is essential for taxation purposes. (b) It helps producers to estimate future demand as consumer's income change. If ηY is high, then as incomes increase, producers should supply more. 4.2.7 Cross Elasticity of Demand (η ηC) This is a measure of the degree of responsiveness of quantity demanded of a commodity to changes in prices of other commodities. ηCX= Percentage change in quantity demanded of Commodity(Qx) Percentage change in prices of other commodities (Py) = ∆Qx ⁄Qx x 100 ∆Py ⁄Py x 100 = ∆Qx⁄ ∆Py • Py ⁄ Qx Where ∆Qx = Change in quantity demanded of commodity X, Qx = Original quantity demanded of commodity X, ∆PY = Change in prices of other commodities (Y), PY = Original price of other commodities (Y) and ηCX = Cross elasticity of demand of commodity X. 25 4.2.8 Interpretation of Cross Elasticity of Demand (a) When ηCX is positive, their commodities X and Y are substitutes. This means that the increase in price of other commodities (Y) leads to an increase in quantity demanded of the commodity. For example, when the price of peas increases, quantity of beans demanded increases because consumers shift to the substitute cheap beans. (b) When it is negative, then commodities X and Y are complements (joint products). This means that the increase in prices of other commodities (Y) leads to a decrease in quantity demanded of commodity (C). For example, if the price of bread increases, the quantity of butter bought may decrease. Similarly if the price of cars increases, the quantity of petrol demanded may fall because of the fall in quantity of cars. (c) When ηCX is zero, the two commodities are not related at all i.e. quantity demanded of commodity X is not affected by change in price of commodity Y. 4.3 Elasticity of Supply (εε) This is a measure of the responsiveness of quantity supplied to changes in determinants of quantity supplied. Since other determinants of quantity supplied of commodity are difficult to measure, we only talk of price elasticity of supply to mean the elasticity of supply. ε = Percentage Change in quantity supplied Percentage Change in the price of the commodity = ∆QS ⁄ QS x 100 ∆Px ⁄ Px 100 = ∆QS • Px ∆Px QS Where ∆QS = Change in quantity supplied of the commodity, QS = Original quantity demanded of the commodity, ∆Px = Change in own price of the commodity, Px = Original price of the commodity and ε = Price Elasticity of supply. 4.3.1 Interpretation of Price Elasticity of Supply (a) Perfectly Inelastic - This is when elasticity of supply is equal to zero. (d) Inelastic supply - When elasticity of supply is greater than zero but less than one. Percentage change in price is greater than percentage change in quantity supplied. 26 (e) Elastic - This is when elasticity of supply is greater than one but less than infinity. Percentage change in quantity supplied is greater than percentage change in price. (f) Unit Elasticity of Supply - This is when elasticity of supply is equal to one i.e. percentage change in quantity supplied is equal to percentage change in price. (g) Perfectly Elastic - This is when at, or above a certain price. Below that price, sellers do not supply at all. 4.3.2 Determinants of Price Elasticity of Supply (a) Cost and Availability of factors of production - When cost of production is low and when factors of production are available, elasticity of supply is high because when the price increases producers increases production and supply immediately. When cost of production is high and the factors of production are scarce, elasticity of supply is low because the price increases, producers cannot easily increase supply. (b) Nature of the Commodity - Durable commodities have greater elasticity of supply because they can be stored for a long time such as the price increases, suppliers supply more. Perishable products such as milk have low elasticity of supply because they can't be stored for a long period to be brought to the market even if their prices increases, supply then cannot be increased. (c) Gestation period - A commodity with a short production cycle, has a very high elasticity of supply because when its prices increase, supply can be increased within a short time. When gestation period is long, supply cannot be increased easily to correspond to the increased price because it takes long to produce a commodity. (d) Method of production (technology) - Commodities which can be produced with simple technology have a high elasticity of supply because they can be easily produced when prices increase. (e) Time –There are three time periods in which supply can be varied: • Very Short run - Elasticity of supply is very low. Time is very short such that suppliers can only increase supply by drawing from stocks in stores. • In the short run - Elasticity of supply is low. Time is short and producers can increase production by varying only the variable factors. • In the long run- Elasticity of supply is high. Time is long enough for producers can vary both fixed and variable assets of production to increase production and thereby supply. 27 (f) Government Policy - Elasticity of supply may be low when the government restricts importation of commodities. In such case the supply may not increase even if prices increase. When trade is free, elasticity of supply tends to be high because more of the commodity is imported as the price increases. (g) Price Expectations - Price elasticity of supply may be low if there is expectation of price to change. Producers usually hesitate to supply more despite the increase in the price until the increase in price is permanent. (h) Ease of entry of new firms in the market - When new firms are restricted from joining the market (as with Monopoly), elasticity of supply is likely to be low because output is restricted by few (or a single) suppliers so as to keep price high. With perfect competition elasticity of supply is likely to be high because if the price of a commodity increases, then supply increases since more firms join the market. 4.3.3 Point Elasticity and Arc Elasticity Point elasticity refers to elasticity at one point on the Demand or Supply Curves. All along we have been talking of point elasticity, so unless mentioned when calculating price elasticity of Demand or Supply, it is meant for point elasticity which is given as (-) ∆Q⁄ ∆P x P⁄ Q. Arc elasticity refers to the elasticity between two points on the demand or supply curve. The formula is: (-) ∆Q ⁄∆P x P”⁄ Q” Where P”(Average Price) = [P1 + P2] ⁄ 2 and Q”(Average Quantity) = [Q1 + Q2] ⁄ 2 P 10 A ∆P 5 B ∆Q 0 3 Fig.4.2 Arc Elasticity of demand 5 Q Arc elasticity from A to B is given as (-)2⁄5 x [20 + 10] /2 = -0.5 [4 + 8] /2 28 The advantage with the formula for arc elasticity is that price elasticity from A to B is equal to that from B to A. This isn’t the case with the formula of point elasticity. ? 1. Why do we always insert a negative sign in front of demand elasticity? 2. What is meant by perfect inelasticity and infinite elasticity? 3. Describe and illustrate the five categories of supply elasticity 4. Mr. Juma is a butcher who recently raised the price of steak at his market from Tshs 2000 to 2500 per kilo. Correspondingly, his sales dropped from 500 kilos to 400 kilos per day. Is the demand for steak at mr. Juma’s market elastic or inelastic? Show your workings 5. At Tshs 250 a piece, Mr. Mwema sells 100 chocolate bars per week. If he drops his price to Tshs 200, his weekly sales will increase to 110 bars. Is the demand for chocolate bars elastic or inelastic? 29 LECTURE FIVE FUNDAMENTAL ECONOMIC CONCEPTS FOR ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY ANALYSIS 5.1 Introduction The main goal of this lecture is to introduce you to the application of the principles of microeconomic analysis to environmental policy questions. We have seen above that Economics is the study of the allocation of scarce resources. Economics is a theory of how markets can be used to allocate scarce resources. However, note that markets are not the only way to allocate scarce resources (e.g. command economy). Microeconomics studies the interaction among individual economic units. The two key questions are therefore: • How to utilize resources most efficiently - What to produce? - How to produce it? E.g. how much capital and how much labor • How to allocate the goods and services that is produced - In a market economy, goods and services are allocated based on ability to pay. Key concepts in economics we are going to discuss in this lecture are those concepts that we will come back to throughout the course, as they are fundamental to the way economists think. I introduce them now to highlight their importance. At the end of this section you are expected to be able to define and explain the following concepts: 1. Marginal analysis 2. Sunk costs 3. Opportunity costs 4. Scarcity and models of scarcity 5. Positive Economics 6. Normative Economics 5.2 Marginal analysis Economists focus on things at the margin – that is, what is the benefit of the next good that is bought or sold. Once you have purchased something, what matters is what you will do next. Can you make yourself any better? Our goal is to maximize total net benefit: the value of the good minus the cost. To do this, we focus on the marginal benefits (MB) and marginal costs (MC). • If MB > MC, total benefit will increase. You should purchase. 30 • If MC > MB, total benefit will decrease. Do not purchase. • The only time that total benefit will not rise or fall is when MB = MC. This is where total net benefit is maximized. 5.3 Sunk costs Sunk costs are expenditures that have been made and cannot be recovered. Following from marginal analysis, sunk costs should be ignored. Since sunk costs cannot be changed, they should not influence decision-making. 5.4 Opportunity costs Opportunity cost is the value of the best alternative use of a resource. It is the cost of forgone opportunities. For some students who could have been working and earning a salary, the opportunity cost of foregoing their jobs by undertaking university studies is tuition fees plus the salary they forgo by not working. Opportunity costs are important to consider, but often ignored. Opportunity costs relate to the key concept of scarcity (this is covered well in net section). Once a resource has been used, it cannot be used for something else. 5.5 Scarcity: The Key Problem in Economics Scarcity is the key problem in economics Economists study how incentives affect individual behavior. Due to scarce resources, individual behavior is constrained. Economists study how incentives affect the choices people make when faced with these constraints. Although economists often discuss prices as the incentive mechanism, the incentives can be offered in other ways as well. 5.6 Positive Economics Vs Normative Economics Note that there are two types of economic analysis: • Positive economics – studies how the economy actually functions. It is purely descriptive, e.g. how do people respond to higher energy prices? • Normative economics – the study of whether or not the economy produces socially desirable results. This requires value judgments, e.g. what is the best way to reduce gasoline consumption (e.g. tax, oil import tariff)? Even though we cannot prove scientifically which values are correct, we can have rational discussions about them, and can evaluate what goals are being met – leaving it to politics, etc. to decide which goals should be met. 31 When economists discuss how people respond to incentives, it is positive analysis. For example, when we say that firms maximize profits, we are describing behavior we observe, not stating whether or not we think it is correct. Contrast with a moral approach to the environment – that polluting is the result of unethical behavior, and the solution is to increase awareness and morality. Thus, an important question is why do we wish to protect the environment? Is it so that environmental resources can provide us with benefits, or are there more basic ethical reasons? The answer to this question can affect the level and types of protection desired. 5.7 Models of Scarcity: The Key Problem in Economics Popular models of scarcity include among others the following: 5.7.1 Malthus Model: because land is fixed, scarcity is inevitable. Malthus noted that, since the supply of land was fixed, scarcity was inevitable. Because land was fixed, Malthus argued that diminishing returns to labor must set in as population grew. Population would grow faster than the marginal product of labor. He noted that population grew geometrically (1,2,4,8…), but food grew arithmetically (1,2,3,4…). Malthus predicted that population growth would stop when the limits of the food supply were met. There are reasons as to why Malthus was wrong. • Malthus ignored factors other than labor. • Technological change made inputs more productive. • It may be that we simply haven't reached the point in which population growth passes food growth, but perhaps that point is coming. 5.7.2 IPAT : Devised by biologist Paul Ehrlich in 1971 According to Ehrlich, environmental Impact = Population*Affluence*Technology. The concern is that growing population puts increased pressure on the environment. He advised two ways on how increased impacts can be avoided: • Increases in technology • Increase the effect of affluence by providing alternatives. For example reducing the impact of cars by increasing public transportation. 5.7.3 Doomsday Models: computer models that predicted severe shortages of resources The most famous is The Limits to Growth. A key feature missing from these models is prices i.e. as resources become scarcer, prices rise. This leads to: increased conservation, the development 32 of new technologies, and exploration for new resources. As an example, Limits to Growth predicted there were 550 billion barrels of oil reserves, and predicted they could be used up in 20 years. Instead, between 1970 and 1990, 600 billion barrels of oil were used. In 2007, there were 740 billion barrels of known reserves in the Middle East alone. Globally, there are about 1.3 trillion barrels of known reserves. As oil became more expensive, more exploration was done, and previously underutilized sources of oil, such as the North Sea and the Northern Slope of Alaska, became viable. Because of new technologies and new resource discoveries, the price of most resources has actually fallen over time! In addition, food prices for example, have fallen by 50% worldwide since 1960, and 90% since 1800. However, do note that the prices established by the market may not be correct, because they do not account for environmental damage. This leads to the question of market failure which we are going to cover later in this course. 5.7.4 Lomborg Model: pessimistic predictions get more attention than reality Lomborg discusses why he thinks that pessimistic predictions get more attention than reality. For instance: • Funding for scientific research goes to areas with many problems • Environmental groups need to be noticed by both the mass media and by potential donors. • Attitude of the media- bad news is more interesting than good news. • Poor individual perception - faulty risk perceptions 33 LECTURE SIX MARKET STRUCTURES 6.1 Introduction Market structures refer to characteristics of the forms of organizations or firms which enable them to exercise a strategic influence on the nature of competitiveness and pricing in the market. Such aspects include the following: size and number of firms, conditions of entry to the market, goals of firms, the degree of product differentiation and Degree of knowledge about the market. These aspects are used to mark or explain the difference and similarities among these structures and we will be referring to them throughout this lecture. Market structures can be classified into four types according to the number of firms in the industry/market namely Perfect Competition, Monopoly, Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly. We are going to discuss them all in this lecture. By the end of this lecture you should be able to: 1. Explain characteristics of perfect competition, monopoly, price discrimination, oligopoly and monopolistic competition 2. Discuss the advantages and disadvantages of the market structures 3. Explain factors that may cause a market to be monopolistic 6.2 Perfect competition This is a market structure with the following characteristics: (a) There are many sellers (firms) of the same size and many buyers. Therefore one firm cannot influence the market price; as such sellers are price takers and not price makers. (b) Homogenous products - There is no any product differentiation so competition is centred on only prices. (c) Free entry and exit - when firms earn abnormal profits, other firms are free to join the market and exhaust the profits. When there are no profits they are also free to leave the market. (d) Perfect knowledge - no ignorance on side of buyers and sellers in the market. There is perfect knowledge about future trends relevant to their decision making presently. (e) Perfect mobility of factors of production - factors of production can move freely from one firm to another but not monopolized. 34 (f) No government regulation - no tariffs, subsidies, rationing, price controls etc by the government. (g) Profit and utility maximization - while all sellers aim at profit maximization, consumers (buyers) aim at buying cheaply to maximize utility. In practice, there is no perfect knowledge about the market by both sellers and buyers in pure competition. In addition the assumption that the factors of production are freely mobile among firms is not fulfilled in pure competition. So though sellers are also price takers but there is an element of monopoly in pure competition. 6.2.1 Advantages of Perfect Competition (a) In the Long run, there is efficiency in production and full utilization of factors of production. (b) In the Long run consumers enjoy high standard of living because more commodities are available at cheaper prices. (c) There is no wastage of funds in advertising. (d) There is improvement in quality of products. 6.2.2 Disadvantages of Perfect Competition (a) Consumers cannot enjoy a variety of commodities since commodities are homogenous. (b) In the Long run, expansion of the firm may be very difficult because there are no enough profits to `plough back.' (c) Research may be impossible because profits earned are not enough to cater for research activities. (d) There is a high risk of unemployment when inefficient firms are pushed out of the market. (e) Public utilities such as water supply and roads may not survive in perfect competition hence need for government intervention. (f) Assumptions of perfect competition are unrealistic and may be misleading. 6.3 Monopoly This is a market situation where there is one seller of a product which has no close substitutes. No persuasive advertising and also entry of new firms is restricted. In Pure Monopoly there is one firm, which deals in a product that has no substitutes at all. In practice there is no pure monopoly 35 because there is no commodity, which has no close substitutes at all. Monopoly is a market situation where there is only one buyer of commodity or a factor of production e.g. one employer. 6.3.1 Factors leading to Monopoly The factors that lead to monopoly include: (a) Patent rights - examples authors of books, where the law forbids other firms to deal with the same. (b) Ownership of strategic raw materials - These are usually under the government control e.g. minerals. (c) Exclusive methods of production e.g. Genetically Modified crop production. (d) Long distance among products - this results to each producer monopolizing the market in his locality commonly called Spatial Monopoly. (e) Advantage of large scale of production which makes small competitors unable to compete successfully with large firms. Also where there is room for only one seller e.g. electricity supply, railways etc, usually such understanding is controlled by the government since they are government utilities, thereby creating natural monopolies in the market. (f) Protectionism - this is when foreign trade barriers are imposed on the product to exclude foreign competitors. In such way a local producer may become a monopolist. (g) Take-overs and mergers - `take over' occurs when one firm takes over the assets and organization of another whereas mergers are formed when firms combine their assets and organizations into one to achieve strong market position. Both situations usually may result into monopoly. (h) Collective (Collusive) monopoly - this occurs when firms come together in a formal or informal agreement to achieve monopoly power since they can fix quotas, or limit pricing (setting very low price with the objective of preventing new entry of other firms). 6.3.2 Examples of Monopolies in Tanzania (as of 2004) (i) Tanzania Electricity Supply Company (TANESCO) (ii)Tanzania Railways Corporation (TRC). (iii) Coffee Marketing Board (CMB) - However the monopoly of CMB is gradually being scaled down by allowing private exporters to participate in the market. (iv) Dar es salaam Water and Sewerage Authority (DAWASA). 36 It should be noted that a monopolist has no supply curve because he is the sole controller of the output in the market. So there is no unique relationship between market price and quantity supplied. This implies that short run and long run monopoly firms are the same. 6.3.3 Advantages of Monopoly (i) Resources are saved since there is no duplication of services. This means that if there is one hydroelectric power (HEP) plant, there may not be a need to set up another one in the same area. (ii) Infant industries can grow up when they are kept from competition. (iii) No need of persuasive advertising, which leads to wastage of resources as well as increased prices. (iv) Control by the government of public utilities like roads, telephone etc. (v) Research can be carried out using the abnormal profits. (vi) There is a possibility of selling the same commodity at different prices which benefits the low income earners. (vii) Firms enjoy economies of scale since they can use the abnormal profits to expand production. 