WORKING PAPER 99.13 UNDERSTANDING THE 1998 FOOD CRISIS: SUPPLY, DEMAND OR POLICY FAILURE? Steve R. Tabor, H.S. Dillon and M. Husein Sawit March 1999 A joint research project on Linkages Between Indonesia’s Agricultural Production, Trade and the Environment funded by the Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research, between CASER (Bogor) • CIES (Adelaide) • CSIS (Jakarta) • RSPAS (ANU, Canberra) Lead institution: CIES • University of Adelaide • Adelaide • SA 5005 • Australia Telephone (61 8) 8303 4712 • Facsimile (61 8) 8223 1460 • email: cies@economics.adelaide.edu.au Homepage: http://www.adelaide.edu.au/cies/ CASER/CSIS/CIES/ANU joint research project on Policy analysis of linkages between Indonesia's agricultural production, trade and environment Rapid economic growth in Indonesia has been accompanied by significant structural changes, including for its agricultural sector and its unique natural environment. Recently questions have been raised about the impact of Indonesia’s agricultural, industrial, trade and environmental policies on sustainable rural development. The nature of interactions between the economic activities of different sectors and the environment are such that an intersectoral, system-wide perspective is essential for assessing them. An international perspective also is needed to assess the impact on Indonesia of major shocks abroad, such as the implementation of the Uruguay Round agreements, APEC initiatives, or reforms in former centrally planned economies. There is increasing pressure on supporters of liberal trade to demonstrate that trade reforms at home or abroad affecting countries such as Indonesia will not add to global environmental problems (e.g., deforestation, reduced biodiversity). Again, this requires system-wide quantitative models of the economy and ecology, because typically there are both positive and negative effects at work, so the sign of the net effects ultimately has to be determined empirically. To begin to address these issues, the Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research (ACIAR) has generously provided funds for a collaborative 3-year project (to mid-1999) involving the University of Adelaide’s Centre for International Economic Studies (CIES) as the lead institution, Bogor’s Centre for Agro-Socioeconomic Research (CASER) which is affiliated with the Ministry of Agriculture, Jakarta’s independent Centre for Strategic and International Studies (CSIS), and the Economics Division of the Research School of Pacific and Asian Studies (RSPAS) at the Australian National University in Canberra. Being based on Indonesia with its rich diversity of environmental resources (and on which there are relatively good data) and its rapid economic growth, the project could also serve as a prototype for similar studies of other developing countries in Southeast Asia and elsewhere. The key objective of the project is to assess the production, consumption, trade, income distributional, regional, environmental, and welfare effects of structural and policy changes at home and abroad particularly as they will or could affect Indonesia’s agricultural sector over the next 5-10 years. Among other things, the analysis will focus both on the effects of economic changes on the environment, and on the impacts on Indonesia’s agricultural production and trade of resource and environmental policy changes. The implications of regional and multilateral trade liberalization initiatives and Indonesia’s ongoing unilateral trade reforms will be analysed, along with other potential domestic policy changes and significant external shocks such as the entry of China and Taiwan into the World Trade Organization. The analysis will draw on and adapt computable general equilibrium (CGE) models such as the national INDOGEM Model (built as part of an earlier ACIAR project) and the global GTAP Model. The project is being undertaken in close collaboration with the Indonesian Ministry of Agriculture and ministries involved in trade, planning, and the environment. A Research Advisory Committee has been established to encourage close collaboration of representatives from those and other ministries. ACIAR INDONESIA RESEARCH PROJECT WORKING PAPER 99.13 UNDERSTANDING THE 1998 FOOD CRISIS: SUPPLY, DEMAND OR POLICY FAILURE? Steve R. Tabor, H.S. Dillon and M. Husein Sawit Senior Agricultural Economist International Service for National Agricultural Research The Hague, Netherland. Agricultural Economist and Executive Director Center for Agricultural and Policy Studies Jakarta, Indonesia Senior Agricultural Economist Center for Agro-Socioeconomic research Bogor, indonesia March 1999 Indonesian food security in historical perspective During the past three decades prior to 1997, Indonesia made remarkable progress in improving food security. Throughout this period, food security was accorded a very high political priority. Key elements in the campaign to enhance food security included a rice self-sufficiency oriented agriculture development effort, rice price stabilisation, rural infrastructure investment, human resource development, labor-intensive industrialisation and the generation and dissemination of improved smallholder food crop technology (Sajogyo 1980, Amang 1996). These microeconomic efforts were embedded within a macroeconomic framework characterised by financial stability, equity and competitiveness (Tabor and Meijerink 1997). Over time, the focus on improving food security led to a pattern of economic growth in which the poor actively participated, resulting in what Sen (1981) has described as “growth mediated security”. According priority to agriculture development and labor-intensive industrialisation were considered the main elements of Government’s efforts to bolster food security, in contrast to the numerous income transfer schemes used in other middle-income economies (Peng 1997). Food availability and poverty indicators attest to the success of this strategy. Per capita food availability increased from around 2000 calories per day in the 1960s to close to 2700 calories per day by the early 1990s (FAO 1996). The proportion of the population classified as poor fell from 44 percent in the 1970s to 11 percent in 1996. The combination of higher levels of food availability and a much smaller poor population significantly enhanced food security, at both a national and a household level. But the climatic and economic shocks of 1997 and 1998 reversed many of these hard fought gains. An unprecedented series of climatic, food supply, economic and political shocks caused the numbers of poor to surge, food prices to oscillate wildly and, for months at a time, priced basic foodstuffs out of many consumer’s reach. Ultimately, the combination of rising staple food prices and falling real incomes brought large numbers of angry protesters to the streets. Paradoxically, it was mounting food insecurity that triggered the downfall of the New Order government. The FAO (1997) defines food security as a situation in which all households have both physical and economic access to adequate food for all members, and where households are not at risk of losing such access. Food security implies that there is adequate availability, stability and access to essential foods. Adequate food availability means that, on average, sufficient food supplies should be available to meet consumption needs. Stability refers to the probability that, in difficult years or seasons, food consumption will not fall below consumption requirements. Access refers to the fact that many people still go hungry because they do not have the resources to produce or purchase the food they need. The principal determinant of food security is purchasing power, or income adjusted for the cost of living (FAO, p.7, 1996). In Indonesia’s case, the 1997 and 1998 shocks adversely affected all three dimensions of food security: availability, stability and access. Mounting food insecurity was first triggered by a sharp decline in domestic food production. Food production levels fell as a result of the 18 month El-Nino drought and the forest fires that blazed in the wake of the drought. In 1998, after more normal rains resumed, an upsurge in pest and rodent infestation battered food production levels. To combat domestic food supply shortages, official imports were increased to record levels. Coming shortly on the heels of the El Nino drought, Indonesia’s financial crisis resulted in a sharp fall in domestic demand, soaring inflation, falling real wages, rising under-employment and a surge in urban poverty levels. Despite ample pledges of international financial assistance, the growing ranks of distressed companies and moribund financial institutions caused investment to fall and capital outflows to rise. The Rupiah’s free-fall, from Rp.2,450 to the US dollar in June 1997 to Rp. 14,900 to the US dollar in June of 1998 propelled the cost of basic foodstuffs beyond the means of large segments of the domestic population. The May 1998 civil disturbances and the riots and civil strife that followed in late 1998 and early 1999 further aggravated the food security situation. Ethnic Chinese grain traders were one of the “targets” in the May 1998 disturbances. In various parts of the country, private food stocks were subject to confiscation and traders were charged with hoarding and price manipulation. The partial breakdown in law and order effectively raised the costs and hampered the delivery of food from surplus to deficit regions. Indonesia’s political transition has ushered in a far greater degree of press freedom than ever before. This, in turn, had an important effect on domestic food security. In early 1998, the agencies charged with stabilising food prices came under greater public scrutiny, leading to reports of corruption and misuse of authority in the public grains trade. Public confidence in the ability of Government to secure an adequate food supply plummeted. In mid-1998, the Chairman of BULOG was replaced and in May and June of 1998, (inaccurate) press reports of empty BULOG warehouses sparking panic buying and a sharp upsurge in retail prices (Kompas 8 June 1998). Table 1: Retail foodstuff prices in 27 major cities Period Rice Wheat flour Soybean Sugar Cooking oil (Rp./kg) 1994 1995 1996 1996-1 1996-2 1996-3 1996-4 1996-5 1996-6 1996-7 1996-8 1996-9 1996-10 1996-11 1996-12 660 776 883 857 860 856 851 849 855 899 913 910 904 915 918 836 872 905 879 890 880 888 894 895 906 916 922 925 927 930 1233 1271 1324 1263 1265 1281 1282 1303 1314 1317 1331 1382 1377 1383 1392 1287 1428 1502 1454 1475 1461 1489 1516 1522 1533 1527 1516 1511 1507 1509 1347(*) 1453 (*) 2724 2724 2740 2780 2804 2819 2826 2880 2917 2899 2892 2893 1997-1 1997-2 1997-3 1997-4 1997-5 1997-6 1997-7 1997-8 1997-9 1997-10 1997-11 1997-12 965 972 1014 1016 1021 1033 1046 1062 1088 1123 1207 1215 959 972 966 980 1000 994 988 992 1009 1017 1018 1015 1410 1430 1452 1470 1471 1485 1481 1474 1475 1707 1548 1666 1514 1522 1522 1534 1577 1573 1567 1561 1560 1567 1584 1581 2905 2907 2904 2903 2906 2905 2903 2921 2907 3122 3117 3210 1998-1 1290 1086 1888 1723 1998-2 1439 1164 2171 1836 1998-3 1475 1115 2329 1715 1998-4 1532 1625 2569 2153 1998-5 1623 1816 2632 2285 1998-6 1988 1935 Na 2368 1998-7 2202 2950 Na 2802 1998-8 2529 3676 Na 3599 1998-9 3009 3753 Na 3891 1998-10 2828 3582 Na 3785 • prices refer to average quality in major urban centers throughout Indonesia. • 1995 and 1996 values are Rupiah per bottle for cooking oil. Source: BULOG. 