chapter Economic management using macroeconomic monetary policy 6 6.1 Definition of monetary policy Monetary policy is a macroeconomic instrument operated by the Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA), involving the regulation of the nation’s money and the rate at which credit flows into the economy via the financial sector. Most importantly, monetary policy relies heavily on changes in interest rates to alter the cost, availability and demand for credit (borrowed money). In turn, interest rates have the capacity to alter levels of AD, economic activity, cyclical unemployment and demand inflation. However, as we know, interest rate changes will also affect production costs, business profits and the supply side of the economy. Overall, monetary policy is regarded as a fairly flexible instrument in that it can change direction at quite short notice without requiring the approval of parliament. 204 Economics Down Under Book 2 THE SUPPLY OF MONEY OR CREDIT IN THE ECONOMY Definition of money Money consists of items which can be used for making purchases of goods and services (a medium of exchange). Money also fulfils other functions. For instance, it is commonly regarded as a measure of value (a unit of accounting), it retains its purchasing power fairly well over time (a store of value) and it enables things to be purchased using credit (a standard of deferred payments). Measuring the money supply In Australia, the money supply or volume of money is measured by the RBA and consists of the following components: ■ ■ ■ ■ ■ The volume of coins and notes (cash or money base) held by the non-bank public and deposits of banks with the RBA PLUS The volume of both operating and fixed bank savings deposits EQUALS M3 (one commonly quoted measure of the volume of money) PLUS Net deposits of savings in non-bank financial institutions (NBFIs) EQUALS Broad money (a wide or comprehensive measure of the money supply or volume of money). Knowing changes in the volume of money is relevant when considering factors that affect the level of economic activity and the setting of monetary policy. The process of credit creation How does money come into existence? In the case of cash, the RBA supplies as much currency to the banks as is required to meet the demand. However, these days, we are slowly becoming a cashless society. Today the largest proportion of Australia’s volume of money is deposits of different types with financial institutions. Bank deposits are mostly passbook or accounting entries. These deposits are not backed up with piles of cash sitting idly in bank vaults. Instead, deposits partly come about through the process of credit creation conducted by financial institutions. Assume, for instance, that you make a deposit of money with your bank and gain the advantage of receiving interest on your savings. The bank enters this deposit against your account. Typically, part of your deposit is put aside to ensure that the bank retains enough liquidity (assets easily converted in cash) to meet normal customer withdrawals, to promote customer confidence and to avoid embarrassment by institutions. Since 1998, the liquidity position of all financial institutions has been monitored by the Australian Prudential Regulation Authority (APRA) rather than the RBA. This organisation checks that financial institutions have an effective liquidity management policy in place, as well as ensuring that banks meet varying capital adequacy requirements that reflect the level of ‘risk’ involved with lending. Now, returning to the process of credit creation, the remainder of your savings deposit is lent by the bank to some creditworthy borrower you don’t even know. After paying interest to the bank, this customer then uses the credit to purchase a good or service, by means of a cheque or electronic funds transfer. The seller receiving the money then makes a new deposit within the financial sector, causing the level of total deposits to grow (now consisting of both your deposit plus the one by the seller). Armed again with extra funds which they are keen to lend in order to make a profit, financial institutions may start a second round of the credit creation process. Lending has multiplied the level of deposits which, in turn, are included as part of our volume of money. In addition to this, there are also other sources of credit growth including endorsed bills of exchange. Whatever, when the volume of credit grows quickly, this fuels some types of household and business expenditure. AD (especially C + I) is affected, as is the level of domestic economic activity. It is even possible that inflation may result from too much credit or money in an economy which is already operating at its capacity. This aspect was emphasised by an economic theory called monetarism which for this reason advocated strict government control of the volume of money. By contrast to this worry, it is also true that too little credit growth can strangle activity. The deliberate regulation by the RBA of interest rates on savings deposits and on credit (loans) is one way of ensuring that the growth in AD and economic activity is neither too fast nor too slow to ensure stability. This is an important stabilising feature of monetary policy. CHAPTER 6 Economic management using macroeconomic monetary policy 205 THE FINANCIAL SECTOR AND CAPITAL MARKET Nature and structure of the financial sector The capital market involves the borrowing (demanding) and lending (supplying) of credit at a price or cost which is called the rate of interest. Banks and other types of financial institutions (e.g. building societies, managed funds, superannuation funds, credit unions, insurance companies, finance companies and the stock exchange) play a pivotal role in this market. As can be seen in figure 6.1, the RBA heads the financial sector and uses its monetary policy to help avoid inflation and improve domestic economic stability. Deregulation of the financial system Despite a need for supervision, over the last two decades there has been considerable deregulation of Australia’s financial system. Deregulation involves removing unnecessary government restrictions and other impediments to the efficiency of the Table 6.1 financial system. Deregulation has included the reforms listed in table 6.1. The Reserve Bank of Australia is: • Banker to the government, banks and other NBFIs • Issuer of coins and notes, custodian of overseas reserves • Promoter of domestic stability (especially the 2–3% price stability target) and external stability using monetary policy Banks of different types • Trading/savings banks • Merchant banks • Domestic and foreign banks Other financial institutions • Finance and insurance companies • Building societies and credit unions • Superannuation funds • Managed funds Figure 6.1 The structure of Australia’s financial sector TRY SHORT ANSWER EXERCISE 1, p. 229 000 Landmarks in the deregulation of Australia’s financial system 1981 Campbell inquiry into the financial system recommended widespread deregulation to improve efficiency by strengthening competition. 1983 Martin inquiry reaffirmed the need for deregulation. 