6.3.4 Disadvantages of Monopoly (i) The firm can become inefficient and produce low quality products. (ii) Firms produce at excess capacity i.e. they under-utilize their resources so that they produce less output to boost prices. (iii) Shortage of the commodity in case a monopoly firm stops producing. (iv) A higher price than in perfect competition is changed. (v) Since monopolist firms are controllers of production, they at times exert pressure on governments thereby influencing decision-making. 6.3.5 Measures to Control Monopoly Due to the above disadvantages, the following measures can be used to control the monopolist's activities: (a) The government can fix prices of commodities. 37 (b) The government can impose taxes to tax away the abnormal profits. However, if not taken with care the burden of taxation may be shifted to the final consumers in form of high prices. (c) Nationalization of monopolists by the government. (d) Subsidization of new firms for them to compete with monopolist firms. (e) Anti-monopoly (antitrust) legislation - laws are imposed to control monopolies. The laws can inhibit monopolization and collusion among firms to raise prices to inhibit competition. 6.4 Price Discrimination under Monopoly Price discrimination exists when the commodity is sold at different prices irrespective of the cost of production. Price discrimination may also be used to sell units of the same commodity at different prices to the same customer e.g. telephone charges being high on first 3 minutes and then low on the other minutes. There are various forms of price discrimination according to: (a) Personal income - rich people are charged higher prices than poor people. (b) Sex or age of customers. (c) Geographical discrimination. (d) Time of service e.g. higher price in the morning and low in the evening. (e) Nature of product e.g. higher prices on branded commodities than unbranded ones of the same type. (f) Use of the product - e.g. low transport charges for inputs and high charges for luxuries for the same means of transport and same distance. (g) Differentiation of the commodities - high prices of cold drinks in tourist hotels and low price of the same type of drinks in non-tourist hotels. Price discrimination occurs only when a monopolist sells the commodity and it becomes impossible for buyers to transfer the commodity from where the price is low to where the price is high. Again the elasticity of demand should be different in different market segments whereby a higher price should be charged in the market where elasticity of demand is low than where elasticity of demand is high. 6.4.1 Advantages of Price Discrimination (a) Total output sold increases thereby increasing total revenue of the seller. (b) It is the way the rich subsidize the poor thus income distribution. 38 (c) Enables the poor to get essential services at low prices. (d) It helps producers to dispose off surplus commodities e.g. dumping. (e) It increases sales and consumption. Price discrimination has similar disadvantages as those of monopolies. 6.5 Monopolistic competition This market structure has similar characteristics to those of perfect competition except that the commodity in question in monopolistic competition is not homogenous. Products, though closely substituting, are differential in form of packaging, design, quality etc. So there is need for persuasive advertising and the seller has some control over the market price due to differentiation e.g. restaurants, vehicle garages, hair salons etc. 6.5.1 Advantages of Monopolistic Competition (a) Consumers get a variety of products because of product differentiation. (b) The quality of products is improved. 6.5.2 Disadvantages of Monopolistic Competition (a) There is under-utilization of the resources - there is excess capacity and output produced is lower than that in perfect competition. (b) In the long run, there is no profit to make improvements, so the firm may not enjoy economies of scale. (c) The price charged on buyers is higher than in perfect competition. (d) No research is carried in the long run because no abnormal profits. (e) Need for advertising thereby increasing costs and the price. 6.6 Oligopoly This market structure is characterised by the following: (a) There are few, unequal, competing sellers. Each seller (firm) is faced with competition from other sellers. However each has got market power and therefore cannot be a price taker. (b) There is non-price competition - e.g advertising and quantity of services that if one seller reduces the price, others may do the same and all end up losing. (c) In most cases there is product differentiation. (d) Each firm is concerned with activities of other firms so as to act/respond accordingly. 39 6.6.1 Examples of Oligopolies in Tanzania: (a) Dealers in beer: Safari, Heinken, Serengeti, Hakuna Matata etc. (b) Dealers in petrol: Oilcom, Caltex, BP, Total, Agip, Shell etc. At times, firms avoid underselling each other (price war), by coming into an agreement (cartel) whereby they fix quotas and sometimes fix prices to restrain competition. This makes oligopolist behave like a monopolist. ? REVIEW QUESTIONS 1) What is pure competition? What are the conditions necessary for the perfect competition? 2) Is it possible for many firms to sell exactly the same product, and still be in monopolistic competition? 40 LECTURE SEVEN MARKET FAILURES FOR ENVIRONMENTAL RESOURCES 7.1 Introduction A market failure is something that is inherent to the market that causes the market equilibrium allocation to be inefficient. There is a famous theorem in welfare economics that shows that under certain conditions the allocation of resources in long-run competitive equilibrium is efficient. This result is both amazing and fantastic; somehow, everyone doing their selfish best, ignoring their impacts on others, results in an efficient allocation from society’s perspective. Wow – Adam Smith’s invisible hand at work. When this theorem is presented, often the details are passed over and the presenter does not emphasize that the result only holds under certain conditions. Pure competition only achieves efficiency in the absence of market failures. Market failures are numerous in the resource and environmental sector of the economy. The market fails in the allocation of many environmental and natural resources, making the overall allocation of resources inefficient: Adam Smith’s invisible foot tripping up the allocation of resources. At the end of this section you are expected to be able to: 1. Explain the Adam Smith’s invisible hand phenomenon and its implications on environmental resources 2. 7.2 Describe externalities and other market failures and their categories The Invisible Hand The main objective of this lecture is to discuss why the free/competitive market we discussed in the previous chapter may fail, and to discuss the consequences when that happens. To begin, we must consider how the market should function. Adam Smith, who coined the phrase "The Invisible Hand," was the first classical economist to notice that a free market of individuals acting in their own self interest leads to a socially-desirable result. He explained why this occurs as follows: • Demand = Marginal Benefit (MB) • Supply = Marginal Cost (MC) • In equilibrium, Price (P) = MB = MC At equilibrium point no further beneficial transactions are possible. Normally, a free market brings us to this point. However, there are times when private marginal benefits or costs are not equal to social marginal benefits or costs. When this occurs, the market is unable to allocate 41 resources efficiently. We call this market failure. The welfare lost because beneficial transactions do not occur is known as deadweight loss. 7.3 Categories (Causes) of market failures We now need to examine the different sorts of market failure and see how they prevent the market from achieving efficiency. Let us identify and briefly explain some of the categories of market failures (common property, externalities, public commodities, excess market power, lack of markets, and distortions in capital markets). This classification is arbitrary and probably not complete. Also, the categories often overlap. 7.3.1 Common property resources are one category of market failure. The market (or lack of) puts a zero price on common-property resources. A resource is common property if access to it is not controlled. That is, it is common property if no one effectively owns the resource. While few resources in this world are pure common-property resources (access to them is completely uncontrolled), access to many environmental resources is largely uncontrolled, or controlled to only a limited extent. Common Property Resources (also called Open Access Resources) are resources or facilities that are open to uncontrolled access by individuals who wish to use the resource. The problem is a lack of property rights. Consider someone using a public grazing area. • Individuals equate MB = MC • The benefits are the value of using the grass. • There are two costs: The cost of obtaining the resource and the opportunity cost of not being able to use the resource later The user bears all of the first cost, but only part of the second cost, as it is shared by all users. As a result, MPC < MSC. Thus, MB = MPC < MSC. This leads to overutilization of the resource. A common-property fishery causes the market to fail, so will a common property oil field, a common-property wilderness area, a commonly-owned air space, and a commonproperty rain forest. The common-property nature of many animals is a significant contributor to their being endangered. Aficionados of inadequate property rights make many subtle distinctions between different degrees of property rights. Hopefully they will excuse me for lumping them all together; one needs to start simple. 42 The common-property nature of the air in many places is a major reason for excessive air pollution from an efficiency perspective. Consider a commercial fisherman. They produce caught fish, which they sell. Inputs into the production of caught fish include labor, capital and fish swimming around in water. The capital and labor is used to get the fish out of the water and onto the dock. Labor and capital are not common-property resources, so must be paid for. If the fish stock is owned, the fisherman will have to pay the owner for each fish harvested, and the owner will charge an amount sufficient to cover the decreased value of the stock because it is reduced in size by the harvest. Put simply, the fisherman will have to pay the opportunity costs of all of the inputs it uses to produce docked fish. Contrast this with the meat-packing company that must pay the rancher to harvest his cattle. The rancher controls access to his herd, so won’t give them up for free. Alternatively, if the stock is common property with no owner who charges for harvesting from the stock, the commercial fisherman will not take into account the opportunity cost to society of reducing the stock because he or she will not have to pay this cost. That is, when an input is free, people will overuse it – not surprising. Many of the ocean’s fisheries are or have been common-property resources. Why are some resources common property but many others not? “In the beginning” there was no need to control access to resources. Most resources are now scarce but when man first arrived on the scene, scarcity was not a big issue – big garden with only two residents and a talkative snake. All resources started off as common property but now access is controlled for many of them. However, even now, after years of private-property capitalism, there remain resources that are both terribly scarce and effectively common property. This happens, in part, because the characteristics of some natural resources make them expensive for either a private agent or the government to define and enforce property rights. Think about why cows are not common property, but many ocean fish are? Cows were bred to minimize the cost of controlling them: stupid, can’t jump over fences, easy to spot, cheap to brand, kids stand next to mom, and willing to wait in line to be slaughtered– how convenient. Wild fish, on the other hand, are very difficult to keep track off. Maybe we need to breed domestic fish which don’t like to run around!!!! Contrary to popular belief, private property and the market system were not created by God. 43 There are cultural and historical reasons that some resources remain common property. People who exploit common-property resources get very upset when someone suggests they should pay to use the resource. “My father fished here, my grandfather fished here, my great-grandfather ….It is my god-given right.” Selling stuff like clean air to the highest bidder makes many people queasy, not economists, but maybe they are a different species. 7.3.2 Externalities are another class of market failure To define externalities let us first define external effects: An external effect exists if the actions of one or more economic agents enter as direct arguments in the utility or production functions of other economic agents. That is, an external effect exists if the actions of one economic agent directly affect one or more other economic agents. Externalities: There is an externality if an economic agent(s) does something that directly influences (not indirectly through market prices) some other economic agent(s) and there is the potential to make one of the parties better off without making some of the others involved worse off. It is important to get the wording just right. Or, equivalently, there is an externality if an external effect is produced at an inefficient level. Contrast direct effects with indirect effects. A footballer kicking the ball on you in the face is a direct effect; but a rich footballers buying houses in Mbezi Beach and driving up housing prices in the area affects you, but not directly – it is an indirect effect. Effects felt through the market place are indirect effects. The existence of a negative or positive non-price impact on others (external effects) is necessary but not sufficient for the existence of an externality. If the provision of the external effect is at the efficient level there is no externality, even though there are external effects. • Think of examples of negative and positive external effects. Then speculate on how likely they are or aren’t produced at inefficient levels. • What might cause an external effect to be produced at the efficient level? Or not produced at the efficient level? 44 Consider smoking: If smokers are allowed to smoke wherever and however much they want (with not regulation or incentive to cut back) there is likely to be an inefficient level of smoking –too much. Why, because the private cost to the individual of smoking another cigarette is less than the cost to society of him smoking another cigarette. If smoking is taxed such that the efficient amount of secondhand smoke is produced, the efficient amount of smoke is produced and the amount is positive. There is no externality even though some individuals continue to be injured by the secondhand smoke. Consider a second example. If the efficient amount of secondhand smoke is achieved through a regulation, there is no externality, and people are still adversely affected by the remaining secondhand smoke. Elaborating on the definition of an externality: An externality is an activity of one entity that affects the welfare of another and is not reflected in market prices. A key feature of this definition is that the welfare of others is not reflected in market prices. To find the efficient level of activity, we need to know the marginal social cost. Marginal social cost is the sum of marginal private costs and the marginal external costs, which represent the damage done by the externally. Note that, without policy, the free market will not lead to an efficient solution. Prices will reflect private costs, but not the additional external costs. When the external effect is positive and the economic agents who produced the effect are compensated to take full account of their actions, there is no externality. It does not matter whether the funds for that compensation are collected from the agents who benefited from the action or from some other source. Whether producers of the positive externalities should be compensated is an equity issue. And, when the effect is negative and the economic agents who produced the effect are required to fully incorporate the damages produced, there is no externality. If the negative externality is internalized with a Pigouvian tax (a per-unit tax on pollution), it does not matter whether the funds collected are paid to the damaged agents. Whether they should be is an issue of equity. In summary, if the producer of the external effect has the correct incentive to take the effects into account there is no externality. Note that if a tax (subsidy) internalizes an externality, the tax revenues collected (total subsidy paid) will not necessarily equal the total damages to the injured (value of the benefits received). Efficient taxes/subsidies are, in general, based on marginal effects rather than total effects. 45 Externalities result when property rights are not well defined. Therefore, one might conclude that common property and externalities are closely linked. Could externalities exist if all property rights were well defined? 7.3.3 Public Commodities Public commodities possess the property that multiple agents can consume the same units of the commodity. That is, the commodity is noncongestible in the sense that one agent's consumption of a unit does no preclude or impinge on another agent's consumption of that same unit. Another term for non-congestible is non-rivalous. Most economists would agree that non-congestible is a necessary condition for a commodity to be a public commodity, but some economists would conclude it is not a sufficient condition. Some would add the property of non-excludable, meaning that once units of the commodity are provided to one agent no other agent can be excluded from consuming those same units. The definition of a public commodity can be further restricted by assuming, in addition to non-congestible and non-excludible, that everyone is forced to consume all units of the public commodity produced. Note that this last condition does not require that all are affected the same, but does imply non-excludible. A commodity is a private commodity if one agent’s consumption of a unit of the commodity precludes another agent’s consumption of those same units – we can’t both eat the same ice cream cone. Note that paying for a commodity is not a necessary condition for the commodity to be a private commodity. If it was, a commodity would not be a private commodity if someone received it as a gift. Thus we can define public commodities as those commodities that are noncongestible and everyone consumes every unit of the commodity that is produced. Public goods that are provided by the government are not necessarily public goods. For example, roads and public schools are not public goods in our sense of the word. So, we need to distinguish between public goods and goods provided by the government. The air is not a public good. It is definitely congestible and no two individuals can consume the same unit of air. If air was noncongestible, pollution would not be a problem and everyone could breathe the same liter of air. There are no pure public good, and no pure private goods: consumption always has some effect, often small, on others. It is probably better to use the word commodity than the word good when discussing public commodities because many public commodities are goods for some members of society and bads for other members. 46 Public goods have two key features: First is non-rival i.e. one person enjoying the good does not keep others from enjoying it. Second feature of public goods is that they are Non-excludable i.e. people cannot be kept from enjoying the good. This leads to free-rider problem. Because the goods are non-rival, efficiency requires that the sum of each individual's marginal benefit equal marginal cost. Underprovision results when public goods are provided by a free market e.g. climate, clean air, parks etc. The government can provide public goods and finance them with taxes. This helps to alleviate the free-rider problem. However, it still may be difficult to get people to reveal their true preferences for the good. The market is incapable of efficiently allocating public goods. This is the heart of public economics. The main reason is that a producer of the public good can’t make all those who benefit from its availability pay for it. The producer does not have the ability to “tax”, and people won’t freely pay for something if they can get automatically get it for free when someone else pays the cost of production. In more detail, society wants public commodities produced up to the point where the cost to society of the last unit produced (marginal social cost) is just equal to the benefits to society from the last unit produced (the marginal social benefits). Marginal social benefits are the sum of benefits all members of society get from the last unit produced. A private firm will produce units of the public commodity up to the point where marginal private cost of production (maybe equal to marginal social costs) equals marginal revenue, but for public commodities marginal revenue will be way less than marginal social benefits: there is no way the firm can get all member of society to pay the amount that they value the last unit produced because once a unit is produced everybody consumes it regardless of whether they pay. Only an entity with the power to tax (the government) can produce public commodities in the efficient quantities. Cite as many examples as possible to distinguish between public resources and common property resources. 