ASSESSMENT OF DAMAGES FOR MISREPRESENTATIONS INDUCING CONTRACTS D W McLAUCHLAN* I INTRODUCTION The purpose of this article is to identify and analyse some of the issues that arise in relation to assessment of damages for actionable misrepresentations inducing contracts, particularly in light of developments in the Commonwealth authorities over recent years. The article considers both the measure of damages recoverable for the torts of negligent and fraudulent misrepresentation and the related body of rules governing damages for representations which are, or are deemed by statute to be, terms of a concluded contract between the representor and representee. It is also proposed to use the issues discussed as a vehicle for generating some observations about the general relationship between damages for breach of contract and damages for tort. As Cooke J has recently observed:! The assessment of damages is a pragmatic subject in tort as in contract. It does not lend itself to hard-and-fast rules, although in some standard situations experience has led the Courts to evolve prima facie rules . . . . Subject to this qualification, the law governing assessment of damages for misrepresentation would generally be regarded as well settled and reasonably predictable in its operation, 2 though perhaps in need of some rationalisation (along with the remainder of the substantive rules governing liability for misrepresentation) in view of the somewhat artificial distinctions between tort and contract actions. Nevertheless, the writer has found that on a number of important issues of principle there is much uncertainty and considerable conflict in the authorities. Before embarking on a discussion of these issues, it is first necessary to canvass some of the basic and relatively non-controversial rules. 1 The causes of action for misrepresentation at common law Where a person is induced by a misrepresentation to enter into a con-, tract and he seeks compensation for a resulting "loss", a number of causes * Professor of Law, Victoria University of Wellington. This article has its origins in discussions, correspondence and exchange of drafts during the period 1978-1982 between the writer and Professor D J Mullan of Queen's University, Canada. We planned to write a joint article but, unfortunately, we never managed to complete it. Much of the credit for any good points in this article probably belongs to Professor Mullan. Naturally,t however, the writer accepts responsibility for all errors or other inadequacies. 1 Takaro Properties Ltd v Rowling [1986] 1 NZLR 22 at 69. 2 The best discussion will be found in McGregor on Damages (14th ed 1980) ch 39. See also Waddams, The Law oj Damages (1983) at paras 577-605. Damages for Misrepresentations 371 of action may be available to him at common law. If the misrepresentation is fraudulent or negligent, he may have an action in tort for deceit or negligence respectively. A misrepresentation is fraudulent where the representor knows that his statement is false, or has no belief in its truth, or makes it recklessly, not caring whether it is true or false. 3 A negligent misrepresentation is one which is made without reasonable ground for believing it to be true and in breach of a duty of care owed to the representee. After some initial doubts, 4 it is now accepted that the required "special relationship" which gives rise to a duty of care at common law may subsist between parties negotiating a contract. 5 In addition, where the representation is made by or on behalf of the party with whom the contract is made and the representation can be classified as a term of the contract (or a term of a collateral contract), the representee may recover damages from the other party for breach of contract. The accepted test for determining whether a pre-contract representation is a term of the contract is the intention of the parties. Here, as in other branches of the law of contract, the courts use an objective standard. The question to be determined is whether a reasonable person placed in the situation of the parties would infer that a warranty was intended. 6 It has been noticeable in recent years that the courts have generally been more willing to accept that pre-contract representations are contractually binding. 7 Technical obstacles which might formerly have prevented such conclusions appear no longer to cause difficulty. Thus, the parol evidence rule, which prohibits the addition of oral terms to written contracts, is often ignored altogether or side-stepped on the ground that the statement is a term of a partly written and partly oral contract or a collateral contract. 8 Of course, the damages recoverable under the above causes of action are not necessarily the same. Where the statement is contractually binding, the representee recovers the contract measure of damages. For fraud 3 Derry v Peek (1889) 14 App Cas 337. 4 See generally McLauchlan, "Pre-Contract Negligent Misrepresentation" (1977) 4 Otago LR 23. 5 See eg Esso Petroleum Co Ltd v Mardon [1976] QB 801, Capital Motors Ltd v Beecham [1975] 1 NZLR 576, Coleman v Myers [1977] 2 NZLR 225, and Halliday v Johnson [1985] 2 NZLR 563. 6 Hospital Products Ltd v· United States Surgical Corporation (1984) 58 ALJR 587 at 593, Oscar Chess Ltd v Williams [1957] 1 WLR 370 at 375. 7 See Ellul and Ellul v Oakes (1972) 3 SASR 377, Sealand of the Pacific v Robert C McHaffie Ltd (1975) 51 DLR (3d) 702, Esso Petroleum Co Ltd v Mardon, supra, Sodd Corporation v Tessis (1977) 79 DLR (3d) 632, to name just a few of the many relevant Commonwealth authorities. 8 The trend of modern cases supports the view that a claim for breach of an oral warranty will usually be upheld where there is an actionable misrepresentation, ie a clear misstatement of fact is made which induces the contract. Under the guise of the test of intention, the real question which the courts have been asking themselves is - is it reasonable to regard the representor as having accepted responsibility for the accuracy of his statement? In the absence of special circumstances; where there is a statement of fact on a matter within the representor's knowledge which induces the contract, the natural answer to this question is yes. The representor has taken it upon himself to make the statement and therefore it is reasonable to infer that he has agreed to bear the consequences if the statement turns out to be false. 372 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 and negligence the tort measure is applicable. As is well known, these measures can sometimes lead to markedly different results. 2 Statutory causes of action for misrepresentation (a) New Zealand The common law has been substantially modified in New Zealand by the Contractual Remedies Act 1979. Section 6(1) provides: If a party to a contract has been induced to enter into it by a misrepresentation, whether innocent or fraudulent, made to him by or on behalf of another party to that contract (a) He shall be entitled to damages from that other party in the same manner and to the same extent as if the representation were a term of the contract that has been broken; and (b) He shall not, in the case of a fraudulent misrepresentation, or of an innocent misrepresentation made negligently, be entitled to damages from that other party for deceit or negligence in respect of that misrepresentation. The principal effects ofthis section are as follows. First, a contracting party who seeks to recover damages from the other party in respect of a misrepresentation which induced entry into the contract is no longerrequired to establish fraud, negligence, breach of warranty or breach of a collateral contract. Damages are recoverable for a purely innocent misrepresentation. Secondly, since the damages are to be assessed as if the representation were a broken term of the contract, the contract measure is obviously applicable. Thirdly, the statutory remedy supersedes the tort remedies for negligent and fraudulent misrepresentation. It is important to emphasise, however, that the section has no application where the person making the misrepresentation is not a party to the contract entered into by the representee nor an agent of a party. In such cases the potential tort liability of the representor remains. Furthermore, it is only the contracting party responsible for the misrepresentation who is liable to pay damages in accordance with the contract measure and who cannot be sued in tort. The personal tort liability of an agent is unaffected. 9 Thus, the real estate agent continues to be liable for fraudulent or negligent misrepresentation. to It follows that, despite the passing of the Contractual Remedies Act, the distinction between the contract and tort measures of damages for misrepresentation remains of considerable practical importance. Nevertheless, the potential operation of the Act must continually be borne in mind throughout this article. Many of the cases discussed involve tort actions' for misrepresentation between contracting parties which can no longer be brought in New Zealand. The representee must sue under the Act and seek the contract measure and, as we shall see, this mayor may not be to the representee's advantage. The pre-Act cases do, of course, remain good authority for actions where the defendant is not a party to the contract induced by the misrepresentation. 9 See further Dawson and McLauchlan, The Contractual Remedies Act 1979 (1981) at 23-24. 10 As in eg Richardson v Norris Smith Real Estate Ltd [1977] 1 NZLR 152. Damages for Misrepresentations 373 The distinction between the contract and tort measures may be significant in other contexts as well. Thus, under section 43 of the Fair Trading Act 1986 the courts have a discretion to award compensation for "loss or damage" suffered by, inter alia, misrepresentation in contravention of sections 12 and 13 of the Act. This provision is modelled on Australian legislationll pursuant to which the courts have held that the appropriate measure is more akin to that in tort than that in contract. 12 (b) United Kingdom In the United Kingdom the representee may also have a statutory cause of action under section 2(1) of the Misrepresentation Act 1967 which provides: Where a person has entered into a contract after a misrepresentation has been made to him by another party thereto and as a result thereof he has suffered loss, then, if the person making the misrepresentation would be liable to damages in respect thereof had the misrepresentation been made fraudulently, that person shall be so liable notwithstanding that the representation was not made fraudulently, unless he proves that he had reasonable ground to believe and did believe up to the time the contract was made that the facts represented· were true. This provision, which will be mentioned on a few occasions in the course of this article, differs significantly from section 6 of the Contractual Remedies Act 1979. First, the representor can escape liability by proving that he had reasonable ground for his statement. Section 6 gives no such defence. 13 Secondly, it seems that the measure of damages under section 2(1) is the tort measure. 14 Thirdly, section 2(1) does not abolish the actions for pre-contract fraudulent and negligent misrepresentation. 3 The "Contract" measure The fundamental purpose of damages for breach of civil obligations isIS to put the party whose rights have been violated in the same position, so far as money can do so, as if his rights had been observed. 11 Trade Practices Act 1974(Cth) s 87. A provision giving a statutory right to damages, identical to s 82 of the Australian Act, was struck out of the Fair lfading Bill after the hearing of submissions by the Commerce and Marketing Committee. 12 See Gates v City Mutual Life Assurance Society Ltd (1982) 68 FLR 74 at 91-92, (1983) 68 FLRI0l at 104 ("... the question is not how much better off [the representee] would have been if the statements had been true but how much worse off he is by reason of having taken the steps which he did in reliance on the statements"). See also Frith v Gold Coast Mineral Springs Pty Ltd (1983) 65 FLR 213 at 226-233, Yorke v Ross Lucas Pty Ltd (1982) 69 FLR 116, and Mister Figgins Pty Ltd v Centrepoint Freeholds Pty Ltd (1981) 36 ALR 23. 13 Unless, of course, the fact represented is that there are reasonable grounds for, say, a statement of opinion. See infra. 14 See McGregor, supra n 2 at paras 1482-1489 and Thylor, "Expectation, Reliance and Misrepresentation" (1982) 45 MLR 139. 15 Victoria Laundry (Windsor) Ltd v Newman Industries Ltd [1949] 2 KB 528 at 539 per Asquith LJ. See generally McGregor, supra n 2 at para 10. 374 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 Applied to actions for breach of contract, where "the wrong consists not in the making but in the breaking of the contract",16 the general rule becomes - the plaintiff is entitled to be put in the position he would have been in if the contract had been performed. 17 He is to be compensated for the loss of his bargain, his lost expectation. In the case of a misrepresentation which is held to constitute a breach of contract, prima facie the measure of damages is the difference between the value of what the representee received and what he would have received if the representation had been true. 4 The "Tort" measure The object of tort damages, on the other hand, is restitutio in integrum, because "the plaintiff is not complaining of failure to implement a promise but of failure to leave him alone".18 The plaintiff is entitled to be put in the position in which he would have been if the tort had not been committed and, in the case of a tortious misrepresentation inducing a contract, this is usually taken to be the position he would have been in if the contract had not been entered into. Generally speaking, therefore, the plaintiff recovers the difference between the value of what he received and the amount he has outlaid - his positive losses. In tort, the relevant question is "what loss flows from the entry into the contract induced by the misrepresentation?" whereas in contract it is "what loss flows from the lack of truth of the representation treated as a term of the concluded contract?" The basic distinction is that in contract the plaintiff is entitled to the benefit of his bargain, whereas in tort he recovers his out-of-pocket loss. Since most of the early cases involved misrepresentation inducing the plaintiff to purchase property (usually shares) either from the defendant or a third party, it was commonly stated that the normal measure of damages for tortious misrepresentation is "price paid minus value received at the time of the contract". However, it is now accepted that, since the object of tort damages is to compensate the plaintiff for the net loss resulting from his reliance on the defendant's representation, "consequential" losses are also recoverable in appropriate cases (subject to the rules relating to causation, remoteness and mitigation of damage). 19 Although at one time some doubt as to the position in England appears to have been entertained,20 the distinction between the contract and tort measures must now be taken to be firmly entrenched in the common law. 16 McGregor, supra n 2 at para 573. 17 See Robinson v Harman (1848) 1 Ex 850 at 855; Wertheim v Chicoutimi Pulp Co [1911] AC 301 at 307; British Westinghouse Electric and Manufacturing Co Ltd v Underground Electric Railways Co of London Ltd [1912] AC 673 at 689; Monarch Steamship Co Ltd v Karlshamns O/jefabriker (A/B) [1949] AC 196 at 220; Koufos v Czarnikow Ltd [1969] 1 AC 350 at 400, 414 and 420; Inder Lynch Devoy & Co v Subritsky [1979] 1 NZLR 87 at 95; and other authorities cited in McGregor, supra n 2, para 10. 18 McGregor, supra n 2 at para 573. 19 See eg Doyle v Olby (Ironmongers) Ltd [1969] 2 QB 158, Gould v Vaggelas (1984) 58 ALJR 560, and McGregor, supra n 2, paras 1472-1474. 20 See McGregor on Damages (13th ed 1972) paras 1359 and 1459. Damages for Misrepresentations 375 It is established by a long line of English,21 New Zealand,22 Australian, 23 and Canadian24 decisions. The position in the United States of America, however, is quite different. 25 A majority of jurisdictions apply the "benefit of bargain" measure where a plaintiff is induced by the defendant's fraudulent misrepresentation to enter into a contract with the defendant. Some jurisdictions have gone further and allow the plaintiff the option of claiming the benefit of his bargain or his out-of-pocket loss and this is the position adopted in the Restatement (Second) of Torts. 26 However, the out-of-pocket measure applies where the misrepresentation is merely negligent and also where the plaintiff suffers his loss not through entering into a contract with the defendant but in dealing with a third person. 5 Some consequences of the distinction Whether application of the contract or tort measure will be more satisfactory from the representee's point of view (in the sense of yielding a greater recovery) depends on the nature of the representation and the other circumstances of the case. It is dangerous to generalise but it is perhaps fair to say that the contract measure, since it seeks to give the representee the benefit of his "bargain", will in the majority of cases lead to a larger award than the tort measure. Nevertheless, it needs to be borne in mind that a significant number of cases can arise where application of the contract measure will result in recovery of a sum which is the same as, or even less than, that recoverable in tort. The representee will recover more in contract than tort in cases where, had the representation been true, his assets would have been increased or 21 See McConnel v Wright [1903] 1 Ch 546; Doyle v Olby (Ironmongers) Ltd supra, and the numerous other authorities establishing the application of the tort measure in actions for deceit cited in McGregor, supra n 2 at paras 1460-1465. 22 Canavan v Wright [1957] NZLR 790; Scott v New Zealand Refrigerating Co Ltd [1969] NZLR 30; Foster v Public Trustee [1975] 1 NZLR 26. 23 Holmes v Jones (1907) 4 CLR 1692; Toteff v Antonas (1952) 87 CLR 647. 24 Steele v Pritchard (1907) 7 WLR 108; Rosen v Lindsay (1907) 7 WLR 115; Hepting v Schaaf (1963) 43 DLR (2d) 168; Parna v G & S Properties Ltd (1969) 5 DLR (3d) 315; Bango v Holt (1971) 21 DLR (3d) 66; West Coast Finance Ltd and Booth v Gunderson, Stokes, Walton & Co [1974] 2 WWR 428; Uncle Ben's Tartan Holdings Ltd v Northwest Sports Enterprises [1974] 4 WWR 69. See also the numerous other authorities noted by Waddams, supra n 2 at para 582. 25 See generally McCormick, Handbook on the Law ofDamages (1935) 448-454; Prosser and Keeton, The Law of Torts (5th ed 1984) 765-770; Dobbs, Handbook on the Law ofRemedies (1973) 594-598; Barnett, "Deceit Damages in California: Old Problem New Departure?" (1974) 14 Santa Clara Lawyer 325, 328-338. 26 (1977). Section 549 provides: "(1) The recipient of a fraudulent misrepresentation is entitled to recover as damages in an action of deceit against the maker the pecuniary loss to him of which the misrepresentation is a legal cause, including (a) the difference between the value of what he has received in the transaction and its purchase price or other value given for it; and (b) pecuniary loss suffered otherwise as a consequence of the recipient's reliance upon the misrepresentation. (2) The recipient of a fraudulent misrepresentation in a business transaction is also entitled to recover additional damages sufficient to give him the benefit of his contract with the maker, if these damages are proved with reasonable certainty." 376 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 his situation otherwise improved. The contract measure enables a representee, whether or not he has suffered a loss in his pre-contract net wealth, to be put in the position he would have been in if the representation had been true and thus to obtain the expected benefit. Illustrations 1 P is induced to buy D's house by a misrepresentation that it is "on main sewerage". P seeks damages of $550 being the cost of connecting the house to the sewer. P succeeds in contract even if the house unsewered is worth more than he paid for it. 27 2 P wishes to raise the level of his· sea-life display vessel. D advises that he has a lightweight concrete with a dry density of 30 Ibs per cubic foot which, therefore, can do the job. P orders the concrete and the work is carried out. The concrete turns out to be much heavier than represented with the result that the vessel sinks even deeper into the water. In contract, P recovers not just the cost of restoring the vessel to its earlier state (the "tort" damages), but the added cost of raising the level. He is entitled to his lost expectation. 