3785 5158 5266 5778 6959 6414 6834 6512 6130 5015 In 1997 and 1998, public policies were crafted to restore food security. From mid-1997 to mid-1998, the Government maintained administrative controls on the food supply, held domestic food prices well below world market prices and provided highly subsidised agroinputs to food producers. After the May 1988 civil disturbances, government-backed cooperatives were authorised to market a growing range of price-controlled foodstuffs. Government’s ability to provide food at a low price hinged on its ability to defend a large wedge between domestic and world market prices. In a nation of thousands of islands, enforcing such a policy would be a costly undertaking, even in periods of relative calm. From May to September 1998, as Indonesia was battered by civil unrest, the authorities were no longer able to defend the large wedge between domestic and international prices. Domestic food prices soared while the press regularly issued reports of rice and fertiliser being smuggled out of the country. More market-friendly approaches to food policy were adopted after the May to September price surge. In the last quarter of 1998, the government liberalised food trade, limited BULOGs mandate to rice operations, removed fertiliser subsidies and marketing restrictions, sharply increased the sums provided for subsidised farmer working capital, increased funding for a wide sweep of public works programs and provided monthly rice rations at low prices to a large number of poor households. Global grain prices fell in the second half of 1998, thanks partly to Russia’s unexpected withdrawal from global grain markets. Falling global grain prices amplified the effects of Indonesia’s exchange rate appreciation and helped to lower the cost of food on the domestic market. By early 1999, domestic rice prices were some 20 to 30 per cent higher than equivalent import parity prices, prompting calls for the application of an import tariff to protect producer incomes and stabilise domestic rice prices. The events of 1997 and 1998 leave us with many important, and still largely unanswered questions. Why did food security deteriorate so quickly in Indonesia after such impressive progress was been made in reducing poverty levels and stabilising domestic food markets during the past three decades? Was this due more to production shortfalls, the impacts of the financial crisis, political upheaval or to flaws in food policy? This paper reviews some of the evidence regarding the causes of Indonesia’s recent bout of food insecurity and draws lessons for future policy making. Mapping shocks to food security Both supply and demand-side shocks influence food security through their effect on “food entitlements”, or the ability of households to afford an adequate diet. An environmental shock (such as El Nino, forest fires or widespread pest infestation) that reduces food output will generally lower the incomes of food producers, raise food prices to consumers and require increased reliance on food imports. Food entitlements can decline because of lower producer incomes, falling consumer purchasing power and the diversion of public and private resources to pay for staple food imports instead of, for example, more costly (but more protein and vitamin-rich) foods. The main way in which Indonesia’s financial crisis affects food security is through a fall in aggregate demand and a sudden increase in the price of tradeables (such as food) to non-tradeables (such as property or other home goods). As a result of the macro-economic crisis, aggregate demand falls as output declines. Rising inflation causes a decline in real (but temporarily sticky) wages, reduces consumer purchasing power and erodes the real value of private savings. Falling demand and a downturn in investment reduce labor demand, adding to the ranks of the under-employed and unemployed. Capital outflows cause the nominal exchange rate to devalue, raising the price of imported goods and increasing the opportunity cost of domestically produced foodstuffs. Devaluation, rising interest rates and financial sector distress raise enterprise capital costs and trigger an upsurge in private enterprise failure. This, in turn, further reduces labor demand and caps real wage growth. As economic activity declines, government revenues fall. This, together with a rising public debt burden, constrains Government’s capacity to transfer income or otherwise protect the poor. How can the effects of food supply and macro economic shocks be disentangled, particularly when both influence incomes and both are so closely inter-related? To answer this, we apply a conceptual framework developed by C. Peter Timmer (1997) that relates income growth, income distribution and food security. Figure one presents the familiar Engel’s relation (in semi-log form) between income and food consumption. According to Engel’s law, when income rises, consumers spend a declining share of their household budget on foodstuffs. Below a certain point, households are poor, and when incomes drop even further, households will not have sufficient purchasing power to maintain adequate food security. The degree to which household food security is protected or threatened also depends on whether or not food prices are kept “high” or “low”. For any given level of income, food consumption will be higher at “low” than at “high” prices. Linked to the Engel’s curve, in figure 2, is a plot of the cumulative distribution of income against the log of income growth. The steeper the curve, the more equitable the income distribution. For Indonesia, the income and food security situation in the early 1990s was similar to that depicted as curve C1 in figure 1 and curve Yd1 in figure 2. Food prices had been kept somewhat high, because of modest amounts of trade protection accorded to rice and wheat and relatively high levels of trade protection accorded to sugar and soybeans. In addition, after many years of rapid economic growth with low inequality, income was quite evenly distributed. In 1996, the average incomes of the top 20 per cent of the household expenditure classes were 43 per cent and the bottom 40 per cent had 20.5 per cent of total income. Only one-seventh of the population had incomes that would place them below the poverty line, and of this, only a very small segment had an income below the ‘serious food security risk’ line. In response to the 1997 and 1998 shocks, Government initially intervened to reduce and to stabilise food prices. Prices of basic staple foods were held from 10 to 50 percent below prevailing import parity prices. In figure 1, the shift from a “high” to a “low” food price policy is equivalent to a shift from curve C2 to curve C1. At the same time, there was a sudden reduction in aggregate income and an increase in income inequity. Falling real wages, fewer inflation hedges for the poor and the government’s limited capacity to effectively transfer income would have led to a shift in the aggregate income curve from (Yd1) to (Yd2). In this situation, a larger number of households would have an income below the poverty line, and more would have an income below the “food security” risk threshold. Figure 1 : Income Growth, Poverty and Severe Food Insecurity Food Consumption Y/P Low = C2 C1=Y/Phigh Poverty Line Severe Food Insecurity Line Log Y YSFI Yp Figure 2 : Cumulative Income Distribution, Growth and Shocks Yd2 1.0 Yd1 0.14 Log Y . YSFI Yp In the last quarter of 1998, the Government abandoned the ‘low food price’ policy and concentrated its efforts on targeted income transfers to the poor. This would be equivalent to an attempt to increase the slope of the Yd2 curve (in figure 2) while shifting back to the lower C2 Engel’s curve (in figure 1). The ultimate effect on food security would depend on the degree to which the income gains to the poor from a targeted ‘cheap food’ transfer effort would outweigh the effects of higher prices on the ability of the poor to afford an adequate diet. During an economic crisis, there is a strong economic rationale for Governments to intervene to keep food prices low (on the C2 curve), to stimulate income growth (to shift back from the Yd2 to the Yd1 curve) and to redistribute income to the poorest groups (to raise the slope of the Yd2 curve to keep the poor from falling below the food security threshold). In practice, this has high fiscal costs and requires well-functioning institutions to implement effectively. Figures 1 and 2 also illustrate another important point. In an “income shock” situation, income transfers, between households and between government and households, are often the most important buffer between “poverty” and a severe “food security risk”. Within the household, inter-temporal income transfers can occur through dissaving---selling off land or other assets. Income transfers can occur through borrowing, either through banks or more commonly for the poor, in the curb markets. Indonesia also has long-established traditions of mutual self-help, which take hundreds of different forms in villages throughout the country. By keeping income distribution within reasonable bounds, private income transfers help ensure that the poor do not fall below the food security risk line. At any point in time, Government can combine “cheap food” and “income redistribution” efforts to deliver as much “food security output” as possible within the limits of the resources that can be mobilised for these efforts. In figure 3, this is portrayed as a public sector production problem, in the form of a set of production isoquants (P1, P2, P3) and fiscal budget constraints (the amount of funding allocated to these efforts, B1, B2, B3). In the short-run, the issue may not be so much one of funding resources that can be mobilised, but of the capacity of Government to effectively deliver “food at affordable prices” and “income redistribution” services. In figure 3, this would be the difference between curve P1 and curve P3. In general terms, the institutional capacity to effectively deliver “food at affordable prices” and to “transfer income to the poor” is a function of: i) the information available about the nature and extent of the food insecurity problem; ii) the speed of problem recognition, understanding and response by policy makers; iii) the amount of institutional change necessary to deliver the needed services (noting that large public institutions tend towards inertia); iv) the general level of managerial efficiency and accountability within these government services; and v) the degree to which institutional incentives guide efficient and effective service delivery. What research does exist on this point suggests that Government’s institutional capacity to deliver such services varies considerably from Province to Province. A study published by the Agricultural University (IPB), Unicef and the Ministry of Agriculture’s Planning Office (Hardinsyah et. al, 1998) suggests that poor coordination, limited information availability and weak accountability systems significantly inhibit Government’s capacity to monitor the food security situation and deliver relief. Other studies have pointed at delays and