1983 The fixed exchange rate system (where the RBA each day determined the appropriate rate for swapping the Australian dollar with other currencies) was replaced with a floating exchange rate system (where buyers and sellers of currencies in the foreign exchange market determine the Australian dollar’s value). However, the RBA reserves the right to use a dirty float (the RBA itself becomes a buyer or seller of Australian dollars) so as to smooth out and affect the exchange rate. 1985 During this year, there were several developments: ■ Sixteen foreign banks were granted bank licences to operate in Australia to create more competition for the major banks in the capital market. ■ The RBA controls which set maximum interest rates on loans and overdrafts were abolished. ■ Direct liquidity ratio controls on banks were streamlined and scaled down. 1986 RBA restrictions governing maximum housing loan interest rates were partly abolished. 1987 The RBA-imposed reserve or liquidity ratio for savings banks was lowered and subsidy to savings banks removed so as not to discriminate against other types of banks. 1989 The RBA eliminated most of the remaining distinctions between trading and savings banks and further reduced the liquidity ratio for savings banks to bring them more into line with other banks. Liquidity arrangements for trading banks were modified and the RBA moved towards prudential supervision and capital adequacy requirements for banks to gradually replace direct liquidity controls. Deliberate variations to liquidity ratios were no longer to be used by the RBA to control bank credit creation and to influence AD and economic activity. 1990 The prime assets ratio (the PAR was part of the RBA’s regulation of bank liquidity) was further reduced but prudential supervision and capital adequacy requirements were tightened to help maintain financial stability and confidence. 1991 The partial privatisation of the Commonwealth Bank commenced via a share float. 206 Economics Down Under Book 2 1993 Additional licences were granted for foreign banks to operate branches in Australia. Foreign banks were encouraged to operate and compete in Australia by the introduction of special tax concessions. Restrictions on the interest rates that could be charged by banks on credit cards were removed. 1996 Stage two of the privatisation of the Commonwealth Bank was undertaken. Banks and building societies found that they faced stiffer interest rate competition in home lending due to the spread of special institutions like RAMS. Additionally, the Wallis Inquiry into our financial system’s efficiency commenced. 1997 Continued conversion of some building societies to bank status added to competition. The Wallis Report was published, generally recommending further deregulation but also recommending modifications to the system of control and prudential supervision of the financial sector. 1998– 1999 The system of having special or official dealers in the short-term money market was abolished and the short-term money market further deregulated. The 3 per cent prime assets ratio (liquidity ratio for banks designed to promote financial stability and confidence among customers) was abolished. However, the Australian Prudential Regulation Authority (APRA) was set up to generally monitor all types of financial institutions to ensure that they have sound policies in place for managing their liquidity and capital adequacy (reflecting the riskiness of particular types of lending). The RBA relinquished this responsibility which was expanded to include NBFIs. Additionally, the Australian Securities and Investment Commission (ASIC) was set up to promote competition, offer consumer protection and the resolution of disputes, replacing the Australian Securities Commission. Soon, the government is expected to create the Council of Financial Regulators (CFR) to oversee financial regulation. 2000 In order to increase competition with banks, credit unions and some other NBFI were given the right to issue cheques in their own name. The RBA and the ACCC also conducted an inquiry into credit card fees. 2001 The Basle Committee released the new capital adequacy recommendations. These reflected risk profiles and credit ratings of borrowers, rather than prescriptive liquidity ratios. 2002 The ACCC/RBA inquiry deemed Bankcard interchange fees set by banks were excessive and secretive. Disclosure is now required to promote greater competition and efficiency. 2004 Recommendations of Basle Committee to be phased in. APRA introduced a new system of prudential supervision for the insurance industry. 2005– 2006 The RBA indicated it was to introduce reforms and regulations for the EFTPOS system and ATM fees and charges. 2007 2008 6.2 The aims of monetary policy The Reserve Bank Act of 1959 sets out the functions of the RBA and its board: . . . to ensure that the monetary and banking policy of the [Reserve] Bank is directed towards the greatest advantage of the people of Australia and that the powers of the Bank . . . are exercised in such a manner as . . . will best contribute to the stability of the currency of Australia; the maintenance of full employment in Australia; and the economic welfare and the prosperity of the people of Australia.’ Given this charter, it seems that RBA policy could be used to pursue any of the government’s economic objectives including price stability, sustainable economic growth, full employment, external stability, efficiency in resource allocation and equity in the distribution of income and wealth. However, in practice, the main aims of RBA policy are much narrower: it is the key instrument used to stabilise domestic economic activity. The pursuit of price stability Since 1993, the RBA has used inflation targeting or ‘fight inflation first’, as the priority guiding changes in monetary policy. These days, inflation targeting means achieving an inflation rate averaging between 2–3 per cent per year over the CHAPTER 6 Economic management using macroeconomic monetary policy 207 course of the business cycle. This is the medium-term aim of monetary policy. Hence, when inflationary expectations exist and there are signs that inflation will exceed the upper end of the target range, the RBA will tighten its stance (i.e. set higher interest rates) in a counter-cyclical way, so as to depress inflationary expectations, slow rising spending and curb economic activity. The pursuit of sustainable economic growth and full employment Only when price stability has actually been achieved, will the RBA turn its attention to other aspects of domestic (i.e. internal) stability such as the pursuit of sustainable economic growth and full employment. Again, achieving these two objectives often means that the RBA adopts a counter-cyclical expansionary stance to stimulate economic activity (without causing an acceleration of inflation or an excessive rise, the CAD and the NFD). The main reason for the RBA giving priority to the control of inflation is that price stability is seen as a precondition for achieving these other objectives. Limiting inflation is seen as the best way to create conditions that maximise the sustainable rate of economic growth and minimise cyclical unemployment. The reasoning behind this approach is simple. For instance, low inflation helps to maintain consumer and business confidence that is