28 3 D, seeking to sell land to P, tells P that half of the land is covered with good pine timber. P buys the land for $30,000. There is no timber on the land but it is still worth $30,000. The evidence establishes that, if the representation had been true, the land would have been worth $40,000. P may recover damages of $10,000 under the contract measure. 29 In some cases, however, it will not matter which measure is applied. The amount required to restore the status quo ante may be the same as the amount required. to put the plaintiff in the position he would have been in if the contract had been performed - either because performance of the contract would not have improved the plaintiffs resources or would at least have ensured retention of the status quo. Illustrations 1 P is induced to buy a car for $10,000 by D's representation that the car is a 1983 model. In fact, the car is a 1982 model having a market value of $9,500. If the representation had been true, the value of the car would have been $10,000 - the amount paid for it. In contract, P recovers $500, which is the same as his out-of-pocket loss. 2 P, a nursery firm, purchases a new brand of weedkiller relying on D's representation that, like the brand P has been using, no harmful residue will be left in the soil within a certain period following its application. The representation is false and subsequently causes the destruction of P's stock and consequent loss of profits. Subject to the question of remoteness of damage, P will recover the same damages in tort and contract. Precisely the same losses would have been averted (a) if the representation had been true or (b) if the misrepresentation had not been made and the weedkiller not purchased. 30 27 See Ellul and Ellul v Oakes (1972) 3 SASR 377. 28 See Sealand of the Pacific v Robert C McHaffie Ltd (1975) 51 DLR (3d) 702. See also Snarski v Barbarich [1969] WAR 46 where there was a fraudulent misrepresentation by the vendor of a farm property that the water supply was adequate for the purpose of conducting the business. The purchaser's claim for loss of profits due to the lack of water was rejected. 29 A similar illustration is given in the Restatement (Second) of Torts (1977), Comment (i) to s 549. If the value of the land bought were not $30,000 but $25,000, P could prima facie recover $5,000 under the tort measure and $15,000 under the contract measure. 30 Cf the difficult case of Fillmore's Valley Nurseries Ltd v North American Cyanamid Ltd (1958) 14 DLR (2d) 297. Damages for Misrepresentations 377 The representee may also recover the same amount in contract and tort in situations where, because the position he would have been in if the representation had been true is too uncertain or because of the qualified nature of the representation, the court can only grant damages designed to effect restitutio in integrum. 31 Illustration P enters into a lease of a new petrol station relying on D's statement - "We estimate that the throughput of the station in its third year of operation will amount to 200,000 gallons." The circumstances are such that this statement carries the implied representation that the forecast is based on reasonable grounds. That representation is false. Further, only about half of the estimated throughput is achieved. P cannot recover damages in contract for the loss of the profit that he would have made on a turnover of 200,000 gallons. The actionable statement is not that the throughput would be achieved, but that the· estimate was based on reasonable grounds. It does not follow that if D did have reasonable grounds 200,000 gallons would have been sold. The estimate might have been well founded but still wrong. 32 The representee will recover less in contract than in tort where he is induced to enter into what is a losing contract irrespective of the misrepresentation. Illustration P purchases goods for $5,000 in reliance on D's fraudulent misrepresentation as to their quality. The goods are worth $4,000. However, even if the representation had been true, their market value would still have been $4,500 only. In pripciple, P recovers in cQntract $500 - the amount required to put him in the position he would have been in if the representation had been true. 33 In a tort action for deceit, he recovers $1,000 - the amount required to restore his precontract financial position. 34 It is not only in "losing bargain" cases that application of the tort measure is more satisfactory from the representee's point of view. Often the essence of the representee's complaint is not that misrepresentation results in his bargain being less valuable than it would have been if the representation had been true but that he has suffered loss through entry into the contract induced by the misrepresentation. In other words, he is saying "your false statement induced me to act in a way that I would not otherwise have acted l 31 See Dawson and McLauchlan, supra n 9 at 29 and New Zealand Motor Bodies Ltd v Emslie [1985] 2 NZLR 569 at 596. 32 This illustration is, of course, identical to the well-known case of Esso Petroleum Co Ltd v Mardon [1976] QB 801 where P's damages were limited to the losses resulting from his entry into the contract. It is arguable that, in so far as damages are awarded for breach of contract in this situation, they should be abated to take into account the chance that, if the representation had been true (ie D did have reasonable grounds for his estimate), P might still have suffered the losses. 33 Quaere, however, whether the victim of fraudulent misrepresentation might be entitled to an award of exemplary damages where his action is for breach of contract? See McGregor, supra n 2 at para 323. 34 But cf Wehr v Thom [1969] WAR 39 where the court refused to award damages based on the difference between price paid and actual value in a 'bad bargain' situation. Instead, the contract measure was applied. The decision must be regarded as wrong on both counts. 378 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 (entry into the contract) and my reliance on you has cost me". In such cases, a "benefit of the bargain" analysis may be completely unworkable or lead to unacceptable results. The following illustration, modelled on an example given in the Restatement (Second) of Torts,35 highlights the difficulties. The owner of a valuable piece of china is induced to sell it for $10 by a representation that it has certain defects which make it practically worthless. If the damages are assessed by comparing the representee's actual position with the position he would have been in if the representation had been true, the result is that he suffers no loss. He would have sold worthless property for a substantial price. 36 Similar problems in attempting to apply a benefit of the bargain analysis may arise where the representation concerns a "collateral" matter - ie a matter which does not relate to the condition or value of the subject matter of the contract or the benefit/burden of the contract - for example, a representation by a purchaser of shares that "A is no longer interested in buying them from you for a certain (higher) price", and a representation by a seller that "A (a reputable person known to the purchaser) is investing $X in the company". 37 The limits of tort damages While the distinction between contract and tort damages for misrepresentation is easy to state in general terms and readily comprehensible, its application is not always nearly so straightforward. Indeed, an examination of the authorities reveals that in certain areas there is a great deal of confusion and inconsistency in the application of the competing measures. In some tort actions, plaintiffs have recovered what appear to be damages for loss of bargain. In others, damages have been wrongly denied or limited on the ground that the plaintiff was .seeking to recover for his loss of bargain. The distinction between recovery in tort and recovery in contract has been both understated and overstated. As we shall see, much of the difficulty stems from the failure on the part of the courts to address adequately a number of crucial issues. In tort, for example, it is accepted that the representee is entitled to compensation for "damage suffered" or "loss sustained" through reliance on the negligent or fraudulent statement. But, what precisely is the meaning of "damage" in this context? What is involved in restoring a plaintiff to his "pre-tort position"? To the extent that the formula of "price paid minus value" is the usual or prima facie means of expressing this objective, how is "value" to be determined? To what extent are plaintiffs free to choose alternative measures of damage? It is accepted that "consequential" losses are also recoverable, but does this extend to losses other than out-of-pocket expenses, for example loss of the opportunity to enter into other contracts? 6 35 Comment (g) to s 549. 36 Cf for a similar situation Gray v Trick 220 NW 741 (1928) where damages for fraudulent misrepresentation were awarded on the basis of the difference between actual value of the property and the price received. See also Erde v Fenster 141 NY Supp 943 (1913), noted (not altogether accurately) in 55 Harv LR 1023. 37 Cf Potts v Miller (1940) 64 CLR 282. Damages for Misrepresentations II 379 ApPLICATION IN PRACTICE OF THE PRICE PAID MINUS VALUE RULE A good illustration of the inconsistency in the authorities is provided by the quite different analyses which the various Commonwealth courts would accord to the following simple situation: P is induced to buy farm land by D's misrepresentation that the land includes an operating water well. P brings an action in tort claiming damages of $5,000. It is admitted that this sum represents either the cost of remedying the misrepresentation or the difference between the price paid and the value of the property if it had been as represented. One would think that P cannot succeed in his action unless he proves in addition that the price paid for the land exceeded its actual value by the amount claimed. It is not sufficient for P to prove that the property was not worth as much as it would have been worth if the representation had been true for this is to award damages for loss of bargain. In Ellul and Ellul v Oakes, 38 which concerned a misrepresentation that a house was "on main sewerage", the Supreme Court of South Australia dismissed the plaintiffs' action for negligent misrepresentation on this ground. 39 Bray CJ held that the plaintiffs' claim 40 must fail because it is based on tort and damage is the gist of the action and no damage was shown. The measure of damages applicable to a claim for negligent misrepresentation certainly cannot be greater than in a claim for damages for fraudulent misrepresentation and it is well settled that in the latter case it is the difference between the value of what the plaintiff parted with and the value of what he got in consequence of relying on the representation. It is not the contractual standard of the difference between the value of what he got and the value of what he would have got if the representation had been true. There is no evidence that the property unsewered and with the septic tank was worth less than [the price paid]. There was, indeed, evidence, which was hardly needed, that an unsewered property is less valuable than the same property sewered, but there was no evidence as to the value of this property in its unsewered state .... Zelling J41 and Wells J42 took a similar view. Ample support for this approach is to be found in other, more authoritative, decisions of the New Zealand and Australian courts. Thus, in Canavan v Wright, 43 the purchaser of a farm property claimed damages for fraudulent misrepresentation by the vendor as to the carrying capacity of the land. It was held by the New Zealand Court of Appeal, inter alia, that, as there was no evidence from which the value of the land at the time of the sale could be determined, the plaintiff had failed to prove his cause 38 Supra n 27. 39 The plaintiffs did, however, recover damages for breach of warranty amounting to $550, being the cost of connecting the house to the sewer. 40 Supra n 27 at 379. 41 Ibid at 389-390. 42 Ibid at 393. 43 Supra n 22. 380 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 of action and no damages could be awarded in respect of the land. 44 Two recent decisions of the New Zealand Court of Appeal and the High Court of Australia are to a similar effect. 45 In both, the plaintiff failed on the ground that there was insufficient evidence that price paid exceeded value. It was emphasised that, while it was not necessary for a plaintiff to prove his loss with final precision, it must be proved with some degree of certainty. The onus was on the plaintiff to adduce sufficient evidence to enable the calculation to be made as a matter of clear inference from proved facts. There are, however, a significant number of cases in which plaintiffs have recovered damages for tortious misrepresentation without proof on their part that price paid exceeded value. Thus, in Van den Esschert v Chappell 46 a vendor fraudulently misrepresented that there were no white ants in the house. In the Supreme Court of Western Australia the purchaser recovered damages in respect of the cost of their eradication. Jackson SPJ stated: 47 . . . the price paid as between the vendor and purchaser who are freely negotiating but arguing is prima facie evidence of the value of this dwelling-house free of white ,ants. If it is not free of white ants but is infested then, I think, it can be readily inferred that its value must be less than otherwise .... The extent of depreciation, the value may well be the subject of evidence from experts, but it cannot be in any sense less than the cost of the eradication of the white ants. Hence in this case, although the Court cannot say affirmatively what the total damage is that the plaintiff has suffered, it is clear on the evidence that she has suffered at least, in my view, the cost of eradication In other'words, his Honour was prepared to assume that price paid equalled the value of the house as represented. From here it was but a short step to conclude that price paid exceeded actual value. Although not adverted to in Chappell, strong support for this approach is to be found in the leading case on the measure of damages for deceit, McConnel v Wright. 48 There Collins MR, in an often cited passage, said of the deceit action: 49 is not an action for breach of contract, and, therefore, no damages in respect of prospective gains which the person contracting was entitled by his contract to expect come in, but it is an action of tort - it is an action for a wrong done whereby the plaintiff was tricked out of certain money in his pocket; and therefore, prima facie, the highest limit of his damages is the whole extent of his loss, and that loss is measured by the money which was in his pocket and is now in the pocket of the company. That is the ultimate, final, highest standard of his loss. 11 44 The plaintiff did, however, recover in respect of certain consequential losses. See also the leading Australian case of Holmes v Jones (1907) 4 CLR 1692 at 1702-1704 (Griffiths CJ), 1708-1709 (O'Connor J), and 1715-1717 (Isaacs J) where it was "perfectly consistent with the evidence given by the plaintiffs that they have suffered no loss, or even that they have made a good bargain" (1717). 45 See Newark Engineering (NZ) Ltd v Jenkin [1980] 1 NZLR 504 and Ted Brown Quarries Pty Ltd v General Quarries (GUston) Pty Ltd (1977) 16 ALR 23. 46 47 48 49 [1960] WAR 114. Ibid at 117. Supra n 21. Ibid at 554-555. Damages for Misrepresentations 381 His Lordship continued (in a less well known passage):50 But, in so far as he has got an equivalent for that money, that loss is diminished; and I think, in assessing the damages, prima facie the assets as represented are taken to be an equivalent and no more for the money which was paid. So far as the assets are an equivalent, he is not damaged; so far as they fall short of being an equivalent, in that proportion he is damaged. Romer LJ stated: 51 I apprehend that when in a case like this application is made for shares in a company on a representation stating what advantages that company has, in the absence of evidence to the contrary, it should be taken that the price paid for the shares was equivalent to the value of the shares in the company having the advantages stated in the prospectus. Cozens HardyLJ stated: 52 As a rule of convenience, and indeed almost of necessity, the property which would have been acquired by the company, if all the statements in the prospectus had been correct, must prima facie be taken to be worth the precise sum paid for the property, neither more nor less. This is the prima facie presumption, and it is sufficient for the decision of the present case, for no evidence has been adduced by the defendant to rebut the presumption. It is interesting that, while this presumption has generally been ignored in Australia and New Zealand, 53. it has been consistently applied by the Canadian courts. In Hepting v Schaaj54 the plaintiffs were induced to buy a house from the defendants for $17,700 by a fraudulent misrepresentation that it contained a legally rentable suite. It was held by the Supreme Court of Canada that the plaintiffs were entitled to damages of $2,500 - the amount which the defendants had admitted was the difference between the house with and the house without a legally rentable suite. Although the court adopted and purported to apply the tort measure of price paid minus value, it is clear that the actual result was that the plaintiffs recovered damages for their loss of bargain. They recovered precisely the same amount that they would have recovered in an action for breach of warranty. According to Spence J, citing McConnel v Wright, not only was price paid presumed (in the absence of proof to the contrary·by the defendants) to equal the value of the property as represented, but this also justified the further presumption that any difference in value between the 50 51 52 53 Ibid at 555. Emphasis added. Ibid at 556. Emphasis added. Ibid at 559. However, it was the subject of some discussion by the High Court of Australia in Potts v Miller (1940) 64 CLR 282 at 299-300 (Dixon J) and 307-309 (Williams J). The presumption was held to be of no assistance because the representation in question had "no relation to the value of the shares or the nature or quality of the assets or business of the company" (Dixon J at 3(0). See also Field v Shoa/haven Transport Pty Ltd [1970] 3 NSWR 96 at 107-109, where the presumption is referred to as "the principle in Potts .v Miller". 54 [1964] SCR 100; (1963) 43 DLR (2d) 168. 382 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 property as represented and the actual property equalled the difference between price paid and value. 55 A similar decision was reached 13 years later by Verchere J in the British Columbia Supreme Court in Chua v Van Pelt. 56 The vendor of a market gardening operation fraudulently misrepresented the heating capacity of a boiler and the purchaser claimed as damages for deceit the difference between the contract price and the fair market value of the premises without the represented boiler capacity, "of which the estimated cost of installing that additional capacity ... was the proper and only measure".57 After accepting that in an action for deceit the plaintiff was only entitled to recover the difference between price paid and value received, Verchere J held that, in the absence of compelling evidence of actual value, "that value would have to be arrived at indirectly".58 It was necessary "to determine first, the value of the premises as represented, and second, the cost of making that representation good; and then, by deducting the one from the other, to arrive at the sought after figure".59 On the basis of McConnel v Wright the value of the property if it had been as represented was presumptively the price paid. His Honour held that the presumption had not been rebutted - somewhat surprisingly in view of his statement that the purchaser "probably 'got a bargain' "60 - and, as a result, the damages awarded were the difference between price paid and value, value represented by the price paid minus the cost of completion, which of course equalled the cost of completion. As in Hepting v Schaaf, the award was tantamount to damages for loss of bargain. 