weaknesses in the delivery of social safety net programs and attributed this to hurried planning, excessive centralisation and inadequate involvement of non-governmental organisations in publicly funded community development efforts. What is often ignored is the fact that Government’s ability to stabilise food prices or to transfer income to the poor is seriously constrained by macro economic volatility itself. Exchange rate volatility, unto itself, causes food prices to oscillate quickly from a “high” to a “low” cost Engel’s curve. The contractionary effects of a real exchange rate devaluation cause aggregate demand to fall, exposing a growing segment of the population to poverty and food insecurity. Macro economic volatility is quickly transmitted to the domestic economy, causing immediate changes in domestic supply and demand conditions. By the time public policy responds, macro-economic conditions may have changed once again. We can depict the food security dilemma posed by macro economic distress in figure 4 below. Imagine that prior to the crisis, the Indonesian economy was operating at point A somewhere within the production possibility frontier PPF(1). Because of extensive capital inflows, the economy was producing an amount of food (which will be a proxy for tradeables) and non-tradeables at point Q1 ( or A), and the real exchange rate (tangent ER1) was defined at an equilibrium point that reflected the expectations of healthy growth and continued net capital inflows. Figure 3. Government Food Security Interventions : Production Side Issues Q2 Government Affordable Food Price Service C B A P2 B3 B2 B1 P1 P3 Q1 Government Income Redistribution Service Where P = f ( institutional capacity) B = f (fiscal capacity) With the onset of the macroeconomic crisis, capital inflows became a flood of outflows and, for many different reasons, confidence turned sharply against the Rupiah. The real effective exchange rate ratcheted downward and has oscillated within a band shown in figure 4 as ER2. To restore external equilibrium, aggregate demand would have to be sharply compressed, to a point such as Q2 or Q2* in figure 4. While ultimately the output of tradeable goods may not fall very much (for example, to point B in figure 4), the incomes of producers of nontradeable goods, spread over the labor force involved in those subsectors, may be insufficient to afford an adequate diet. But identifying and transferring income to those whose cannot afford an adequate diet may be difficult, particularly if the exchange rate is volatile (and hence shifting the aggregate demand curve facing different sectors) and if, as is expected, labor shifts from the production of non-tradeable to tradeable goods and services. In fact, devaluation should inspire resource allocation shifts from the non-tradeable good sectors (such as property) into the tradeable good sectors (such as agriculture). But in the short-run, inter-sectoral resource shifts are constrained by structural factors, such as banking sector distress and inter-regional barriers to labor mobility. Furthermore, with capacity constraints (such as small, fragmented land holdings) it may be difficult for the tradeable goods sectors to quickly absorb large labor inflows. Macroeconomic distress also causes the economy’s overall technical production capacity to erode (PPF1 in figure 4 above becomes PPF2). Institutions function less efficiently, the technology stock becomes “globally” stale and education quality declines. In effect, the nation’s production potential gradually declines. F ig u re 4 : M a c ro - C ris is , F o o d O u tp u t a n d D e m a n d Q nt ER1 Y = Q nt + Q T A Q1 Q 1* non T ra d a b le s O u tp u t E R 2 ( v o la tile ) B Q2 Q 2* PPF2 PPF1 QT Q 2* Q 1* Q2 Q1 F o o d ( + o th e r tra d a b le s ) o u tp u t Q 1 * = p re - s h o c k m a c ro -e q u ilib riu m w ith o u t c a p its l in f lo w s Q 2 * = p o s t- s h o c k m a c ro - e q u ilib riu m w ith u n re s tric te d c a p ita l o u tflo w s Q1 = p re -s h o c k m a c ro - e q u ilib riu m Q 2 * = p o s t- s h o c k m a c ro - e q u ilib riu m , w it h c re d it -c o n st ra in e d g o v e rn m e n t in te rv e n tio n in The food supply situation: availability, imports and public stocks Food production and availability The available evidence suggests that aggregate national food availability did not play a significant role in Indonesia’s food insecurity in1997 and 19981. Although food production did register a sharp fall, this was off-set by rising imports and government grain stock releases. Pierre van der Eng (1997) has compared food availability during the 1890 to 1990 period with a number of indicators of social welfare, such as infant mortality rates and human nutrition. His research shows that mass hunger problems (of the sort that result in significant upsurges in infant mortality) have occurred in Indonesia during periods when average food staple availability fell below 1500 kilocalories per capita per day for several years in a row. This was the case in the 1890s, the 1920s, the 1940s and in the early 1960s. In 1997 and 1998, by contrast, there is no evidence whatsoever that staple food availability was ever less than 2500 kilocalories per capita per day---well above the levels historically associated with widespread hunger in Indonesia. Rice output and secondary food crop production estimates are presented below in tables 2 and 3. The Ministry of Agriculture reports that 1997 rice production fell by 3.7 percent, due mainly to a 4.3 percent fall in area harvested. Corn production fell by 5.9 percent due primarily to a 10.5 percent fall in area harvested. Soybean production declined by 10.5 percent and cassava production fell by 8.6 percent. Sugar production was little changed from previous years, but was some 30 percent below levels prevailing in the early 1990s. In 1998, rice production is estimated to have fallen by 8.8 per cent, the biggest single-year decline in the past two decades. Rice yields are estimated to have fallen by 5.2 per cent and area harvested by 5.9 per cent. Milling yield is also estimated to have declined by 3 per cent due to poor grain quality. For 1998, domestic rice production is estimated at 29.2 MMTs of milled rice, some 4 MMT’s less than what was produced in 1996, and a level comparable to domestic supply a decade earlier. With the exception of corn, production of the other secondary food crops continued to decline in 1998. Corn production rose by 11 per cent in 1998 while cassava, soybeans and sugar production fell by 1.1, 3.7 and 15.5 per cent respectively. The growth in corn production is explained primarily by a shift in nearly 400,000 hectares of land from rice production to corn, largely in response to drought conditions. 1 Garcia-Garcia (1998) was one of the first to point out that rising food insecurity was not a problem of aggregate food availability. In 1997 and the first half of 1998, the El-Nino induced drought was the major cause of the food production decline. This was aggravated by the effects of Eastern Indonesia forest-fires, particularly in the latter half of 1997 (Fox, 1998, Department Perhubungan 1998). In mid-1998, pest, disease and rodent outbreaks contributed to the decline in domestic production. In late 1998, some areas experienced flooding, delaying domestic production credit in 1997 and early 1998 contributed to a fall in agro-input applications. While farm credit conditions eased in the second half of 1998, shortages of key fertilisers, followed by a surge in domestic fertiliser prices in November after subsidies were removed, reduced agro-input applications (FAO-WFP, 1998, Ministry of Agriculture 1998). planting and reducing expected output. A sharp decline The decline in domestic food production was partly offset by an increase in food imports and a diversion of secondary food crop use from livestock feed to human consumption. Table 4 below presents an estimate of changes in food crop trade for the main staples during the 1990 to 1998 period. In both 1997 and 1998, imports of rice, wheat, soybeans and sugar were significantly increased to offset the low levels of domestic production. From 1996 to 1998, there was a 4.1 MMT decline in rice availability, a 2.1 MMT decline in cassava availability, and a decrease of 200,000 tons and 250,000 tons of soybeans and sugar respectively. To compensate for this, rice imports were increased by 3.1 MMT’s (over 1996 levels), wheat imports by .4 MMT’s and sugar imports by 700,000 tons. As a result of higher rice, sugar and wheat imports, total “starchy staple” availability declined by only about 1.2 million metric tons over the two year period. Table 5 below estimates the effect of a 1.2 million metric ton grain decline on per capita calorie availability. Given that the population has increased by approximately 6 million persons between 1996 and 1998, a reduction of 1.2 million metric tons in grain availability (compared to 1995/96 conditions) would imply a decline in per capita grain availability of 9 percent. A 9 percent decline in per capita grain availability would reduce aggregate caloric availability by approximately 200 Kcal per day. This would imply that staple food availability has been reduced to just over 2500 Kcal per day, a level prevailing in the early 1990s. Table 2: Rice - area harvested, production and yield 1982 - 1998 Year Area harveste d (‘000) 8509 8495 8368 8360 8929 8850 9005 9382 8988 9162 9764 9902 9988 9923 10138 10531 10502 10282 11103 11013 10734 11439 11569 11141 11055 Average yield (tons/ha) Paddy output (‘000 tons) 22464 22331 23301 23347 25772 26283 29652 32774 33584 35302 38134 39033 39726 40078 41676 44726 45179 44689 48240 48181 46641 49744 51101 49377 46443 Rice output (‘000 tons) 15276 15185 15845 15876 17525 17872 20163 22286 22837 24006 25933 26542 27014 27253 29340 29072 29366 29048 31356 31318 30317 32334 33215 32095 29167 Growth (%) 1974 2.64 1975 2.63 -0.6 1976 2.78 4.3 1977 2.79 0.2 1978 2.89 10.4 1979 2.97 2.0 1980 3.29 12.8 1981 3.49 10.5 1982 3.74 2.5 1983 3.85 5.1 1984 3.91 8.0 1985 3.97 2.3 1986 4.00 1.8 1987 4.04 0.9 1988 4.11 4.0 1989 4.25 2.6 1990 4.30 1.0 1991 4.35 -1.1 1992 4.34 7.9 1993 4.38 -0.1 1994 4.35 -3.2 1995 4.35 6.7 1996 4.41 2.7 1997 4.43 -3.7 1998 4.20 -8.8 RII a/ Estimated on the basis of a conversion factor of 0.68 from paddy into rice for the years prior to 1989, and a factor of 0.65 for the years 1989 and following. 