7.3.4 Excess Market power (monopoly and oligopoly) The excess market power in resource and good markets are another category of market failure. Monopoly power prevents the market from achieving efficiency. In general, excess market power causes the producer to under-produce from society’s perspective. Under-producing from 47 society’s perspective is how a monopolist makes excess profits. The monopolist can control total production of the product, so can produce less than would have been produced by a competitive industry. It does this because the decrease in units sold is more that made up for by the higher price it charges – doing this increases its profits. There is a lot of monopoly and oligopoly power in the resources sector, e.g., big oil companies, big mineral companies, OPEC, etc. Firms that harvest natural resources are often large. Note that monopolistic holders of scare natural and environmental resources tend to be the conservationist’s friend, and this is typically not a good thing. If, for example, only competitive firms owned oil reserves, every year more of each year’s reserves would be extracted than if the oil reserves were owned by only one or only a few agents (firms, governments, etc.). 7.3.5 Lack of markets The market cannot efficiently allocate resources if markets do not exist for some of those resources. If there is no market for beer (places where beer is bought and sold), the market economy won’t efficiently produce or allocate beer. There is only a very limited market for the use of air. Water markets are imperfect, at best, and often non-existent, the same is true for many other environmental resources and amenities. In the U.S for example., there are tradable permits for SO2 emissions. Many potentially important futures markets don’t exist. A futures market for commodity X is a market where one can buy and sell X today for delivery at some specified future data, and payment either now or at some specified future date. Society wants to achieve intertemporal efficiency in the use of its scarce natural resources, but the market cannot do it if markets for the future delivery of these resources do not exist. Assuming three generations (now, the near future, and the distant future) define intertemporal efficiency. If we want the market to efficiently allocate oil between now and 2050, a market has to exist where one can buy and sell oil now for delivery in 2050 and payment either now or in 2050. If there are no long run futures markets for oil, producers are more likely to leave too little in the ground for the future. Markets require well-defined property rights, including enforcement, and low transactions costs. Lack of these will result in a lack of markets. This suggests that one way 48 to reduce the inefficiencies associated with market failures is to create markets, future or otherwise, where they do not currently exist. This can be achieved through: • Clear up ambiguities with reference to property rights; that is, make sure property rights are well defined • Create institutions and policies that will decrease the cost of trades Examples of new markets – the U.S. market for SO2 emissions, EBay, and the web in general. The effect could, in theory, go the other direction, but this is unlikely. 7.3.6 Distortions in capital markets That is, the market rate of interest is either too high or too low from an efficiency perspective. The following sorts of factors would cause such distortions: • Lack of access to capital markets by some of the players in the market place. For example, poor farmers in poor countries often have no place they could go to borrow money for seeds and fertilizer. Micro-credit, a recently new phenomenon, is a program to fill this gap in credit markets; it proves small loans (a few hundred dollars at most) to small businesses in developing countries. • Racial minorities often have less access to credit than others. For ethical reasons one cannot use human capital as collateral for a loan. While this is good from an ethical point, it likely causes inefficiency in the capital market. If human capital was collateral on a loan and one faulted on a loan, the loaner would then own your capital – this is called slavery, and it is frowned upon. 7.3.7 Imperfect Information The market depends on perfect information, so that everyone knows all of the options available to them. If this is not possible, people may not make optimal choices. Note that imperfect information is when different parties have different levels of information. If no one realizes an activity is bad, imperfect information is not the problem. It may be that the result is uncertain. Uncertainty is an important consideration for environmental policy, which we will discuss later in the course. However, if all sides have the same knowledge, even if uncertainty exists, imperfect information is not a problem. Imperfect information is relevant to environmental economics because people may have imperfect information about things such as health risks or the dangers of pollution. To overcome or lessen impact of imperfect information the following can be done: 49 • Information can be provided by the government or by private individuals. • The government may provide services that are not provided by the market because of imperfect information (e.g. insurance). One must distinguish between market failure in capital markets and a divergence between the market rates of interest and the social rate of discount due to intergenerational equity issues. We have been talking a lot about market failures. The following is a list a set of conditions that increase the likelihood that there will be no market failures; that is, conditions under which the competitive equilibrium will be efficient. i) Well-defined property rights for all scarce resources ii) Well-developed markets for all scarce resources iii) Complete set of futures markets iv) All markets competitive as possible v) Absence of external effects vi) Absence of public commodities We have talked a lot about how the market does or doesn’t do a good job of allocating resources We need to keep in mind what markets are. The market system is an institution that developed to allocate resources and allocate goods and service. There are other institutions that have also evolved to allocate resources and distribute goods. They include: the government, the family, centrally planned economies, tribes, dictators, the religious institutions, etc. They all have their advantages and disadvantages. Note that some of the largest centrally-planned economies are big corporations such as Microsoft and Wal-Mart. While, ceteris paribus efficiency is a good thing…..If society had to choose between a specific efficient allocation that was very unfair and a specific inefficient allocation that was fairer, a welfare maximizing society might choose the inefficient allocation over the efficient allocation. 50 LECTURE EIGHT VALUING ENVIRONMENTAL BENEFITS 8.1 Introduction The most controversial aspect of analyzing the costs and benefits of environmental aspects is placing a value on human life. Two questions deserve asking concerning the true meaning of value: Is it merely the opportunity cost (e.g. foregone wages)? Or Are there other values (perhaps non-market values) that need to be considered? In this lecture we will consider various ways used to assign a value and hence willing to pay for the envisaged environmental benefits. First let us start with the concepts of the value of a life. At the end of this section you are expected to be able to: 1. Describe the concept of value in relation to the environment 2. Explain different Revealed Preference Approaches (RPA) of valuing environmental policy and resources 3. Explain Stated Preference Approaches (SPA) of valuing environmental policy and resources 8.2 Concepts of the value of a life The most commonly used value is the value of a statistical life. We don't know who will die, but we expect someone will. The value of environmental protection is lessening the risk of someone dying. Note that specific deaths capture the attention of individuals. However, that is not what a statistical life focuses on. We are valuing changes in the probability that a random individual will die, by asking what the willingness to pay for changes in risk. For policy, this is the most appropriate measure, because policy does not prevent death, but rather changes the probability that death will occur. The value can also be put into annual figures as Value of a Statistical Life Year (VSLY). Contrast this with the optimal insurance and compensation of accident victims. Here, things such as the opportunity cost of foregone wages and medical expenses make sense, since now we are focusing on a specific loss. Let us now reflect ourselves to consider what makes up the value of environmental amenities: a) Use value This is the benefits people get from direct use of a good. For most consumer goods, this is what we care about. For environmental goods, this can include but limited to the value of recreation at 51 a site, the value of open land near a home, the value from better health, and the value of ecological services provided (e.g. by a wetland) b) Non-use value For environmental goods, not all value is use value. Examples of non-use value include the following: i) Option value – the amount a person would be willing to pay to preserve the option of being able to experience a particular environmental amenity in the future. Even if you won’t go to the Ngorongoro Crater this year, preserving it may have value to you so that you can visit in the future. ii) Existence value – a willingness to pay simply to help preserve the existence of some environmental amenity. Protection of endangered species is an example. iii) Bequest value – a willingness to pay to leave behind environmental quality for future generations. iv) Stewardship value – a value placed on preserving the environment not for human use, but rather to maintain the health of the environment for all living organisms. To measure value, economists focus on willingness to pay (WTP). We can see willingness to pay from a demand curve we covered earlier in this course. WTP is simply the area under the demand curve. Recall that the difference between what consumers actually pay and the actual price is the consumer surplus. Willingness to pay includes actual expenditures and consumer surplus. Thus, simply using a direct measure of expenditures ignores the consumer surplus, and underestimates the value. Putting these together, the net value is the sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus. Since policy analysis should focus on marginal analysis, we want to ask how these change as we have an incremental change in pollution. Economists typically use one of the following two approaches to measure the benefits of environmental quality: Revealed Preference Approaches RPA) and Stated Preference Techniques (SPT). Let us discuss each of these approaches in the rest of this lecture. 8.3 Revealed Preference Approaches (RPA) RPAs infer the value of environmental goods from other market transactions. Note that revealed preference approaches get at use values, but not non-use values. The most popular RPAs include 52 aversion costs, travel cost method, and hedonic pricing techniques. We will briefly discuss these approaches in the rest of this section. 8.3.1 Aversion Costs This refers to expenditures necessary to reduce risk. For example, how much more will people spend for a car with airbags, or for bottled drinking water? The main challenge is separating value assigned to changing risk to other characteristics (e.g. other features of the car, or better taste for bottled water). Note that, in reaction to environmental harms, people may undergo expenses to remedy the problem. For example, filters for drinking water, air conditioners so that windows can remain closed, medication to mask symptoms of health effects, shrubbery to hide a polluted neighboring site etc. By studying how much people spend on averting expenditures, we can estimate the benefits they would receive if the harm were removed. Example: a study of Los Angeles in 1986 found that people would pay $0.97 to avoid shortness of breath to $23.87 to avoid chest tightness. In order to reduce risks through increased expenditure requires people to have perfect information about risks, and to be able to evaluate this information properly. People must take risks knowingly and willingly? 8.3.2 Travel Cost Method The travel cost method looks at how far visitors travel to come to a site. By placing a value on the cost of travel, we can infer the value of the site. The travel cost includes both direct costs (e.g. airfare) and indirect costs (e.g. the opportunity cost of travel time). We can infer the value of a change in quality by looking at demand during different days (e.g. in different types of weather). Example: Some USA economists surveyed 826 tourists in Florida and asked interviewees the following questions from which they could derive a demand curve: how many days did you use the beach? Where are you from? How much did it cost to get there? What is the total length of your stay? The results were that average tourist spent 4.7 days at the beach and the average daily expense was $85. To calculate consumer surplus, the economists needed to know the slope of the demand curve. Using regression analysis, they found that demand for beach days was inelastic i.e. 10% increase in “price” leads to a 1.5% decrease in time on the beach. Using this, they could plot the demand curve and found that the consumer surplus for 4.7 days = 53 $179 (average of $38/day). To get a total value of beaches, they note that tourists spend 70 million tourist days/year on the beach, hence concluding that the total value of Florida beaches = $2.37 billion. There are some potential problems with the travel cost method ie: • What is the opportunity cost of time? • Only measures value of those that use the amenity. We need to account for substitutes. For example, do all beach users in Florida come for the beaches, or are they there for other reasons (e.g. Disney)? • Quality is not always measured. • Sampling bias in surveys. 8.3.3 Hedonic Pricing Techniques Hedonic pricing techniques look at the value that people place on the attributes of a good. That is, it assumes that people don't value a house itself, but rather the features of a house (e.g. number of rooms, location, is there a fireplace). One such feature is environmental quality. Using regression analysis, we can find the correlation between housing prices and environmental quality in an area. Most studies find an elasticity of housing prices with respect to pollution that is around 0.1. That is, a 1% decrease in pollution leads to a 0.1% increase in housing prices. A sample study is "The Determinants of Residential Property Values with Special Reference to Air Pollution," By Ronald G. Ridker and John A. Henning (Review of Economics and Statistics, May 1967). If you are interested in reading the article, you can click on the title to be taken to it in J-Stor (http://jstor.org/cgi-bin/jstor/viewitem) 8.4 Stated Preference Approaches (SPA): Contingent Valuation SPAs ask individuals hypothetical questions about their willingness to pay to protect environmental resources. So far, we have studied revealed preference approaches to valuing environmental amenities. Those approaches look at actual market transactions to infer value. Unfortunately, there aren't always market transactions that can serve this purpose. For example, how do we value protection of endangered species? In these cases, economists simply ask people for their valuation. The most common technique is contingent valuation (CV). 54 Is the CV method capable of providing estimates of lost nonuse or existence values that are reliable enough to be used in natural resource damage assessments? How contingent valuation works: i) Ask people their willingness to pay (WTP) to bring about a specific environmental improvement. The problem must be described carefully and it must be specific. Types of questions: • open-ended - ask respondents for maximum WTP. • close-ended -ask respondents whether they are WTP a certain amount. This amount is varied across respondents. • bidding games -ask respondents whether they are WTP a certain amount. If they say yes, ask them about a higher amount, until you find the highest amount they are WTP. ii) A payment mechanism is specified. The mechanism must be believable (e.g. increase sewer fees to improve water quality). It should not be controversial (e.g. property taxes). This is because the survey shouldn't serve as a referendum on the type of payment mechanism chosen. iii) Information about the respondent is gathered e.g. income, age, education etc. Allows verification of results, estimation of income elasticities, etc. Examples of Results: a) First CV: Davis (1963) found the value of outdoor recreation opportunities in the Maine woods to be between $1 and $2 per day. b) Valuing clean air: • WTP to avoid health problems: $10 per asthma day reduced • WTP for better visibility: A 10 percent increase in visibility has been valued as between $7 and $101. Increased visibility at the Grand Canyon has been valued between $5 and $10. c) Valuing cleaner water: • WTP to improve water from "boatable" to "fishable": $12.30 • WTP to improve water from "boatable" to "swimmable": $29.60 However, WTP is a small percentage of income. There could be large substitution effects between X and Y 55 LECTURE NINE COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS OF ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY 9.1 Introduction to Cost-Benefit Analysis (CBA) The primary goal of CBA is to maximize total net benefits (= total benefits - total costs). CBA calculates the costs and benefits of a project and finds the total net benefits. Note that some costs and benefits can be observed directly from market data. Others will need to be inferred from data. At the end of this section you are expected to be able to: 9.2 1 Explain important steps of carrying out CBA of any environmental aspect 2 Explain how environmental uncertainty can be handled when undertaking CBA 3 Describe discounting methods of Costs and benefits of any environmental aspect 4 Describe Various concepts of environmental cost and its computation 5 Explain main categories of environmental cost. Steps to cost-benefit analysis i) Specify clearly the project or program - For environmental economics, this is usually a physical project such as a dam or wastewater treatment plant, or a regulatory program, such as pollution control standards. ii) Determine quantitatively the inputs and outputs of the program - This can be difficult – for example, general equilibrium effects. Also, it is important to distinguish between transfers of resources due to substitution and the creation of new resources. For example, jobs created by a project should normally not be included as a benefit. Jobs created are a transfer of resources. If the project wasn't done, the workers could have been used elsewhere. iii) Estimate the social costs and benefits of these inputs and outputs. iv) Compare these costs and benefits - Here; one can also include other considerations, such as equity. 9.3 Dealing with Uncertainty The first step in dealing with uncertainty is risk assessment. Risk has two components: a) stochastic – depends on chance and b) systematic – depends on circumstances (e.g. a smoker is more likely to get cancer) 56 In addition, assessing risk involves two concerns: the probability of an event occurring and how serious the event will be. We can assess risk through the following: a) Focusing on finding the probability of an event occurring. Risk can be determined by looking at past records. However, it is important to be aware of changes that occur over time. For example, increased safety features reduce the risk of death from auto accidents. This is a change in systemic risk. b) We can also assess risk by component analysis which is a tool often used to assess the risks of new technologies. The problem with this tool is that components may be related. c) Risk by analogy- Often, time lags make perceiving risk difficult. For example, cancer may be caused after exposure to a toxin, but only after many years. As a result, studies on animals are often used to extrapolate human risks. The problems with risk by analogy approach are: • Animals are exposed to unrealistically high doses of toxins in the laboratory. • Need to extrapolate risk of humans from low exposure from calculated risk based on high exposure. • Physiology of animals and humans may be different. • The risk may be different for different people. A complication for policy makers is that, even after risk assessment is complete, people have a hard time perceiving risk accurately. Risk assessments are hard to understand, as they typically involve low probability events. Thus control is important. Consider that most people worry more about air travel than auto travel, although the likelihood of dying in a car accident is greater. People may pay more to avoid unpleasant deaths. For example: what should the standard for ammonium perchlorate in groundwater be? This example shows how different criteria for risk assessment suggest different answers by US environmental stakeholder: a) Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) proposes a standard of 1 part per billion (ppb). They look at sensitive populations, including the risk to fetuses. They also make use of laboratory studies. b) Pentagon - Proposes a standard of 200 ppb. Note that this standard would release the Pentagon from most cleanup responsibility. They base their figure on a study of exposure to human adults. Thus, one study focuses on more sensitive populations, whereas the other focuses on exposure to a typical person. 