61 The essential difference between these Canadian cases and the decisions of the Australian and New Zealand courts noted earlier is that the latter place the onus on the plaintiff to prove actual. damage. He must bring evidence to establish that actual value received fell short of the price paid. The cases proceed on the basis that, despite the misrepresentation which renders the subject matter less valuable than it might have been otherwise, the plaintiff may well have gained offsetting advantages from other parts of the contract. As Isaacs J pointed out in Holmes v Jones,62 "it is perfectly consistent with the evidence given by the plaintiffs [that there was misrepresentation which diminished the value of the property] that they have suffered no loss, or even that they have made a good bargain". In the Canadian courts, the lot of a plaintiff in an action for damages for misrepresentation is considerably easier. They are prepared to presume that damage - one of the essential elements of the torts of deceit and 55 It is to be noted that the headnote at 43 DLR (2d) 168 is wrong in so far as it states that the onus was on the defendants to prove that the property had a "lesser value" than the contract price. 56 (1977) 74 DLR (3d) 244. 57 Ibid at 250. 58 Ibid at 254. 59 Idem. 60 Idem. 61 In Chua, the purchase price was $95,000 and the court found that the cost of making good the representation at the time of the purchase was $10,000. Damages were thus calculated on the following basis: $95,000 - ($95,000-$10,000) =$10,000. 62 (1907) 4 CLR 1692 at 1717. Damages for Misrepresentations 383 negligence - has been suffered. The McConnel v Wright presumption is operated so that the court presumes not only that price paid equals the anticipated value of the subject matter if it had been as represented but also that real value equals price paid minus the deficiency in value (as in Hepting v Schaaf) or the cost of completion (as in Chua v Van Pelt). The onus is on the defendant to prove that real value exceeded the price paid or that if the property had been as represented its value would have exceeded the price paid. It must, however, .be noted that, while sometimes producing the same result as an action for breach of contract, application of the McConnel v Wright presumption does not strictly represent an expectation theory of recovery. If the defendant proves that the property would, if as represented, have been worth more than was paid for it, damages will only be awarded to the extent that t.b.e cost of completion is not offset by the excess of value if as represented over. the price paid. 63 The same cannot be said of a test that equates difference between price paid and value in fact with difference between value as represented and value in fact or deficiency in value stemming from the matter misrepresented. Both look directly to expectations and the latter does not even take account of compensating advantages. While the McConnel v Wright presumption may enable the courts to reach results which are practically just, it is to be doubted whether it is justified in principle. Is price paid a good indicator of value, given that we all look for bargains and often succeed in procuring them? More importantly, it can be argued that the dicta in McConnel v Wright have been taken out of context. The presumption was used as the basis for concluding that there was sufficient evidence that damage had been suffered, not as the basis for measuring the quantum of damages. The basic question before the court was whether there ought to be an inquiry into damages and that depended on whether there was sufficient prima facie evidence of damage. McConnel, and many of the other early cases which considered the law relating to damages for misrepresentation, involved proceedings under statutes imposing liability for misrepresentations in, or omissions from, company prospectuses. 64 And, as Jordan CJ pointed out in Potts v Miller, 65 "difficulties are likely to be occasioned by some of the observations in certain of [these] authorities" unless attention is paid to the trial procedure adopted. Unlike the common law actions for deceit which were tried before a jury thus requiring determination of the damages issues at the trial, the cases arising under the statutes governing prospectuses were ordinarily tried in the Chancery Division where the practice was to remit inquiries as to 63 Thus, suppose that in Chua, where the price paid was $95,000 and the cost of making good the representation was $10,000, the defendant proved that the value of the subject matter if as represented would have been $100,000. The damages awarded would have been, not $10,000, but $5,000: $95,000 - ($100,000-$10,000) =$5,000. Cf, however, Thylor, "Expectation, Reliance and Misrepresentation" (1982) 45 MLR 139 at 147. 64 Principally, s 38 of the Companies Act 1867 and s 3 of the Directors Liability Act 1890. The leading authorities, apart from McConnel, are: Cackett v Keswick [1902] 2 Ch 456; Broome v Speak [1903] 1 Ch 586 (affirmed sub nom Shepheard v Broome [1904] AC 342); and MacLeay v Tait [1906] AC 24. 384 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 damages to the Master's office. "So long as the evidence suggested that the plaintiff might have suffered damage, the question whether he had in fact done so was remitted to the Master for determination ...."66 Accordingly, the question for the court in these cases was not whether the evidence justified an award of damages, but whether it justified "an inquiry as to whether any damage had in fact been sustained as the result of the fraud". 67 This "usual practice" was described by Lord Lindley in Shepheard v Broome68 as "extremely convenient. It saves the trouble and expense of going into evidence which will be useless if the plaintiff fails to establish any liability of the defendant to him." This may well explain why Cozens Hardy LJ in McConnel v Wright referred to his presumption as "a rule of convenience, and indeed almost of necessity".69 It is not without significance either that in the later case of MacLeay v Tait70 Lord Lindley stated that McConnel "goes no further than" identifying what may be prima facie evid~nce of damage to justify an inquiry into the amount of damages. III PRICE PAID MINUS VALUE V DAMAGES FOR LOST OPPORTUNITIES 1 Introduction In the examples considered so far, we have been concerned with what is required of a plaintiff (P) who seeks to recover damages on the normal tort measure of price paid minus value. Let us assume now that the evidence establishes that the value received by P is greater than the price paid and that, in this sense, he is better off as a result of his entry into the contract induced by the misrepresentation. Does this necessarily mean that P cannot recover damages in tort? What is the position if P proves that, but for D's misrepresentation, he would have offered and D (or the other contracting party, as the case may be) would have accepted less than the price paid or that he would have entered into a contract with a third party to acquire similar property at a lower price? Consider the following simple example. P buys a car for $5,000 relying on D's representation that the car is a 1976 model. In fact it is a 1975 model worth $5,200. If it had been a 1976 model, the car would have been worth $5,400. Prima facie, the result is - P can recover damages of $200 in contract, but nothing in tort since, despite the misrepresentation, P has made a good bargain. But what if P proves that she would have secured the car for $4,800 if the misrepresentation had not been made, and she contends that as a result of the tort she has "lost" $200? She argues that but for D's tort she would have made a profit of $400, not merely $200, and that, 65 66 67 68 69 70 (1940) 40 SR (NSW) 351 at 357. Ibid at 358. Idem. See also Potts v Miller, supra n 37 at 307-308. [1904] AC 342 at 348. Supra n 21 at 559. [1906] AC 24 at 31. See also Lord James in Shepheard v Broome, supra, who stated (at 346) that "a prima facie cause of action being established, the plaintiff must be afforded an opportunity by an inquiry of shewing whether he has sustained any damage. I express no opinion whether the facts established at the hearing do or do not sustain a claim for damages". Damages for Misrepresentations 385 although on the surface she is better off, she has in a real sense suffered a loss. The issue is squarely raised, though not resolved, by the decision of the New Zealand Court of Appeal in Scott Group Ltd v McFarlane. 71 2 The Scott Group Case The material facts for present purposes were as follows. The plaintiff, Scott Group Ltd, completed a takeover of John" Duthie Holdings Ltd (Duthie). In formulating its takeover offer Scott Group relied, inter alia, on the consolidated group accounts of Duthie which were audited by the defendants, a firm of chartered accountants. The accounts showed that the Duthie shares had a sound asset backing but a relatively poor income record. Scott Group hoped that the takeover would strengthen its capital structure and, to a lesser extent, improve profitability and eliminate competition. The takeover involved a two for one share offer; two shares in Scott Group were offered in exchange for one share in Duthie. Shortly after completion of the takeover, it was discovered that the accounts of Duthie overstated the shareholders' funds by $38,000. Scott Group claimed this sum by way of damages in an action against the defendants for negligence in their audit of the consolidated accounts. It was alleged that, as a result of this negligence, Scott Group had been induced to offer and pay $38,000 more than the actual value of the Duthie shares. The defendants admitted that they should have detected the error in the accounts but denied liability. At first instance,72 Quilliam J held that the defendants did not owe a duty of care to Scott Group. His Honour then proceeded, in case his decision was wrong, to consider whether there was proof of loss resulting from the defendants' negligence. In his view the loss was not necessarily the amount of the overstatement of the shareholders' funds ($38,000), but rather the difference it made to the price paid for the Duthie· shares. In other words, the plaintiffs loss was the difference between the price actually paid and the price that would have been paid if the true position had been known. His Honour felt that there was insufficient evidence to enable him to conclude what the difference in the eventual price would have been, although he doubted "whether it would necessarily have been the equivalent of $38,000".73 If it had been necessary he would have directed an inquiry by an independent expert. The plaintiff's appeal was dismissed by a majority of the Court of Appeal. Richmond P found that the defendants did not owe a duty of care. His Honour said nothing on the damages issue. Cooke J disagreed with Richmond P on the duty issue, but he too dismissed the appeal on the ground that the plaintiff had not suffered a loss. Woodhouse J (dissenting) held that a duty was owed and he would have awarded damages of $24,500. Our present concern is solely with the opinions of Cooke and Woodhouse J on the damages issue. 71 [1978] 1 NZLR 553, noted by Johnston in (1978) 8 NZULR 175. 72 [1975] 1 NZLR 582. 73 Ibid at 591. 386 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 Although both judges agreed that the question to be decided was whether the price paid for the shares was more than their real value in the takeover situation at the time, their approaches to the measurement of value were totally different. Woodhouse J stated: 74 Their [the shares1 stock exchange value was 85 cents, a figure much below their adjusted asset backing of about $2.75. So that the open market value does not assist in any direct way, although no doubt it is a consideration which would have a powerful influence upon the mind of a shareholder when offered a price significantly higher than 85 cents. I have mentioned that the assets backing of each share was regarded on both sides as considerably higher than the value of the shares for the purposes of a takeover bid so that figure too is not immediately relevant. Its significance is further minimised by the fact that it was much more than the breakup value that could have been obtained if the company had been put into liquidation or the assets sold off and some sort of capital distribution made. So in the absence of "takeover" competition for the shares the assets backing was a decisive bargaining factor only for the limited purpose of ensuring that any offer would need to equal at least the breakup value. And the Scott Group Ltd takeover was negotiated in a situation where there was a minimum of competition. There is a fleeting reference to one other group considered to have been interested in making a takeover offer for the John Duthie Holdings Ltd's shares. But ift that interest was in fact translated into a firm offer it was not taken beyond $1.85~ In the circumstances, although the breakup value can probably be regarded as a base price for the shares, any assessment in excess of that figure must depend for present purposes upon the agreement that would have been reached at the time by John Duthie Holdings Ltd and Scott Group Ltd as willing vendor and willing purchaser, in each case with proper knowledge In my opinion it is the theoretical price that would have been acceptable to the very parties that alone will decide whether Scott Group Ltd made a loss in respect of which it should be compensated in the present action. If the price actually paid by Scott Group Ltd can be regarded as exceeding that theoretical price then more was paid for the shares than their true takeover value at the time; and that excess consideration is the measure of the damages that should be paid. Otherwise I think the claim for damages must fail. In other words, for Woodhouse J, since neither the open market value, the adjusted asset backing value nor the breakup value were appropriate in this case, value had to be measured by the theoretical price that the plaintiff would have paid had it known the truth. Before going on to ascertain this amount based on his interpretation of the facts, his Honour provided further justification for this statement of the damages principle. 75 I have mentioned earlier in this judgment that Scott Group Ltd made its offer because it was attracted by what it regarded as under-employed assets possessed by John Duthie Holdings Ltd. It hoped that better use could be made of them if the two businesses were amalgamated within its own organisation. In the result the value of the net assets it acquired exceeded by a substantial margin the value of the consideration it provided for all the shares in John Duthie Holdings Ltd. But that fact should not be allowed to obscure the true nature of the transaction. In considering whether Scott Group Ltd received value for price it is essential to keep in mind that the agreement reached was for a sale and purchase not of assets but of shares in a company that remained in business as an active commercial undertaking. I say that because the particular character of the transaction has a double consequence. On the one hand, Scott Group Ltd is unable to claim that damages should be measured directly by the fact that the asset backing for the shares it acquired turned out to be $38,000 less than had been anticipated. In tort a representee cannot claim damages by reference to the 74 [1978] 1 NZLR 553 at 576-577. 75 Ibid at 577. Damages for Misrepresentations 387 situation he would have been in if the misrepresentation had been true. Conversely the auditors are unable to take refuge in the substantial asset backing of the shares in order to show that Scott Group Ltd did well to purchase the shares. The damages are not to be measured by considering the collateral implications of the bargain but by the price paid for the shares less their actual value at the time. Ultimately, after a lengthy discussion of the evidence, Woodhouse J felt able to conclude that the parties would have agreed upon a price of 5 cents less per share which, in terms of total consideration, amounted to damages of $24,500. Cooke J, on the other hand, held that the plaintiff was not entitled to any damages on the basis that it was clear on the evidence presented that the value of the shares to the plaintiff exceeded the price paid. In his Honour's view,76 it was essential to remember that we are in the sphere of damages for tort - that is to say, reparation for harm done. It is not a case in contract, where the damages broadly represent the benefit which the plaintiff was promised. In an action in tort for deceit leading to a contract of purchase, the normal measure of damages is the difference between the price paid and the fair value at the time of purchase .... Where the contract has been induced by the negligence of a third party rather than by fraud, I think that the same measure should prima facie apply. Later, after specifically disagreeing with the test applied by Quilliam J (and by the same token that applied by Woodhouse J), Cooke J continued: 77 Further as to the true test: the distinction between inducement and damages is crucial. Suing in tort, the plaintiff must prove not only that it acted on the defendants' statement but that it sustained damage by so doing .... There is evidence that if aware of the mistake the plaintiff would have offered less. I doubt whether there is any substantial evidence that the Duthie directors would have accepted or recommended acceptance of less, but if that question were important I would concur in Quilliam J's view that an inquiry into damages would have been appropriate .... But while the question of a possible lower negotiated takeover offer, and the calculations in that connection made by my brother Woodhouse, would have a bearing on inducement or causation, I am not persuaded that they can be carried over into the field of damages once inducement or causation is proved. In considering damages one has to start, not before the sale, but immediately after it was completed. This is clearly brought out by Cotton LJ in Peek v Derry (1887) 37 Ch D 541, 591-593, unaffected on that 'point by the decision of the House of Lords, Derry v Peek (1889) 14 App Cas 337. In principle it must be so, because the tort measure is the plaintiffs loss, which cannot be ascertained without taking into account the benefit that the transaction has in fact brought him. His Honour then proceeded to find on the facts that the benefit of the transaction to the plaintiff exceeded the price paid. The plaintiff company by its own admission had not suffered a loss - the results of the takeover were eminently satisfactory in terms of the objective of strengthening capital structure. It was simply a case of the profit not being as great as it would have been if the aC~Qunts had been correct. The plaintiff made a very good 76 Ibid at 585. 77 Ibid at 586-587. 388 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 bargain but one that was "fractionally less good"78 than it appeared at first sight. In no sense could it be said that at the conclusion of the transaction the plaintiff was "out of pocket". The critical question to be considered therefore is whether, on the assumption that the plaintiff would have paid less for the shares if the misrepresentation had not been made, the excess of price paid ought to have been recovered in tort either on the basis suggested by Woodhouse J or on some other basis. Woodhouse J attempted to justify his award of damages, based on the difference between price paid and the price that would have been paid had the misrepresentation not been made, as simply another way of expressing the traditional test of price paid minus value. The writer does not wish to consider at this stage whether his Honour was correct in tying value to the amount that would have been paid,79 although as we shall see later there is considerable support in the cases for this approach. 