1998 refers to the third forecast. For 1998, the milling yield was reduced to 0.63. Source: Ministry of Agriculture, Bulletin Informasi Agribisnis, Oct-Dec 1998, 1998 and Department of Statistics, Third Production Forecast, 1998. Food stocks Food stocks provide a line of defence against sudden food availability shocks, at both the national and household levels. Because of a high degree of seasonality in supply, the Indonesian rice market needs to keep about 6 million metric tons of rice in storage from the peak season to the deficit season, for the market to stay in balance. Table 3: Production, area and yield of the other staple food crops 1993-1997, and 3rd forecast for 1998) 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 R3 Corn Area (mill ha) 2.94 3.11 3.65 3.74 3.35 3.75 Yield (kw/ha) 21.9 22.1 22.6 24.9 26.2 26.1 Output (mmt) 6.5 6.9 8.2 9.3 8.76 9.79 Cassava Area (mill ha) 1.40 1.36 1.32 1.42 1.24 1.21 Yield (kw/ha) 123 116 117 120 122 123 Output (mmt) 17.3 15.7 15.4 17.0 15.07 14.9 Soybeans Area (mill ha) 1.47 1.41 1.48 1.28 1.12 1.10 Yield (kw/ha) 11.6 11.1 11.4 11.9 12.1 11.9 Output (mmt) 1.71 1.56 1.68 1.52 1.36 1.31 Sugar (mmt) 2.46 2.44 2.08 2.09 2.19 1.85 Source: Ministry of Agriculture, Bulletin Informasi Agribisnis, Jan-Mar 1998, 1998 and Department of Statistics, Second Production Forecast, 1998. Table 4: Food imports, 1990 - 1998 (‘000 mt) Year Rice Corn Soybeans Wheat Sugar 1990 29 -127 475 1,680 278 1991 178 292 526 2,071 306 1992 634 -81 558 2,270 316 1993 0 442 752 2,459 260 1994 876 1084 697 3,188 128 1995 3.014 894 473 3,614 687 1996 1.090 595 593 3,820 975 1997 3,582(*) 619 779 3,958 1,336 1998 4,200(*) 500 700 4,250 1,716 forecast Note: 1997 and 1998 rice import values refer to the fiscal year estimates provided by BULOG.1998 values are BULOG forecasts for the fiscal year. Source: Bulog. Table 5: Staple food availability in Indonesia, 1970-1998 Year/Ind icator 1970 1995 Cereals produced (000 mt) 15,719 41,425 Cereals imported (000 mt) 1,527 8,598 Per capita kilograms of cereals (per annum) 123 189 1998 39,770 9,350 175 Source: FAO Agrostat for 1970 and 1995. Author’s calculations for 1998. Total staple calories (per day) 1824 2732 +-2500 Ellis et. al. (1991) surveyed the Indonesian rice market during three relatively favourable years. They found that farmers and traders typically hold the largest rice stocks. In the early 1990s, farmers carried over rice stocks equivalent to 1.3 MMTs from the first to the second season and normally increased these to 2.0 MMTs in the third season. Private traders carried over rice stocks of 3.3 MMTs from the first to the second season and reduced these to 2.7 MMTs in the third season. By comparison, Bulog typically carries over stocks equivalent of 1.2 to 1.5 MMTs throughout the year to meet sudden shortfalls in domestic demand and to provide food rations for budget groups. The same survey finds that farmer and trader stockpiling has little to do with the profitability of storage. Farmers primarily store rice to meet household consumption requirements while traders store rice to maintain supply continuity and meet milling requirements. In both cases, private rice storage activity is sensitive to supply availability. Farmers will store more in poor production years to meet home consumption requirements while traders will store less if milling requirements fall and if they can speed-up transactions. In good years, the marketed surplus of rice is approximately 70 percent of what is produced, and of this, just over half reaches the urban areas. In poor production years, we can expect that the rice producers (some 12 million out of Indonesia’s 32 million households) will increase their own stocks to protect home consumption. A 10 percent increase in the level of private, on-farm stocks (meaning that only 60 percent of what is produced is sold) would mean a 17 percent reduction in availability for non-rice producers in both urban and rural areas. If private food stocks did increase in 1997 and 1998, then Government would have to raise its stock levels to maintain adequate inter-seasonal supplies. The results presented in Table 6 below suggest that Government did, in fact, increase its public food stocks in response to the various shocks of 1997 and 1998. Food stock levels rose in 1997 and declined modestly in 1998. The fall in public stocks in May of 1998 can be explained by the fact that Government planned to rely far more on official imports of rice for market operations, and hence, was relying on the “international market” to hold a larger portion of Indonesia’s public rice stocks. At all times, Bulog maintained public stock levels above its target one million metric ton, “iron reserve stock” level. Bulog’s market operations---or injections of rice into the market to maintain stable prices---increased substantially in 1997 and 1998. During the years 1994 to 1996, Bulog injected an average of 700,000 mts of rice into the domestic market to stabilise rice prices. In 1997, Bulog’s market operations increased to 1.3 MMT’s and in the first 10 months of 1998 to 2.6 MMTs. During the May to September 1998 period, BULOG market operations increased substantially, rising to more than 300,000 tons in August of 1998----straining the limits, in fact, of the amount of rice that Government could inject into the market at that time. Table 6a: Bulog food stocks (‘000 metric ton) May 1996 May 1997 May 1998 Rice 2.866 3.108 2.371 Sugar 432 480 425 Wheat 490 (*) 470 463 Soybean 102 (*) 124 120 * refers to end-April values; Source: Bulog, Monthly Report to Ekuin, June 1998 and June 1997. Table 6b: Bulog's rice market operations in the 1990s (tons) Month Avg. 1990-93 Jan 44,435 Feb 35,654 Mar 7,507 Apr 4,294 May 3,204 Jun 9,466 Jul 2,696 Aug 2,737 Sept 6,010 Oct 10,062 Nov 33,341 Dec 54,471 Total 213,877 Source: Bulog Avg. 1994-96 165,311 82,037 39,021 22,769 30,227 29,576 34,668 27,017 35,678 48,196 91,634 115,115 721,248 1997 50,533 18,770 26,362 59,612 40,744 12,364 21,904 15,266 34,951 269,276 341,901 445,734 1,337,417 1998 413,974 482,793 386,882 120,080 77,632 162,519 216,437 310,306 284,678 145,862 Na Na 2,601,163 Whether or not public stock and market injections were adequate or inadequate hinges very much on the size and utilisation of private stocks. Unfortunately, information on private food stock changes in 1997 and 1998 is unavailable. In past years, farm level stocks increased when food production levels fell or when inflation rose. Field reports suggest that this also occurred in 1997 and 1998. Consumer (or household) food stocks may have also increased, particularly in response to press reports of urban shortages and low public stocks. On the other hand, stocks held by the private grain traders in major urban areas are likely to have declined due a rising risk of confiscation and urban lawlessness. Macroeconomic volatility and food insecurity Macroeconomic distress has had a direct affect on the second and third components of food security---stability and access. Food prices were highly unstable in 1998, due largely to exchange rate instability and shifts in Government food trade and marketing policy. The macroeconomic crisis has also reduced “access” to adequate amounts of food because of the fall in aggregate demand, erosion of real wages and the sharp decline in output and incomes. The wild gyrations of domestic food prices are a sign that the stability of the food supply was compromised in 1998, particularly during the period from April to September. Sharp, sudden changes in food prices threaten the consumption levels of the poor and reduce the purchasing power of the wage-earning population. Poor households spend between 60 and 70 per cent of their earnings on food stuffs. A sudden increase in real food prices of 20 to 30 per cent can price basic foodstuffs beyond the reach of the poor and near-poor households. Since more than half of the food producers are net food consumers, rapid oscillation in food prices threatens both their incomes and consumption levels. All of Indonesia’s main food staples are products that are internationally traded. Changes in the exchange rate will either change the price directly (after a lag for stocks to adjust) or change the level of wedge between domestic and international prices. The principal cause of food price instability was exchange rate volatility and the shift in public policy from an “administratively low” to a “market determined” food price policy stance. Civil disturbances also added to market price volatility, as political uncertainties increased the risks and uncertainty faced by consumers and producers. From November 1997 to January 1998, the Rupiah devalued from 3648 to 10, 375 to the US dollar. This increased the import parity price for imported rice from just under Rp. 1,000 per kilogram to just under Rp. 3,000 per kilogram. Government intervened heavily to maintain low rice prices, but with porous borders, domestic prices began to creep upwards to world market levels. Domestic rice prices rose by 6 per cent in January, 12 per cent in February, 3 per cent in March and 4 per cent in April of 1998. Still, by April, domestic rice prices were still only 60 per cent of equivalent import parity prices2. Between April and June, the Rupiah devalued from 7,970 to 14,900 to the US dollar. Global grain prices also tightened between January and June of 1998, pushing up the equivalent import parity price for rice to the equivalent of Rp. 4,600/kilogram. Despite an increase in market operations, from May to September 1998, domestic food prices lurched sharply higher. Average retail rice prices rose from Rp.1623 per kilogram in May to Rp. 3,000 per 2 Global grain prices for Thai 25% rice were $232 per metric ton in December 1997, $260 in June 1997 and $220 in December 1998. An additional $25 per ton and 8 per cent for handling charges is added to compute an equivalent import parity price. The world market price for sugar (CIF London) rose from US$272 per ton between December 1997 to $302 in June 1998. During that same period, wheat (Australia White FOB) prices eased from $171 per ton to $145 per ton, corn (No. 2 Yellow Bangkok) prices fell from $133 per ton to $89 per ton and palm oil prices (5% bulk Malaysian) fell from $566 per ton to $533 per ton. kilogram in September, rising by 22 per cent in June, 11 per cent in July, 15 per cent in August and 19 per cent in September. Rapid increases in food prices contributed to high rates of inflation and by July and August of 1998, had priced basic foods beyond the reach of many low-income households. From September to December of 1998, the exchange rate strengthened. The average bilateral rate of exchange to the US dollar increased from 14,900 to 8,025 to the US dollar. On global markets, grain prices also eased, bring the import parity price for rice down to approximately Rp. 2200 per kilogram. Domestic rice prices gradually adjusted downwards, but were still some 25 per cent higher than import parity levels at the end of the year. Throughout 1998, food producers and consumers were exposed to tremendous food price volatility. In some months, basic staple prices changed by 10 to 20 per cent. The volatility in food prices can be traced, initially, to volatility in the exchange rate, and secondly, to a switch in Government’s food price policy stance. Extreme volatility in food prices threatens food security for the poor, for food accounts for a large share of their total consumer expenditures and their ability to use savings to stabilise consumption is limited. The failure to stabilise food prices is not a failure of food policy per se. Macro economic instability, in the form of tremendous exchange rate volatility, created “wedges” between global and domestic prices that, by mid-1998, Government could simply no longer maintain. In 1998, the main cause of food price volatility was volatility in the exchange rate, and in this sense, the “culprit” for threatening food price stability was clearly the macro economic crisis, and in particular, its effects on the exchange rate. Indonesia’s macro-economic crisis also had a direct effect on access to food, by increasing the numbers of the absolute poor and by reducing the purchasing power of low income households. The Central Statistics