needed for a steady rise in spending. Low inflation also discourages speculative activity, promotes adequate saving and attracts resources into productive investment in new plant and equipment. During the past ten years, the RBA’s approach illustrates the idea of controlling inflation as the first step in reducing the severity of the business cycle. For example, with inflation on the rise between late 1998 and August 2000, monetary policy was tightened to slow spending. However, by late 2000 and early 2001, inflation was back on target. The RBA was able to again reduce interest rates and become expansionary to stimulate economic growth and reduce unemployment. However, between late 2001 and late 2006, monetary policy gradually became more contractionary, signalling some concern over the gradual rise in inflation to the upper end of the RBA’s target range. Other aims of monetary policy As also seen in the RBA’s charter, other government economic objectives may sometimes be pursued. However, these are seen as less central aims and are usually sought, first by controlling inflation, and then by promoting sustainable economic growth and full employment. For instance, low inflation, sustainable economic growth and full employment are all helpful for promoting equity in the distribution of personal income. Avoiding severe cyclical fluctuations in economic activity (i.e. maintaining low inflation, sustainable growth and full employment) can also create economic conditions where resources are most likely to be allocated efficiently and productively. Moreover, price stability and domestic stability are beneficial for external stability by helping to limit the size of the CAD:GDP and NFD, and by promoting conditions that help strengthen international competitiveness and the exchange rate. While monetary policy can have indirect effects on all government objectives, it is clear that the main priority involves the pursuit of domestic economic stability. TRY SHORT ANSWER EXERCISE 1, pp. 2, p. 000 229–30 6.3 Specific instruments of monetary policy The RBA has three specific instruments of monetary policy: ■ By far, the most frequently used and powerful policy involves changing interest rates through market operations. ■ A less important monetary measure entails influencing the exchange rate (through a dirty float and changes in interest rates). ■ Additionally, persuasion about the desired direction of lending activities of the financial sector is also used on occasions. 208 Economics Down Under Book 2 RBA ‘market operations’ to affect interest rates Interest rates are central to monetary policy and are used by the RBA to regulate the level of AD and economic activity. In general terms, interest rates represent the cost or price of credit. As such, they are normally determined in financial markets by the demand for credit by borrowers (e.g. households, firms, governments), relative to the supply of credit by How the RBA can increase interest rates — a contractionary stance Assume that the RBA wanted to increase interest rates. First it would announce a rise in the cash rate target, and provide a detailed explanation of its reasons. It would then set out to achieve this target by selling government securities at a discounted rate in the short-term money market. Financial institutions, Cash rate % keen to make a profit, would suddenly find these securities more attractive, because when purchased at a lower price, their yield would rise. This gives owners a better rate of return on their investment. Organisations taking up this good offer would transfer deposits to the RBA, in exchange for receiving government securities. This directly reduces deposits or the supply of cash held by financial institutions in their Exchange settlement accounts. Competition among institutions for limited funds to top up their Exchange settlement accounts would increase the cash rate towards the announced target (see figure 6.2). A rise in the cash rate set by the RBA, is usually indicative of a tighter monetary policy stance and is often used when inflation rises. S1 (reduced supply of cash) S2 (original supply of cash) Increased cash rate E2 Original cash rate E1 RBA undertakes sales of government securities, lowering the supply of cash in the money market and lifting the cash rate. D1 (demand for cash) Q2 Q1 Quantity of cash (Q) Figure 6.2 How the sale of government securities in the short-term money market can increase the cash rate (a contractionary stance) How the RBA can lower interest rates — an expansionary stance Suppose that the RBA wanted to reduce interest rates and so it announced a lower cash rate target, again giving the reasons for its decision. To reach this target, the RBA would need to buy back government securities from the financial institutions operating in the short-term money market. RBA buying would cause the price paid for securities to increase, thereby lowering their yield, so that financial institutions would be happy to get rid of them. When this occurs, deposits are transferred from the RBA to financial institutions, in exchange for government securities. As shown in figure 6.3, this increases the supply of cash or the level of deposits held by financial institutions in their exchange settlement accounts, leaving the market with excess funds. The consequence of this would be a fall in the cash rate towards the desired RBA target. Lower rates are often announced when economic activity is weak and usually reflect an easier or looser monetary policy stance. Cash rate % lenders (e.g. households and businesses who place their savings in financial institutions). However, the RBA has the capacity to affect interest rates generally, by setting the cash rate. The cash rate is the interest rate that applies to a specialised market called the overnight, or short-term money market. This rate depends on the overall supply of cash (i.e. deposits) in the overnight money market which, in turn, is controlled by the RBA through its market operations (to be explained shortly). These activities affect the size of special balances held by each major financial institution (e.g. banks, building societies, finance companies and superannuation funds) in its Exchange settlement account with the RBA. But how does this complex system work to affect interest rates? First, more background information is needed. Each major financial institution is required to keep its Exchange settlement account with the RBA in credit (for which it receives interest). These account balances exist mainly for the purpose of settling transactions between institutions during the day’s trading. These transactions are caused mainly by the movement of cheques (e.g. a customer with one bank writes out a cheque payable to a customer at another bank). In turn, through the Reserve Bank information and transfer system (RITS), cheque amounts are either credited or debited electronically against the Exchange settlement account for each institution. This settlement process does not affect the total level of cash or deposits in these accounts (since rises in deposits for one institution are offset by a fall in deposits belonging to another). As a result, transactions of this type do not cause deposited funds to become either scarcer