80 Let us assume for the moment that Cooke J was correct and "value received" exceeded price paid. Does it follow that damages cannot be recovered in a tort action? Or is the plaintiff entitled to recover on the basis that he suffered a loss to the extent of the difference between the price paid and the price that would have been paid but for the misrepresentation? The answer depends on whether one sees "price paid minus value" as the only appropriate measure of damages in this situation. In determining whether application of the "price paid minus value" formula ought to be seen as providing the answer to the Scott Group problem, it is necessary to return once again to some first principles of damages law. It is axiomatic that the object of damages is to put the party whose rights have been violated in the same position, so far as money can do so, as if his rights had been observed. Therefore, in a tort action the object is to put the plaintiff in the position he would have been in if the tort had not been committed. This means that, subject to the rules governing certainty, remoteness and mitigation, the plaintiff is entitled to be compensated for all damage resulting from the defendant's wrongful conduct. In so far as pecuniary loss is concerned, compensation may be awarded not only for positive losses (the diminution in existing assets as a result of expenses incurred, property damaged or other change in position) but also consequential losses (losses of profits and earnings which would have been received by the plaintiff, or which he would have had the opportunity of obtaining, if the tort had not been committed).81 Of course, where the evidence establishes merely the loss of the chance to earn a profit or to 78 79 80 81 Ibid at 589. See generally Cane, "The Valuation of Shares in the Law of Tort" (1982) JBL 79. See 6 Difference in price paid and lost opportunities infra. See Ogus, The Law of Damages (1973) at 18. Damages for Misrepresentations 389 avoid a loss then, under the rules relating to certainty, account must be taken of the possibility that the chance would not have been realised. 82 There are many situations where, in order to restore the plaintiff to his pre-tort position, damages must be awarded for gains prevented/ opportunities lost as a result of the tort. Thus, as McGregor points out: 83 Where the plaintifrs goods have been damaged he may be allowed damages for loss of profits, or, where no specific loss of profits can be shown, he may be awarded damages for general loss of use, or, in default of either of the preceding, an award of interest may be given. Similarly, where goods have been destroyed, successful claims have ranged from damages for loss of profits to awards of interest. Misappropriation of goods also may give rise to awards of damages for loss of profits or for loss of use, and again interest should be allowed in default of either. Similarly, loss of earnings or profits may be recovered in actions involving negligence causing personal injury or economic loss,84 false imprisonment, malicious prosecution, inducement of breach of contract, passing off and other economic torts. Although sometimes lost sight of, the same general principles are obviously applicable in a tort action involving misrepresentation. The starting-point is that recovery is "based on the actual damage directly flowing from the [tortious] inducement".85 It is clear that, depending on the circumstances, damage may include both positive and consequential losses in the sense used above. Thus, as in the case of other torts, an assessment of damages designed to restore the status quo may involve taking account of opportunities for gain of which the plaintiff has been deprived because of the tort. It is convenient for the purposes of this article to isolate and consider separately two situations where damages for lost opportunity may be sought in an action for tortious misrepresentation. First, situations where the plaintiffs alteration of position involves either (a) conduct other than entry into a contract or (b) entry into a contract other than a contract of sale and purchase. In these cases recovery on the basis of price paid minus value is obviously out of the question. Secondly, situations where the plaintiff's alteration of position does involve entry into a contract of sale and pur82 For a recent illustration, see Craig v East Coast Bays City Council [1986] 1 NZLR 99. The defendant negligently authorised the erection of a house in such a position as to impair the view from the plaintifrs house without giving the plaintiff the opportunity to exercise his right to object. The value of the plaintifrs house was reduced by $6,750 as a result of the impairment of the view. In light of this, and taking into account the chances of the plaintifrs objection being successful, it was held by the Court of Appeal that damages for the loss of the right to object should be assessed at $5,000. 83 McGregor supra n 2, para 50. See also the decisions of the New Zealand Court of Appeal concerning damages for loss of use of an income earning chattel in Greig v Tasman Rental Cars Ltd [1982] 2 NZLR 171 and Newmans Coach Lines Ltd v Robertshawe (1983) unreported, CA 122/82, 16 December 1983. 84 See eg Takaro Properties Ltd v Rowling [1986] 1 NZLR 22 where the plaintiff recovered damages in respect of the lost opportunity to pursue a development project as a result of the defendant's negligence. 85 Clark v Urquhart [1930] AC 28 at 68 per Lord Atkin. See also Cooke v Caldwell's Wines Ltd (1925) 25 SR (NSW) 161 at 173, Toteffv Antonas (1952) 87 CLR 647 at 650 and Gould v Vaggelas (1984) 58 ALJR 560 at 562-563. 390 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 chase. Although in these cases price paid minus value can properly be regarded as the normal measure, it is far from an inflexible rule and indeed sometimes an assessment in terms of this measure may not be feasible at all. 3 Cases where misrepresentation does not lead to contract of sale Where the plaintiffs action in reliance on misrepresentation involves conduct other than entry into a disadvantageous contract, it is clear that the recoverable loss may consist of expenses incurred,86 parting with property or forgoing opportunities for gain or to avoid loss. Thus, in Barley v Walford,87 the defendant fraudulently misrepresented to the plaintiff, a printer of silk goods, that a particular pattern was the subject of a registered design. The plaintiff recovered damages, inter alia, in respect of loss of profits by discontinuing his use of the design. A somewhat unusual example of the same principle is provided by the decision of the High Court of Australia in Commercial Banking Co of Sydney Ltd v R H Brown & CO.88 The respondent firm had contracted to sell goods to a dealer. Prior to delivery they heard rumours that the dealer was in financial difficulties. However, upon receipt of the appellant's representation that the dealer was creditworthy, the goods were duly delivered. One month later a receiver of the dealer was appointed. The company was "hopelessly insolvent" and, as a result, the respondents did not receive payment. The appellant's misrepresentation was found to be fraudulent. The respondents recovered damages based on the value of the wool at the time of delivery. But for the misrepresentation the respondents would have refused to deliver any wool except in return for cash or a proper security. Such refusal may have been a breach of contract on their part, but at worst this would have rendered them liable to pay nominal damages - the value of the goods had fallen below the contract price - whereas by acting on the misrepresentation they had lost the total value of the wool. Although this case actually concerned recovery for positive losses or a forgone opportunity to avoid loss, there can be no doubt that the respondents would also have recovered if the facts involved the respondents, in some foreseeable manner, forgoing an opportunity for gain in reliance on the bank's fraudulent misrepresentation. The same principles apply where the representee's alteration of position does involve entry into a contract (either with the representor or a third party). An interesting early recognition of the notion of lost opportunity providing an acceptable measure of damages in such cases is provided by Equitable Life Assurance Society of the United States v Bertie, 89 a decision of the New Zealand Court of Appeal. The respondent took out an insurance policy with the appellant which provided for payment of the sum insured only on death. He was induced to sign the proposal by a fraudulent mis- 86 87 88 89 - See eg Richardson v Silvester (1873) LR 9 QB 34. (1846) 9 QB 197; 115 ER 1249. (1972) 46 ALJR 297. (1890) 8 NZLR 579. For a modern analogue, see Gates v City Mutual Life Assurance Society Ltd (1986) 60 ALJR 239 (decided since the time of writing). Damages for Misrepresentations 391 representation that it provided for an endowment policy, thus entitling him in 20 years to payment of the sum insured and bonuses. Three years later the respondent discovered that he had entered into a life policy. He elected not to rescind the contract and brought an action claiming damages for deceit. This action failed on the ground of lack of proof of damage the respondent had not proved that he was in a worse position than he would have been in if the representation had not been made. The significant point for present purposes is that the court indicated that it would have been prepared to award as damages the extra benefits of the policy that the respondent thought he was getting from the appellant provided that he had actually lost, through impaired health or some other cause, the opportunity of obtaining that kind of policy at the same rates as were previously available after making necessary adjustments for increased age and so forth. In the absence of proof of such factors, the court held that to award the extra benefits of the endowment policy would amount to an expectation level of recovery which was not appropriate in a tort action. A more recent example of the recognition of the notion of lost opportunity is to be found in the well-known decision of the English Court of Appeal in Esso Petroleum Co Ltd v Mardon. 90 For the reason noted earlier,91 Mardon could not recover in respect of the profits he would have made if the estimated turnover of 200,000 gallons had been achieved, nevertheless it was held that his damages included not only his positive losses (wasted capital and overdraft liabilities incurred) but also the earnings from an alternative business that he had forgone during the disastrous tenancy. 92 Another recent example is McNally v Welltrade International. 93 The plaintiff had entered into a contract for employment in Libya in reliance upon the defendant's negligent misrepresentation as to the nature of the work and his suitability for the job. After only two weeks his employment was terminated. Upon his return to England the plaintiff was out of work for some months and it was a further year before his earnings matched what they were before joining the defendant. In an action for negligent misrepresentation (both at common law and under section 2(1) of the Misrepresentation Act 1967 94) the plaintiff recovered, in addition to travelling and other expenses, the amount of earnings he had lost by giving up his previous employment. 95 Authority for the recovery of lost opportunity damages is also to be found in two cases concerning liability of agents to their principals for breach of duty involving misrepresentation. These cases are significant for present purposes because the misconduct of the agents did not in the circumstances entitle the principal to the expectation level of recovery and 90 91 92 93 94 95 [1976] QB 801. See text to n 32. Supra n 90 at 821. [1978] IRLR 497. See Introduction section 2 (b). For a comparable earlier case, see Burrows v Rhodes [1899] 1 QB 816 (discussed by McGregor, supra n 2 at para 1474 and Ogus, supra n 81 at 253). See also Archer vBrown [1985] QB 401 at 426-427. 392 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 damages had to be assessed in accordance with principles akin to those applicable to tort actions for misrepresentation. The first case is Salvesen & Co v Rederi Aktiebolaget Nordstjernan. 96 Shipowners employed an agent to find freight at a certain rate per ton for one of their ships. The agent incorrectly reported that a charter had been concluded. When the shipowners were informed of the true position, they made no effort to find an equally advantageous charter. Instead, they used the ship to fulfil an existing contract at a much lower freight rate. In an action against the agent, the shipowners claimed as damages the difference between the amount actually earned and the amount that would have been earned under the contract which the agent said had been concluded. However, it was held by the House of Lords that, although the agent breached its duty in supplying the incorrect information, the appropriate measure of damages "was the loss actually sustained by the principal in consequence of the misrepresentation, and that it did not include the anticipated profit which he might have made if the representation had been true".97 In the result recovery was limited to expenses reasonably incurred as a result of the misrepresentation. However, Lord Davey emphasised that there was "no evidence that the [shipowners] lost any opportunity of profitably employing their ship owing to their belief that a charter had been arranged ...."98 It can be inferred that his Lordship would have allowed damages if any such lost opportunity had been established. Lord Robertson was more positive and suggested: 99 If, for example, acting on the faith of the alleged contract, the [shipowners] had incurred expense, or if, misled into inaction, they had missed other chances for the ship, these and the like would be heads of damage. In the second case the plaintiff did recover damages for lost opportunity. In Johnston v Braham & Campbell Ltd100 an actress was induced to enter into a contract of employment by the misrepresentation of her agent as to the takings of the hall at which she was to perform. Under the contract she was entitled to receive 60 percent of the takings. In an action against the agent for breach of duty, the actress recovered, in addition to her outof-pocket expenses, the sum of £20 for loss sustained "by reason of the fact that she lost the opportunity of profitably employing her time" during the period she was fulfilling her engagement. 101 This award, as the court emphasised, was calculated on the basis of the plaintiffs regular earnings and not on the basis of the profits she would have made if the representation had been true. It should be observed, however, that, as in Salvesen, there was no evidence before the court of specific lost opportunities. The plaintiff did not allege that, as a result of the defendant's misrepresentation, she had turned down 96 97 98 99 100 101 [1905] AC 302. Ibid at 311 per Lord Davey. Idem. Ibid at 312. Emphasis added. [1916] 2 KB 529, afrd [1917] 1 KB 586. [1916] 2 KB 529 at 537 per Sankey 1. Damages for Misrepresentations 393 other equally lucrative contracts. It is clear that if there had been such evidence the plaintiff would have been awarded an amount equivalent to the profits she would have made if the representation had been true. Rowlatt J stated: 102 If in the present case the plaintiff could have proved that she had refused other employment by reason of the negligence of the defendants, I have no doubt she could have recovered damages upon that ground. However, in the absence of evidence that the plaintiff would have made the profits represented elsewhere if the contract had not been entered into, the court awarded her a sum designed to compensate her for "broadly the value of her time taking it on an average".103 Her position was treated as 104 analogous to that of a workman, or professional man, or any person who earns his living by labour. If he meets with an accident caused by negligence and sues for damages he recovers what he would have made during the time he was laid up, not because at the time it is ascertained in point of fact that he would have made that sum, but because that time which was of value to him he has lost by negligence. A similar approach to tort damages for misrepresentation has also found favour with the Supreme Court of Canada in the recent case of V K Mason Construction Ltd v Bank of Nova Scotia. 105 The plaintiff contractor agreed to construct an office and shopping complex in reliance on a negligent misrepresentation from the developer's bank, the defendant, that the project was adequately financed. The project collapsed after construction had been substantially completed by the plaintiff and the developer was unable to pay the balance of $1.058 million owing to the plaintiff. The trial judge awarded tort damages of $898,000, representing the balance owing minus the plaintiffs projected profit of $160,000. However, in the Supreme Court of Canada it was held that the judge was wrong in subtracting profit from the damages award. The court was entitled to assume that the plaintiff would have found a profitable means of employing itself had it not been induced to work on the particular project by the defendant's misrepresentation. The lost profit on that project was a reasonable estimate of what the plaintiff would have been likely to make if it had decided to find other work. "That is to say, the lost profit on this contract represents the lost opportunity for profit on any contract."106 It was also held that the plaintiff was entitled to interest from the date of the completion of the contract. 107 102 Ibid at 535. 103 Ibid at 534 per Rowlatt 1. Presumably if the defendant had been able to prove that the plaintiff would not have been able to secure any other engagements during the period in question, no award (apart from expenses incurred) could have been justified. 104 Idem. 105 [1985] 1 SCR 271. 106 Ibid at 286. The court also observed: "If Mason had made an exceptional profit on the ... project it might be disentitled to an award of the entire amount of that profit in tort damages, but this would be so only because it was not reasonably foreseeable that it would have made a similarly exceptional profit on some other contract." 107 Idem. 394 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 In other words, to put Mason in the position it would have been in absent the misrepresentation we must assume that it would have in hand at the time it completed the project that amount of outlay and anticipated profit which it lost in completing the project. It seems to me to be only reasonable to assume that it would have been able to put that money to profitable use. Interest is the court's way of compensating Mason for the loss of the opportunity to invest that money. 4 Cases where misrepresentation induces contract of sale and purchase The only distinction between this type of case and those discussed in the previous section is that normally the essence of the plaintiff/ representee's complaint is that he has been wrongfully induced to part with his property or money for a less than adequate return consideration. In these circumstances the difference between price paid and value received will, more often than not, satisfactorily reflect the plaintiffs loss. Since the cases which most frequently come before the courts involve misrepresentations inducing contracts of sale, it should not be surprising that price paid minus value has come to be expressed as the standard measure of recovery in tort. This measure was so often accepted and applied in the early cases (most of which involved misrepresentation inducing the purchase of shares) that it appeared to be a settled "rule" only to be departed from in exceptional circumstances. Modern authorities confirm, however, that price paid minus value is far from being an immutable principle. Rather it represents a convenient standard for measuring damages in the absence of other evidence. The governing principles are no different from those identified in the previous section. The question in each case is the same - what foreseeable damage did the plaintiff suffer as a result of the tortious misrepresentation? What amount is required to effect restitutio in integrum? Indeed, in some cases involving contracts of sale, the plaintiff will not be complaining that he has parted with his property for an inadequate consideration and, as a result, recovery on the basis of price paid minus value will be out of the question or quite unrealistic. A good example is provided by the controversial case of Watts v Spence. lOB This case is also instructive for the broader purposes of this article since it provides a recent example of the difficulties that can arise through failure to take into account the flexibility of tort concepts relating to damages and, in particular, the availability of lost opportunity recovery. The material facts of Watts v Spence for present purposes were as follows. The plaintiff entered into a contract to buy a house from the defendant for £7,000. Graham J found that the defendant had represented to the plaintiff that he was the sole owner of the house and in a position to sell it. In fact the house was jointly owned by the defendant and his wife who refused to join in the sale. It was held that the plaintiff was entitled to damages for loss of his bargain under section 2(1) of the Misrepresentation Act 1967 (UK), which the judge found was the difference between the value of the house at the date of the contract and its value at the completion date. 108 [1976] Ch 165. Damages for Misrepresentations 395 It has been convincingly argued by McGregor 109 that it is the tort, not the contract, measure which is applicable under section 2(1) and that, therefore, Watts v Spence was wrongly decided. 