Bureau reports that real GDP declined by 13.7 per cent in 1998. Per capita incomes, in constant 1993 terms, are reported to have fallen from Rp.2.2 million in 1997 to Rp.1.8 million in 1998. The IMF (Long et. al. 1999) estimates that domestic demand will have fallen by close to 20 per cent in 1998. According to reports from the Statistic’s Department, on an annually adjusted basis, real private consumption expenditures fell by 3.4 per cent in the second quarter and 5.1 per cent in the third quarter of 1998 alone. Table 7: Consumer price, food price, exchange rate and rice price instability in 1998 Month Food Price Index 1996=100 Consumer Price Index 1996=100 Rupiah to US$ exchange rate % change in the Rp/US$ exchange rate June-97 104 105 2450 0.4% Nov-97 117 110 3648 -0.1% Dec-97 121 112 4650 27.47% Jan-98 133 120 10375 123.12% Feb-98 158 135 8750 -15.66% Mar-98 167 142 8325 -4.86% Apr-98 177 149 7970 -4.26% May-98 183 157 10525 32.06% Jun-98 196 164 14,900 41.6% Jul-98 220 178 13,000 -12.75% Aug-98 240 189 11,075 -14.8% Sept-98 261 196 10,700 -12.42% Oct-98 256 196 7,550 -29.4% Nov-98 256 196 7,300 -3.3% Dec-98 263 198 8,025 9.93% note: rice prices refer to medium-quality rice in major urban areas (Bulog) Source: Bank Indonesia and Bulog. Average Rice Price in Major Cities (Rp/kg) 1033 1207 1215 1290 1439 1475 1532 1623 1988 2202 2529 3009 2828 2830 2758 % change in medium rice prices The effect of the “demand collapse” on access to food depends on how the fall in incomes was distributed across different classes of households. A national household income and expenditure survey, and preferably one conducted post September1998, will be needed to accurately assess the distribution of the income collapse. Unfortunately, the economic crisis also disrupted Indonesia’s regular socio-economic reporting and poverty assessment system. Firm comparisons between the numbers of those classified as poor prior to the macro economic crisis and those reported as “absolutely poor” in 1997 and 1998 will have to await the processing of the 1999 SUSENAS survey. In the absence of a national household income and expenditure survey, indirect indicators and small-sample surveys have to be relied on to assess the probable impacts of the macro-economic shocks on absolute poverty and food access. What is known, however, is that prior to the macro-economic shocks, a large segment of the population was classified as “nearly absolutely poor” and that those who were “absolutely poor” had a high risk of food insecurity. Furthermore, a large share of the “nearly absolutely poor” households had malnourished children. In 1996, 23 million persons were classified as absolutely poor, while another 37 million persons reported monthly expenditures that were within Rp. 10,000 per month of the absolute poverty line (see table 8). The absolute poverty incidence was higher in rural areas (12.3 per cent) than in urban (9.7 per cent). By the yardstick used prior to the 1.2% 7.48% 0.66% 6.17% 11.55% 2.50% 3.86% 5.94% 22.5% 10.8% 14.8% 18.9% -6.0% 0.0% -2.5% 1997 and 1998 shocks, some 23 million Indonesians would have been classified as “poor”. Table 8: Absolute poverty incidence, 1976-1996 Year Urba n (%) Rural (%) Total (%) Urban (millio ns) 10 9.5 9.4 7.2 Rural (milli ons) 44.2 32.8 17.2 15.3 Total (mill ions) 54.2 42.3 25.9 22.5 1976 38.8 40.4 40.1 1980 29.0 28.4 28.6 1990 16.8 14.3 15.1 1996 9.7 12.3 11.3 38,42 27,413 Poverty 6 Line (1996 Rp) 1998 20 30 26 15 38 53 est. note: 1998 values are author’s estimates based on 1996 income distribution, and applying an estimate of a 10 percent real income decline and a 12 percent in real prices facing the near-poor in 1996. Source: BPS (1998) and author’s calculations for 1998 values. Prior to the macro-economic crisis, the share of households with malnourished children was approximately three times higher than the share of households classified as absolutely poor. In the early 1990s, progress was made in reducing child malnutrition rates. The percentage of children under 5 years of age who were malnourished declined from 35 per cent in 1992 to 30 per cent at the start of 1998-. Malnutrition rates in early 1998 were 32 per cent in rural areas and 27 per cent in urban areas (Saadah 1999). Absolute poverty is closely correlated to food insecurity and under-nutrition in Indonesia. According to nutrition surveys, those earning less than Rp.40,000 per month in 1996 report average energy consumption levels below minimum-norms set for Indonesia (Jalal and Atmojo 1997). A special food security concern is the plight of the most nutritionally vulnerable groups. UNICEF (1997) reports that, of the under-five year old children, 36 percent suffer from energy/protein deficiency, 35 percent from anaemia and 30 percent from an iodine deficiency. Of the pregnant women, 41 percent suffer from energy deficiency. Of all women, 24 percent suffer from chronic food energy deficiency. Mild and moderate forms of malnutrition are reported to be the main cause of almost half of all child deaths in Indonesia. How did the macro economic collapse affect the numbers of the poor? In early 1998, the Department of Statistics issued estimates of a rise in the number of absolutely poor to nearly 80 million persons. This appears to be an over-estimate, and is based largely on assuming unchanged nominal incomes and triple-digit price inflation. Table 9: Monthly expenditures, calorie and protein consumption in 1996 Daily protein Population share Daily energy Expenditure consumption (percentage) consumption group (grams) (Kcal) (Rp/month) under 15,000 .1 1240 28 15,0001.3 1404 33 19,999 20,00010.7 1604 40 29,999 30,00018.0 1786 46 39,000 40,00029.5 1985 52 59,999 Source: Central Bureau of Statistics as reported in Jalal and Atmojo (1997). The IMF (IMF, October 1998) estimates that the numbers of absolute poor increased by between 4.8 and 11.2 per cent of the total population (or to some 32 to 45 million persons) in 1998. The IMF estimates are based on estimating the elasticity of the number of poor to average consumption expenditures and adding an additional amount for higher unemployment. A national Ministry of Family Planning (BKKBN 1998) survey of living standards conducted in September 1998 reports that 18 per cent of the population are impoverished and that another 21 per cent of the population are nearly-impoverished. In September 1998, the BKKBN reported that 8.1 million households in Indonesia (or some 36 million persons) could be classified as badly impoverished (“pra-sejahtera”). Another 9.4 million households (42 million persons) were classified as KS-1 households, or those “having less than adequate means”. The poorest BKKBN group (the KPS) are those households that are unable to satisfy their basic needs, including food. BKKBN reports that the highest incidence of badly impoverished households was in East Timor (56%), Nusa Tenggara Timor (52%), Irian Jaya (46%), Central Java (33%), and Lampung (28%). Out of 140 districts surveyed nation-wide in May of 1998, the Ministry of Food and Horticulture reports that 40 percent could be classified as food insecure. More than 50 million rural residents live in districts that were classified as food insecure. This includes 9 out of 25 districts in West Java, 12 out of 33 districts in Central Java, 3 out of 5 districts in Yogyakarta and 16 out of 37 districts in East Java. The highest absolute number of food insecure rural households are in Java. But the highest regional incidence of rural food insecurity was reported in West Kalimantan, Central Kalimantan, Maluku, Irian Jaya, NTB, NTT and East Timor. The results of a number of small sample surveys suggest that the largest declines in income in 1997 and 1998 have been registered by the middle and upper income groups, that urban areas have been hit harder than rural areas and that the greatest increase in poverty levels has been registered in the urban areas and in Java (SMERU 1998 and Poppele et. al. 1999). The pronounced fall-off in construction, industrial and services sector activity has disproportionately reduced urban labor demand and urban incomes. Rising export prices (post-devaluation) appears to have increased tree crop producer incomes, an important source of earnings for the residents of Sumatra, Kalimantan and Sulawesi. Parts of eastern Indonesia that were hard hit by the drought appear to have recovered, and some are enjoying record earnings from tree crop exports. The data also show that there has been little change in open unemployment, a modest decline in urban secondary school enrolment and insignificant change in household nutrition status. The small-scale survey results indicate that the effects of the macroeconomic crisis on living standards bear little relationship to the numbers and distribution of the poor prior to the macro-shock (Filmer et. al. 1999, Poppele et. al. 1998). Field surveys report that households are adopting a number of coping strategies to offset the adverse income shocks. In some areas, poor urban residents are returning to villages, local communities are pooling resources to cushion consumption from the income loss, and falling incomes and rising import costs are leading to a substitution of domestically produced (and labor intensive) goods and services (such as food consumption at open-air markets instead of restaurants) for imports (Irwanto 1998, World Bank 1998b). Real wages, for unskilled labor, are often used as an indirect indicator of poverty levels. Many poor households depend primarily on wage labor for their income. With falling aggregate demand, the scope for higher employment will be limited. Accordingly, a decline in real wages would be consistent with an increase in the numbers of absolute poor. Although real wage data is subject to considerable error, the evidence suggests that growth in nominal wages has lagged significantly behind inflation and behind the rise in food prices. According to the BPS data, between 1997 and 1998, agricultural wages for unskilled rural Javanese labourers working in land preparation and planting increased in nominal terms by an average of 21 to 43 per cent. By comparison, on a year-to-year basis, inflation was 77 per cent and food prices rose by 117 per cent. Between December and March of 1998, average wages in industry, hotel and mining rose by 1, 21 and 22 per cent respectively. Average food prices increased by 34 per cent during this period while average retail rice prices rose 21 per cent (see Table 10b). The CASER’s PATANAS survey on socio-economic conditions in rural areas is one of the most accurate barometers or rural living conditions. According to PATANAS reports, from the wet season in 1998 to the dry season in 1998, average agricultural day-wages rose from 9 to 14 per cent (see Table 10b). During this same period, food prices and rice prices increased by more than 70 per cent. In January 1997, the minimum daily wage was equivalent to 6.3 kilograms of rice. In December 1997, the minimum wage was equivalent to. Table 10a: Rural wage growth in 1997 and 1998 Land preparation Province Planting Year 1995 1996 1997 1998* % change 98/97 Year 1997 1998* % change 98/97 Daerah Istimewah Aceh Sumatera Utara Sumatera Barat Sumatera Selatan Lampung 2,706 3,077 3,329 4,848 46 2,704 3,914 45 2,675 3,019 3,315 4,382 32 2,948 3,935 33 2,419 2,627 2,910 3,741 29 2,905 