or more plentiful, and so they do not affect the cash rate. What can add to or reduce the overall size of cash deposits in Exchange settlement accounts are the activities between financial institutions and the RBA. For example, when companies and individuals use cheques or electronic funds transfer to pay taxes to the government, the overall level of balances in exchange settlement accounts falls. In reverse, when the government through the RBA pays tax refund cheques into individuals’ bank accounts, overall balances in Exchange settlement accounts grow. However, while these transactions may have some effect on the cash rate in the short-term money market, they do not allow the RBA to actually control or determine the cash rate. The main determinant of the cash rate (along with other interest rates generally) is the daily conduct of market operations that directly affect the supply of cash in the short-term money market. Market operations involve the RBA either buying back or selling secondhand government securities or bonds to members of the RITS through the short-term money market. Here you should think of securities or bonds as simply government IOUs for particular amounts of money that earn a given rate of interest over a period of time. Armed with this understanding, let us take a look at the three positions or stances on interest rates that the RBA may want to adopt in its regulation of economic activity. S1 (original supply of cash) S2 (increased supply of cash) Increased cash rate E1 Lower cash rate E2 RBA undertakes buying back of government securities, increasing the supply of cash in the market and cutting the cash rate D1 (demand for cash) Q1 Q2 Quantity of cash (Q) Figure 6.3 How the buying back of government securities in the short-term money market can decrease the cash rate (an expansionary stance) CHAPTER 6 Economic management using macroeconomic monetary policy 209 The RBA decides to smooth out or alter the exchange rate using a ‘dirty float’. Using a ‘dirty float’ in the foreign exchange market, the RBA becomes a net buyer (D) of A$s, or reduces its net sales of the A$ causing the dollar to appreciate. Using a ‘dirty float’ in the foreign exchange market, the RBA becomes a net seller (S) of A$s, or reduces net purchases of the A$ causing the dollar to depreciate. A stronger A$ than otherwise will tend to increase the current account deficit and inflation, but slow AD, economic activity and employment. A weaker A$ than otherwise will tend to reduce the current account deficit, lift AD, economic activity and export incomes, but cause inflation to rise. The effect of a dirty float involving the RBA buying the A$ in the foreign exchange market to help moderate downward instability in the exchange rate is illustrated below: The effect of a dirty float involving the RBA buying the A$ in the foreign exchange market to help moderate downward instability in the exchange rate is illustrated below: RBA Buys P2 P1 S–A$ D1– D2– A$ A$ Q1 Q2Quantity of A$ Exchange rate (A$) 2. The RBA wants to decrease the exchange rate or to prevent a further erratic and/or uninformed rise in the A$. Exchange rate (A$) 1. The RBA wants to increase the exchange rate or try to prevent a further erratic and/or uninformed fall in the A$. S1of A$ S2–A$ RBA Sells ER1 ER2 D–A$ Q1 Q2 Quantity of A$ Figure 6.4 RBA intervention in the foreign exchange market to affect the exchange rate How the RBA can keep interest rates steady — a neutral stance Often, however, the RBA just wants to keep interest rates steady since they are already at an appropriate level, given current economic conditions. In this case, the RBA’s daily selling and buying back operations will seek to avoid changing the overall supply of cash in the short-term money market, so that the current cash rate remains unchanged. When the cash rate is held steady at around 4.5 per cent to 5.5 per cent, this is considered to be a fairly neutral stance and within the normal range for a healthy economy. In this situation, there are no significant events requiring corrective action by the RBA. By contrast, if the 210 Economics Down Under Book 2 cash rate is kept above or below this neutral range, there must be inflationary or deflationary circumstances. By being able to control the cash rate in this way, RBA policy has the capacity, through a ripple effect, to influence other commercial interest rates (e.g. those on home mortgages, overdraft, credit cards and savings deposits) that are generally applicable elsewhere in the financial sector. As we shall see, changing monetary policy’s stance through variations in the cash rate target is a very handy instrument for stabilising the level of spending and economic activity. A ‘DIRTY FLOAT’ BY THE RBA TO AFFECT THE EXCHANGE RATE In international trade, the exchange rate is the price at which the Australian dollar is swapped against other currencies. As part of the deregulation of Australia’s financial system, 1983 saw the introduction of a floating exchange rate. In the case of a clean float, the Australian dollar’s value is dictated by the forces of supply and demand for our currency in the foreign exchange market. In other words, sellers (suppliers mostly living in Australia) and buyers (often living overseas) of our currency interact in the market to negotiate the equilibrium price or exchange rate. At equilibrium, the quantity bought and the quantity sold are exactly equal, and the market is cleared of either a shortage or glut of Australian dollars. However, as part of its monetary policy, the RBA still retains the option of a dirty float. A dirty float is where the RBA tries to affect the exchange rate by becoming a net buyer or seller of the Australian dollar in the foreign exchange market. Nowadays, it is mainly reserved for special occasions when changes in the dollar are uninformed and erratic, leading to great uncertainty in international transactions. These principles are illustrated in figure 6.4. How the RBA can lift the exchange rate If the RBA was faced with a situation where the Australian dollar was falling in an erratic and misinformed way, it is likely that it would intervene in the foreign exchange market. Using a dirty float, the RBA would increase its net purchases of our dollar (or reducing net sales of our dollar would have a similar effect), by using its limited foreign exchange reserves. As we know, increased demand or buying of the dollar relative to its supply, will tend to raise our exchange rate (cause an appreciation) because our currency becomes relatively scarcer. Sometimes, this may be all that is needed to smooth the dollar and arrest the fall, especially if interest rates are also increased at the same time. For instance, during September–October 2001, there was heavy selling of our dollar on the foreign exchange market. This fall reflected the perception among traders that our currency was overvalued given the downturn in the US, Japan, Taiwan and Singapore. To an extent, the market was correct, but the RBA felt that the dollar’s fall to US$0.49 was a misinformed overreaction. Without firm support from the RBA at the time, the currency may have gone into a free-fall. There are also other circumstances where a higher dollar may be desirable. For