110 In addition, as both McGregor and Treitel111 point out, the true contract measure was not in fact applied in the case. That measure is the difference between the contract price and the value of the house at the date of completion. As Treitel states: 112 Suppose a purchaser agrees to buy for £24,000 a house worth £27,000 at the time of purchase and £36,000 at the time of completion. If the house is not conveyed, his damages for loss of bargain should be £12,000; under the Watts v Spence formula, they would be £9,000. Accordingly Treitel concludes: 113 The actual method of assessment adopted in Watts v Spence is therefore hard to justify on any principle. In the writer's view, however, the really fundamental criticism that can be levelled against Watts is the apparent failure to consider whether application of tort principles as to assessment of damages would have achieved the desired result of adequately compensating the plaintiff. 114 Clearly, the standard measure of price paid minus value was inapplicable. No price was paid and no value was received. One must therefore return to first principles and ask - what damage did the plaintiff suffer as a result of altering his position in reliance on the misrepresentation? The representation in question was that the defendant was entitled to sell the house. This representation was false and, as a result, the sale could not be completed. Clearly, if the representation had not been made, the plaintiff would not have entered into the contract. Having committed himself to buy from the defendant, the plaintiff lost the opportunity of pursuing an alternative contract. If it is reasonable to assume that he would have been able to secure another property for a similar price, 115 his loss was prima facie the difference (if any) between that price and the amount required to purchase a replacement at the time the misrepresentation was discovered. On the further assumption that the price agreed to be paid to the defendant was the equivalent of the market value, this is tantamount to the actual award in Watts of the difference between value at the date of the contract and value at the date for completion. 109 McGregor, supra n 2 at paras 1486-1489. 110 McGregor's arguments have since been accepted, and Watts v Spence not followed, by Mervyn Davies J in Sharneyford Supplies Ltd v Edge [1986] Ch 128. This decision was reversed by the Court of Appeal [1987] 2 WLR 363, but on different grounds. Indeed, the criticism of Watts was expressly endorsed by the court (per Balcombe LJ at 376). 111 Treitel, The Law of Contract (6th ed 1983) 275. 112 Idem. 113 Idem. 114 It is difficult to agree with McGregor (para 1489) that the court was "faced with a deliberate choice between the tortious and contractual measures". Neither the court nor McGregor identifies what the result of application of the tort measure would be. 115 Cf Taylor, supra n 14 at 145-146. 396 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 Thus, let us suppose that in Watts the evidence established that house prices had risen by 10070 in the interval between the date of the contract and its completion date. The damage suffered by the plaintiff is that he is now required to pay £700 more than he would have had to pay if the tort had not been committed. Can there be any doubt that an award of this sum is consistent with the tort principle of restitutio in integrum? 116 Such an award is not based on an expectation theory of recovery, though the same result might be reached by an application of the contract measure. The amount recoverable in contract would clearly be the same if the plaintiff had agreed to pay the market value of the defendant's property. Otherwise if the plaintiff could establish that the purchase price was less than the market value and thus he had made a good bargain. Watts v Spence did, of course, concern a rather unusual situation, but other cases will also arise where, although the misrepresentation induces a contract of sale, recovery on the basis of price paid minus value is either not feasible or will not meet to any significant extent the plaintiffs foreseeable damage. This will be the position where property has been purchased for some purpose other than its inherent value or profit earning capacity. Take, for example, the illustration given earlier 117 of the misrepresentation on the sale of a weedkiller to a nursery which results in the destruction of the nursery's entire stock and consequent loss of profits. Or, take the case of a misrepresentation on the sale of a burglar alarm and the buyer suffers a substantial loss of stock (which the purchase of another available system would have avoided) when burglars break into his premises. 118 Even where property has been purchased for its inherent value or profit earning capacity, it is clear that price paid minus value is no more than a prima facie measure. This is exemplified by those decisions in which plaintiffs who had bought goods or a business in reliance on misrepresentation have recovered in respect of "consequential losses" - a term used in this context to mean losses over and above the difference between price paid and value. 5 Consequential losses In one of the few House of Lords' statements on the present subject, Lord Campbell LC stated in Davidson v 1Ulloch 119 in 1860 that the object of damages for fraudulent misrepresentation was not to put the plaintiff in the position that he would have been in had he not entered the contract in question. This would mean that the court would have to look at the consequences of all subsequent events resulting from the contract. Rather, damages were to be measured by the difference between the price paid and the value of the property at the time of the sale. 116 See generally Emery, "In Defence of the Rule in Bain v FothergUf' (1978) 42 Conv 338, 342-343 where a similar example is discussed. 117 See text at n 30. 118 Cf Davis and Co (Wines) Ltd v Ala-Minerva (EM!) Ltd [1974] 2 Lloyd's Rep 27, discussed by McGregor, supra n 2 at para 1485. 119 (1860) 3 Macq 783 at 790; followed in Arkwright v Newbold (1881) 17 Ch D 301 at 312. Damages for Misrepresentations 397 .However, this did not prevent the Court of Common Pleas some six years later in Mullett v Mason 12o awarding damages for consequential losses flowing directly from a fraudulent misrepresentation. In that case the plaintiff purchased an infectious cow which passed on its disease to five other cows and he recovered not only the difference between the price paid and the value of the cow but also for the loss suffered as a result of the other cows contracting the infection. This possibility was reiterated by Cotton LJ in Arnison v Smith 121 two years after that same judge had held in Peek v Derry 122 that it was the difference between price and value at the date of the purchase, not value at the date of the trial, that was the touchstone. Obviously what is at stake in pegging value as at the date of purchase is a concern that the defendant not be held liable for collateral events not flowing directly from the misrepresentation or, to use an example given in one of the early cases,123 for infirmities occurring in an animal after the contract rather than those that were there already. There is also present the consideration that principles of restoration to the pre-tort position should not overshadow the defendant's interest in a plaintiff mitigating and in not being responsible for a plaintiffs decision to take the risk and affirm the contract once knowledge of the misrepresentation has been acquired. However, as later cases indicate, these reservations do not eliminate completely the claims of a plaintiff for consequential losses. Often there will be no possibility of rescission. Furthermore there may be unavoidable consequential losses flowing from entry into the contract both before and after knowledge of the misrepresentation. Thus, in the leading New Zealand decision of Canavan v Wright, 124 the Court of Appeal awarded damages to the purchaser of a farm for stock losses resulting from a misrepresentation as to the carrying capacity of a farm. Similarly, in Doyle v Olby (Ironmongers) Ltcfl25 and Siametis v Trojan Horse (Burlington) Inc126 purchasers who were induced to buy businesses by fraudulent misrepresentations as to takings recovered damages for trading losses incurred while they continued to operate the businesses. Moreover, in Canavan v Wright and the New South Wales decision of McAllister v Richmond Brewing Co (NSW) Pty Ltd, 127 the argument that consequential losses are adequately reflected in the difference between value and price paid is explored and rejected. The first part of that argument is that the profit potential of a contract is reflected in both the price paid and the market value and, on the presumption that price paid will correspond to market value if all representations are true, the award of damages on the basis of price paid minus actual value reflects the profit potential lost because of the misrepresentation. Therefore, it is argued that to award 120 121 122 123 124 125 126 127 (1866) LR 1 CP 559. (1889) 41 Ch D 348 at 371-372. (1887) 37 Ch D 541. 1Wycross v Grant (1877) 2 CPD 469 at 544-545. [1957] NZLR 790. See also Gould v Vaggelas (1984) 58 ALJR 560 at 562. [1969] 2 QB 158. (1979) 25 OR (2d) 120. (1942) 42 SR (NSW) 187. 398 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 consequential losses as well as the difference between price and value is to double count damages. This argument is, of course, interesting in that it suggests that, notwithstanding many statements to the contrary, the common basis for awarding damages in misrepresentation cases includes an expectation element (value being the present capitalized sum of future expectations). However, that aside, it also involves a fallacy so far as double recovery is concerned. A claim for consequential losses is not, if framed properly, a claim for loss of profits. It is a claim for falling below the pre-tort position or making a loss on a transaction. Even to give a plaintiff back the total purchase price indicating no value in the subject matter of the contract at the time of its conclusion may sometimes not be enough. Thus, in Mullett v Mason, the infected cow was not only worth nothing but also caused positive harm, beyond the loss of the purchase price. In fact, even if the cow had "value" as "scrap", the plaintiff should recover his consequential losses as well as the purchase price minus the scrap "value". Scrap value is here different from value as a cow and because of that is to be properly treated as a compensating advantage rather than involving a situation in which value has not in fact sunk to zero. It is also possible in this case to view the harm as being separate and distinct from that of purchasing the cow. Thus, even if the cow continued to have value as a cow because it could be cured, the consequential losses could be awarded on the basis of an independent tort of a misrepresentation inducing not the purchase but the action of placing the cow with others and thereby causing foreseeable loss. There may, nevertheless, be difficulties involved in ascertaining the proper extent of a claim for consequential losses and in separating such a claim from one for loss of the profits that would have been earned if the representation had been true. A good example is provided by Foster v Public Trustee, 128 a decision of Cooke J in the New Zealand Supreme Court. Here, by agreement, the judge awarded as damages the amount spent in putting a piece of farm machinery into the state it was fraudulently misrepresented to be in at the time .of the sale. This in itself is, of course, one method of measuring expectation loss, the cost of completion, and because of this it is surprising to see it so readily accepted as a measurement of the difference between price paid and value. That aside, questions were then raised about two other items, a claim for loss of farming profits and a loss sustained on employing outside contractors to do the work which the machine should have done. Both were rejected by Cooke J. The first may have been a claim for expected net profits and not for actual operating losses and therefore in conventional theory was properly disallowed. As to the second, Cooke J stated that, aside from not being causally related to the misrepresentation, it was also not recoverable on the theory that if loss of profits were not recoverable, the cost of mitigating or avoiding a loss of profits was also not recoverable. However, in so far as the use of outside contractors represented a less profitable or more expensive way of performing the labour contemplated than using one's own machinery, this would seem to present a proper claim for consequential losses at least in 128 [1975] 1 NZLR 26. Damages for Misrepresentations 399 a situation where it is clear that the plaintiff would but for the misrepresentation have purchased other machinery. While in one sense it is a claim for profits not being as high as they would otherwise have been, it is also quite possible to characterise it as either a lost opportunity or consequential loss of the transaction. Of course, in the particular case, there may simply have been no evidence of the extent to which this represented a more expensive way of completing the work than would otherwise have been employed. In this respect it is interesting to note that in Canavan v Wright 129 F B Adams J justified the award of consequential losses by reference to the decision of the House of Lords in Liesbosch Dredger v S S Edison. 130 In that case there is a very convincing demonstration of the proposition that simply to give the market value of a negligently sunk ship does not necessarily compensate a plaintiff for all his losses. Market price was the appropriate level of recovery if the vessel could be replaced immediately. However, as it could not be, compensation had also to be given for pending engagements lost as a result. Of course, this no more than exemplifies the law of torts' general concern to take account of opportunities of which someone is deprived because of tortious behaviour. Thus, in a negligence case involving personal injury, the plaintiff receives compensation at common law for, inter alia, wages lost and loss of amenities of life. These provide an acceptable measure of that which has been taken away from the plaintiff and which needs to be restored to him if he is to be put in the same position he would have occupied had the tort not been committed. As explained earlier in this article,131 similar considerations have clearly been taken into account in misrepresentation cases not involving sales. There can be no sensible basis for excluding them in sales cases. Of course, in a number of the latter cases where consequential losses have been awarded the question of the extent of the plaintiffs recovery has been viewed from a rather narrow perspective without regard to considerations of lost opportunity. Indeed, they have concerned claims for what the writer has earlier categorised as basic or positive losses - rather than true consequential losses - in other words, claims for expenditure incurred which resulted in a diminution in the value of the plaintiffs pre-tort assets. 132 Doyle v O/by (Ironmongers) Ltd133 is a good example. No account seems to have been taken of the opportunity cost to the plaintiff of his entry into the contract. Damages were simply calculated on the basis of the difference between outgoings and receipts. Indeed it seems that no award of interest on that difference was made in favour of the plaintiff. Even in cases where it is accepted that the measure of damages is the difference between price paid and market value, the courts will generally take account of the opportunity cost of the induced transaction by awarding interest to the date of trial or judgment on the sum awarded as damages. However, as Canavan v Wright demonstrates, recognition of the fact that, in cases of misrepresen129 130 131 132 133 Supra n 124 at 805-806. [1933] AC 449. Supra, part III section 3. See text to n 81-85 supra. Supra n 125. 400 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 tation inducing sales, price paid minus value does not represent a universal measure of recovery, necessarily leaves the way open for awards of damages for proved lost opportunities. An actual example of such an award is to be found in the case of Hornal v Neuberger Products Ltd,134 although it may be doubted whether there was in fact satisfactory proof of lost opportunity. The plaintiff bought a capstan lathe, which he required for immediate use in his business, from the defendant in reliance on the latter's misrepresentation that the machine had been "Soag reconditioned". On delivery the machine was found to be defective and its repair took some seven weeks, during which time the plaintiff was unable to make use of it. The trial judge dismissed the plaintiffs action for fraudulent misrepresentation on the ground that he had suffered no damage. The machine was worth at least as much as he had paid for it. However, in the Court of Appeal Denning LJ (Hodson and Morris L JJ concurring) held that some damages could be awarded for the delay in getting the machine put right. His Lordship stated: 135 [One] way of approaching the case is to ask: what would have been the position if the statement had not been made? We do not know. The plaintiff might have offered less, and got the machine for less than it was worth; or he might not have gone on with the transaction at all, but bought another machine elsewhere, and thus saved himself the seven weeks' delay in getting this one put right. In either case he would have suffered damage .... The damage may be difficult to assess. It may only be £20 to £30. But that there was some damage sufficient to support the action, I do not doubt. Judgment was entered for the plaintiff with agreed damages under this head of £40. An even more interesting example is given in the judgment of Davidson J in McAllister v Richmond Brewing Co (NSW) Pty Ltd. 136 According to the judge, if in the sale of a business, it could be established that at takings of £120 per week the business had no value and it in fact took only £80 despite a representation of higher than £120 returns, then the plaintiff would be entitled to further damages as well as the price paid. To allow such a claim is, however, to move beyond any conventional view of consequential losses. Even at takings of £80 per week, the business may not be operating at a net trading loss. However, the net profits may be so small as to deprive the business of any market value. In such circumstances, an item of damages reflective of the extent to which the takings fall below the point at which the commercial value of the business is nothing is really to say that, in the formula price paid minus value, value can in fact be a negative amount. The only way that this can be justified in terms of the objectives of tort damages is on the basis that the net opportunity cost of employing the price paid in this manner is greater than that price. This assumes a situation where the alternative investment opportunities are at a level where even to make a profit on the business may be in effect to make a loss. In other words, losses caused by a misrepresentation are not simply to be measured 134 [1957] 1 QB 247. Cfthe sharp criticism of this decision by J G Fleming (1957) 31 ALJ 27. 135 Ibid at 259-260. 136 Supra n 127 at 200-201. Damages for Misrepresentations 401 by the purchase price and the extent to which the plaintiff suffers positive losses in excess of that but rather by the extent to which the plaintiffs capital is less profitably employed than it would have been but for the tort. The McAllister example may also, of course, be justified in expectation terms on the basis that the plaintiff in the example has succeeded in rebutting the presumption that value equals the present capitalized amount of future profits. To be given his anticipated profits he therefore needs to be awarded more than the purchase price and one way of reflecting this is to award the gross amount by which the takings are less than the point at which the takings represent $0 value. This again suggests a certain correlation between lost opportunity claims and claims for loss of profits. 