3,725 28 2,329 2,463 2,555 3,258 28 2,161 2,699 25 2,162 2,527 2,590 3,011 16 2,101 2,527 20 Jawa Barat 3,593 3,914 4,320 5,353 24 2,690 3,371 25 Jawa Tengah 2,023 2,438 2,701 3,441 27 2,101 2,588 23 D.I. Yogyakarta Jawa Timur 1,089 1,176 1,258 1,801 43 927 1,182 28 3,103 3,555 4,025 5,411 34 2,640 3,198 21 Bali 3,760 4,165 4,507 5,915 31 2,853 3,527 24 30 2,494 3,237 30 22 3,549 4,564 29 39 5,091 7,489 47 25 2,391 2,856 19 Nusa 2,485 2,800 3,073 3,999 Tenggara Barat Kalimantan 3,624 4,138 4,344 5,318 Selatan Sulawesi 3,025 3,476 4,141 5,747 Utara Sulawesi 2,185 2,492 2,688 3,358 Selatan \Source: BPS, Statistik Upah Buruh Tani di Pedesaan, Jakarta. Table 10 b: Average weekly wages for selected sectors and daily agriculture wages Sector Industry Hotel Mining December 1997 (Rp 000) 52,8 54,8 111,2 West Season 1998 (Rp) March 1998 (Rp 000) 53,4 66,2 135,9 Dry Season 1998 (Rp) Agriculture1) Jawa Tengah 5.800 6.800 Jawa Timur 4.500 4.900 Lampung 3.700 4.200 Notes: (1) Average wage rates for a half days work from the CASER’s PATANAS survey. (2) Preliminary data. Source: BPS (Statistik Upah Triwulanan I tahun 1998) and CASER Bogor (PATANAS data) 4.8 kgs of rice. By June 1998, the “rice purchasing power” of the minimum wage had fallen to 2.6 kgs. of rice. Falling real wages are a sign that the purchasing power of the poor has declined. Since many of the households classified as “nearpoor” in 1996 would rely primarily on unskilled wage labor for their income, even a modest decline in real wages would be enough to expose a large segment of this group to absolute poverty Both survey and real wage data are consistent with a rise in the number of poor households, particularly in urban areas and in Java. While estimates of the number of households that could be classified as absolutely poor (and hence at high risk of being food insecure) due to the macro-economic crisis are not known with any certainty, there is agreement that the main causes of deepening absolute poverty include the fall in real incomes, an increase in food prices faster than the rate of inflation and a decline in real wages. One way to make an approximate estimate of the number of poor households is to use the income distribution and poverty line measures prevailing in 1996 and to convert 1998 income to 1996 levels using estimates of the real income fall and the change in the GDP deflator facing the poor and near-poor. Even if one were to assume that most of the income shock was registered by upper-income groups, a fall in real income of 5 to 10 per cent for the middle and lower-middle income households in 1998 could be expected. Furthermore, with food prices rising in excess of the CPI (and the GDP-deflator) we would expect that the poor and near-poor faced a larger increase in the cost-of-living than for the average income earner. If we combine a conservative estimate of the income-shock (5-10 per cent) and higher cost-of-living (10-15 per cent) for households that were classified as lower-middle income (or “near-poor”) in 1996, this would imply an increase of 8 million urban poor and 23 million rural poor residents in 1998. In total, this would increase the number of absolute poor (or those vulnerable to food insecurity) to approximately 53 million persons in 1998. Not all of those who would become absolutely poor will be immediately food insecure. Private savings will be drawn down to protect consumption levels. Assistance will be provided by family members and the local communities. Efforts to combine resources, particularly in rural areas, will also help to buffer the poor from food insecurity. The Government has also attempted to cushion the fall in incomes for the low income groups. In 1996, nearly 6 per cent of GDP was expended on what the Government classifies as social safety net activity (Lane 1999). Of this, close to a quarter was provided in the form of food subsidies. Subsidies have also been provided for fuel, electricity and basic medicines. Other social safety net outlays have been provided for community-based, public employment activity, the abolition of school fees, an expansion of school lunch programs, and an increase in farm working capital credit (KUT) and special credit schemes for small enterprises (Gupta 1998). Food Policy and Food Insecurity From mid-1997 to mid-1998, the government used trade restrictions and BULOG subsidies to hold food prices below prevailing import-parity levels. Subsidies were provided for the import and sale of rice, sugar, soybeans, wheat, corn, soy meal and fish meal. Export restrictions were used to maintain domestic cooking oil prices below export parity levels. For 1998 alone, the budgetary cost alone of maintaining general food subsidies was estimated to be approximately Rp. 12 trillion3. In addition to large fiscal costs, a policy of low food prices also constituted a large transfer of income from food crop producers to food consumers. Since food crop producers are also the single largest group of low income households in Indonesia, a “low” food price policy would be expected to aggravate income distribution and increase the number of rural poor. In the first half of 1998, the domestic price of rice was held at approximately 60 percent of the equivalent import parity price of $295 per metric ton. On average, consumers were paying Rp.2200 per kilogram for their rice instead of an import parity price equivalent of Rp. 3,500 per kilogram. Farmers were receiving (approximately) Rp. 1600 per kilogram (for milled rice equivalent at the farm gate) instead of Rp. 2200 (milled equivalent import parity price). 3 Until September 1998, Bulog was provided monopoly import authority, budgetary subsidies and access to foreign exchange and credit on preferential rates to maintain food prices below import parity levels. Consumers gain and producers lose income from a low food price policy. If we assume that the aggregate rice supply elasticity is 0.3 and that the aggregate price elasticity is 0.4 (Suryana et. al. 1997), and if we apply the 1997 rice production and consumption estimates as basevalues, than the total consumer surplus from a “cheap” rice policy in 1998 was equivalent to 42 trillion rupiah. The producer surplus was equivalent to -21 trillion rupiah. In other words, small farmers assumed a large share of the economic costs for providing general price subsidies to the rest of the economy. Although food producers bore a large share of the cost of general food subsidies, this might have a positive welfare effect if, in fact, the poor consumed the bulk of the subsidised food stuffs. The evidence, however, indicates that this was not the case. Using the 1996 SUSENAS data, we can examine the distribution of food consumption by the very poor (the bottom 10 percent of the households), the poor and near-poor (the bottom 30 percent of the households) and the middle and upper income groups. For the lower income groups, rice is a major part of the diet and accounts for a significant share of their total expenditures. But only about 28 percent of all of the rice is consumed by the lowest 30 percent of the 1996 income earners. The upper 70 percent consume 72 percent of all of the rice. For the other food commodities, the distribution is even more skewed to the middle and upper income groups. In the case of wheat and sugar products, the poorest thirty percent consumes only about onefifth of the total consumption; eighty percent is consumed by the upper 70 percent of the income spectrum. Table 11: Share of basic staple food consumption by income group, 1996 Commodity Rice Wheat Corn a/ Soybeans Palm Oil Poultry Sugar Lowest Decile * 9.6 4.5 13.6 5.5 6.9 0.8 5.5 Lowest 3 Deciles ** 27.5 18.3 22.7 23.5 21.5 3 21.3 Upper 70 percent 72.5 81.7 77.3 76.5 78.5 97 78.7 * refers to the bottom 12 percent of the households, as classified by total expenditures in 1996. ** refers to the bottom 30.1 percent of the households, as classified by total expenditures in 1996. a/ adjusted to reflect the allocation of two-thirds of total corn availability to the feed industry in 1996. Source: CBS, Susenas 1996. In fact, wheat products are primarily consumed by the upper third of the income spectrum. About two-thirds of the imported sugar is used in the confectionery and processed food industry, whose products are sold mainly to middle and upper income consumers. Soy meal and fishmeal are high value inputs for feed manufacture. Feed is primarily used in the poultry and beef industry, products which are consumed predominantly by the upper income groups. In August 1998, the Government changed its food price policy to allow food products to trade at international market prices. Food imports were opened to private traders holding general import licenses. BULOG’s monopolies on imports and domestic marketing of food staples were eliminated. Budget subsidies and preferential exchange rate arrangements for BULOG were halted. In place of general food subsidies, the Government introduced a special market operations program (the OPK program) in which households classified as impoverished by BKKBP family planning surveys were allowed to purchase 10 kilograms of rice per month at a concessionary price of Rp.1,000 per kilogram. Implementation of the program proceeded rapidly, and by October of 1998, the program was providing low-cost rice to nearly 7 million households. OPK program monitoring reports indicate that the program was generally implemented effectively and that the recipients are, by and large, drawn from low income households. However, the program fails to reach many peri-urban poor households who lack proper urban residency permits. In some regions, the ration rice is shared amongst a larger group within the village, reducing the income-transfer benefit to the very poor. Public awareness of OPK program goals, eligibility criteria and implementation responsibilities is also reported to be limited (SMERU 1998). In October, the Government announced that the OPK program would be extended to 17 million households, involving nearly one out of every two households. In addition, the monthly ration amount would be increased to 20 kilograms per beneficiary. In practice, the scaling-up the ration amount and beneficiary coverage has been limited by Government budget constraints. In November 1998, the Government also abolished subsidies on fertilisers. To compensate for this, the amount of working capital production credit was sharply increased, outstanding farm working capital loan arrears were forgiven and fertiliser marketing restrictions were eased. Fertiliser price liberalization was undertaken in response to reports of widespread shortages of fertiliser in late 1998. Higher domestic prices were viewed as a way of discourage stockpiling and smuggling and to improve incentives for retailers to sell fertiliser to small farmers. After subsidies were removed, the price of urea rose from Rp. 450 per kilo to Rp.1,115 per kilo. On a per hectare basis, the Ministry of Agriculture estimates that total fertiliser costs would rise by approximately Rp. 350,000, or approximately Rp.83 per kilogram of expected paddy output (Department of Agriculture, 1998). While higher fertiliser prices will reduce the benefit-cost ratio from producing rice, it is expected that improved availability will largely off-set these losses (Department Pertanian 1998). From September