57 Both environmental stakeholders (EPA and Pentagon) can be justified. Which is correct? Once risk has been assessed, policy makers face several alternatives for using the information: a) For CBA purposes, pieces of information needed to deal with risk include: • The risk probability - The governments often use conservative estimates (e.g. 95% percentile). • The population exposed - For example, USA’s superfund regulations consider possible future populations on a site. • The value of a life b) Avoid upper bound of risks - Government agencies, such as EPA, often use conservative risk estimates (e.g. 95% percentiles). However, this adds up If 95% percentiles is used for several estimates, actual percentile is above 99% (.95 x .95 x .95). Consider two chemical hazards scenario: Chemical A poses a known risk of 2 in 100,000 and chemical B is uncertain. 9 out of 10 scientists believe no risk 1 out of 10 believe risk is 6 in 100,000. Government policy says risk of B is greater, since focuses on upper bound – that is, greatest potential risk. However, chemical A has a higher expected value of risk. c) Cost-Effectiveness analysis - Rather than compare costs and benefits, simply show that the agency has adopted the cheapest way possible to achieve its goal. This analysis takes the policy objective as worthwhile. We can then ask if the costs justify the benefits received, without needing to place a dollar value on the benefits. d) Risk-risk analysis - Compare risk after regulation to risk before. Notes that regulation will affect behaviors, and could even increase risk. Let us consider special attention in risk-risk analysis: • Substitution risks - If substances that replace banned substances are also risky, net gain from banning the substance is not as great as it seems. • Risk of other economic behavior - For example, what is the additional risk of industrial accidents from workers who manufacture scrubbers for power plants? • Opportunity costs of diverted resources - What do we give up in other expenditures (e.g. health care) by spending more on regulation? 58 9.4 Discounting methods The costs and benefits we've discussed often occur at different times. To compare them fairly, it is important to discount costs and benefits that occur in the future. The idea is to compare a flow of benefits and costs into a single value. The present value of a future amount of money is the maximum amount you would be willing to pay today for the right to receive that money in the future. Present value accounts for the opportunity cost of not investing the money elsewhere. For example: Suppose you have $100 now, if you put it in the bank, you will get 5% interest. Next year, that money is worth (1 + 0.05) x100 = $105. After two years, it is worth (1.05)(1.05)(100) = (1.05)2(100) = $110.25. General rule of the discounting method: FV = PV(1 + r)t Whereby FV = future value, PV = present value, r = interest rate. As a result, you wouldn’t give up $100 now for $100 next year, because you could invest the money and get $105 next year. The present value of $100 next year is the most you would give up today to get $100 next year i.e. FV = PV(1.05) = $100(1.05) PV = FV/r = 100/1.05 = $95.24 General rule PV = FV/(1 + r) For a stream of payments: PV = x + X/(1+r) + X/(1+r)2 + … + X/(1+r)t. For payments forever: PV = X/r “Rule of 70” is normally used to get the number of years needed to double an investment, divide 70 by 100 times the growth rate. Example: if money is invested at 10%, it doubles every 7 years [= 70/(0.1x100)] 9.4.1 Discount rate, r To proceed, we need to know what value to use for r. This is the discount rate. The discount rate reflects the relative value a person places on future consumption compared to current consumption. Lower values show a greater preference for future consumption. If your discount rate is greater than the interest rate, you will be willing to borrow money. A high discount rate says that current consumption is important to you. If your discount rate is lower than the interest rate, you will be willing to loan money. A low discount rate says that future consumption is important to you. Since the market interest rate reflects equilibrium of lenders and borrowers, we 59 can use the market interest rate as a measure of the discount rate. Let us explain briefly as to why the discount rate matters: a) Discounting affects the value placed on future benefits and costs. b) Higher discount rates place less importance on future returns. - Note, for example, how this is a particular problem for long-term problems such as climate change. A very low discount rate suggests we would give up virtually all consumption today to protect the future. However, a higher discount rate suggests very distant benefits have little weight in decision making. c) There are several market interest rates. Which should we use? Typically, economists use a risk-free rate. In USA fir example, investors looking for a safe return invest in U.S. Treasury bills. Thus, the return on T-bills is a measure of the nominal risk-free rate. To purchase assets that are riskier, investors need to be compensated with a higher rate of return. This additional return is known as a risk premium. d) Note also how the discount rate relates to economic growth theory Discount rate = pure rate of time preference + growth rate of income x elasticity of marginal utility for income. The first term captures the relative weight placed on the future versus today and involves ethical judgments The second term acknowledges that, due to economic growth, we expect future generations to be richer. If the marginal utility of income falls as we get richer, then additional money is less valuable when we are richer. e) Might the social discount rate deviate from the market rate? The above estimates use market data to determine the discount rate. Are their reasons to believe that the market rate is flawed? Some economists argue that the opportunity cost of foregone future consumption might differ from the opportunity cost revealed in the markets. In this case, it might make sense to use a social discount rate which is lower than the rates observed in the marketplace. 9.4.2 Social discount rate The social discount rate represents the willingness of society to trade off present and future consumption. If there are market failures, this may differ from discount rates observed from market behavior. Let us ask ourselves as why market rates might not be appropriate. Although long term projects involve benefits or costs for future generations, the future generations are not represented in the market. People may be myopic, and thus not save sufficiently. There may also be other externalities that cause the market rate of return on investments to deviate from the social discount rate, such as positive externalities from research and development. Uncertainty 60 may be a concern, therefore, risk aversion may justify using a lower discount rate. However, uncertainty is not an excuse to do nothing. Let us suggest what can be done to select appropriate discounting rate • Compromise view: Use the market rate for the first 30 years of a project, and a lower social discount rate afterwards. The intuition is that, for the first 30 years or so, the market rate is a reasonable guide to individual preferences. However, since the market rate may ignore future generations, a lower rate is used for benefits and costs affecting future generations. • Alternatively, analysis can be done without discounting. Note that this is a controversial view in economics. Most mainstream economists would disagree with a zero discount rate. 9.5 Concepts of Cost 9.5.1 Important concerns on how costs will be conceptualized a) Establishing the baseline - We want to compare costs with regulation versus without regulation, not before and after regulation. Even without regulation, we expect some things to change over time. b) Distributional issues - Note that costs will often be focused on a few individuals (e.g. affected firms or communities). Benefits are more likely to affect a wider range of people. Thus, equity concerns will be an issue. 9.5.2 Broad categories of costs a) Opportunity costs Opportunity cost is the value of the best forgone opportunity. It is what we give up by using a resource for this use, rather than the next best alternative use. Example: an opportunity cost of going to school is foregone salary. It is also very important to distinguish between costs and transfers. b) Environmental costs Because most regulations focus on a single pollutant, regulating one pollutant may increase the use of another pollutant. Example: using scrubbers to clean SO2 emissions leaves behind a sludge that must be disposed of. c) Enforcement costs For enforcing laws, regulations and standing orders. For example court levies, policing costs, rents etc 61 d) Implicit costs Non monetary costs of inconvenience, time searching for substitutes, lost product variety, etc. Few studies include implicit costs 9.5.3 Estimating Costs a) Costs of a single facility For some projects, such as building a wastewater treatment plant, we need only consider the cost of a single facility. In other cases, we may need to aggregate the costs per facility to get industry totals. Estimation depends primarily on engineering estimates. After regulations are in place, survey data is available. Two types of costs can be obtained: • Fixed cost of building a facility (considered capital costs by accountants) - Expenditures for plant, equipment, construction, and making process changes. These costs won’t change as the level of abatement changes. • Variable costs of operation (operating and maintenance costs) - Costs incurred in the operation and maintenance of abatement processes, such as labor, energy, and R&D. These costs will vary with the level of abatement. The present value of costs over the life of a facility is needed. b) Estimating the cost of lost jobs, lost income to merchants, etc. If the workers will be absorbed into the economy, these are not a cost to society. Certainly the workers themselves are affected, but the resources are still being employed. For larger scale regulations (e.g. an entire industry), we cannot assume that resources now unused will be used elsewhere. The US Department of Labor regularly surveys firms for the reasons for mass layoffs. Less than 0.1% are attributed to environmental regulations. c) Abatement cost data These are costs incurred normally by governments in order to decrease/lessen the perceived environmental risks. For example US spent 121.8 billion on Pollution Abatement and Control Expenditures (PACE) in 1994. This was equivalent to about 1.7% of GDP (http://www.census.gov/econ/overview). The amount was spent as follows: 96.6% on abatement, 8.0% personal spending, 62.9% business, 25.6% government, 1.8% on monitoring, and 1.6% on R&D. A 1999 pilot survey (http://www.census.gov/prod/2002/pubs/ma200-99.pdf) focused on USA’s PACE in manufacturing industries found out that $5.8 billion was spent on PACE capital expenditures and $11.9 billion on PACE operating and maintenance expenditures. 62 9.5.4 How Accurate are Cost Estimates? a) Sources of error – One difficulty is that errors can come in many ways. The most obvious is incorrectly estimating the costs of control. However, even if the cost of control is estimated correctly, predictions about emissions levels, number of plants, etc. can also be wrong. b) Evaluation of estimates Harrington et al.1 study 25 estimates of the cost of regulation. They compare pre-regulation estimate to actual costs after the regulation is in place. They label an estimate as “accurate” if it within 25% higher or lower than the actual costs. They find that the costs more likely to be overestimated as shown in the following table of results: Accurate Overestimate Underestimate Unable to Determine Quantity Reduction 10 9 4 Unit Pollution Reduction Cost 7 12 6 Total Cost 5 12 2 2 6 Source: Harrington et al (2000) Discussion of Harrington’s results: The two underestimates were for rather “minor” regulations: EPA2 aldicarb ban and OSHA’s3 powdered platform regulation. EPA and OSHA tend to overestimate reductions, but not per unit costs. As a result, total costs are overestimated. State and foreign agencies were more likely to overestimate per unit costs. For market-based polices, seven of the eight estimates overestimated costs! Note that this is where we would expect technological innovation to be most important. c) Why do errors occur? • Many estimates ignore the possibility of technological innovation. • Regulators have an obligation to identify a means of complying with the regulation, which usually means considering current technologies. • Future technologies are much harder to predict. • Quantity errors - misestimating baseline emissions. However, keep in mind that this also means that benefits are wrong. For example, overestimating emissions reductions overestimates costs, but also overstates the benefits. 1 Harrington, W., et al. (2000) ‘On the Accuracy of Regulatory Cost Estimates’, Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, Vol. 19, Spring 2000 (No. 2), 297-322. 2 Environmental Protection Agency 3 Occupational Safety and Health Agency 63 • Regulations may change during the public comment period. Thus, cost estimates aren’t for the final regulation. • Estimates may focus on maximum values, rather than means. This is so especially if analyses rely on industry for data. • Asymmetric correction of errors. Firms are likely to bring underestimates to the attention of regulators. There is no similar group with strong incentives to bring overestimates to the attention of regulators. 64 LECTURE TEN NATIONAL INCOME 10.1 Introduction It is important to explain how the overall production performance of the economy is measured. This is referred to as national income accounting. By definition national income refers to the total of all incomes, including wages, rents, interest payments, and profits received by households. By the end of this lecture, you should be able to: 1. Define and appreciate the use of the national income accounting 2. Understand computation of national income accounts 3. Correlate the relationship between national product, expenditure and national income. 10.2 National Income Accounting National income accounting is the recording of the nation’s economic activity over time. The department of the government ministry in charge of gathering economic activity data publishes these accounts. National income accounting measures the level of production at some point in time and it explains immediate causes of that level of production. 10.3 Uses of National Income accounts Uses of national income accounts include, among others, the following: (a) National income accounts help us to assess the economic performance. It enables us to understand better the pattern of our economic activity and explain the reasons behind the pattern. (b) It is possible to track the long run flow of the economy and observe whether it has grown, been steady or stagnated. (c) Governments use national accounts data to formulate appropriate medium and short-term stabilization policies. (d) They are used to measure the standard of living of a country, for example income per capita. (e) They are used to compare the wealth of different nations. 65 (f) The accounts are used by business to anticipate market trends and subsequent investment expenditure. 10.4 Measurement of national Product In lecture 11 we defined Macroeconomics as the study of the economic aggregates and the relationships among the major aggregates, which constitute the economy. For example studies on total employment, the unemployment rate, national product and the rate of inflation fall under macroeconomics. One way of judging the performance of the economy is to measure the aggregate production of goods and services. Measuring aggregate production implies adding up a range of product into a single measure of national product (e.g. cars + cement). Markets provide an answer to the measuring of national product. Table 10.1 Determination of market value Item Quantity Unit Price (million) Market Value Cement 20 3 60,000 Tractor 10 15 150,000 Table 10.1 illustrates the procedure used to compute market value of goods and services. It is indicated for example, that one tractor is worth 5 tons of cement. When market prices are used it should be possible to compare cement and tractors and it is possible to add cement and tractors (in terms of their values). Thus in our complex economy, the total value of output can be found in a similar way as follows: • By taking quantity times the market price, it is possible to find expenditures on a particular product. • Adding up expenditures for many goods produced we can get a monetary measure of National Product. • Adding up incomes of the different factors of production, we can also get a measure of National Product. • Thus national product can be measured by either expenditure approach or income approach 66 10.5 Expenditure Approach to GNP Measuring national product through the expenditure approach requires that only expenditures on the final product be added. Adding expenditures on final products avoids double counting e.g. bread and cars are final products but wheat and steel are intermediate products. Thus to avoid double counting national product is found by adding up only expenditures on final products. Double counting in this case is adding up the expenditure on intermediate product purchase and final product purchase. Value added is the difference between the value of a firm’s product and cost of intermediate product bought from outside suppliers. Table 10.2 Illustration of Value Added Wheat Value Added Flour Bread(Wholesale) Bread(Retail 100 250 450 600 100 150 200 150 National product in the expenditure approach is the money value of final goods and services produced in the economy. Expenditure on final goods/products falls into the following categories: (a) Government purchases of goods and services (G). Transfer payments such as subsidies are not included. (b) Personal consumption expenditure (C) on durable goods, non durable goods and on services (c) Private domestic investment (I) in Plant and equipment (new and renovations) and Changes in inventories (increases in inventories or decreases in inventories). (d) Exports of goods and services (X). This includes services demanded by foreigners e.g. Hotel accommodation (e) Imports of goods and services (M). This is subtracted in expenditure because these products have not been produced in the country. Gross National Product (GNP) = Personal consumption expenditures (C) plus Government purchases (G) plus Private domestic investment (I) plus exports of good and services (X) less imports of goods and services (M) Or GNP = C + I + G + X – M. 67 10.6 Income Approach to GNP Each time something is produced and sold, someone obtains income from producing it. More precisely, each unit of expenditure will find its way partly into wages and salaries, and partly into profits, interest or rents. It follows that if we add up all incomes we should get the value of total expenditure. It would be most convenient if we could simply say that the total expenditures upon the economy’s annual output flows to households as wage, rent, interest and profit incomes. Unfortunately this is complicated by two non-income charges against the value of total output, that is, against GNP. These are (i) a capital consumption allowance, and (ii) indirect business taxes. Capital consumption allowance refer to the depreciation charge made for the economy as a whole against the total receipts of the business sector in order to accurately state profits and total income for the economy. Indirect business taxes refer to certain taxes levied by the government such as general sales taxes, license fees, excise and business property taxes, and customs duty – which business firms treat as costs of production. These taxes are called indirect taxes because they are not levied directly upon the corporation, partnership, or proprietorship as such but rather, upon their products or services. In national accounts, profit is broken down into two basic accounts namely proprietor’s income or income of unincorporated businesses and corporate profits. Three things can be done with corporate profits: (i) A part will be claimed by, and therefore flow to, government as corporate income taxes (ii) A part of the remaining corporate profits will be paid out to stockholders as dividends (iii) The remaining part of corporate profits after paying (i) and (ii) above is called undistributed corporate profits. GNP can therefore be determined by adding up the following: Capital Consumption allowance (CA), Indirect business taxes (IT), Wages (W), Rents (R), Interest (I), Proprietor’s income (PI), Corporate income taxes (CT), Dividends (DP), and Undistributed corporate profits (UP). 