6 Difference in price paid and lost opportunities Viewed from one perspective, the decision in Hornal v Neuberger Products Ltd can be explained as one where the trial judge applied one concept of value (market value) and the Court of Appeal moved to another, that of value to the plaintiff, the latter being fixed on the basis of the opportunity lost to the plaintiff to make use of the capstan lathe. This also perhaps explains the differing views of Woodhouse and Cooke JJ in Scott Group Ltd v McFarlane. For Woodhouse J, market value immediately after the transaction simply did not tell the whole story and value to the plaintiff indicated recovery based on the difference between what the company did pay and what it would have paid had the truth been known. Aside from H ornal and the other cases noted in the course of this paper which sanction lost opportunity recovery, there is other, albeit weaker, authority for the Woodhouse measure in the Scott Group case and also for the further alternative of the loss of another contract that would have been entered into with a third party were it not for the misrepresentation. The authority is much weaker in the sense that, with one exception, the proposition is asserted, not as a justification for the damages actually awarded, but as a comment that if damages were to be available evidence supporting such a mode of assessment should have been adduced. Thus, in Blanke and Burke v New Good Eats Cafe Ltd and Litras137 purchasers of a restaurant business claimed damages for a fraudulent misrepresentation that the prices on a menu had been approved by a price control body. The action was dismissed by MacFarlane J of the British Columbia Supreme Court, inter alia, on the ground that the plaintiffs had not proved damage. His Honour stated: 138 I think it is well settled that the measure of damages in an action for misrepresentation in the sale of chattels is the difference between the price paid and the fair value of the subject of the sale at the time of the purchase. There was nothing in the evidence presented in this case on which I could arrive at a figure which I could say was the actual value of the business at the time of the sale .... The plaintiffs declined to state at the trial what they would have paid for the business if the menu later approved had been the one shown to them. That is, I think, what the evidence should have revealed, and it does not. 137 [1947] 2 DLR 431. 138 Ibid at 435. 402 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 Of somewhat greater authority is the judgment of Slesser LJ in London County Freehold & Leasehold Properties Ltd v Berkeley Property and Investment Co Ltd. 139 This case concerned a fraudulent misrepresentation on the sale of a block of flats that the rents were paid promptly and without dispute. In ordering an inquiry as to the damages sustained by the purchasers, Slesser LJ said: 140 The damage will be the difference between £611,000 paid for the property and the amount which the plaintiffs would have paid had they known the actual circumstances as to [the] flats. No authority was cited nor did the other two Court of Appeal judges say anything which indicated their support for this measure, but it is interesting to note that there was some evidence before the court that, if the plaintiffs had known the true position, they "might have purchased at a reduced price".141 Slesser LJ's dictum has since been cited with approval by the Canadian courts in the leading cases of Hepting v Schaa.f42 and Chua v Van Pelt. 143 The above measure of damages appears to have been accepted by the Ontario Court of Appeal in the interesting case of Sodd Corporation Inc v TessiS. 144 The defendant, a trustee in bankruptcy, advertised for sale by tender the stock-in-trade of a furniture business carried on by the bankrupt. The plaintiff submitted a tender which was eventually accepted in reliance on the defendant's representation that the retail value of the stock was $33,500, this figure being calculated on the basis of twice the wholesale cost. It was subsequently discovered that the stock was overvalued by approximately 100070. The trial judge (Dymond J) awarded the plaintiff damages of $4,500 for the tort of negligent misrepresentation and this award was upheld by the Ontario Court of Appeal. Lacourciere JA said: 145 While the [defendant] attacked the assessment of damages as being based in part on the plaintiffs figures which were found to be inaccurate, we are satisfied that the assessment of damages can be supported on the basis outlined by the learned trial judge. Unfortunately, the reasoning of the trial judge is not reported but it appears that damages were assessed on the difference between the price paid for the stock and the price that would have been paid had the negligent misrepresentation not been made. This in turn was calculated on the basis of first establishing the percentage of the represented wholesale value that 139 140 141 142 143 144 145 [1936] 2 All ER 1039. Ibid at 1047-1048. Ibid at 1044. [1964] SCR 100, see text to n 54 supra. (1977) 74 DLR (3d) 244, see text to n 56 supra. (1977) 79 DLR (3d) 632. Ibid at 635. Damages for Misrepresentations 403 the plaintiff actually paid (55070) and awarding as damages the amount by which the price paid exceeded the same percentage of the actual value. 146 The award of $4,500, which exceeded the plaintiff's out-of-pocket loss by some $2,000 has been criticised as inappropriate in tort but "unexceptionable had the misstatement been a warranty". 147 However, the writer believes that, in so far as the sum awarded was well below the difference between the represented value of the goods and their actual value, it did not in fact reflect the expectation level of recovery. The following simple example will illustrate the point. Plaintiff (P) buys goods from Defendant (D) for $1,000. P expects to resell the goods for $1,500 if D's representations are true. The representations are untrue and the goods are in fact worth only $1,200 on resale. The evidence shows that P was only prepared to pay a price which would yield a 500/0 profit. (Hence $1,500 = 500/0 profit on $1,000.) Since the actual value received was $1,200 and in order to have made his 500/0 profit P would have invested $800 only, the damages should be calculated as follows: $1,000 (price paid in anticipation of a 50070 profit) - $800 (price that would have been paid to secure 50070 profit on value actually received) = $200. At the end of the day P has $1,400 in his pocket - $1,200 value received from D and $200 damages. This is clearly not an expectation level of recovery. An expectation award would give P $300, the amount required to bring him to $1,500 in the pocket. As to the further alternative mentioned above of recovery for the loss of another contract which but for the misrepresentation would have been entered into with a third party, there is very little authority to be found in cases involving sales. However, it is interesting to note that this possibility was recognised by Phippen JA of the Manitoba Court of Appeal in Rosen v Lindsay.148 This case concerned an action for damages in respect of fraudulent misrepresentation by a vendor on the sale of an hotel. After expressly rejecting the expectation level of recovery, his Honour stated that the plaintiff might possibly have had a cause of action if he had shown that the $4,000 that he actually made while operating the business was in fact a loss "because he had given up a more profitable investment or occupation". 149 An award of damages on the latter basis and one based on the difference in price paid are both, of course, lost opportunity awards. The first involves the loss of an opportunity to make a profitable (or perhaps less unprofitable) contract with someone else while the second involves the loss 146 See Schwartz, "Hedley Byrne and Pre-Contractual Misrepresentations: Tort Law to the Aid of Contract?" (1978) 10 Ottawa LR 581 at 615. On a literal interpretation of the trial judge's reasoning (as reported by Schwartz at 615), it might appear that she awarded as damages 55070 of the difference between the represented wholesale value and actual wholesale value. But it is submitted that it is more likely that she had in mind the measure stated in the text. As will be explained later, if a true "price paid" measure is applied, the plaintiff's actual position is generally irrelevant. 147 Idem. 148 (1907) 7 WLR 115. 149 Ibid at 119. 404 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 of an opportunity to make a lower priced contract with the same person. However, it should be noted at this point that, because one is based on profits and one on price, the way in which the- plaintiffs actual position is viewed for the purposes of calculating damages is somewhat different. If the claim is one based on the anticipated profits of another contract, the plaintiff receives the anticipated benefits of that missed opportunity but then, depending upon whether his actual position is better or worse than his financial position prior to the tort, a deduction or addition is made to the award. If he has nevertheless made some profits, this obviously has to be set off against the award for the lost opportunity. However, if the actual transaction has been a losing proposition, he is not adequately compensated for his lost opportunity unless he is given both his net loss on the actual transaction as well as his anticipated gains on the lost opportunity. In one case, the lost opportunity has been offset to an extent by an actual trading gain. In the other, he has not only lost the opportunity but suffered a trading loss as well. (In the case of a chattel, this latter figure will be the extent to which the chattel is less valuable than·the price paid and the former figure the extent to which the chattel is more valuable than the price paid.) On the other hand, if the claim is one based on difference in price paid, the plaintiffs actual position is generally irrelevant. Because the focus of the inquiry is upon price and not anticipated gains and because difference in price is itself directly a reflection of the position that the plaintiff is in and the position that he would have been in, albeit in price rather than profit terms, there is, with one exception, no need to be concerned with the plaintiffs actual position. The one exception comes in the case of the sale of a business. As the McAllister case 150 demonstrates, there comes a point at which value and also price that would have been paid reach zero. Indeed, sometimes this may occur even in situations where the business is still showing a small gain. Such a business may simply have no value or price because people will not pay anything for a business with such limited potential. Against this background, it is arguable that the plaintiff should be able to recover more than the total price paid to the extent that the actual trading position falls below a position where the business is valueless and has no price. Simply giving back the price paid as a reflection of the difference between price actually paid and price that would have been paid (here, zero) may not do enough to compensate a plaintiff. Another way of viewing this same point is on the basis of a presumption that any business which is making a trading loss is not only worth no part of the price that was paid for it but the extent of the trading loss represents further or additional compensable loss. It is interesting that this, of course, is the same position that would be reached if the basic mode of assessment is the generally accepted price paid minus value plus consequential or additional losses instead of simply difference in price paid. 150 Supra n 127. Damages for Misrepresentations 405 7 Some contrary authorities Apart from the judgment of Cooke J in the Scott Group case, the writer has found only two cases in which the above methods of assessment have been expressly rejected. In Waddell v Blockey151 the defendant sold the plaintiff rupee paper, representing it to have been bought on the exchange. In fact, it was the defendant's own rupee paper. The English Court of Appeal rejected damages based on the difference between the price the plaintiff paid and the price at which he could have bought on the exchange. 152 Rather, damages had to be assessed by the standard measure of the difference between price paid and what he could have resold the rupee paper for on the day it was purchased. This is clearly the equivalent of Cooke J's holding in Scott Group. The second, and more interesting, case is Parna v G & S Properties Ltd153 which involved an alleged fraudulent misrepresentation as to net income on the sale of an apartment building. At the trial, Ferguson J of the Ontario High Court calculated damages on the basis of the difference which the misrepresentation caused to the price paid. This he worked out by first noting that, as represented, the income was a yield of 9.6010 on the price paid. (There was also evidence that the plaintiff only made the offer to purchase on the basis that the net annual profits would return this percentage on his investment.) His Honour then ascertained what sum the real income was 9.6070 of and awarded the difference between that sum and the price paid. Thus, the represented income was $24,193. This would have provided a return to the plaintiff of 9.6070 on the purchase price of $251,000. The actual income was $21,807 and, in order to have obtained the desired 9.6070 return on his capital, the plaintiff would have had to reduce his offer to $226,210. The difference between price paid and the price that would have been paid if the misrepresentation had not been made was thus $24,790 ($251,000 - $226,210). However, this method of assessment was rejected by the Ontario Court of Appeal on the basis that it represented the contract measure - "the difference between the actual value and the worth of the property calculated as if the false representations had been true".154 On further appeal to the Supreme Court of Canada the defendant was successful in a cross appeal on the issue of liability but Spence J (delivering the judgment of the Court) affirmed the Court of Appeal's view that the trial judge's assessment of damages "was upon the basis of damages for loss of a bargain".155 In the writer's view, however, the contract measure was not applied by the trial judge, just as it was not applied in Sodd Corporation Inc v Tessis,156 the later Ontario Court of Appeal decision in which a theoretically similar method of calculating damages was affirmed. In Sodd the damages award did not have the effect of giving the plaintiff his expected gains on the 151 (1879) 4 QBD 678. 152 Ibid at 682. 153 (1968) 67 DLR (2d) 279 (Ontario High Court, Ferguson J); (1969) 5 DLR (3d) 315 (Ontario Court of Appeal); (1970) 15 DLR (3d) 336 (Supreme Court of Canada). 154 (1969) 5 DLR (3d) 315 at 317 per Evans JA. 155 (1970) 15 DLR (3d) 336 at 343. 156 Supra n 144. 406 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 property he thought he was buying. Rather, by receiving the difference between the price that he did pay and the price that he would have paid if the misrepresentation had not been made, he is put in the position that he would have been in had he calculated his profits and price on the goods as they actually were, not as they were promised to be. His award is in one sense an expectation award but it is calculated on his expected profit margin on the smaller amount that he would have paid for the goods as they actually were, not his expected profit margin on the money he actually invested. In other words, the ultimate award does not take account of the investment potential of the difference between the price that was paid and the price that would have been paid. The same is also true of the Ferguson J's award in Porno. The difference between price paid and the price that would have been paid is certainly calculated on the basis of the profits he hoped to make with his money but, in so far as the award is a reflection of lost profits, it is so on the basis of the smaller amount that would have been paid had the truth been known, not the larger amount that was in fact paid. Of course, the awarding of interest at an appropriate rate to the date of trial might be seen as making up this difference. However, if justified on the basis of other investment opportunities available for the money rather than the expected profits from the particular contract, the overall award could still be seen as restorative rather than as compensating for particular lost expectations.. It also merits observation that in both Sodd and Ferguson J's judgment in Porno the difference between the price paid and the price that would have been paid was calculated by reference to percentages of either market value or actual rates of return. This perhaps provides some explanation of why they have been perceived as expectation awards or damages for loss of profits. However, to the extent that the award is based on other evidence such as convincing testimony as to what the plaintiff would actually have paid had he known the truth, any necessary link with loss of profits or expectation disappears. Whether such an award is higher, lower or the same as an award based on expectation in either of the senses identified will depend on whether the plaintiffs and the defendant's perception of the relation between price paid and market or income is good or bad. This also suggests a general observation about the differences between contract and tort damages. Tort may simply be concerned to fix damages by reference to the actual direct financial consequences of the misrepresentation, for example, paying more, irrespective of market and expectation considerations. However, in the absence of anything else, market. is frequently a handy basis for measuring loss. On the other hand, in the case of contract damages, because of the greater concern with foreseeability of loss, market is generally a much more integral or essential part of damage calculation. In other words, difference between price paid and price that would have been paid will be a satisfactory measure in contract so long as there is reasonable correlation between that measure and the difference in market price. If there is not, then such a measure has to be discarded. In tort, given its greater concern with opportunities actually lost or steps actually taken, difference in price paid will always be a satisfactory measure. To this extent, it can be argued that the law of torts is far less concerned Damages for Misrepresentations 407 than contract with objective and external measures of loss such as market value and much more with the subjective issue of what the plaintiff actually did, albeit that, as presumptions frequently founded in truth, market price will be useful either as a basis for calculating difference between the price paid and the price that would have been paid or as part of the standard formula price paid less actual market value. 8 The Scott Group case reconsidered In light of the foregoing discussion, it is now possible to attempt an answer to the question posed earlier in relation to the Scott Group case. That question was whether, on the assumption that the plaintiff would have paid less for the shares if the misrepresentation had not been made, the excess of price paid was recoverable in tort. It will be remembered that Cooke J denied recovery whereas Woodhouse J would have awarded damages of $24,500. Cooke J accepted that the general purpose of damages in tort is to place the plaintiff in his pre-tort position. His Honour emphasised thoughout his judgment that the concern of tort is "reparation for harm done",157 that "the tort measure is the plaintiffs loss, which cannot be ascertained without taking into account the benefit that the transaction has in fact brought him",158 and that "it is not a case in contract, where the damages broadly represent the benefit which the plaintiff was promised". 159 Superficially, his decision to deny recovery can be seen as forwarding that philosophy. If, after the tort, the plaintiff has more money or other advantag~s than he had before the tort, it could be said that he hassuffered no damage. The tort may have meant that he has not gained as much as he could or should have, but he is still better off and lost gains are the concern of expectation and contract, not restitution and torts.