one thing, a stronger dollar makes imports relatively more competitive against our exports. Keeping the dollar fairly steady also helps to slow both cost and demand inflation. Although it seems reassuring that the RBA can affect the exchange rate in this way, the very limited level of overseas reserves held by the RBA places a constraint on the amount of support that can be given to the Australian dollar. Besides, in the end it is the market, not the RBA, that will have the final say as to the exchange rate. How the RBA can lower the exchange rate If the situation above was reversed and it was felt that the market was misinformed, causing the Australian dollar to be too high, a dirty float may again be warranted. This time, instead of buying the dollar, the RBA may intervene in the foreign exchange market by increasing its net sales of our currency (or reducing net purchases of the dollar would have a similar effect), so as to put downward pressure on our exchange rate. If successful, a weaker dollar would tend to make exports and capital inflow more attractive against imports and capital outflow. This has the potential to increase AD and reduce our current account deficit (CAD). However, there is the risk that a lower dollar will ignite inflationary pressures. CONTINUED RBA DEREGULATION OF THE FINANCIAL SECTOR Between 1982 and 2007, continual deregulation of the financial sector has been an important strategy aimed at improving the efficiency and competitiveness of domestic interest rates (see table 6.1, p. 206). This approach does not really come under monetary policy as such; it is better classified as part of microeconomic policy. Even so, it has had an enormous impact on how monetary policy is conducted. Instead of relying on direct controls over interest rates and the exchange rate, the RBA now relies on more subtle intervention in various markets. RESERVE BANK OF AUSTRALIA ‘PERSUASION’ OVER FINANCIAL SECTOR LENDING LEVELS When the RBA makes public comment in the media, typically businesses and those involved in the capital market listen and respond accordingly. In the past, there have been occasions where the RBA has tried to influence the direction and levels of lending by financial institutions so that government economic objectives are more effectively pursued. Sometimes there are attempts to talk up lending and spending; other times, an effort is made to talk down activity. TRY SHORT ANSWER EXERCISE 1, p. 230 3, 000 6.4 Using monetary policy to improve domestic economic stability Domestic economic stability means simultaneously achieving: ■ price stability (annual average CPI rise between 2–3 per cent over the economic cycle) ■ sustainable economic growth (annual average rate of economic growth around 4 per cent) ■ full employment (unemployment rate of between 5 and 6 per cent of the labour force). The RBA’s monetary policy is often seen as the main macroeconomic instrument, used in the short to medium term, to help stabilise the general level of economic activity. It does this mainly by regulating the strength of AD in a counter-cyclical way, using either an expansionary or contractionary stance. This helps to ensure that AD does not outstrip the growth in Australia’s productive capacity (AS). In doing this, the RBA is mainly guided by its desire to ‘fight inflation first’ and keep the annual average inflation rate to within its 2–3 per cent target (over the duration of the economic cycle). Hence, in any particular year, it may be a little higher than 2–3 per cent, but in others, a bit less. This medium-term aim of monetary policy is called inflation targeting. However, once inflation is safely within this range, the RBA may turn its attention to pursuing other aspects of domestic stability. In fact, it will usually try to achieve the highest sustainable rate of economic and employment growth that is possible, without causing inflation to accelerate. CHAPTER 6 Economic management using macroeconomic monetary policy 211 Generally, a rate of economic growth averaging around 4 per cent with unemployment between 5 and 6 per cent should be achievable and consistent with the objective of price stability. So, how does the board of the RBA, when it meets every two weeks, go about deciding whether to adopt an expansionary or contractionary stance? Typically, it uses a checklist of important indicators. CHECKLIST After weighing up often conflicting evidence, the RBA then adopts a particular policy stance. This could be contractionary (to slow AD, economic activity and inflation during an upturn), expansionary (to lift AD and economic activity in a downturn), or a neutral stance (to keep economic activity steady). These three positions are summarised in the figure 6.5. DESCRIPTION OF ITEMS 1. Inflation The RBA takes a careful look at quarterly trends in the CPI, the underlying inflation rate, costs of materials used in manufacture and wage costs. 2. National spending and production A close watch is kept on the growth in AD relative to the economy’s productive capacity or AS. The RBA monitors trends in private consumption and investment spending (as well as recent changes in consumer and business confidence as leading indicators of future expenditure), retail trade, housing approvals and household debt. 3. Labour market Changes in labour market conditions are seen as important, including the unemployment rate, employment growth, job vacancies and labour force participation rates. 4. Budgetary policy stance Account is taken of budgetary policy outcomes (e.g. surplus or deficit) and the stance (e.g. expansionary or contractionary) being adopted by the Treasurer. 5. International developments Overseas trends in inflation, economic activity, interest rates and other events are reviewed, as well as changes in Australia’s exchange rate and CAD. The RBA’s monetary policy stance, indicated by the monthly cash rate target (%) RBA contractionary stance — five rises in interest rates from 4.75% (1999) to 6.25% (late 2000) when economic activity and inflation were rising RBA contractionary stance — eight rises in interest rates from 4.25% (2002) to 6.25% (late 2006) when inflation was tending to accelerate due to strong AD when there was increasingly little unused productive capacity Cash rate target (%) 8 6 4 2 0 RBA expansionary stance — five cuts in interest rates from 7.5% (1996) to 4.75% (late 1998) when AD and economic activity slowed 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 RBA expansionary stance — six cuts in interest rates from 6.25% (2000) to 4.25% (late 2001) when AD and economic activity slowed 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Figure 6.5 Changing the RBA’s monetary policy stance to help improve domestic economic stability STANCE OF MONETARY POLICY 1. Contractionary or tighter monetary policy stance (e.g. 1999–2000, 2002–07) 212 THE MAIN INDICATORS OF THIS POLICY STANCE RBA announces an increase in its cash rate target (above the normal range) and proceeds to push up interest rates using its market operations involving net sales of government securities in the short-term money market. Economics Down Under Book 2 AIM OF THE POLICY STANCE The aim here is to use higher interest rates to reduce inflation to 2–3 per cent. This works mainly by slowing AD and economic activity, and through other transmission mechanisms. STANCE OF MONETARY POLICY THE MAIN INDICATORS OF THIS POLICY STANCE AIM OF THE POLICY STANCE 2. Expansionary or looser monetary policy stance (e.g. 1996–99, 2000–02) RBA announces a reduction in its cash rate target (below the normal range) and proceeds to bring down interest rates by its market operations involving net repurchases of government securities in the short-term money market. The aim here is to use lower interest rates to help lift economic activity and reduce unemployment, without increasing the inflation rate. Again this occurs by boosting AD and other transmission mechanisms. 