68 10.7 Other Social Accounts (a) Gross Domestic Product (GDP) National product is usually measured either by the GDP or by the GNP. GDP is defined as the value of the gross output of goods and services produced in the country. GNP is the same as GDP except that GNP includes income earned abroad and excludes income transferred out of the country by foreign owners. (b) Net National Product (NNP) Gross National Product (GNP) refers to the total market value of all goods and services produced in any economy over a given period of time, usually one year. GNP as measure of national product tends to give an exaggerated picture of the year’s production because it fails to make allowance for that part of the year’s output that is necessary to replace capital goods consumed in the year’s production. Due to wear and tear of plant and equipment, an allowance has to be made on depreciation. Subtracting the capital consumption allowance (depreciation) from GNP gives NNP. Thus, NNP = GNP - Depreciation (c) National Income National Income is the income earned by resource suppliers for their contributions of land, labour, capital and entrepreneurial ability, which go into the year’s net production. The only component of NNP, which does not reflect the current productive contributions of economic resources, is indirect business taxes. If indirect business taxes are subtracted from the NNP, the resulting figure is the National Income (d) National Disposable Income (NDI) It may happen that a country/individual receives or sends substantial remittances. National Disposable Income becomes national income plus net transfer receipts/payments. National Disposable Income (NDI) measures the aggregate resources available to the nation for consumption or saving. 10.8 GNP, Expenditure and National Income We have seen that GNP is the value of output of goods and services produced during a given period of time. The types of prices used are market prices. Market prices have two components i.e. Market prices = Factor costs + Indirect taxes 69 Factor costs are payments to factors of production. Indirect taxes are taxes such as sales taxes levied by government. They are included in prices paid for goods and services. It should be noted that: (a) If all income is to be presented by payments to factors of production then this income is known as national income at factor cost (i.e. we assume that all expenditures and commodities go to suppliers of factors of production). (b) If it happens that the government imposes taxes on commodities purchased, by simply summing up such expenditures we obtain national expenditure at market prices. Inclusion of indirect tax does not amount to additional output since the tax accrues to the government and not paid to factors of production supplied. Indirect taxes are those taxes levied on goods and services. (c) If subsidies are included, they perform a negative function of indirect taxes, which will mean that market prices are lower than the factor cost of the goods and that factors of production receive incomes from sale of goods in excess of consumers expenditure on them. (d) Combining indirect taxes and subsidies, one can obtain net indirect taxes. If net indirect taxes are positive then national expenditure at market prices exceeds national income at factor cost by this amount. National Expenditure at market Price MINUS Indirect taxes PLUS Subsidies EQUALS National Income at Factor Cost 70 Fig 10.1 Determination of National Income • Net factor income paid abroad EQUALS factor income obtained from abroad minus factor income paid abroad. • Excluding net indirect taxes from market prices gives factor cost. Exclusion of depreciation (allowing for) reduces gross values to net values. In this lecture we have explained various national income accounts and how they are measured. The understanding of all these accounts is necessary because they can help us assess the performance of our national economy and be able to give explanation on the differences. It can as well be possible to make comparison between national economic performance and those of other nations. We have also learnt that two approaches are commonly used to assess national product: the expenditure approach and the national income approach. Both approaches give the same final value of GDP. It was also realised that national product can be measured using input cost hence called GNP at factor cost or using market price hence called GNP at market prices. 71 ? REVIEW QUESTIONS 1. Are the national income figures good indicators of genuine socioeconomic welfare? Explain your answer 2. Compare the output or expenditure approach with the income approach in national income determination. Which one is more effective? Why? 3. Review your understanding on the meaning of the following terms National income, National product, National disposable income, Personal disposable income, Gross national product, Gross domestic product, and Value added 4. The following are the items of the income statement of the economy for the year 2005 (in billion of US dollars): Rents…………………………………………………...24 Personal consumption expenditures………………..1,080 Corporate income taxes………………………………..65 Undistributed corporate profits………………………..18 Net exports……………………………………………...7 Dividends……………………………………………...35 Capital consumption allowance……………………...180 Interest………………………………………………...82 Indirect business taxes…………………………… ..163 Gross private domestic investment…………….…….240 Compensation of employees……………………….1,028 Government purchases of goods and services.………365 Proprietors’ income…………………………….……..97 Determine the Gross National Product using: (a) Expenditure approach (b) Income approach 72 LECTURE ELEVEN ECONOMIC GROWTH AND THE ENVIRONMENT 11.1 Introduction Up to now, the analysis of environmental resources has focused on microeconomic issues. That is, how individual actors do behave, and what incentives do affect this behavior. This analysis allows us to find the optimal level of various activities. However, all of these activities affect the economy as a whole. Consider, for example, the effect of higher energy prices on the economy during the 1970’s. Also, we need to know how economic growth affects the environment. Is economic growth good or bad for the environment? To begin, we must distinguish between economic growth and economic development. Growth refers to increases in aggregate level of output. Development refers to sustained increases in population’s welfare, lessened inequality, poverty and unemployment. Thus population is more important when discussing development. At the end of this section you are expected to be able to: 1. Explain the difference between economic growth and economic development 2. Explain fundamental environmental issues in GDP 3. Discuss how the environment affects the economy 4. Describe historical development of environmental policy in Asia and Africa 5. Describe Environmental Kuzinet’s Curve (EKC) and its implications on economic growth 11.2 The fundamental issues of environment in GDP We saw in the previous chapter that the traditional measure of macroeconomic performance is Gross Domestic Product (GDP). We found that GDP is the sum of the money values of all final goods and services produced in the domestic economy during a year. This implies that in computing GDP does not include sales of intermediate goods and services. Only market activity is included. Since there isn’t a market for most environmental goods, they are not included in GDP. In contrast, defensive expenditures (e.g. repairs after an auto accident) are included. The following environment related problems that result include: • The value of environmental amenities is not included in GDP. • Depleting a stock of natural resources (e.g. oil, minerals, forests) increases GDP, since it results in new sales. • For comparison, depleting the capital stock hurts, as capital won’t be there for future generations (measured in net domestic product, or NDP). 73 • Similar reasoning should follow for natural resources. Example: Repetto4 recalculated Indonesia’s growth rate including natural capital. The growth rate is 7%. Recalculating to include the degradation of resources such as timber lowers the growth rate to 4%. • Growth that comes from the consumption of capital, including natural capital, is not sustainable. • Defensive expenditures are included. Defensive expenditures are expenditures made to eliminate, mitigate, or avoid damages caused by other economic activity. For example, after a car accident, the costs to repair the car, provide medical treatment to the victims, pay for lawyers, etc. all add to GDP. But, has the car accident really increased welfare? A study of Germany found that 10% of the countries GDP consisted of defensive expenditures. 11.3 How Does the Environment Affect the Economy To see how the environment can affect the economy, we proceed with a more detailed model of the economy. Economists usually model output by using a production function. From this, we can derive a growth equation, as we discussed in class. The basic form of the equation is: Rate of growth of output = A + a*(rate of growth of capital) + b*(rate of growth of labor) + c*(rate of growth of energy) + d*(rate of growth of materials). In this model, A represents changes in technology. With this model, we can address two questions: a) How does environmental policy affect economic growth? • Environmental regulations divert inputs from the production of output to other goals, such as reducing emissions. • Since environmental benefits are not measured in GDP, they are not part of measured output. Thus, resources diverted to environmental protection cannot be considered in the equation. GDP falls, so economic growth, as traditionally measured, slows. • In 1994 (the last year with available data), PACE were $121.8 billion, which was 1.7% of GDP • Environmental regulations may also prohibit certain resources, such as timber, from being used at all. This lowers rate of growth of output. 4 environment.research.yale.edu/documents/.../0-9/04_Indonesia.pdf - 74 • Environmental policy can affect technological change, which affects A. Whether this is good or bad for growth is a debated topic. b) How does the environment benefit economic growth? There are positive effects of the environment on the economy. Even though most environmental benefits are not included in GDP, there are some benefits to have tangible monetary values. For example: • Environmental resources are an input to production. If clean water is not available, it cannot be used. Environmental regulations that protect water thus benefit GDP. • Environmental quality affects the quality of other inputs. For example, reduced air pollution makes agriculture more productive and provides healthier workers. Not only are healthy workers more productive, but health care is a large portion of GDP spending. If average costs are rising, reducing the number of sick people reduces the costs of treating them. Note that this raises the question of how to incorporate the environment into GDP. We’ll discuss that during the lecture on sustainable development. 11.4 Income and the Environment: Case study of the environment in East Asia The article from Environment magazine focuses on the evolution of environmental policy in three East Asian countries: Japan, South Korea, and China. Let us briefly discuss the history of environmental policy in East Asian countries. 11.4.1 History of Japan’s environmental policy Early concerns arose in 1868, in response to damage from copper mining. Government did not pay serious attention to the environment until after Second World War (WWII). National economic development was the central government’s top priority. Pollution was originally thought of as a local government problem. Rapid growth in the 1950s led to increases in pollution. In response to disease outbreaks from water pollution, the National Diet passed two water quality laws in 1958. These are the first laws at the national level. International pressure played a role. Before hosting the Tokyo Olympics in 1964, there was international pressure to improve water quality in the Sumida River in Tokyo. Led to the creation of the Pollution Control Division of the Ministry of Health and Welfare (1964) & the Basic Law for Environmental Pollution Control (1967). More recently, policy focus shifted to global issues. Global warming became part of agenda in mid-80s. There is now more of a focus on “quality of life” issues. 75 11.4.2 History of environmental policy in South Korea Environmental policy was not an issue in South Korea until after Korean War.During 1960s, Korea was under an authoritarian regime (President Park). Focus was on Five-Year Economic Development Plan of 1962. In 1963, Pollution Prevention Act passed, but it was ineffectual due to lack of resources. Rapid growth led to greater water and air pollution in 1970s. Environmental Preservation Act passed in 1977. Set water quality standards in 1978, and SO2 standards in 1979. Reducing air pollution became a priority before the Seoul Olympic Games in 1988. Government supplied lower sulfur oil beginning in 1981. Strengthened vehicle emission standards in 1987. Made clean fuels such as liquefied natural gas mandatory for large cities in 1988. 11.4.3 History of environmental policy in China Under Mao Zedong (beginning in 1949), the government insisted pollution was a capitalist problem that did not exist in socialist countries. In 1972, water pollution began to attract the government’s attention, so the government sent a representative to the 1972 Stockholm Conference on the Human Environment, and a national conference was held in 1973. Environmental protection was introduced into the Chinese Constitution in 1978. The Constitution stated that protecting the environment was the responsibility of the state. Environmental Protection Law passed in 1979. Included the responsible that polluters should be held responsible for pollution treatment, including a polluter pays fee system. Despite increased institutional attention, positive results for the environment are limited by a lack of resources. 11.4.4 Convergence of environmental policy In each country, economic growth came first, followed by a reaction to resulting environmental problems. International pressure played a role in each case. The Olympics were important for Japan and South Korea, as they were important for China in2008. Note that for all three countries, attention first focused on water and air pollution on a sector by sector basis. Broader environmental regulation came later. 11.4.5 Differences Latecomers had the advantage of learning from other nations' environmental policies. In Japan, local governments played a bigger role in policy. This makes it easier for citizens to influence the decision making process. Market forces played a bigger role in Japan. Levels of democracy differ in each country. 76 11.5 The Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC) The Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC) hypothesizes that the relationship between per capita income and the use of natural resources and/or the emission of wastes has an inverted U-shape. According to this specification, at relatively low levels of income the use of natural resources and/or the emission of wastes increase with income. Beyond some turning point, the use of the natural resources and/or the emission of wastes decline with income. Reasons for this inverted U-shaped relationship are hypothesized to include income-driven changes in the following: a) Composition of production and/or consumption b) Preference for environmental quality c) Institutions that are needed to internalize externalities; and/or d) Increasing returns to scale associated with pollution abatement. The term EKC is based on its similarity to the time-series pattern of income inequality described by Simon Kuznets in 1955. A 1992 World Bank Development Report made the notion of an EKC popular by suggesting that environmental degradation can be slowed by policies that protect the environment and promote economic development. Subsequent statistical analysis, however, showed that while the relationship may hold in a few cases, it could not be generalized across a wide range of resources and pollutants. Some forms of pollution appear first to worsen and later to improve as countries’ incomes grow. The world’s poorest and richest countries have relatively clean environments, while middleincome countries are the most polluted. Because of its resemblance to the pattern of inequality and income described by Simon Kuznets (1955), this pattern of pollution and income has been labelled an ‘environmental Kuznets curve’ (EKC). Empirical studies of the relationship between per capita income and pollution typically find one of three patterns: • For some problems (e.g. access to drinking water), income growth always leads to less of a problem. • For many pollutants (e.g. SO2), the level increases as per capita income begins to grow, but then falls as income continues to grow. Initially, growth leads to industrialization that causes pollution. As income grows more, the country becomes more willing to devote resources to pollution control. • For still other problems (e.g. CO2 emissions), the problem gets worse as income grows. 77 Environmental damage Income per capita Figure 11.1 Kuzinets Curve Typically, studies look at cross-country data using Global Environmental Monitoring Systems data (GEMS). This seems to only fit for a subset of pollutants. Results are sensitive to the specification. Important Issues to note: • Data availability is a problem. Current research focuses on criteria pollutants, because that is where the best data is available. What about toxins? • More time series studies needed. Cross-section studies do not capture dynamics. Time series studies of Netherlands, Germany, the UK and the US find that economic growth has a positive effect on emissions of CO2, NOX, and SO2 (meaning emissions increase), although technological change may offset this. 11.5.1 Theoretical requirements for EKC • Marginal utility of consumption falling or constant. So that cost of giving up consumption falls as incomes are higher 78 • Marginal disutility of pollution rises. As problems get worse, it is more valuable to do something about them • Marginal damages rising • Marginal abatement costs rising. It is expensive to do a lot. 11.5.2 Implications of the EKC While EKC relationships have been observed using the data above, critics raise concerns that suggest other possibilities: a) Revised EKC: proposes that the curve could shift downward over time b) Might the peak be lower for newly developing countries, since they can use technologies first developed elsewhere? c) Race to the Bottom: promoted by globalization. d) Intuition: once everyone’s income rises, where does the pollution go? New Toxics e) Over time, countries shift away from traditional pollutants, but use more of pollutants that are more dangerous. Note that there is little empirical evidence for the last two theories. 79 LECTURE TWELVE THE ENVIRONMENT IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 12.1 Introduction One of the main objectives of this lecture is to discuss what is considered to be different about environmental problems in developing countries, as compared to developed countries. At the end of this section you are expected to be able to: 1. Explain the meaning and use of Environmental Sustainability Index 2. Explain the causes of environmental problems in LDCs 3. Describe root causes to difficulties in access to clean water in LDC 4. Explain causes of air pollution and deforestation in developing countries 5. Discuss the impact of agricultural activities on the environment and how to make agriculture more sustainable in developing countries Let us begin with a discussion of key issues pointed out in one of the US Economists article on the Environmental Sustainability Index (ESI)5: • Unlike the environmental Kuznets curve literature we discussed before, this article attempts to address causation, that is, what factors lead to better environmental quality. • Income is particularly important when there are immediate health effects. • Income is less important when the environmental impacts are long term, or when they do not directly impact human health. • Good governance is important. According to the 2005 Environmental Sustainability Index (ESI) produced by a team of environmental experts at Yale and Columbia universities, Australia was rated 13th in the world in environmental sustainability out of 146 countries, just ahead of Gabon, but behind New Zealand and Latvia. The Index released earlier in 2009 at the World Economic Forum in Davos, Switzerland, ranks Finland, Norway, Uruguay, Sweden and Iceland as the top five sustainable nations, respectively. Their high ESI scores are attributed to substantial natural resource endowments, low population, and successful management of environment and development issues. 5 www.highbeam.com/doc/1G1-132774446.html 80 Discuss reasons why countries like Tanzania, Nigeria and DRC, which are endowed with natural resources, do have their respective ESIs very low? 12.2 Causes of environmental problems in developing countries Let us outline the causes of environmental problems in developing countries. Our list includes abut not limited to the following problems: • Higher population growth rates in developing countries as compared to industrialized countries • Industrialization - Developing countries are moving from agrarian societies to industrialized societies, which results in more pollution. • Increasing urbanization - As industrialization occurs, people move to the cites, as that is where jobs are. Environmental problems become problems when people are close together, so that their actions affect others nearby. Also, infrastructure to support increased populations is lacking in many cities. • Weak governance - Not only are regulations often weaker, but when they do exist enforcement limits compliance. Corruption and lack of democracy are also problems. • Lack of information/education - Demand for environmental regulations depends on awareness of the problems • Poverty/pressures for economic growth - As a result of lower incomes, developing countries place less weight on future considerations. With lower incomes, current needs take precedence. • Poorly defined property rights • Technological constraints - Technologies used may be less efficient than those used in developed countries, leading to more energy and resource use. 12.3 Access to clean water in LDCs Access to clean water is a major concern in developing countries. 