--In. other words, the compensating advantages of the whole transaction have led to an improved post-tort position, even perhaps to the extent that the plaintiff should be grateful for the misrepresentation having induced him to act. Like other judges before him, Cooke J restates the restitutionary pur.. poses of tort damages in the more precise form that 160 the normal measure of damages is the difference between the price paid and the fair value at the time of purchase .... In deciding to reduce the general principle of recovery of damages in tort to these terms, with value having an objective or market sense rather than connoting value to the plaintiff in the sense of price that the plaintiff would pay, Cooke J is in fact making a very important judgment about what "restoring a plaintiff to his pre-tort position" involves. More specifically, he is disregarding or treating as irrelevant the fact that, before the tort, the plaintiff was not simply a person with $X but a person with $X plus 157 158 159 160 [1978] 1 NZLR 553 at 585. Ibid at 587. Ibid at 585. Idem. 408 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 the ability to choose certain courses of action. It can be argued that accurate restoration to the pre-tort situation will only take place if both elements are recognised or compensated for. If, but for the tort, the plaintiff would either have paid the defendant less or would not have entered into the transaction but instead entered into another one with similar expected profitability potential, then, to the extent that these opportunities no longer exist, they must be compensated for in order to achieve true restoration. The difference between Cooke and Woodhouse JJ is therefore not one in which Woodhouse J has under the guise of tort theory moved to expectation recovery, as Cooke J at times tends to suggest. Rather, it is similar to the debate that has characterized discussion in the law of contract about what precisely compensating for wasted reliance as opposed to defeated expectations involves. Does reliance involve not only positive reliance or does it also embrace wasted or forgone opportunities? Of course, to view reliance as involving wasted or forgone opportunities may in fact serve to equate recovery on the basis of reliance and recovery on the basis of expectation in the sense that the wasted opportunity may have been one to employ capital elsewhere at the same level of profitability as was expected from the defective transaction. 161 However, that will clearly not always be the case in that the defeated transaction may often be the best possible transaction available had it fulfilled the plaintiffs expectations. Moreover, if one talks about reliance in terms of paying more than one would otherwise have (as Woodhouse J did in Scott) rather than the wasted opportunities of profit elsewhere, reliance and expectation will not generally equate. Paying more in a business transaction is frequently calculated to produce greater profits. Thus, an extra investment of $X will normally be expected to add $X plus $Y to gross income, not just $X. Indeed, this is roughly reflected by the actual award made by Woodhouse J in Scott of $24,500, somewhat less than the shortfall in the accounts of $38,000. In the last analysis, it seems quite clear that the conclusion of Woodhouse J on the damages issue was not in fact precluded by the well-established general principle of measurement of damages in torts cases. That wellestablished general principle of measurement simply does not address the problem in precise enough terms. Thus, the writer sees the judges in Scott as having had a choice as to which way to go on the issue and, as a result, their judicial time would have been better employed in analysing the effects of this choice than in simply asserting consistency with the true doctrine and reaching contradictory results. There is, of course, considerable practical wisdom in having price paid minus value as the prima facie measure of damages in misrepresentation cases involving sales. Price paid will usually be readily ascertainable and, while difficult disputes can arise over the facts of value and also at what point it should be assessed, it is still a more ascertainable standard than either assessing how much less the plaintiff would have been prepared to pay had he known the truth and also how much less the "vendor" would have been prepared to accept or, in the case where a contract would not 161 See eg Fuller & Perdue, "The Reliance Interest in Contract Damages" (1936) 46 Yale LJ 52 at 74. Damages for Misrepresentations 409 have resulted had the misrepresentation not been made, what alternatives were available and what profits they would have produced. Furthermore, allowing the plaintiff to succeed on the basis of price paid minus value may not only make trials shorter but also presumably ensure that more plaintiffs win, notwithstanding the failure of the plaintiff in Scott. To adopt a fuller sense of reliance would simply provide problems of onus too formidable for plaintiffs in such cases. Nevertheless, the fact must be faced that the price paid minus value formula involves a one-dimensional view of what is involved in reliance or acting upon a misrepresentation and this raises a number of questions. Does the formula have any independent value aside from the relative ease of calculation as compared with what would be involved if reliance were viewed in a fuller sense? If not, should it be completely rejected or do the interests of plaintiffs or the procedural/ evidential advantages of the rule dictate that it be used either exclusively or unless the plaintiff brings forward compelling evidence upon which to base an award of damages reflecting reliance in its fullest sense? If it continues to stand as the prima facie measure, should it also be able to be rebutted by the defendant's showing that the excess of price paid over value was greater than the higher amount that the plaintiff was induced to pay because of the misrepresentations? As the cases discussed in previous sections demonstrate, damages in tort generally are concerned, not with restoring the plaintiff to the financial position that he was in the moment before the tort, but rather with restoring him to the position that he would have been in but for the tort. The costs of tort are measured not simply in terms of the direct money expenditures caused by the tort, but also by reference to the opportunities lost - ~g, to use one's now destroyed arm, to earn a living until retirement. Indeed, this philosophy has been accepted in the torts of actionable misrepresentation. Thus, where the misrepresentation has caused physical harm the same notions of lost opportunity dictate the level of damages as they also do where the misrepresentation has caused the plaintiff not to exploit a financial opportunity. The latter example also provides a good illustration of the fact that the law of torts is not completely opposed to awards based on lost profits. Even where the misrepresentation has led to a personal services contract, this has not prevented the court from assessing damages by reference to the lost opportunity standard of wages that would otherwise have been earned but for the misrepresentation and the entry into the contract in question. To deny damages or even damage on the basis of lost opportunity in the case of misrepresentations inducing contracts of sale and purchase is therefore to create an exception to general principles of tortious liability.162 162 It is interesting to note the following observations of Cooke J with regard to the Scott Group case some five years later in Gartside v Sheffield, Young & Ellis [1983] NZLR 37 at 43: "Generally speaking, damages in tort have been given to compensate for impairment of the plaintifrs existing position. This includes of course loss of prospects. An assessment of the value of the plaintiffs prospects is often necessary in tort. But it has not been usual in tort to give damages representing the benefit that would have accrued to the· plaintiff if the defendant had performed a promise. That has been traditionally seen as the distinctive role of damages in contract. It was basically this consideration, together with the desirability of keeping some limitation on liability for negligent mis- 1 410 Otago Law Review IV RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN MATTER MISREPRESENTED AND Loss CLAIMED (1987) Vol 6 No 3 1 Introduction There is one other problem that has concerned the writer in the course of reviewing the authorities governing the measure of damages in misrepresentation cases. Does the availability of damages for tortious misrepresentation depend upon the incorrect or misleading statement affecting the market or objective value of the contract induced? In other words, are damages recoverable if the misrepresentation does not itself involve the contract being less valuable? It is well established that, in calculating tort damages under the price paid minus value formula, account must be taken not only of the matter misrepresented but also of all offsetting gains or advantages in other parts of the transaction. The purpose of the inquiry is to determine the net loss incurred by the plaintiff through having acted in reliance on the misrepresentation and, accordingly, "any appreciable value received . . . as the result of the transaction must be brought into account in reduction of the damages".163 The logical corollary of the theory that the court must take into account compensating advantages in the rest of the contract should be that, if there are further disadvantages in the contract other than those which stem from the misrepresentation itself, they should increase the award. It should also follow that where the misrepresentation, although it did induce the contract, has no effect at all on the value received, damages are still 'recoverable if for other reasons price paid exceeded value. But is this in fact the legal position? The issue was first drawn to the writer's attention by the decision of Cooke J in Capital Motors Ltd v Beecham. 164 There the plaintiff (Beecham) purchased a car from the defendant motor vehicle dealer in reliance on the salesman's careless misrepresentation that the car had not had more than two previous owners. The plaintiff claimed damages in tort for negligent misrepresentation. Cooke J upheld the magistrate's award of $100 - the difference between the price paid for the car and its market value at the time of the purchase. The writer's first impression of this case was that it provided a straightforward example of a situation where application of the tort and contract measures will lead to the same result. The plaintiff had paid $1,400 for a car which had a market value of $1,300 as a result of its having had more than two owners. He recovered in tort the difference of $100. This put him in the position he would have been in if the tort had not been committed and the contract not entered into. Applying the contract measure, the amount required to put the plaintiff in the position he would have been in if the representation had been true was the same - $100. statements, that led me to the view that no damages should be given in Scott Group Ltd v McFarlane . ..." 163 New Zealand Refrigerating Co Ltd v Scott [1969] NZLR 30 at 35 per Macarthur 1. 164 [1975] 1 NZLR 576. For a brief earlier discussion see McLauchlan, "Pre-Contract Negligent Misrepresentation" (1977) 4 Otago LR 23 at 38. Damages for Misrepresentations 411 However, a closer analysis of the facts revealed that the plaintiff would only have been entitled to nominal damages if he had sued for breach of warranty and, as a result, the contract measure applied. It seems that the principal reason for the depreciation in the value of the car was not the fact that it had had more than two owners but that the first owner was a rental-car company. Cooke J stated that 165 the succession of owners went back to a rental-car company, the car having been used for rental purposes for about the first 20,000 miles, and the magistrate found that in the light of this history the true market value was only $1,300. It follows that, if an action had been brought for breach of warranty, the plaintiff would have been entitled to nominal damages only because the cause of the loss was not the breach. If the representation had been true and the car had had only two owners, he would still have suffered the loss. He had made a bad bargain. 166 The question then arises whether the damages of $100 ought to have been recoverable in tort. In other words, was the plaintiff entitled to recoup the loss resulting from his bad bargain by proceeding in tort as Cooke J found? It can be argued that damages were not recoverable because there was no causal connection between the misrepresentation and the loss. If the representation had been true the plaintiff would still have suffered the loss. Although a plaintiff can sometimes redress the consequences of his bad bargain by suing in tort, it must still be shown that the misrepresentation caused some of the IOSS.167 In Beecham Cooke J stated that "it was reasonably foreseeable . . . that if it had been known that there were more owners [than two] the market value of the car might well have been diminished".168 That was certainly so but, on the facts as stated by his Honour, the greater number of owners did not account for the decrease in value. The answer to the question depends on whether, in order to recover damages in tort for misrepresentation, it is enough that the misrepresentation induces an alteration of position (such as entry into a contract) and 165 Ibid at 581. 166 There is a question, yet to be finally resolved, whether a plaintiff in an action for breach of contract can elect to claim damages in respect of his relian~e interest (wasted expenses) or restitution interest where that would protect him against the consequences of his bad bargain. (The prevailing view is that he cannot; see Ogus, The Law of Damages (1973) at 351-352, L Albert & Son v Armstrong Rubber Co 178 F (2d) 182 at 189 (1949), Bowlay Logging Ltd v Domtar Ltd (1978) 87 DLR (3d) 325, C & P Haulage v Middleton [1983] 1 WLR 1461 and CCC Films (London) Ltd v Impact Quadrant Films Ltd [1985] 1 QB 16.) Even so, it is difficult to see how there can be a reliance or restitution claim in contract for money paid with a deduction for value received when the contract has been substantially performed as in Beecham. Furthermore, it is to be noted that the situation in Beecham differs from the example discussed by Ogus at 351 and the earlier example at 287. In Beecham the defendant's breach of contract did·· not cause any part of the $100 to be lost, whereas in the examples given by Ogus there is a causal connection between the failure to perform and the wasting of a substantial part of the expenses claimed. 167 See the examples cited by Treitel, supra n 111 at 274 and Ogus, supra n 166 at 287 where. this requirement is satisfied. 168 Supra n 164 at 581. 412 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 loss flows from that alteration, or whether there must be some more immediate causal connection between the misrepresentation and the loss. It will be contended below that, while there is some authority for the latter view that damages must be confined to the amount by which the contract was less valuable by virtue of the misrepresentation, in principle and on the balance of authority the former is the better view. On this basis Cooke J's award of damages in Beecham was correct. 169 The plaintiff was induced by the defendant's misrepresentation to enter into a contract which he would not otherwise have entered into and as a result suffered loss - he paid $1,400 for a car worth $1,300. According to the tort measure of damages he was entitled to be put in the financial position he would have been in if the tort had not been committed - the amount by which the value of the car was less than the price paid. 2 Authorities against recovery in Beecham The only Commonwealth authority directly in point that the writer has found is contained in dicta of the New Zealand Court of Appeal in Dimond Manufacturing Co Ltd v Hamilton. 170 This case concerned an action for negligent misrepresentation which induced the plaintiffs to buy company shares. After noting that damages were to be assessed in accordance with the tort measure of price paid minus value, Thrner J said: 171 And there may in this case be a further adjustment still to be made ... if it can be shown that in making their offer for the shares these purchasers offered a sum in excess of what their true value would have been had the balance sheet been correct; for if, in order to obtain the assets of this particular company, the purchasers were prepared, in making their original offer, to incur some financial loss in any case, this loss should be deducted from that which they ultimately sustained, as· a loss not brought about by the representation. North P expressed a similar view. 172 The only difference between this and the Beecham case is that in Hamilton the plaintiff was assumed to know that he was giving more than market worth but, because he was an anxious buyer, was willing to do so, whereas the plaintiff in Beecham (and the other cases to be considered) was simply ignorant. The writer has also found two interesting American cases which support the view that, in an action for deceit, damages are not recoverable or must be reduced where the excess of price paid over value arises wholly or partly from factors outside the scope of the representation. In Goodwin v Dick173 the plaintiff was induced to buy shares from the defendant by the latter's fraudulent misrepresentation that they were treasury stock. His action· to recover damages for deceit failed because, although the shares were worthless, the evidence established that they would still have been worthless if the representation had been true. It was held by the Supreme Court of Massachusetts that the plaintiff had not established an essential 169 However, it is difficult to go along with his Honour's suggestion (at 581) that it was not necessary to consider the difference between damages in contract and damages in tort. 170 [1969] NZLR 609. 171 Ibid at 638. 172 Ibid at 644-645. 173 107 NE 925 (1915). Damages for Misrepresentations 413 ingredient of his cause of action, "namely, that he suffered damage in consequence of the false representation".174 The significance of the Goodwin decision is reduced, however, by the fact that Massachusetts is one of the jurisdictions in the United States of America where the measure of damages in deceit actions is governed by the "loss of bargain" rule. 175 Indeed, the court in reaching its decision simply applied the loss of bargain formula - "he can recover only the difference in value between the stock which in fact he got and the treasury stock which he would have got if the representation made by the defendants had been true".176 On the other hand, it is interesting that, in commenting on this decision, Professor Palmer states: 177 The court was able to reach this result by a mechanical application of the loss of bargain formula, without explicitly considering the causation issue, but this would not be possi-:ble in a jurisdiction following the out-of-pocket rule. In such a jurisdiction the result would doubtless be the same, since the worthlessness of the stock was not attributable to the misrepresentation. Of somewhat more significance is Davidge v Guardian Trust Co ofNew York 178 which was a decision of the Supreme Court (Appellate Division) of New York, a state which has traditionally favoured application of the out-of-pocket rule in deceit actions. 179 In Davidge the plaintiff bought certain bonds from the defendant company relying on the fraudulent misrepresentation that the bonds were secured by a first mortgage. The bonds were in fact worthless but, even if they had been secured by a first mortgage, they would have been considerably less valuable than the price paid. It was held that the plaintiff was entitled to recover only the sum that the bonds would have been worth if they had been as represented - some 40070 of the price paid. The rest of the loss resulted not from the representation but the plaintiff's own poor judgment. No mention was made of the point that the plaintiff would presumably not have bought the bonds and therefore would have suffered no loss at all were it not for the defendant's fraud. Apart from the above cases and a few isolated observations in texts on the law of misrepresentation,180 the writer has not found any other authorities which would deny recovery in the Beecham situation. 