to December 1998, the exchange rate strengthened and global rice prices fell. By the end of the year, Indonesia’s domestic rice prices were 20 to 30 per cent high than equivalent global rice prices. Private international rice trade has started, narrowing the margin between global and domestic prices. With the start of the 1999 wet-season rice harvest, domestic farm gate prices have been falling. In some areas, there are reports that farm gate prices have fallen from Rp.1800 per kilogram for rough rice in mid-1998 to less than Rp. 1000 per kg in early 1999. In the first five months of 1998, Bulog’s procurement and market operations prices were changed three times. Procurement prices were increased from Rp. 600 to Rp. 700 and then to Rp. 1000 per kilogram. As a result of inflation and devaluation, Bulog had little choice but to raise procurement prices to keep pace with prevailing market conditions. Furthermore, since almost all Bulog stocks in 1997 and 1998 were from imports, the actual floor price had relatively little effect on the agency’s operations. In early 1999, there are reports that farm prices are falling below the Bulog floor price level, and that neither the cooperatives or private traders are able to procure adequate supplies of rice on Government’s behalf. In response to falling farm gate prices and BULOG’s apparent inability to defend the floor price, in early 1999, the Minister of Food declared that the Government should impose an import tariff of 30 to 40 per cent to support rice producer incomes. But would higher farm prices necessarily increase rural welfare? The answer to this depends very much on the degree to which farm producers are net sellers or net purchasers of rice, and the relevant demand and supply elasticities prevailing in the market. Since some 11 million rice producers cultivate plots that are less than 0.35 hectares, and since an estimated 7 million rural households are landless or nearlandless labourers, this would imply that a large segment of the rural work force are net rice consumers. Myer’s et. al. (1986) have derived a reduced form model that can be used to estimate the effect of varying rice procurement prices on different categories of producers. The model is as follows: %Yg = ((MS/QC + e(s) (1 + MS/QC) - e(d) )/ (Y/(P*QC) + n )* dPR/PR where: % Yg = MS = QC = e(s) = e(d) = PR = n = percent change in income; marketed surplus (positive, if net seller) household consumption supply elasticity (w.r.t.. price) demand elasticity (w.r.t. price) price income elasticity The computations presented in table 12 below employ this model to estimate the effect of a 40 percent price rise (ie. the difference between domestic prices and prices with a 40 per cent import tariff) on income for agricultural producers who would buy all of their rice, buy half of their rice, buy none of their rice and sell half of their rice. If real farm-gate prices were increased by 40 percent (to 40 per cent above world market import parity levels), those farmers who buy all of their rice would suffer a fall in incomes equivalent to 24 per cent of their total income. Those who are self-sufficient would suffer a modest income increase (6 per cent) while those with a positive marketed surplus would witness about a 26-34 percent rise in household income. Ultimately income distribution would widen between those farm families with a large marketed surplus and those who are net rice consumers. Landless labourers and the near-landless farmers, who are already amongst the poorest rural residents, would suffer a pronounced fall in their real income. Should this happen, this could lead to further rural asset concentration and deeper rural poverty. This does not necessarily imply that farm gate floor prices should not be held above border prices to enhance agricultural incentives. As the above example demonstrates, the effect of boosting farm prices would be to significantly raise the incomes of those producers with a positive marketed surplus of rice. It does imply, however, that such policies could have long-lasting social dislocation effects if real farm gate procurement prices are adjusted rapidly at a time when the “net consuming” producers have little ability to offset the adverse household income effects resulting from much higher rice prices. Table 12: Simulation of the impact of a 40 percent real price rise in paddy prices on different classes of rice producer households Impact of the price rise on farm households who Buys all Buys Buys None Sells Half Half Assumptions MS/Q C QP/Q C -1 -0.5 0 0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 -0.5 -0.5 -0.45 -0.45 Rice expenditure share 43 35 28 19 Income elasticity 0.6 0.6 0.5 0.5 Supply elasticity 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 SIMULATION RESULTS % change in household -23.93 6.07 25.79 34.01 income Note: Based on a model developed in Myers et. al. (1986) and using expenditure and supply elasticities reported in Boediono (1978), Tabor (1989), and Suryana (1997). Conclusions: rebuilding food security The 1997 and 1998 shocks adversely affected all three dimensions of food security: food availability, stability and access. Availability was affected by the El-Nino drought, with rice output falling by more than four million metric tons between 1996 and 1998. Availability was also adversely affected by the civil disturbances which targeted the grain trade and hindered the movement of basic foodstuffs from surplus to deficit regions. But aggregate food availability, at a national level, never reached critical levels in 1997 and 1998. Government was able to secure adequate food imports, build public grain stocks and increase injections of rice into the domestic market. Stability of the food supply was, however, a serious problem. This is reflected in the wild gyrations of domestic food prices, particularly during the April to September of 1998 period. Sharp, sudden increases in food prices threatened the consumption levels of the poor and reduced the purchasing power of the wage-earning population. The principal cause of price instability was exchange rate volatility and the shift in public policy from a “low” to a “market determined” food price stance. No doubt, the civil disturbances added to market price volatility, as political uncertainties added to the risks faced by consumers and producers. Access to basic foodstuffs emerged as the most serious food security concern in 1997 and 1998. The macroeconomic crisis resulted in a sharp fall in aggregate demand. Many of the households that were “near-poor” in 1996 would have been classified as absolutely poor in 1998. Those who were absolutely poor would have been at high risk of being food insecure because of inadequate incomes. The economic crisis hit the urban areas particularly hard, and many middle and lowmiddle income urban households found themselves cast into poverty. The Government first tried to combat mounting food insecurity by maintaining market controls and keeping domestic food prices low. This policy conveyed benefits mainly to middle and upper income households, and acted as a heavy tax on low-income domestic food producers. In September 1998, the Government scrapped its general food subsidy effort, liberalised international food trade, and introduced a program to provide subsidised rice to low-income households. By the end of 1998, the combination of a stronger exchange rate and falling global food prices caused Indonesia’s food prices to rise above world market price levels. While a “high” food price policy might be expected to stimulate domestic supply, this would also aggravate rural income distribution and tax domestic food consumers. Looking ahead, the Indonesian Government has a difficult but well-defined political, macroeconomic and microeconomic agenda. On the political front, the challenge is to manage the transition to a pluralistic, representative Government. On the macroeconomic front, the challenge is to restore stability, address the overhang of financial and corporate distress and restart the growth process. On the microeconomic front, the main challenge is to cushion the fall in incomes and rebuild food security. Progress must be forged on all three fronts, for political stability, macroeconomic stability and food security are closely interrelated. But in the short-term, food security must take precedence. Societies that suffer from widespread hunger will be unable to generate the political and social consensus necessary to undertake fundamental, and often painful, macroeconomic reforms4. Furthermore, in an environment in which food security has broken down, macroeconomic reforms will have little effect on investor confidence or investment. The 1997 and 1998 experience demonstrate that improvements in food security should provide no reason for policy complacency. A firm, long-standing commitment to achieving food security is required. But for this to be effective, the Government will need to seek ways of reforming policy and institutions to deliver an acceptable level of food security in a cost-effective manner. One of the first ways of enhancing food security would be to ensure that the private sector continues to be provided the opportunity to use global markets to satisfy domestic food shortfalls. In practice, this 4 To quote Peter Timmer (1988) ... “food shortages in urban areas evokes a universal and visceral reaction. Governments are held accountable for provisioning cities at reasonable costs, and citizens have repeatedly demonstrated their capacity to bring down governments that fail in this obligation (p. 10).” would mean that BULOG’s price stabilisation and floor price protection mandate continue to be limited to rice. During the last quarter of 1998, the private sector demonstrated that it can trade effectively on international markets to satisfy domestic food staple demand and that it can play an important role to augment official rice imports (World Bank 1998a). The Government should continue to aim to buffer the economy from severe rice price instability, but this should be done in a more cost effective fashion. Stabilising rice prices helps to smooth consumer and producer incomes, particularly when supply and price shocks in the thin global rice market are covariant (Timmer 1997a and 1997b). The challenge, however, is to deliver rice stability in the most cost-effective manner possible (Pearson 1997, Sawit 1998, Soetrisno 1998). There are three main strategies that could be pursued to lower the costs of achieving an “affordable level” of rice price stability: • phase out the provision of budgetary rice allocations to civil servants, the military and other special groups. This would reduce the demand for public stocks by approximately one million metric tons; • open up both rice imports and exports to the private sector and use trade-related (eg. tariffs or variable levies) or financial instruments to stabilise import or export parity prices; and • reduce public sector grain holdings to an “iron stock” of rice sufficient to offset sudden, unanticipated disruption in the international rice trade. While there are still large numbers of food insecure households, the Government could continue to use subsidised sales of low-quality rice (the OPK program) to augment incomes of the very poor. The main challenge is to ensure that subsidised