90% of sewage in developing countries is discharged without treatment. Causes of the problem include the following: a) The costs of the necessary infrastructure are high. b) The price of water is subsidized. As a result, infrastructure is allowed to decay and utilities are reluctant to connect new customers. c) Water utilities may be bureaucratic, inefficient, and corrupt. However, these problems may continue with privatization, since the companies have monopoly power. 81 Although pricing water at its true cost is efficient, is it fair? • One suggestion is to have a low base price for a basic unit of water, but to price additional access at a higher rate. • Another alternative may be to price water correctly, but also provide subsidies to low-income people. Take time to suggest potential solutions to this problem A possible solution to the subsidy problem is block pricing ie charging a lower rate for the first units of water used, but high rates to those that use more. Note that this requires infrastructure to monitor usage. 12.4 Air pollution in LDCs The most important air pollution problems in developing countries are: a) Indoor air pollution - One-third of energy in developing countries comes from burning wood, crop residues, and animal wastes in stoves. b) Lead emissions c) Small particles Note that subsidies are a major problem. Because electricity is subsidized, utilities are reluctant to hook up new customers. If few people have access to electricity, they turn to burning fuel in stoves for energy. In addition, transportation policy is also important. 12.5 Timber and deforestation in LDCs Problems caused by deforestation: a) Soil erosion b) Water quality and supply both decrease c) Loss of biodiversity d) Loss of animal habitat e) Carbon emissions increase - because forests serve as carbon sinks Note that the last three are likely to be important to people in developed countries, but less so to developing countries. This is due to that fact that; • Developing countries are reluctant to devote resources to problems such as biodiversity or global warming, as the benefits are long-term. 82 • If people in developed countries want to protect these resources, they need to make it desirable for developed countries to do so. Demonstrating local benefits, such as reducing soil erosion, is important. 12.5.1 Reasons why deforestation is a problem a) Pressures from population growth and migration b) Lack of income c) Exporting timber products provide income - Developing countries are more concerned with current consumption than future consumption. Sustainable policies are not desirable if they don't provide enough income in the present. d) Lack of other energy supplies leads to using timber as a fuel. e) Lack of property rights - People who do not own the land have little incentive to preserve it. Note that, despite laws in Brazil to discourage deforestation (e.g. limiting harvest to 20% of trees on the land), enforcement is difficult due to poorly defined property rights. f) Subsidies - For example, Brazil offered tax breaks for development of forested land (such as for cattle ranching). g) Enforcement is also a problem because it is costly. Countries do not have the resources necessary to enforce existing environmental regulations. h) Demand from developed countries i) Certification can be time consuming in developing countries. One solution that might help enforcement is labeling. Using barcodes, logging firms can prove that timber has been harvested sustainably. This allows firms to differentiate themselves in market. Currently, the price premium is low: about 2-3%. Also makes it possible for developed country consumers to differentiate. For example, developed countries can ban illegal timber for construction projects financed by government. Timber importing countries cannot ban all imports of uncertified timber due to WTO rules. However, legal logs are more expensive, because royalties must be paid to governments. Illegal logging cost governments $15 billion in 2002. 83 12.6 Resource management • Many developing countries have abundant natural resources, yet their populations are poor. Resource-rich countries grow more slowly than other poor countries, even after controlling for other variables. This paradox is known as “Dutch Disease.” Increase in natural resources (e.g. oil) leads to appreciation in domestic currency. This makes non-oil sectors less competitive on world market. As a result, the oil sector dominates the economy. • Moreover, oil-rich countries do worse on issues such as child mortality, nutrition, and education. Oil employs few unskilled workers. Volatility of oil prices hurts poor the most, as they are unable to hedge risks. Ownership of resource concentrated. Thus, revenues pass through few people, making it easy to redirect funds. Oil revenues allow governments to keep taxes low. Thus, population has less incentive to demand change. • Possible solutions: a) Set aside revenues when prices are high. Alaska’s fund that is redistributed to households is an example. However, it is easy to dip into fund for other purposes. Particularly a problem in developing countries, such as Zambia & Venezuela in 1970s. b) ExxonMobil has invested in an oil project in Chad and Cameroon in which funds are deposited in an offshore escrow account. An oversight committee evaluates proposed spending from the account. Ten percent are to be held in a trust fund for future generations. Eighty percent will be devoted to education, health and social services, rural development, infrastructure and environmental and water resource management. However, there have been reports of Chad diverting funds from the account. c) Tony Blair proposes the Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative (EITI). This is a voluntary effort between governments and oil companies to promote transparency. From their website (http://www.eitransparency.org/): “The EITI aims to ensure that the revenues from extractive industries contribute to sustainable development and poverty reduction.” Over 20 countries have joined. 12.7 Agriculture in LDCs Since WWII, agriculture in developed nations has become increasingly intensive, using more capital and fertilizer. This system has spread to developing countries, succeeding in producing more abundant, less expensive food. 84 12.7.1 Costs of increased agricultural productivity a) Soil degradation - Soil is compacted from machines being used on it. There is also water and wind erosion. Depletion of minerals from overcropping and overgrazing are escalating. b) Pollution - Runoff from fertilizers and pesticides is a major non-point source pollution. Pesticide use has doubled over the past 30 years. Pesticides such as DDT are still used in developing countries. Even organic materials, such as manure, cause pollution problems. c) Water scarcity - 40% of the world’s food comes from 5% of the agricultural land that is irrigated. Water is being pumped from the ground faster than it can be replenished. Inefficient use leads to waste of water. Part of the problem is that water is usually provided below cost. d) Biodiversity loss - Intensive agriculture leads to species loss. For example, 13 million hectares of forest are lost to agriculture each year. 7,000 crop species are available for cultivation. 90% of the world’s food comes from 30 of them. Focus is on high-yielding, pest-resistant crops. 12.7.2 Can biotechnology be a solution? Growth of biotech crops has been rapid (44% increase in 1999). Most of the use is in the U.S. Crops are bred to resist herbicides or to be pest resistant. Note that, where used, herbicide applications per acre have fallen by 9% to 14%. However, total applications are up because acreages have also expanded. Yields have not increased. Consider the following concerns: • Access to seeds - GM seeds can be designed so that they cannot be reused. Farmers would thus need to purchase new seeds each year. • Reductions in biodiversity • Genetic resistance – will the surviving weeds be resistant to herbicides? Can the gene be transferred to other crops? • Lacks of consumer demand - Some countries are reluctant to use GM seeds because they are afraid that consumers will not buy crops from their country. 85 Throughout examples cited in this lecture, we have observed following set of common problems: • Lack of property rights leads to overexploitation of resources. • Subsidies encourage inefficient use of resources, but, because of equity concerns, may be difficult to remove. • Poverty is part of the problem. Many of these problems require large capital expenditures. • The pressures of population growth often contribute. 86 LECTURE THIRTEEN SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT 13.1 Introduction The concept sustainable development has ever since included notions of weak sustainability, strong sustainability and deep ecology. Thus sustainable development does not focus solely on environmental issues. The United Nations 2005 World Summit Outcome Document refers to the "interdependent and mutually reinforcing pillars" of sustainable development as economic development, social development, and environmental protection. Indigenous people have argued, through various international forums such as the United Nations Permanent Forum on Indigenous Issues and the Convention on Biological Diversity, that there are four pillars of sustainable development, the fourth being cultural. The Universal Declaration on Cultural Diversity (UNESCO, 2001) further elaborates the concept by stating that "...cultural diversity is as necessary for humankind as biodiversity is for nature”; it becomes “one of the roots of development understood not simply in terms of economic growth, but also as a means to achieve a more satisfactory intellectual, emotional, moral and spiritual existence". In this vision, cultural diversity is the fourth policy area of sustainable development. At the end of this section you are expected to be able to: 1. Explain the four pillars of sustainable development 2. Define and explain the concept of environmental sustainable development 3. Discuss the differences between neoclassical and ecological economics as far as development sustainability is concerned. 4. Demonstrate how to incorporate the environment in economic analysis 5. Explain the meaning of green GDP and how green GDP can be measured 6. Explain the likelihood of sustainable development occurring in market economies 13.2 Definition of environmentally sustainable development a) The Brundtland Report (1987), part of a World Commission on Environment and Development, proposed the following definition of sustainable development: “Sustainable development is development that meets the needs of the present without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own needs.” Note that this definition is quite vague. • How do we know what future generations will need? • What are the needs of the current generation? 87 b) Consider too the following quotes from UNESCO report: • “…every generation should leave water, air, and soil resources as pure and unpolluted as when it came on earth.” • “each generation should leave undiminished all the species of animals it found existing on earth.” These definitions imply no use of natural resources. Is this possible? If not, can you have a moral obligation to do something impossible? c) An economist, Robert Solow defines sustainable development as: “an obligation to conduct ourselves so that we leave the future the option or the capacity to be as well off as we are.” Solow's definition is an example of weak sustainability. This is the approach taken by most neoclassical economists. This is a weak sustainability because any loss of natural capital should be balanced out by creation of new capital of at least equal value. It also assumes natural capital and man-made capital are substitutes. d) Herman Daly (Beyond Growth 1996) distinguishes the definitions of sustainable development for renewable and nonrenewable resources: • For renewable resources: “Keeping the annual offtake equal to the annual growth increment (sustainable yield) is equivalent to maintenance investment.” • For non renewable resources: “The general rule would be to deplete non-renewables at a rate equal to the development of renewable substitutes.” These definitions can be summarized as: “Never reduce the stock of natural capital below a level that generates a sustained yield unless good substitutes are currently available for the services generated.” (Goodstein 1999) These guidelines are examples of strong sustainability – natural systems should be maintained whenever possible. Critical natural capital should be preserved under all circumstances. Assumes natural capital and man-made capital are compliments. This approach is taken by most ecological economists. 13.3 Neoclassical vs. ecological economics Neoclassical economists view man-made capital and natural capital as substitutes. Neoclassical economists view sustainability as a need for dynamic efficiency. Thus, a measure of welfare 88 needs to be maximized. Ecological economists on the other hand, view man-made capital and natural capital as compliments. Note that Daly does acknowledge technological progress, but says that knowledge does not simply substitute capital for nature. Rather, he argues that it makes the uses more efficient. Thus, a key concern for ecological economists is the carrying capacity of the environment. Economics is driven by scarcity. The key question, according to Daly, is how big is the economic subsystem relative to the natural subsystem. Daly claims we are moving to a world in which natural capital is the limiting factor. As noted in our discussion above, clearly defining a sustainable path is difficult. Three dimensions of sustainability are important: The existence of a positive sustainable level of welfare, The magnitude of the ultimate sustainable level of welfare vis à vis current welfare levels, and The sensitivity of the future welfare to actions by previous generations. Both intergenerational and within-generation equity are also issues. Solow notes a paradox: Sustainability says that you should be thinking about poor people today, but helping poor people today requires more consumption, which hurts sustainability. 13.4 How to Incorporate the Environment in Economic Analysis As mentioned earlier, GDP does not give a complete picture of the effect of the environment on the economy, since it ignores the value of natural resources. Desired solution is to adjust GDP to account for natural resources – “Green GDP.” First attempt: Nordhaus/Tobin (1972): • Adjusted GDP to account for amount of welfare-reducing environmental damage done by pollution. Measured as a portion of the difference in wages between wages in urban and rural areas. • They also make other adjustments to GDP: • Add value of leisure Subtract capital purchases, add capital services used. Subtract non-beneficial spending, such as commuting to work. End result: measure of economic welfare (MEW). MEW grew at 1/2 the rate of NNP from 1929-1965. China has begun to incorporate green GDP into its decision making. The motivation is that previous targets focused on economic growth, leading local officials to ignore environmental 89 concerns. Local leaders are evaluated based on an elaborate point system. Points are rewarded for meeting specified targets (e.g. a certain level of GDP growth). GDP growth is a “veto” target: failure to meet the target ensures that the cadre is considered underperforming. This has led to abuse of environment and human rights to meet GDP growth goals. A pilot program in 10 regions began in February 2004. The hope is that a green GDP target will help local leaders focus on environmental concerns. The challenge is coming up with green GDP numbers. One study said growth from 1980-2000 falls from 9.6%/yr to 6.8%/yr if green GDP used. However, the National Bureau of Statistics is skeptical about whether appropriate numbers can be devised. Because of such difficulties, the effort was abandoned in 2006. Instead, China will use what is known as a “satellite system.” Satellite system separates accounts that try to integrate environmental and economic measures. Green accounting data will be provided alongside GDP data. Guidelines for satellite systems were published by UN in 1993. Satellite systems relate economic activity, measured in cash terms, to environmental magnitudes measured in physical units. E.g. tons of CO2 emitted by each sector of the economy. Satellite system measures the effect of economy on environment, but doesn’t adjust values. 13.5 How should Green GDP be measured? The goal is to measure what is enjoyed or consumed. • Traditional GDP uses quantities of goods and services, and prices of these. • Some resources, such as timber or minerals, have market values. However, most environmental benefits do not have market values. The analog for the environment is ecosystem services. “Ecosystem services arise from – and depend on – the broader sets of ecological components, processes, and functions but they are the aspects of the ecosystem that society uses, consumes, or enjoys to experience those benefits.” (p.7 of Boyd et al (1998)6 article) 13.5.1 Principles to measuring green GDP a) Services are nature’s end products, not everything in nature. 6 Boyd, M.T, T.J Montgomery, and BJ. Spargo (1998)"Ecosystem Level Evaluation of Intrinsic Biodegradation at Naval Shipyards and Impact on Adjacent Ecosystems: A Preliminary Report,"NRL Technical Memorandum Report, NRL/MR/6115-98-8140 90 For example, we measure a car in GDP, not the steel, tires, leather, and workers used to produce the car. The value of the car embodies all of these other values. Thus, what we want for the ecosystem is what matters directly to people. It’s not that other things aren’t relevant, but that they should be embodied in this value. b) Ecosystem-services are benefit-specific. Flood protection from wetlands should be counted. They substitute for flood control. Wetlands are not services for the water quality they provide. Instead, this quality should be valued directly. Including it again as a wetland service would be double counting. c) Counts what we can count, not what should be counted. Boyd argues this is what we do for other goods. We consider the price of the car, not the satisfaction from owning it. That is, we use price, rather than consumer surplus, as the value. d) Ecosystem services should be ecological. Recreation itself is not a service. Things in nature that make recreation possible are. e) Ecosystem services should be counted with greatest possible spatial and temporal resolution. People benefit in specific places and times. For example, when and where clean water is available matters. The amount of pollution will have different effects depending on location. May make placing dollar values on these a bit more difficult. Note that key to these principles is marginal analysis. The question isn’t the cost of destroying all trees, but the cost of destroying one additional tree 13.6 Will Sustainable Development Occur in Market Economies? Valuing environmental benefits and costs is the most challenging task when considering sustainable levels of development. In some cases, markets are beginning to appreciate the values provided by ecosystems. Good values depend both on good science and good economics. Early studies often gave implausibly high values, leading to the work being discredited. For example the Panama Canal Crisis - the issue is that deforestation is harming the canal: • Water supply has been drying up. Most freshwater stored upstream in Gatún Lake, an artificial lake created during the canal’s construction, where it accumulates from rainfall. 91 52 million gallons of water is released into the ocean each time a ship uses the canal. Deforested slopes around the lake do not absorb rainwater. Thus, rain runs into the lake too quickly, causing it to overflow and run into the sea. This is important, because while the area gets 10 feet of rain per year (3x more than Seattle), most rain comes in the rainy season from May to December. If the land were forested, the water would be absorbed and would flow into the lake more slowly. • Much of the deforestation has occurred since the 1950s, when a highway made the land accessible to loggers. Sediment and nutrients get into the canal. Nutrients lead to growth of weeds. This leads to expensive dredging • There have been some reductions in deforestation since the 1990s. Leading Panamanian bankers stopped financing cattle ranchers who cut down forests for pasture. When the canal was turned over to the Panamanian government in 1999, government agencies had incentive to protect the watershed. • Still, the agencies do not have enough money for thorough monitoring and enforcement, and reforestation needs to be done. • As a result, a private insurance firm, ForestRe has stepped in with a proposal. The plan would have shipping companies that use the canal underwrite a 25 year bond to pay for reforestation. These companies would ask their big clients, such as WalMart and the Asian auto companies, to buy the bonds. These companies would get discounts on insurance premiums they currently pay to insure against closure of the canal. Other examples a) Catskill Mountains, NY New York City gets its water from the Catskill Mountains watershed. In 1997, the city faced building a water filtration plant to clean water from the watershed. This had an up-front cost of $4-6 billion, plus $250 million/year operating costs. Instead, the city made payments to preserve the Catskill watershed. $250 million was spent to buy land to prevent development. $100 was spent million/year to farmers to minimize pollution. b) Cape Town, South Africa Found that it was cheaper to restore the local watershed than to divert water supplies from elsewhere or build reservoirs. 