3 Authorities supporting recovery in Beecham As suggested earlier, the balance of authority supports the award in Beecham. That authority dates back to the decision of the English Court of Appeal in 1877 in TWycross v Grant. 181 Although it did not concern a 174 175 176 177 178 179 180 Ibid at 925. See McCormick, supra n 25, para 121. Supra n 173 at 925. The Law of Restitution (1978) para 3.8 (p 266). 120 NYS 628 (1909), reversed on other grounds 96 NE 751 (1911). See McCormick, supra n 175. Kerr on Fraud and Mistake (7th ed 1952) at 496; Spencer Bower and Thrner, The Law o! Actionable Misrepresentation (3rd ed 1974) para 144, but cf para 206 nl, citing Tote!! v Antonas (1952) 87 CLR 647 (to be discussed below) with apparent approval. 181 (1877) 2 CPD 469. 414 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 common law action for misrepresentation, the case is generally recognised as one of the leading authorities on the price paid minus value rule. The plaintiff subscribed for shares in a company on the faith of a prospectus issued by the defendants, promoters of the company. The prospectus failed to disclose certain contracts which the defendants had entered into in their capacity as promoters. This non-disclosure constituted fraud under section 38 of the Companies Act 1867. The shares taken by the plaintiff were worthless and he recovered as damages the total price paid. The interesting feature of the case for present purposes is that counsel for the defendants argued that no damages should be awarded since the plaintiff had not suffered any damage by virtue of the concealment. 182 More particularly, it was argued that . (a) damages were to be measured by the extent to w.hich the assets (and hence the shares) of the company were diminished in value by reason of the payments required to be made out of the company's capital under the concealed contracts, and (b) since the shares were worthless anyway due to serious defects inherent in the project for which the company was formed, no damages were recoverable. This argument was firmly rejected by both the Common Pleas Division 183 and the Court of Appeal. 184 The essence of the plaintiffs complaint was that but for the concealment he would not have bought the shares and, once that was established, he was entitled to recover in respect of the loss that was the natural consequence of the fraud - in this case, the difference between the price paid for the shares and their true value at the time of the sale. Cockburn CJ185 regarded the defendants' contention as founded on what appears to me to be a transparent fallacy. The complaint of the plaintiff is that he has been induced by a suppression in the prospectus, to which the statute attaches the character of fraud, to take shares in an undertaking, which, but for this suppression, he would not have joined, and which has turned out to be worthless a fact which the jury have found in his favour. His grievance is not that he has paid too high a price, but that he has been induced to take shares which, but for the fraud, he would not have taken at all. He is, therefore, in the position of a person who has been induced to take shares and pay the price of them by a fraudulent misrepresentation, and he is, therefore, entitled to recover such damages as have resulted to him from taking such shares. If this damage extends to the entire price paid for the shares he is entitled to recover it. In the course of his judgment Bramwell LJ gave the following instructive example of a case where, despite there being no direct causal connection between the misrepresentation and the loss, the damages claimed were recoverable: 186 By a fraudulent statement that the takings of a business are £50 a week a man is induced to buy it. It turns out that they are worth only £40 a week, and the business is worse 182 183 184 185 186 Ibid Ibid Ibid Ibid Ibid at at at at at 480. 490-491. 504 (per Bramwell LJ) and 542-543 (per Cockburn CJ). 543. 504. Damages for Misrepresentations 415 than worthless. But it also appears that if the takings were £50 a week it would be worthless. Would the damages then be nought? The plaintiff says but for your fraud I should not have touched it. This example is clearly indistinguishable from the Beecham situation. An even more persuasive authority is the decision of the High Court of Australia in Toteffv Antonas187 where the central issue was that presently under consideration. The plaintiff was induced to buy the defendant's business for £2,200 by a fraudulent misrepresentation as to the profits and takings of the business. The written contract apportioned the purchase price between goodwill £200, plant £1,750 and stock £250. At the trial of the plaintiffs action for deceit it was established that the fair value of the business was £900. The difference between price paid and value was therefore £1,300. However, the judge held that, since the misrepresentation related only to the value of the goodwill, the damages should be limited to £200, the amount apportioned by the contract in respect of goodwill. This decision was reversed unanimously by the High Court. The misrepresentation had induced the entire purchase and the plaintiff was entitled to the full difference between price paid and value. It was immaterial that there was no representation concerning the plant and stock which had obviously been overvalued in the written contract. Although the facts of Toteff differ from Beecham in that the representation did have some direct effect on the value of the transaction, the reasoning of the High Court is clearly applicable to both situations. Central to that reasoning was the proposition that in an action for tortious misrepresentation the plaintiff is entitled to recover as damages a sum representing the prejudice suffered in consequence ofhis altering his position in reliance upon the misrepresentation. He is entitled to say that but for the misrepresentation he would not have entered into the transaction and, as a result, the focus of the court's inquiry, so far as damages are concerned, must be on what loss flows from the action of entering into the transaction. In Toteffthe effect of the misrepresentation was more than to induce the plaintiff to pay £200 for goodwill. He was induced to pay £2,200 for the business as a whole and, as that business had a real value of £900, the difference of £1,300 was recoverable. Some further support for this view is to be found in the leading New Zealand case of Canavan v Wright. 188 Although the present issue did not arise, it is interesting that Adams J began his instructive judgment by observing: 189 In my opinion damages for fraudulent misrepresentation must, in general, be assessed on the basis of the net loss resulting to the plaintiff by reason of his having acted in reliance on the representation. Where the tort consists in inducing him to enter into a single transaction, the net loss is the difference between what he gains and what he loses by entering into that transaction. It is the entirety of the transaction that matters, with all its gains and losses. If, by a fraudulent misrepresentation that one of two articles is worth £5, a man is induced, in one indivisible transaction, to buy two articles 187 (1952) 87 CLR 647. 188 Supra n 124. 189 Ibid at 802. 416 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 for £10, the misrepresented article being in fact valueless, but the other worth £10 or more, then, unless there be some recoverable consequential damage, the damages are nil, because the plaintiff has suffered no loss by reason of the fraud. He has got full value for his money, and cannot sub-divide the transaction into two parts for the purposes of a claim for damages. Conversely, if both articles were valueless the damages amount to £10, even though the misrepresentation applied to one only. He is, of course, not entitled to claim in tort for the profit he would have made if the representation had been true: aliter, if he can found his claim in contract on the footing that the representation amounted to a warranty. Finally, a case with essentially the same facts as the last example given by Adams J came before the Supreme Court of Minnesota in 1894 and the same result was reached. In Wallace v Hallowel/190 the seller of promissory notes executed by A and B fraudulently misrepresented that A was financially sound. No representation was made as to B's financial standing. Both A and B were unable to pay the notes. It was found as a fact that the purchaser would not have bought any of the notes but for the representation. In a well-reasoned judgment Mitchell J rejected the seller's argument that damages should be limited to the difference between the actual value of the property and its value if it had been as represented. It was held that the purchaser was entitled to recover the loss suffered through acting in reliance on the representation. That action was buying both sets of notes and therefore the purchaser was entitled to recover the. difference between their value and the price paid. In the course of his commentary on this decision, Professor Dobbs states: 191 In situations like this, courts would probably have little reluctance to permit the plaintiff to rescind the contract for fraud. If rescission were granted, the plaintiff would return the worthless notes to the defendant and get back his purchase price. Virtually the same thing can be accomplished - financially speaking - if the plaintiff sues for the difference in value between the notes he purchased and the price he paid. If rescission would give him back the full purchase price, there is little or no reason to deny him the financial equivalent in a damage action, which differs only in form and theory. The author then proceeds to consider the counter-argument that the plaintiff in a fraud case should not be put in a better position than if the representation had been true. 192 Probably, however, this is not objectionable in fraud cases, whatever may be the appropriate view in the somewhat comparable contract cases. For one thing, the element of intentional deceit probably warrants a treatment that fully protects the plaintiff from all losses not clearly too remote. For another, the plaintiff, if allowed a recovery of his investment, is put in a position better than if the defendant's representation has been true. But that is not the whole sto~ The plaintiff is not put in a better position than if the defendant had refused to lie. For if A's credit standing was indeed poor, as it was, and if the defendant had not lied about it, the plaintiff may very well have refused to enter the transaction at all, either as to A's notes or as to B's. In such a case, the plaintiff would not have lost his investment. Thus it is far from clear that the plaintiff who gets restitution on facts like these really is given undue protection. 190 58 NW 292 (1894). 191 Supra n 25 at 605. ) 192 Ibid at 605-606. See also the valuable decision of the issue by Moncrieff, Fraud and. Misrepresentation (1891) at 15-17 and 186-188. Damages for Misrepresentations The conclusion from all this probably should be that once cause in fact of loss is established, the plaintiff should be allowed recovery of his investment, even if a benefit of the bargain recovery is denied on remoteness grounds. 4 The position in principle It is submitted that Beecham and the cases discussed in the previous section were rightly decided and that damages should be recoverable in tort for all disadvantages flowing from the contract induced, whether or not those disadvantages were related to the matter misrepresented. It seems quite inconsistent to the writer to treat additional disadvantages as collateral and not related to the misrepresentation while on the other hand holding that compensating advantages, whether appreciated by the plaintiff at the time of the contract or not, are not collateral and have to be taken into account. On this theory, the plaintiff loses both ways. It seems clear that either both should be treated as collateral and not related to the misrepresentation or neither should. On this latter question, it is the writer's view that neither other advantages nor other disadvantages should be treated as collateral. The action induced by the misrepresentation is entry into the particular contract and the effects of this on the plaintiff's position can only be gauged by looking at the whole contract. Unless there is a clear basis on the evidence for believing that the plaintiff would have either obtained the additional advantages or suffered the additional disadvantages anyway, it is proper to take them into account in adjudicating upon the extent of loss. In the case of additional disadvantages such losses are properly attributable to the misrepresentation. We shall return shortly to the question of what constitutes a clear basis for departing from this principle. Acceptance of the above argument does not, however, lead necessarily to a position whereby the courts have to award damages for all losses in any way attributable to entry into the contract or to reduce the award by reference to all advantages ultimately traceable. to that event. Indeed the courts, in fixing value in the formula price paid minus value as at the date of entry into the contract, have made a deliberate decision to treat subsequent gains and losses in value where the cause is "extrinsic" or "independent" as irrelevant or collateral. 193 Similar judgments are also made as far as claims for consequential losses are concerned. In the sale of a business, trading losses may properly be seen as attributable to factors other than the entry into the contract such as the plaintiffs business incompetence and independent facts such as a decision by a major client to relocate in another city. Where such lines are to be drawn is of course part of a general problem of causation and remoteness which is not the writer's concern here. 194 All that is asserted is that in terms of advantages and disadvantages already actually present at the time of the contract these should generally be taken into account whether related directly to the matter misrepresented or not. 193 See the useful explanation by Cockburn CJ in 1Wycross v Grant, supra n 181 at 544-545. See also Potts v Miller, supra n 37 at 298 and Gould v Vaggelas, supra n 85 at 562. 194 See eg Dobbs, supra n 191 at 603-604. 418 Otago Law Review (1987) Vol 6 No 3 Aside from the fact that the writer believes these matters are sufficiently related in a causal sense to the misrepresentation, there are also practical reasons for not treating them as collateral. The price paid minus value formula has the attraction that one element in the equation is readily establishable in most cases. To say that disadvantages unrelated to the matter misrepresented are not to be taken into account would lead to a much more complicated evidential inquiry in that it would require the court to isolate what proportion of the price was paid for the matter misrepresented as well as to value the matter misrepresented. This would obviously be a complicated and artificial inquiry in the vast majority of cases. Indeed, the only practical way of giving effect to such a test would simply be to give the worth of the matter misrepresented but this could be seen as really moving to an expectation level of recovery. It is also worth observing that situations can occasionally arise where misrepresentations operate as important inducements to conclude a contract yet they have neither any effect nor potential effect on the value of what is received. The representation may relate to a matter which is peculiarly important to the representee but which has no capacity to affect the market or objective value of the transaction. They differ from the cases previously discussed in that the latter involved situations where the representation might have affected, but did not on the actual facts affect, value received. In the present cases a requirement that the contract must be less valuable by virtue of the representation would lead to the quite unsatisfactory conclusion that there could be no question of any damages recovery. Consider the following situations where it should be assumed that P would not have entered into the contract but for the misrepresentation. 1 P is induced to buy a house for $50,000 by D's misrepresentation that the house is situated within the zone of a particular school. It transpires that the property is worth no more than $40,000 but the fact that it is not within the school zone does not, and indeed could not, affect its market value. 2 D, a promoter, induces P to take shares in a new company by the fraudulent misrepresentation that (a) X is chairman of the board of directors, or (b) X has subscribed for some shares. The shares are valueless and the company subsequently collapses. The collapse could not have been averted even if X had been chairman or had invested in the company. There can be no doubt that P ought to recover damages on the basis of price paid minus value at the time of the contract. The question does however arise, in light of the discussion in Part III of this article, as to whether acceptance of measures of damages other than price paid minus value should lead to any different view of compensation for additional disadvantages in contracts induced by misrepresentations. Should the defendant, as with the plaintiff, be permitted to move away from price minus value in the sense of showihg that the effect of applying that formula is to compensate the plaintiff for losses above those actually related to the matter misrepresented? Aside from the argument that there is no necessary compulsion to afford to both plaintiff and defendant equivalent opportunities to move away from Damages for Misrepresentations 419 a standard measure, it is also clear that allowing the plaintiff to claim difference in price paid or for a lost opportunity instead of price minus value is not the converse of a defendant pleading that the matter represented did not cause or was not linked to any or all of the plaintiffs loss. Rather, the converse is for a defendant to show that the plaintiff, even if the misrepresentation had not been made, would either have paid the same price anyway or that he would have entered into an equally disadvantageous transaction elsewhere. Of course, if the defendant establishes the first of these he has in effect 'proved that the plaintiff was not induced, except in the rare case where the matter of inducement was in no sense value or price related. As far as the second is concerned, were one to accept it as a defence or in reduction of damages, it would clearly not arise very often. It is simply going to be a rare case in which the defendant is able to prove that the plaintiff, while not entering this transaction but for the misrepresentation, would instead have entered into another disadvantageous contract. Even given an element of foolishness in other aspects of the transaction in question, the court, in the absence of clear proof to the contrary, is almost certainly justified in presuming that were it not for the misrepresentation the plaintiff would not have entered the contract and still had his purchase money available to him. In terms of the cases, it seems that there was probably insufficient evidence in, for example, Beecham, Toteff, or Davidge, that the plaintiff would still have suffered some or all of the additional disadvantages even had he not entered into the particular contract. Simply pointing to some lack of prudence in the particular transaction should not, in the writer's view, be sufficient. The Hamilton example is somewhat more difficult. However, there are two possible answers to it. First, if a plaintiff is prepared to pay more than market value for a commodity, there is a case for treating that as relevant in the ascertainment of actual value for the purpose of the standard formula. In other words, actual value should perhaps be gauged on a basis other than market value. Secondly, even if the plaintiff is actually expecting a loss on the transaction rather than a gain, it is arguable that in tort the court should be as little concerned about those expectations as it is about expectations of profit and it provides no basis at all for substituting a lesser figure for price actually paid in the standard formula.