rice is, in fact, provided to the food insecure, and not to the large numbers of near-poor and middle-income households (Wiebe 1998 and SMERU 1998). Economic recovery is needed to raise incomes of the poor and the food insecure. An agriculture-led recovery provides the best chance to stimulate sustainable growth while addressing food security, poverty and income distribution concerns. Given the macroeconomic imperative of encouraging resource flows into agriculture and rural development, the faster the pace of reform, the greater the benefits to the economy as a whole. There are a large number of policy and institutional impediments to efficient resource use in the agriculture sector. For much of the past decade, these were but a minor drag on rural economic performance since rural growth was largely carried along by booming urban demand (Tabor 1992). But with the economic crisis delaying recovery in the industry and service sectors, policy and institutional impediments to rural growth have become binding constraints to rural economic growth. An urban (and Java) bias has permeated the development of social and economic infrastructure in Indonesia for the better part of the past two decades (World Bank, 1996). It is important that this be reversed. Despite severe fiscal constraints, public expenditure priority should be accorded to rural primary education, primary health care, and the development of efficient rural road, port and rural power infrastructure. Fiscal transfer mechanisms that allow rural communities a high degree of autonomy in designing and executing rural development efforts can help ensure that rural development efforts capitalise on Indonesia’s heterogeneous regional resource base. Indonesia cannot solve its agricultural and rural development problems by increasing rural public expenditures. The fiscal constraints are too severe, and in many cases the expenditures would do little good anyway. Improving Indonesia’s policy and institutional environment is essential if scarce resources are to flow into rural areas, and if these resources are to be used efficiently and effectively (Tabor 1998). The broad direction for food policy reform is reasonably clear. If resources are to be used more efficiently, the Government should ease regulatory and “public enterprise” impediments to a more business-oriented rural agricultural environment. Over time, the parastatal enterprises and cooperatives providing seeds, fertilisers, pesticides and marketing services should be transformed into market-oriented private businesses. Public investment in rural economic and social infrastructure should be increased, but uneconomic public investment should no longer be tolerated. Completing and capitalising on past investment in rural infrastructure and services is the immediate public investment challenge. Institutional reform should be launched to improve the flexibility and efficiency of rural factor and product markets. An accelerated land registration effort combined with improvements in rural judicial processes is badly required. Special attention should also be provided to augmenting the shelf of relevant rural technology. And finally, the downward spiral of rural resource degradation should be reversed.Few of these challenges can be met in the near-term, and sadly, Government continues to focus its efforts on achieving selfsufficiency in the main foodstuffs rather than improving the rural business environment. A short-lived increase in food production, unto itself, will play only a minor part in restoring national food security. Higher real incomes and wages will result if productivity and competitiveness in agriculture (and other resource-based sectors) increases. For this to happen, the rural business environment will have to improve. References Amang, B., N. Soetrisno and Sapuan. 1996. Can Indonesia feed itself? Paper presented at the second conference of ASAE, Bali, Indonesia, August 1996. Anderson, J. and J. Roumasset. 1996. “Food Insecurity and Stochastic Aspects of Poverty”, Asian Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 2, No. 1. AsDB. 1997d. Constraints on, and Opportunities for Further Growth in Agriculture (draft). Study A-2 under project ADB TA 2660-INO. The leader of this study was Dr. Dudung Abdul Adjid. Team members included Dr. Sudharno Sumarto, and Ir. Sulton Mawardi M.Sc. Bank Indonesia. 1999. Macroeconomic Statistics, Internet Home Page. Bappenas. 1994. Repelita VI, Indonesia’s Sixth Five-Year Development Plan, Jakarta. BKKBN. 1998. Persebaran Keluarga Miskin di Indonesia, January. Boediono. 1978. “Elastisitas Permintaan untuk Berbagai Barang di Indonesia: Penerapan Metode Frisch”, Ekonomi dan Keuangan di Indonesia, Vol XXVI, September, BULOG. 1998. Laporan Kepala Badan Urusan Logistik Pada Sidang Kabinet Terbatas Bidang Ekkuwasbang dan Prodis, Jakarta. BULOG. 1998. Info Bulanan Gasar, No. 33, November. BPS. 1994. Metode penentuan desa tertinggal 1994. Jakarta, Indonesia: Biro Pusat Statistik. BPS. 1997. Indonesian Country Profile. Internet. BPS. 1998. Ringkasan Eksekuif Statistik Ekonomi Makro Indonesia, May. BPS. 1998. Statistical Yearbook and Indikator Ekonomi, Jakarta. BPS. 1998. Produksi Padi di Indonesia (Ramalan III), Jakarta BPS, 1999, Ringkasan Statistik Ekonomi Makro, Jakarta CARD and CADJ (in coordination with BAPPENAS). 1992. Study on Monitoring the Impact of Policy Changes on Food Crop Production, Employment, Income, and Poverty Alleviation in Indonesia. Part of AsDB TA No. 1276-INO. Departemen Perhubungan Badan Meteorologi dan Geofisika (DPBMG). 1998. Ikhtisar Meteorologi dan Geofisika, Bulan Mei 1998, Jakarta. Departemen Pertanian. 1998. Program Penanggulangan Krisis Pangan, Jakarta. Departemen Pertanian. 1998b. Bulletin Informasi Agribisnis, OctoberDecember, Jakarta. Departemen Pertanian. 1998c. Binus Tanaman Pangan, “Biayi dan Penerimaan Usahatani Padi MT 1998” in Surat Mentan No. TP 840/321/Mentan/IX/98, Jakarta. De Tray, Dennis. 1998. “Inside the Indonesian Crisis: What’s Happened? What are the Lessons”, Presentation Delivered at the Indonesia Forum, 19 November. Jakarta. Ellis, Frank. 1993. “Private trade and public role in staple food marketing: the case of rice in Indonesia” Food Policy, Vol. 18, pp: 428-438. FAO. 1996. World Food Summit, 13-17 November 1996. Rome, Italy. Volumes 1, 2 and 3, 6-11. Rome, Italy: Food and Agriculture Organisation of the United Nations. FAO and WFP. 1998. Crop and Food Supply Assessment Mission to Indonesia: October, Rome. Filmer, Deon et. al. 1999. Impact of Economic Crisis on Basic Education in Indonesia, World Bank Watching Brief Issue 2. Fox, James J. 1998. El Nino Report: Indonesia, Research School of Pacific and Asian Studies, Canberra. Garcia-Garcia, J. 1998a. “Indonesia: Food Security, Food Markets and Fiscal Cost of Food Subsidies” (mimeo). Gupta, S. et. al. 1998. Mitigating the Social Costs of the Economic Crisis and the Reform Programs in Asia, IMF Fiscal Affairs Report PPAA/98/7. IMF. 1998. World Economic Outlook, October. Irwanto. 1998. “Perkiraan Pengaruh Krisi Moneter dan Bencana Alam Kekeringa terhadap Anak Dan Remaja Yang Membutuhkan Perlindungan Khusus”, in Y. Raharjo et. al. Dampak Krisis Moneter dan Bencana El Nino Terhadap Masyarakat, Keluarga, Ibu dan Anak di Indonesia, Unicef and PPT-LIPI, Jakarta. Jalal, Fasli and Sumali Atmojo. 1997. Gizi dan Kaulitas Hidup, Jakarta. Kompas. 18 June 1998. 113 Juta Penduduk Miskin di Indonesia, Jakarta. Kompas. 11 June 1998. Defisit Pangan Sudah Melanda 18 Propinsi, Jakarta. Kompas. 8 June 1998. Jujurlah Soal Beras, Jakarta. Kompas. 30 November 1998. KUT Terancam Macet, Produksi Padi Amblek, Jakarta. Kompas. 12 December 1998. Kepijakan Menghapus Subsidy Pupuk, Jakarta. Kompas. 5 February 1999. Hasil Survei: JPS Timbulkan Perpecahan, Jakarta. Lane, Timothy et. al. 1999. IMF Supported Programs in Indonesia, Korea and Thailand: A Prelimnary Assessment, International Monetary Fund, Washington DC. Meyers, W. T. Teklu and S. Johnson. 1986. The Impact of Rice Price Changes on Rural Income, Food and Agricultural Policy Research Institute, Iowa State University. Pearson, S., E. Monke and R. Baulch. 1997. “The Cost of Rice Price Stabilisation under Self-Sufficiency”, in 30 Tahun Peran Bulog Dalam Kethanan Pangan, Jakarta, pp. 353-366. Peng, C. Y., Findlay, C. and R. Stringer. 1997. “Food Security in Asia”, Asia Pacific Economic Literature, Canberra. Poppele, Jessica, Sudarno Sumarto and Lant Pritchett. 1999. Social Impacts of the Crisis: New Data and Policy Implications, mimeo, Jakarta. Saadah, Fadia, Hugh Waters and Peter Heywood. 1999. Indonesia: Undernutrition in Young Children, World Bank Watching Brief No. 1. Sajogyo. 1980. Masalah Kecukupan Pangan dalam Jalur-jalur Pemerataan. Prisma. Sawit, M. Husein. 1998. Produksi Padi dan Pengadaan Beras Dalam Negeri, Kompas, 13 June 1998. Sen, Amartya. 1981. Poverty and Famines. Oxford: Oxford University Press. SMERU. 1998. Implementation of BULOG’s Operasi Pasar Khusus (OPK) in Five Provinces: A Special Report, December, Jakarta. SMERU. 1999b. Nationwide Data on the Impact of the Crisis Soetrisno, N. 1998. Refungsionalisasi Badan Urusan Logistik Pasca Deregulasi Tataniaga Bahan Pokok, Jakarta (mimeo). Suryana, Achmad and Tahlim Sudaryanto. 1997. Penawaran, Permitaan Pangan dan Perilaku Kebiasaan Makan, CASER, Bogor. Tabor, S. and Altemeier, K. 1989. “Food crop Demand in Indonesia: A System’s Approach”, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, 25(2):31-52. Tabor, S. R. 1992. “Agriculture in Transition”, in A. Booth (Ed.) The Oil Boom and After: Indonesian Economic Policy and Performance In the Soeharto Era, Oxford University Press. Tabor, S. R. and G. Meijerink. 1997. “Food Security and Trade Liberalization: Can Opposites Attract?”, in 30 Tahun Peran Bulog Dalam Kethanan Pangan, Jakarta, pp. 367-398. Tabor, S. R. 1998. Revitalising Rural Development in Indonesia, Report Prepared for FAO and the World Bank, May. Timmer, C. P. 1988. “Food Price Stability and the Welfare of the Poor”, Cornell Lecture Series on Food and Nutrition Policy, Cornell University: Ithaca. Timmer, CP 1997a. “Building efficiency in agricultural marketing: the long-run role of BULOG in the Indonesian food economy”. Journal of International Development, Vol. 9, No. 1: 133-145. Timmer, CP 1997b. “Does Bulog Stabilise Rice Prices in Indonesia? Should it Try?” in 30 Tahun Peran Bulog Dalam Kethanan Pangan, Jakarta, pp. 45-81. Timmer, CP 1997c. “Food Security Strategies: The Asian Experience”, (mimeo). Unicef. 1997. Memaksimalkan Potensi Sumberdaya Manusia di Indonesia 1999-2003, Jakarta. van der Eng, Pierre. 1993. Food Consumption and the standard of living in Indonesia, 1880-1990, Economics Division Working Papers, Research School of Pacific Studies, Australia National University, Canberra. Wiebe, Franck. 1998. Special Market Operations: Is Flexible Targeting Appropriate. SMERU Newsletter, December. The World Bank. 1996. Indonesia: A Review of Public Agricultural Expenditures (final draft). The World Bank, Washington, DC The World Bank. 1998a. Report and Recommendation on a Proposed Policy Reform Support Loan, April 28. The World Bank. 1998b. Indonesia and Poverty: the Response to the Crisis, Internet presentation. World Food Programme. 1998. Food Assistance to Drought Affected Regions and for Populations Affected by the Economic Crisis, October, Rome.