92 c) Cauca Valley, Columbia Large agriculture producers pay fees for watershed management projects. Note how the fees address the public goods problem d) Costa Rica Hydro-electric producers, private customers, and the government contribute $57 million/year to protect a local watershed. • Services provided for hydro-electric producers include: Stream-flow regulation, sediment retention, and erosion control. • Service provided by private consumers is irrigation and the government ensures water supply for towns and maintain scenic beauty for recreation and ecotourism 13.7 Audits for resource-rich countries • These focus on providing information to allow market forces to work. Like many other policies we've discussed, the effectiveness of the audits depends on the reactions of the developed world • The proposal would subject resource-rich countries to financial audits of the revenues and resulting spending from sales of natural resources • While corrupt countries may not wish to be audited, the hope is that pressure from consumers would encourage multinational companies to insist on audits. • Records of revenues raised would make it easier to save gains from boom years for later use. Harder to steal funds if there is a public record. 93 LECTURE FOURTEEN INTERNATIONAL TRADE, TRADE AGGREEMENTS AND THE ENVIRONMENT 14.1 Introduction The term international trade is normally interchangeably used with such other terms like free trade, trade across boarders, global trade, foreign trade etc. In this lecture all these terms will be referring to the same context. Historically, free trade is as old as civilization. However, it has assumed great significance after the industrial revolution and is now conducted on a large scale. Free trade refers to the exchange of goods and services between citizens, business firms or governments of different countries. Foreign trade is of three types: import trade, export trade and re-export or entrepot. (a) Import trade – This means purchasing goods from foreign countries. (b) Export trade – Refers to selling goods to foreign countries. (c) Re-exports or entrepot trade – Means first importing goods and then exporting them to other countries. Throughout this lecture emphasis will be placed on the need for appropriate global policies on environmental resources to meet the pace of the desired international trade exchanges. At the end of this section you are expected to be able to: 1. Discuss the benefits and disadvantages of international 2. Explain basic theories governing international trade and their criticisms 3. Describe the Pollution Haven Hypothesis (PHH) 4. Categorise and explain various international trade agreements that have impact on global environment. 14.2 Critical Reasons for International Trade There are 3 main reasons for international trade: resource endowment, technological gap and economies of scale. Let us briefly discuss these reasons. (a) Resource endowment This explains the fact that all nations posses same resources (raw materials) e.g. minerals, wildlife, land, labour etc. Mineral resources can obviously be worked only where they 94 are found. Also many commodities can be grown only under particular climatic conditions or in certain soils. As a result most rubber is produced world wide in Malaysia and the East Indies; most of the world's coffee supply comes from Brazil. This variation in production resources leads to nation's specialisation in production of particular products of these commodities hence International Trade. The country imports those commodities which require resources that it does not posses. (b) Technological Gap According to this theory, the introduction of new technological processes and new products, gives the innovative firm or nation a monopoly in the world market. Such monopoly is based on patent copyrights which are normally granted to stimulate innovations. However as foreign producers (imitators) acquire the technology, enter the world market. This is a problem with the industrialised nations whereby the imitators enter the world market and undersell the innovators. The inhabitants of a region may also develop a special skill for the production of a commodity, which in time may require a special regulation for quality. For instance, Wines such as Sweet Wine and Redtops owe their distinctive qualities in East Africa partly due to the special flavour of locally grown grapes (in Central Tanzania) and partly due to the local method of manufacture that nations haven't acquired. These technologically differentiated products need to be sold to other countries, thereby resulting to International trade. (c) Economies of Scale While the previous two theories explain the trade between developed and developing countries, economies of scale explains that even if two nations are identical in every aspect there is still good reason for mutual beneficial trade baring on the increasing returns to scale (Economies of Scale). The condition of increasing returns to scale refers to the production situation where output grow proportionately more than the increase in inputs. Economies of scale occur mostly through production specialization in developed countries and in developing countries, ability to have modern and specialized machineries. Therefore, it can be observed that most of the trade between Developed and Developing countries is Inter-Industry Trade based on differences in resource endowment and technological gap. A large portion of trade among industrialized countries is Intra-Industry Trade where there is trade in differentiated products from the same industry. 95 14.3 Theories explaining basis for international trade Before we discuss the various theories of international trade, let us point out basic assumptions governing international trade theory. It is generally widely accepted to consider the following assumptions in order to clearly describe various aspects of international trade in a simple and easy way of understanding them: • There are only 2 nations in the world producing 2 products. • There is pure competition in both resources and production markets. • Resources are mobile i.e. they can be moved from one point to another within the nation's boarders. • Liberation of trade i.e. no institution intervention or protection. • No transport costs. As seen before, International Trade seems to arise out of specialisation which results into surplus commodities and therefore the need for exchange. The theories explaining this basis for International Trade can be grouped into three: 14.3.1 Mercantilism This theory was based on the promotion of Exports and discourage Imports. The outcome of this was the initial stage of trade barriers. However not all countries would benefit at the same time. So the mercantilists got criticisms with time. 14.3.2 Absolute Advantage Principle This theory was put forward by Adam Smith. He reasoned that nations will gain from Free International trade if each one specializes in the production of that commodity it can produce most efficiently or in a commodity in which it has absolute advantage over others and then it can exchange part of that commodity output for others it can produce inefficiently i.e. it has absolute disadvantages in their production. This principle can be illustrated with the following example: Assume a case where there are two countries namely Tanzania and Uganda both producing bananas and maize as tabulated below in Table 4.1 Table 14.1 Hypothetical demonstration of absolute advantage principle Country Maize (000’ tones) Bananas (000’ tones) Tanzania 10 5 Uganda 5 15 96 Table 14.1 shows that using 1 unit of labour, Tanzania can produce either 10,000 tones of maize or 5,000 tones of bananas. Uganda on the other hand can produce 15,000 tones of bananas or 5,000 tones of maize using one unit of labour. Therefore Tanzania can produce maize more efficiently than Uganda and Uganda can produce bananas more efficiently than Tanzania. So Tanzania should specialize in production of maize while Uganda should specialize in bananas and then exchange their surplus. From the example Tanzania has absolute advantage in the production of maize while Uganda has absolute advantage in the production of bananas. Adam’s shortcoming is that as time went on, it was discovered that one can't base International trade on absolute advantage. The absolute advantage occurs between developed and least developed countries only. 14.3.3 The Law of Comparative Advantage This law was put forward by David Ricardo in 1817 to improve on Adam Smith's principle of absolute advantage. He argues that even if a nation is less efficient i.e. it has absolute disadvantage with respect to the other nations in the production of both commodities, there is still a basis for mutual beneficial free trade. The less efficient country should specialise in the production of both commodities, there is still a basis for mutual beneficial free trade. The less efficient country should specialise in the production and export of that commodity in which its absolute disadvantage is less (i.e. this is a commodity of its comparative advantage), and import the commodity in which its absolute disadvantage is greater (This is the commodity of its comparative disadvantage). To illustrate this law, let us use the case of Tanzania and Mozambique over the production of cloves and cotton. Table 14.2 Hypothetical demonstration of absolute advantage principle Country Cloves (000’ tones) Cotton(000’metres) Tanzania 5 20 Mozambique 1 10 Table 14.2 shows that Tanzania has absolute advantage in the production of both cloves and cotton. By producing 1 tone of cloves, Tanzania foregoes 4(20/5) metres of cotton while Mozambique foregoes 10 (10/1) metres of cotton by producing 1 tone of cloves. On the other hand, if Tanzania produces one metre of cotton, it foregoes ¼ (5/20) tones of cloves, while Mozambique foregoes 1/10 tones of cloves by producing 1 metre of cotton. 97 From the above analysis, it should be noted that Tanzania incurs less Opportunity Cost (real costs) in producing cloves than Mozambique, while Mozambique incurs less Opportunity Cost in producing cotton than Tanzania. Therefore, we say that Tanzania has a comparative advantage over Mozambique in the production of cloves while Mozambique has a comparative advantage over Tanzania in the production of cotton. A country has a comparative advantage over others if it can produce one or more commodities at less Opportunity Cost than others. The Law of Comparative Advantage can also be stated that, even if a country has absolute advantage in the production of 2 or more commodities, it should produce that commodity where it incurs less real costs (Opportunity Cost). From an example, Tanzania should specialize in producing cloves and Mozambique should specialize in producing cotton, then the 2 nations can benefit by exchanging surpluses. 14.4 Criticisms of the Law of Comparative Advantage (a) The assumption that there are only 2 nations producing 2 commodities is unrealistic because Modern International Trade is multi-lateral and countries produce more than 2 commodities. (b) This law assumes that less developed countries should specialize in the production of primary products where they have a comparative advantage. However, this would lead to unfavourable terms of trade since prices of primary products are always lower than prices of primary products are always lower than prices of manufactured products. (c) This law assumes that a nation cannot exploit more resources and improve on efficiency in the production of a commodity where it incurs more real costs. (d) It assumes that technology is constant and a country cannot reduce production costs in the long run after technological changes and after reaping economies of scale. (e) It does not take into account the need for diversification and self reliance which tend to disagree with specialization. (d) The law assumes that trade is free, but in practice there are restrictions and trade barriers. (e) The law does not take into account transport costs which increase costs and reduce benefits of international trade. (f)With this law, it is difficult to determine the country which should specialize in the production of that commodity which is produced by both countries at the same costs. (g) Once trade begins, a country that becomes specialized has no choice to continue. Thus, critics of globalization ask if diversification has value. 98 (h) Daly notes that the basic principle of comparative advantage depends on immobile factors. If factors are mobile, absolute advantage matters. E.g. all capital can go to the country with lowest costs. The quality of a factor (e.g. skilled vs. unskilled labor) also matters. Factor mobility increases the opportunity set, so should make the country better off. However, a country with monopoly power in world factor markets can make itself better off at the expense of the rest of the world by limiting factor mobility. In sighting of all such limitations, Godfried Haberter wrote a book "Theory of International Trade" in which he argued that the Optimum pattern of production and trade of a country would appear to be determined from the comparison of the Opportunity Cost (real costs) of producing a given commodity with the price at which the commodity can be imported or exported. Haberter’s improvement on the Law of Comparative advantage has made this law a more useful one in basing arguments on the international trade. 14.5 Pollution Haven Hypothesis Does free trade make protecting the environment more difficult? Pollution haven hypothesis – the idea that firms will move from countries with strong environmental standards to those with weaker standards. Developing countries may even be able to attract industry with low standards. Esty notes that, while expanded trade and economic growth need not hurt the environment, there is no guarantee that it won’t. Three effects of economic growth on trade: a) Technique: Higher incomes are linked to cleaner production processes. b) Composition effects: Higher incomes are linked to preferences for cleaner goods. c) Scale effects: Higher incomes lead to increased pollution due to greater consumption. If scale effects dominate, the environment will be worse off. Empirical evidence of the pollution haven hypothesis is however weak. 99 Examples of a test of pollution haven hypothesis: a) The Heckscher-Ohlin model of international trade The Heckscher-Ohlin (H-O) model of international trade states that countries will have a comparative advantage in goods produced with endowed factors that are in relative abundance. Countries with hydroelectric resources trade goods that require a lot of electricity to produce (e.g. aluminum). Countries with cheap labor produce labor-intensive goods (e.g. clothing). Countries with large capital stock produce capital-intensive goods (e.g. autos). Thus, the theory predicts that countries with a large capacity to assimilate pollution will produce pollutionintensive goods. As well as the physical ability to assimilate pollution, income matters. Citizens of wealthier countries are more likely to demand cleaner environments. To determine if lax environmental regulations attract dirty industries, economists use the Heckscher-Ohlin model to explain trade in goods associated with pollution. Controlling for other resource endowments, one can test to see if environment variables are significant, i.e. Net Exportsij = ai + b1Ej1 + b2Ej2 + …+bKEjK + dRj + eij Ejk = endowment in country j of factor k (e.g. capital, labor, land, natural resources) Rj = strictness of environmental regulations in country j (e.g. pollution control expenditures) In general, economists fail to find a significant relationship between environmental regulation and trade. One criticism of such models is that stocks of capital change slowly, as they represent years of accumulation. Thus, measuring flows of capital may be a better alternative. This is done by using foreign direct investment (FDI) as the dependent variable, i.e. FDIij = ai + b1Fj1 + b2Fj2 + …+bKFjK + dRj + eij Fjk = level of variables affecting FDI in country j, such as tax policy Rj = strictness of environmental regulations in country j b) Xing and Kolstad extension of H-O model Using such a model, Xing and Kolstad (1997) find that foreign direct investment (FDI) for dirty industries, such as chemicals, does flow to countries with lax environmental regulations, but find no effect for low polluting industries, such as electronics. There has been more growth of toxicintensive industries in developing countries. A recent paper by Ederington, Levinson and Minier offers explanations for small effects: 100 i) They argue that aggregate data misses effects in specific industries.Their work proposes three reasons why others find little effect: • Most trade is between similar countries (North/North). If one looks specifically at North/South trade, find an effect. They divide countries into low and high environmental costs. When US environmental costs rise, net imports to low cost countries increase. Elasticity is 0.2 (10% increase in US costs 2% increase in imports) • Not all industries are mobile. Industries are mobile if there are low benefits to agglomoration and also if there are low transport costs involved. • Indstries that are mobile are more sensitive to environmental costs ii) Not all industries are pollution intensive. Surprisingly, they do not find a bigger effect of environmental costs on pollution intensive industries, unless they control for mobility. It appears that pollution intensive industries are also less mobile! However, this also means that the argument that there is no pollution haven effect because most PACE costs are insignificant is not sufficient. iii) Other explanations for the weak evidence of pollution haven hypothesis • In general, other factors are more important in choosing location: Skills of workers, proximity to markets, political stability, and availability of materials • As a result, even when evidence of the pollution haven hypothesis is found, the magnitudes are often weak. • The Bureau of Labor Statistics collects data on total layoffs and the reasons. Few mass layoffs are due to environmental regulations. Total layoff events Total people affected Layoffs for environmental reasons 2000 5,620 1,170,427 7 Total people affected by environmental reasons 1,142 2001 8,350 1,751,464 3 445 2002 7,295 1,546,976 3 718 2003 7,346 1,502,825 5 1,044 The most frequent reason for mass layoffs is completion of seasonal work (2,370 layoffs in 2003) and internal restructuring (1,437 layoffs in 2003). Other major reasons are contract completion and slack work. In 2003, 111 were due to import competition. 101 14.6 International Agreements: GATT The World Trade Organization (WTO), and its predecessor, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), provide a framework of rules and procedures to be followed in international trade relationships. GATT began in late 1940’s. The WTO was established in 1995 after the Uruguay round of GATT (1986-1994). GATT covers trade in goods, and still exists as a subset of WTO. It aims to reduce barriers of trade. It also does allow exceptions to protect “human, animal or plant life” and to conserve natural resources. Such import restrictions must be done in a non-discriminatory way. Examples: a) GATT upheld the US tax on luxury cars and gas guzzlers because they applied equally to all autos (Europe protested the taxes). b) Denmark placed a ban on nonrefillable drink containers. Imports of such containers were prohibited. Other European countries felt that this was done to give Danish beverage producers an advantage, rather than protect the environment. The European court ruled in favor of Denmark, since it was non-discriminatory. c) In the 1990’s, the U.S. banned imports of tuna caught in nets that kill dolphins. Mexico complained to GATT & won. GATT accepted America’s aim of protecting dolphins, but objected to the use of discriminatory trade sanctions. Suggested labeling of dolphin-friendly tuna instead. d) The WTO also ruled against a U.S. ban against shrimp harvested with technologies that harm sea turtle because it gave preference to Western Hemisphere countries. The ban gave Western Hemisphere countries more time to comply and provided financial aid for new technologies. India, Malaysia, Pakistan, and Thailand protested to WTO. However, the WTO noted it was the preferential treatment that violated GATT article 20. The ruling made clear, however, that countries did have the right to take trade action to protect the environment, as long as it is nondiscriminatory. The issue becomes cloudier when we consider pollution from production. Consider a firm in a country such as the U.S. that has strong environmental standards, but has a competitor in a nation with weak standards. The competitor has lower costs, so it has an advantage. However, it isn’t clear that the U.S. can do anything legally under GATT. GATT gives the U.S. the authority to protect the health of its citizens. However, imposing stronger environmental restrictions on the second country affects the health of those citizens, not Americans. 