3. Neutral (normal) monetary policy stance. RBA sets its cash rate target within the normal range of about 4.5 per cent to 5.5 per cent for a healthy economy. It then holds interest rates steady by appropriate market operations. The aim here is to neither stimulate nor slow AD and economic activity. Monetary policy is adopting a fairly neutral role. Source: Data compiled using various RBA Monthly Bulletins (table A.2). Let us now investigate further how the RBA has actually implemented its counter-cyclical stabilisation policies involving changes in the cash rate during the past 10 years or so to 2007, as shown in figure 6.5. The effects of these measures will also be illustrated in figure 6.6 using the AD–AS diagram. A contractionary monetary policy can slow AD, economic activity and inflation In theory, inflation accelerates when AD grows faster than the economy’s productive capacity or speed limit (i.e. currently an average rate up to about 4 per cent a year). This is shown in figure 6.6, by AD2, and GDP1–2. At this point, prices rise (i.e. from P1 to P2) because excessive levels of expenditure cause widespread shortages of goods and services (demand–pull inflation). Cost inflation too can occur when there are shortages of resources (e.g. wages costs rise when unemployment falls too low). To help stop demand inflation (‘inflation targeting’ is the RBA’s main priority), monetary policy needs to gradually adopt a tighter or more contractionary stance designed to slow expenditure (i.e. from AD2 to AD1), without jeopardising economic growth (i.e. this remains at GDP1–2) and full employment. In tightening its stance, typically the RBA places greatest reliance on its interest rate policy. This was more or less the type of situation that occurred between 1999 and 2001, and again between late 2001 and early 2007. As shown in figure 6.5, the RBA raised its cash rate target eight times during this latter period, due to excessively strong AD contributing to inflation in an economy close to its capacity (peaking at 6.25 per cent in August 2000 and 6.25 per cent in November 2006). The steps involved in lifting interest rates are as follows: Step 1: The tightening of monetary policy will start by the RBA announcing an increase in its cash rate target in the shortterm money market. This indicates the RBA’s new stance. Step 2: Next, the RBA will set out to achieve this higher target by undertaking market operations involving net sales of government securities to financial institutions, at an attractive lower or discounted price. This lifts the yield (percentage return on money) on securities and makes ownership of them more desirable. AS General price level P2 Demand inflation AD2 = excess AD that causes P1 P0 AD0 = weak AD and recession. This requires an expansionary monetary policy stance to lift spending an inflationary boom. This is corrected using a contractionary monetary policy stance to slow spending and reduce inflation. AD1 = ideal levels of spending as a result of successful countercyclical monetary policy GDP0 = GDP1 and GDP2 = the economy is in a the economy is at its recession with high productive capacity unemployment Real GDP/national output Figure 6.6 Using monetary policy in a counter-cyclical way helps to reduce cyclical instability in economic activity. CHAPTER 6 Economic management using macroeconomic monetary policy 213 Step 3: As financial institutions transfer money to the RBA in exchange for government securities, there is a shortage of cash deposits in their exchange settlement accounts. They must then compete among themselves for limited funds, in order to maintain positive balances in their accounts. The shortage of cash then drives up interest rates in the overnight money market. Step 4: A higher cash rate then spreads to other interest rates in the financial market like a ripple effect. Rates paid on mortgages, credit cards, business overdrafts and savings accounts, all rise. Step 5: The final aspect of this tighter monetary policy stance involves what is called the transmission mechanism or the ways higher interest rates actually work to slow inflation. As shown in figure 6.7, there are at least three of these: 1. Higher interest rates tend to slow economic activity (e.g. between 1999–2000 and 2002–07) by increasing the level of saving and reducing the level of credit-sensitive spending (i.e. C + I) that relies heavily on borrowing. This slows AD (as seen in figure 6.6, removes shortages of goods and services, and reduces demand inflation. 2. Higher domestic interest rates relative to those overseas, tend to cause the A$ to appreciate (e.g. between 2002 and early 2007). This happens because Australia has become even more attractive to foreign investors who are seeking our better rates of return. This increases the demand for the A$ relative to its supply in the foreign exchange market, causing an appreci- ation of the currency. In turn, a higher A$ slows inflation in two ways. For one thing, the cost of imports is cheaper for households and firms. This reduces cost inflation. Demand inflation also tends to ease with a higher $A. This is because sales of our exports are reduced relative to our spending on imports. 3. Higher interest rates can work to slow inflation by helping to reduce inflationary expectations in the community. People become confident that the RBA will not let inflation take hold. Indeed, during both 1999–2001 and 2002–07, rising interest rates did help to keep inflationary expectations in check, thereby improving domestic economic stability. Although the RBA relies mostly on higher interest rates to control inflation, there are also two other less important instruments available. One other approach is that RBA could apply a dirty float to try to lift the exchange rate for the A$. This would involve the RBA buying the A$ in the foreign exchange market, by using its reserves of other overseas currencies. The rise in the demand for dollars relative to their supply, makes the currency scarcer, thus lifting the price or the exchange rate. In turn, a stronger dollar slows inflation in two ways. First, it makes exports dearer and less attractive relative to imports. This tends to reduce net exports and AD, ease shortages of goods and services and slow demand inflation. Second, a stronger currency makes imported household items cheaper and also lowers the cost of imported materials and equipment used in production by local firms. This, too, eases the pressure of costs on inflation. The RBA increases interest rates 1. Higher interest rates slow inflation by affecting the decision to save or spend. Most importantly, higher real interest rates encourage or reward greater saving and they lower credit-sensitive household consumption and business investment spending by making borrowing more expensive. Both C and I spending are deferred. This slows AD and economic activity, removes shortages of goods and services, and reduces demand inflation. 