102 An important question is whether we should do something. Whose standards should matter? A World Trade Organization (WTO) report in the fall of 1999 admitted that trade can harm the environment. Report says that environmentally damaging subsidies for farming, fishing, and fossil fuels should be eliminated. Report says more product labeling should be allowed. The discussion above leads to a bigger question: is it fair for developed countries to expect developing countries to strengthen environmental regulations? Discuss this 14.7 Climate Change and International Agreements Throughout the world discussing are underway on the results of the climate change simulation, in which some of the difficulties of reaching an agreement on international environmental issues are revealed. Important issues include: a) Compensation for developing countries - Developing countries want to continue to grow economically. To willingly accept limits on their emissions (which they often perceive, rightly or wrongly, as limits on growth), they need compensation in return. b) Enforcement of an international agreement - Is there a body that can collect permit fees, for example? Note that bodies gain legitimacy when actors have a stake in the outcome. For instance, the UN body that ratifies Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) projects provides value to the project sponsors c) What balance should be struck between mitigation and adaptation? - Would it be more valuable to spend money on adaptation in developing countries? d) Is an international agreement even necessary? - Pizer notes that global agreements don’t seem to be working for climate change. U.S. is not participating. Developing countries not involved in meaningful discussions. Kyoto participants are not meeting targets. What individual countries have done? • EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS) • Canadian Large Final Emitter Program. Tradable permit system with C$15 safety valve 103 • New Zealand announced NZ$15 carbon tax, however, it did not follow through on announcement • Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) board has approved 50 projects worth more than 100 million tons for the 2008-2012 period. 14.8 Lessons for design of global agreement Three suggested lessons for design of global agreement include: a) More flexible architecture that accommodates quantity, price, and technology policies needed. b) There is support for project-based crediting in developing countries. Can these be expanded and improved? c) Global agreements need to consider how to measure and value domestic policy actions. Based on this, Pizer suggests a new approach based on three principles: • The need for domestic policy development - Because of domestic policies, there is not a global price for carbon. However, the implied carbon prices in the domestic policies are similar. Countries don’t want to put themselves at a disadvantage. Moreover, compliance with Kyoto depends on domestic implementation. In the case of the Montreal Protocol, domestic policies came first. International agreements were based on these policies. Domestic policies can be consistent with domestic pressures. Enabling domestic policies allows for variety in policy types. E.g. more technology policies to help develop new technologies. • Credits in developing countries - Because developing countries want to protect growth, this may be the only way to involve developing countries. Key question is baselines: what would have happened. Can have big transfer of income effects. • Evaluating actions - Participation in public good provision depends on a perception that others are doing their share. Moving beyond simple price and quantity policies necessitates new means of evaluation. What credit should countries get for enhancing technology or providing international aid? 14.9 The Montreal Protocol The Montreal Protocol which outlines the phase-out of chlorofluorocarbons (CFCs), offers an example of a successful international agreement which was signed in 1987. Let us highlight key aspects of the protocol; 104 a) Prohibits exports of controlled substances (CFCs) from any signatory nation to any state not a party to the protocol, and signatory nations may not import any controlled substance from a non signatory state. b) India and China did not sign on until a 1990 revision that provided a $260 million fund to finance the transition in developing countries. c) Goal: to make sure that CFCs and other ozone-depleting chemicals do not simply migrate to nonsignatory nations. Reasons why the Montreal Protocol was successful, even though most international agreements aren’t: a) Only six main companies produce CFCs, so monitoring is simple. b) Clean technological substitutes have developed quickly. This helped keep the costs of compliance low. One substitute, hydrochlorofluorocarbons (HCFC) also depletes the ozone layer, but at a slower rate. It will be phased out by 2030. c) Publicity surrounding the ozone hole over Antarctica provided public pressure. d) Moreover, progress is visible, whereas for climate change, the effects of today's policies won't be experienced for a generation or two. 105 LECTURE FIFTEEN EXHAUSTIBLE RESOURCES 15.1 Introduction Exhaustible resources are resources that even if left alone do not reproduce themselves – at least over any time scale relevant to humankind. Exhaustible resources include minerals like copper, iron, manganese and most carbon based forms of energy such as oil, coal and gas. The purpose of this lecture is to explain why exhaustible resources are seen as an important issue in economic terms and to answer the following question: will we ever run out of resources? The lecture also aims to explain how the market depletes natural resources over time and how changes in the market for natural resources affect their depletion rates. The question of whether Governments should intervene to alter the rate of depletion is addressed. The lecture then looks at how different market structures deplete resources. At the end of this section students are expected to be able to: 1. Explain various concepts such as renewable Vs Non renewable resources, reserve exhaustible resources, economic and non economic reserves, known resvres and yet to be known reserves etc 2. Explicitly distinguish between arbitrage and exhaustion principles used to understand resource problems 3. Explain the role of government in management of exhaustible resources 4. Explain the trend prices of exhaustible resources over time 5. Analyse the cost of optimal extraction of an exhaustible resource 15.2 Quantification of exhaustible reserve resources The quantification of the remaining reserves of exhaustible resources is somewhat difficult. Reserves can be divided into a number of categories including ‘known’ reserves and ‘yet to be discovered’ reserves. Known and unknown reserves can be divided into ‘economic’ and ‘noneconomic’ reserves. By ‘economic’ it is meant that they are profitable to extract given prevailing resource prices. Currently uneconomic reserves might well become economic in the future. Thus one needs to be careful about reading too much into current reserve-production ratios and calculating the number of year’s resources which are remaining since these are apt to change. Even if we were to run out of some resources this does not imply that anything bad would necessarily happen. For many resources it would be possible to substitute to ‘backstop technologies’ which, although slightly higher in price, could provide limitless quantities of energy and materials. All that 106 is required is the incentive to innovate. Even if there are commodities without which certain important forms of economic activity could not occur (and it is difficult to think of examples) it may be possible to stretch out these resources over all future time and still enjoy increasing economic standards of living. It should be noted that exhaustible resources are not destroyed when they are ‘consumed’ but can at least to some extent be collected and used again and again (although a distinction should be made here between finite-yet-recyclable and finite-and-nonrecyclable resources such as carbon energy). Current economic reserves have increased through time for many commodities. 15.3 Principles for understanding exhaustible resource problems There are two key principles necessary for understanding exhaustible resource problems. First of these is the ‘arbitrage principle’ and the second of these is the ‘exhaustion principle.’ Let us briefly explain each of these principles independently. 15.3.1 Arbitrage Principle According to the arbitrage principle the price of the resource should increase at the rate of interest. Suppose that this were not the case and that the price were rising at a rate less than the rate of interest or perhaps not even rising at all. In this case each individual mine owner would prefer to extract all his stock immediately and invest the proceeds. Every mine owner however feels the same way and consequently the current price falls until prices once more rise at the rate of interest. If prices are rising faster than the rate of interest then each individual will conserve the resource. Once again if enough mine owners do this then the current price will until the price once again rises at the rate of interest. Thinking about exhaustible resources like financial assets explains why mine owners don’t want to extract and sell the resource as fast as is possible. 15.3.2 Exhaustion principle The exhaustion principle states that just at the moment when the price reaches the backstop price the last remaining units of the resources are extracted. The exhaustion principle must hold since at the point when the price of the backstop is reached the mine owner is left holding a resource which, if he had extracted it earlier, he could have invested the profits and earned a certain rate of return. As it is he is left with an asset whose price is now fixed by the backstop. Together the exhaustion 107 principle and the arbitrage principle define the complete path of prices and extraction for the resource. Note that a social planner would deplete a finite stock of known size in exactly the same way, ensuring that the net marginal benefit of the last unit of production is the same in each time period subject to the total resource constraint. Hence it is difficult to argue that Governments should intervene to alter the depletion of natural resources. Bear in mind however that there might be externalities from the extraction of the resource. There may also be important differences between the rate of discount used in industry and the social rate of time preferences. Finally there might be market structures that differ from perfect competition as well as strategic considerations. When through technical breakthrough extraction costs are reduced the price falls and the time to exhaustion is shortened. With surprise discoveries of the resource the mine owners all suffer a capital loss. The asset that they hold in the form of the resource is not as scarce as they had supposed. In order that the price should reach the backstop just as the last units of the resource are extracted it must be the case that the current price must fall. This is in order that the stock is all exhausted. Furthermore if the price path is to fall then it is clear that the time to exhaustion is increased as well. Repeated and yet unexpected discoveries can cause the price trajectory to take a scalloped appearance. How would the extraction plan and price trajectory change when the entire stock of a resource is in the hands of a monopoly? Thus far the case of the perfect competition has been dealt with. The question arises of what happens when the entire stock of a resource is in the hands of a monopoly. The problem of the monopoly is still to maximise the present value of discounted profits from the extraction of the resource but unlike in the perfect competition case, the monopoly recognises that it can choose the price that it faces. The monopoly recognises that additional sales reduce the revenue obtained on preceding units and because of this fact the extraction rule is modified. More specifically the monopolist requires the marginal revenue minus marginal cost rise at the rate of interest over time. Unless this condition is fulfilled, along with the exhaustion principle, it would pay the monopolist to change his extraction plans. 108 How does the extraction plan of the monopolist compare with the extraction plans of the perfectly competitive industry The answer to this question actually depends upon the shape of the demand curve and the extraction cost function. The monopolist can actually deplete the resource faster or slower than the perfectly competitive industry. In the case of a linear demand curve with no extraction costs it can be shown that the monopolist depletes the resource more slowly than would a perfectly competitive mining industry. In this sense the monopolist is the friend of the conservationist. The explanation is that with a linear demand curve the marginal revenue curve must be steeper than the demand curve. Hence in order to see marginal revenue rise at the rate of interest a smaller reduction in quantity extracted is required in each period compared to the quantity reduction necessary to see prices rise at the rate of interest. Hence the increase in prices must be attenuated in the case of the monopolist but the initial price must be higher. 15.4 Government taxation on exhaustible resources Depletable resources have often been targeted for Government taxation. In some situations it is possible that the taxes levied do not alter the extraction plans of the industry and do not entail any kind of distortion. This helps to explain why these resources have been targeted. The most obvious form of tax is simply to remove the rent associated with the resource. This tax obviously must compute the rent in each time period so the tax per unit extracted will have to rise at the rate of interest over time leaving resource owners with just a normal profit for extracting it. In this case it is probably better to regard the state itself as the real owner of the resource and the mining company as the contractor who extracts the resource. The existence of large rents associated with scarce resources provides exactly the right incentives for individual companies to explore for more reserves. A company will explore for new reserves where it believes that the marginal costs of discovery are equal to the rental value of the resource that is in turn equal to the marginal social benefit. Although the royalty tax does not alter the time profile of extraction for a stock of known size it does diminish the incentives to discover more of the resource. The implication of this is that it might be necessary to combine fiscal incentives for exploration activities with rent taxes. 109 15.5 Exploration and extraction rights There are problems however if the land that is being explored is common property in this case the amount of exploratory activity may be excessive rather than gradually increasing (this is called ‘racing’). Imagine a situation in which property rights are granted only once deposits of a resource have been located. Everyone wishes to ‘stake a claim’ early on. Rather than the marginal costs of discovery being equated with the rental value of the resource the outcome will be the average discovery cost being equated with the rental value. Alternatively imagine a situation in which exclusive property rights are not granted (or if granted cannot be securely enforced) not even when deposits of a resource have been granted. In such circumstances the amount of exploratory activity might be inadequate. A lucky strike always leads to others immediately jumping in and staking a claim nearby. If it is impossible to stop this happening and at the same time impossible to keep quiet about the discovery then there is little point in exploring in the first place. These problems are resolved by giving each company exclusive rights to explore an area. 15.6 Prices of exhaustible resources over time The theory of exhaustible resources makes some quite strong predictions about the movement of prices of exhaustible resources over time. Does the empirical evidence on resource depletion and price movements support the theory of exhaustible resources? By examining the movements in the price of exhaustible resources over time it is clear that there is very little support for the theory of exhaustible resources, at least not in its simplest format. The evidence from large numbers of commodities is that prices have either not increased at all or have fallen or describe some U shaped curve. The implications of this evidence is that either the theory of depletion is itself is wrong or that the theory makes unreasonable assumptions or that there are other important factors which have not been taken account of. Alternatively it may be necessary to be more precise about what the theory actually says. The theory of depletion does not state that prices should rise at the rate of interest (since that only holds in the case of zero extraction costs) but rather that economic rent should increase at the rate of interest. This means that it is possible for prices not to rise at the rate of interest or even to fall over time provided that technical progress has led to sufficient reductions in the costs of extraction. Alternatively it may be that mine owners are continuously surprised by the fact that more of the resource is being discovered 110 The theory of depletion also abstracts from the process of actually discovering exhaustible resources but instead assumes that the reserves are of known size and that the only question is how to deplete them over time. A more complete theory would consider both processes simultaneously. Such theories have in fact been developed although they are too complex to be considered here. One such model of resource discovery and depletion permits prices charged to first fall and then to rise over time. This would appear to fit the empirical evidence in a number of cases. 15.7 Optimal Extraction of an Exhaustible Resource Let us outline three classifications of exhaustible resources: i) Current reserves - known reserves that can be profitably extracted at current prices. j) Potential reserves - reserves that could be recovered at higher prices. k) Resource endowment - the entire geological supply of resources (including those not yet discovered). Decisions to use exhaustible resources are dynamic decisions, because future availability of the resource depends on what is used today. Thus, exhaustible resources should be treated as an asset. 15.8 The Costs of Extraction There are two costs to using a resource, such as oil, today: a) Extraction cost How much does it cost to obtain the resource? Obviously, only sell if P ≥ MEC (marginal extraction cost). b) User cost This is the opportunity cost of not having the resource to sell in the future. As a result, the price of the resource will be greater than the MEC. Thus the owner of a resource, such as oil, has two options to make money for next year: i) Sell all the oil now, and invest the profits at interest rate i. and ii) Wait and sell the oil next year. Case A: Expected price next year rises less than the rate of interest: Present value of marginal profits next year is less than current value this year: i.e. P1 - MEC > (P2 - MEC)/(1+i) 111 The owner of the oil is better off selling the oil now and investing it. Leads to lower prices now (greater supply) and higher prices next year (lower supply). Case B: Expected price next year rises faster than the rate of interest: Present value of marginal profits next year is greater than current value this year: i.e. P1 - MEC < (P2 - MEC)/(1+i) The owner of the oil is better off waiting to sell the oil next year. This leads to higher prices now (lower supply) and lower prices next year (higher supply). Prices adjust whenever one option (case A or B) looks better. Thus, equilibrium is reached when the expected price of the oil rises at the rate of interest. o P1 - MEC = (P2 - MEC)/(1+i), or o (1 + i)(P1 - MEC) = (P2 - MEC) 15.9 Marginal user cost (MUC) MUC refers to the present value of the opportunity cost of the last unit of oil used not being available in the next period. i.e. P(t) = MUC(t) + MEC(t) If marginal extraction costs (MEC) are constant, the marginal user cost (MUC) rises at the rate of interest, i. This implies that the present value of marginal user cost remains the same! Note that the price of a resource is greater than the MEC. Thus, higher prices are not, by themselves, evidence of abuse of market power. Rather, they simply represent economic rent due to scarcity. The mathematical example shows how the marginal user cost increases as scarcity is more of a problem. 112 15.10 Changes in the marginal extraction cost Up to now, we have assumed the MEC is constant. If marginal extraction costs rise over time, the marginal user cost will fall. Intuition: MUC represents the opportunity cost of using the resource now. If it will be more costly to use the resource in the future, the opportunity cost is not as high. The theories that have been put forward so far all make the assumption that once the resource has been extracted and ‘consumed’ it ceases to exist. This of course is absolutely not the case in some instances (although in the case of energy products it is) and what happens is actually that the material is transformed and then, when the product has reached the end of its useful life, is disposed of. This leaves the possibility for recycling the material in question or taking virgin materials out of the ground. The effect of recycling is to augment considerably the original stock of the resource. For example if 90 percent of a particular metal can be recycled then the effective stock of the resource is multiplied by 10 times. It seems reasonable to assume that as the cost of virgin materials increases, so the quantity of materials recycled will rise asymptotically to 100 percent. 113