2. Higher interest rates tend to slow inflation by pushing up the exchange rate. Higher domestic rates tend to lift the exchange rate by: – attracting overseas investment and money capital into the country which lifts the demand for the A$ in the foreign exchange market, causing a rise in the dollar – slowing total expenditure and hence imports, thereby reducing the supply of the A$ in the foreign exchange market – increasing savings and reducing dependence on overseas borrowing and debt repayments. In turn, a stronger A$ helps to make imports cheaper, relative to exports. This not only slows AD and demand inflation (by slowing net exports), but it also eases cost inflation pressures. 3. Higher interest rates can reduce inflationary expectations. When people get accustomed to inflation and expect it to continue, it becomes a self-fulfilling prediction. Individuals then take action to protect their purchasing power from the effects of rising prices. Wage earners push for more pay, adding to cost and demand inflation. Asset buyers push up property and share prices, fuelling further inflation. By contrast, higher interest rates depress inflationary expectations because they affect peoples’ perceptions and signal the determination of the RBA to control inflation. Inflation slows down Figure 6.7 Some of the transmission mechanisms whereby a tighter monetary policy stance controls inflation 214 Economics Down Under Book 2 An expansionary monetary policy can lift AD, economic growth and employment In theory, applying a more expansionary stance for monetary policy can counteract a downswing or recession in the business cycle. As shown on the AD–AS diagram in figure 6.6 (p. 213) the RBA can use lower interest rates to stimulate AD. Starting on this diagram at AD0, GDP0 and P0, a reduction in interest rates would tend to accelerate expenditure from AD0 to AD1, and lift national production from GDP0 to GDP1 (without much increase in the inflation rate). Clearly, domestic economic stability should be improved and recession avoided. In more detail, the main steps involved with an expansionary approach are as follows: Step 1: The loosening of monetary policy will start by the RBA announcing a reduction in its cash rate target for the shortterm money market. Step 2: The RBA will then set out to achieve this lower target by undertaking market operations in the short-term money market involving net repurchases or buying back of government securities from financial institutions. This action will tend to lift the price of securities, reduce the yield and encourage institutions to get rid of their government securities. Step 3: As the RBA transfers money to financial institutions (in exchange for their government securities), there is a surplus of cash deposits in exchange settlement accounts. The glut of cash drives down interest rates in the overnight money market. Step 4: A lower cash rate spreads in a ripple effect to other interest rates in the financial market. Step 5: Finally, a looser monetary policy stance involving reduced interest rates should tend to stimulate economic growth and reduce unemployment. There are at least two important transmission mechanisms: 1. Lower interest rates tend to boost economic activity by accelerating AD. This happens because lower rates discourage saving and encourage creditsensitive C and I spending (that rely on borrowing). In turn, this tends to cause retail sales to rise and stocks to fall. Firms should respond by lifting production (GDP) and employing more resources, including labour. Indeed, the RBA estimates that a real cut in the cash rate of 1 per cent, helps to accelerate economic growth in GDP by around 0.8 per cent. 2. As seen in 2001–02, a cut in domestic interest rates relative to those overseas causes a fall in our exchange rate. This is partly because there is more capital outflow from Australia seeking better returns elsewhere. This leads to increased sales of the A$ in the foreign exchange market, causing the exchange rate to depreciate. In turn, AD rises due to exports becoming more attractive relative to imports. Again this is helpful in stimulating economic activity during a downturn, thereby helping to improve domestic economic stability. The RBA could also reinforce expansionary interest rate cuts to correct a downturn, by using two other less important measures. First, if it was felt that the exchange rate was too high, theoretically, the RBA could directly weaken the currency a little by selling off the dollar in the foreign exchange market using a dirty float. In turn, a lower exchange rate would tend to stimulate exports relative to imports, thereby strengthening AD. Second, the RBA may use its influence (persuasion) to encourage more lending by the financial sector and to talk up the economy by painting an optimistic picture. Persuasion like this might also help recovery and improve domestic stability. Monetary policy can sometimes promote domestic stability by increasing AS While monetary policy is primarily a macroeconomic measure designed to regulate AD and reduce the severity of the business cycle, it can also have effects on the supply-side of the economy. For instance, if the RBA were able to cut interest rates after it had brought inflation under control (e.g. as in 1996–99 or 2001–02), this would tend to reduce production costs for firms with bank overdrafts, enhance competitiveness, and strengthen business profitability. Firms would then be more likely to expand their operations and be less likely to close. As a result, structural unemployment should be lower, thanks to improved supply-side conditions. Using the AD–AS diagram in figure 6.8, this would result in the outward shift in productive capacity (i.e. from AS1 to AS2). Equilibrium would now occur at a higher level of GDP (i.e. a shift from GDP1 to GDP2) and at a lower level of inflation (i.e. P1 to P2). Domestic economic stability should be improved. AS1 — original supply-side conditions General price level Another monetary policy strategy is that RBA could use its influence or persuasion (e.g. during 1999–2000 and 2004–05) to issue warnings of caution about the excessive levels of lending by the financial sector, or high spending by households and firms. This could help talk down economic activity and inflation, and thus improve domestic stability. P1 AS2 — how increased productive capacity and supply can result from RBA reductions in interest rates Cost inflation P2 AD1 = ideal levels of spending GDP1 = original sustainable rate of economic growth and employment GDP2 = increased sustainable rate of economic growth Real GDP/national output Figure 6.8 How lower interest rates could have a beneficial supply-side effect on domestic economic stability CHAPTER 6 Economic management using macroeconomic monetary policy 215 Unfortunately, however, it is not always possible for the RBA to lower interest rates in this way. Sometimes, the RBA is forced to lift interest rates to slow demand inflation. In this situation, the policy would contribute to higher production costs, business closures, increase structural unemployment, and an inward shift in the AS line (i.e. a decrease in productive capacity with a shift from AS2 to AS1). Other advantages of monetary policy Apart from promoting domestic stability by regulating the level of AD, there are also some other advantages of using monetary policy to improve domestic economic stability. Short implementation lags for monetary policy Long time lags (i.e. delays in recognition, implementation and impact of policy) are a worry for policy makers since they reduce the effectiveness of RBA stabilisation measures. Policy may end up being mismatched to the economic situation that it is meant to correct. Instead of measures being counter-cyclical in their impact on AD, they may become pro-cyclical and actually worsen domestic instability (e.g. policy reduces AD in a recession and increases it in a boom). However, a real advantage of using changes in interest rates to steady economic activity is that their implementation lag is quite short; with delays of only two weeks between one RBA board meeting and the next. This lag is much shorter than discretionary changes in budget tax rates or budget outlays, for example, where implementation may take the Treasurer a year or more. Despite this, there are still long impact lags for changes in the cash rate. Often monetary policy is able to complement budgetary policy as a domestic stabiliser Ideally, monetary and budgetary policies should both work together as macroeconomic measures to help stabilise AD, slow inflation, maintain a sustainable rate of economic growth and deliver full employment. Policies are usually most effective if they are compatible (i.e. complementary) rather conflicting. In the 10 or so years to 2007, often monetary and budgetary policies have been supportive of each other. For instance, in response to rising inflation and strong economic growth during 1999–2000 and again between 2002 and late 2006, both budgetary and monetary policies were tightened simultaneously Table 6.2 to slow the growth in AD. The RBA increased the cash rate while the Treasurer grew the size of the budget surplus. Monetary policy changes are often less political than discretionary fiscal measures The RBA board and its governor are meant to be independent and are not members of the currently elected government. Being outside the political system, monetary policy, therefore, has the advantage over budgetary policy of having fewer political constraints in setting the cash rate target. By contrast, budgetary changes in tax rates and specific government outlays made by the Treasurer (as a member of the elected party and government) are highly politicised. This consideration can sometimes restrict the use of fiscal measures needed for promoting better internal stability. Monetary policy works best in slowing inflation Monetary policy is better at slowing inflation than it is in stimulating economic growth during a recession. This is because rises in interest rates designed to slow economic activity, are felt directly by borrowers who are forced to find extra money to meet interest repayments on existing loans. This makes it a very effective policy because spending on other things just has to be reduced and new borrowing is deferred. By contrast, cuts in interest rates that reduce repayments, do not force people to spend more and there may be no increase in borrowing. It is also possible that once interest rates get close to zero as in Japan (2002–04), there is almost nothing else that monetary policy can do to stimulate economic activity, if people choose not to spend. HAS MONETARY POLICY SUCCESSFULLY PROMOTED DOMESTIC ECONOMIC STABILITY? It is very difficult to measure the success or otherwise of the RBA’s monetary policy in promoting domestic economic stability (i.e. the simultaneous achievement of sustainable rate of economic growth, price stability and full employment). This is because there are so many local and international influences on the economy. However, perhaps we could start our policy evaluation by looking at the statistical data contained in table 6.2. Indicators of trends in domestic economic stability 1996– 97 1997– 98 1998– 99 1999– 2000 2000– 01 2001– 02 2002– 03 2003– 04 2004– 06 2005– 06 Economic growth (% of GDP) 3.8 4.5 5.2 4.0 1.9 3.8 3.2 4.1 2.7 2.8 Inflation (% of CPI) 1.3 0.0 1.2 2.4 6.0 2.8 2.7 2.8 2.5 4.0 Unemployment (% of labour force) 8.3 8.0 7.4 6.6 6.4 6.7 6.1 5.8 5.3 5.1 YEAR 2006– 07 2007– 08 Source: Data derived from ABS, 1350.0. 216 Economics Down Under Book 2 Some strengths Some commentators would say that the figures in table 6.2 lend support to the successful application of monetary policy in the years to 2007. For instance, the RBA consistently and correctly applied its measures in a counter-cyclical way that was designed to improve domestic economic stability. For example, a contractionary stance (involving higher interest rates) was always used to slow inflationary upswings in activity when spending was running ahead of production (e.g. as in 2002–07). This meant that inflation was held down and averaged only 2.6 per cent per year. Despite two inflationary spikes of 6 per cent and 4 per cent in 2000–01 and 2005–06 respectively, this figure was well within the government’s 2–3 per cent target. As for sustainable economic growth and full employment, again the RBA can be proud of its achievements. Although a bit below the 4 per cent target rate, the average 3.7 per cent rate of economic growth has been held at the highest sustainable rate that would not cause inflation. The observation that rates of growth have been a bit slower than expected in the last four out of five years was due only to the fact that the economy had little unused productive capacity. Besides, economic growth over these years has still been fast enough to cut unemployment to a 32-year low (down to only 4.4 per cent in April 2007), create 2 million new jobs and allow for the highest participation rate ever achieved. Some weaknesses Despite monetary policy’s general success in the years leading up to 2007, critics point to some of its weaknesses. The problem of long impact lags for monetary policy Although the implementation delay is quite short for changing the cash rate target, the impact lag for monetary policy is quite long Table 6.3 and nowadays, more variable following financial sector deregulation. For example, the RBA estimates that a 1 per cent reduction in interest rates will take nearly three years to have its full expansionary impact and to lift GDP’s growth by 0.8 per cent. After one year, the impact is about 40 per cent and even after two years, the impact has only reached 80 per cent. This is also complicated by the fact that the impact delay of a given change in interest rates is variable. This is partly because it is affected by the state of consumer and business confidence. For example, a 1 per cent rise in the cash rate designed to slow inflation, will have either less effect or take longer to work when confidence is strong, than it will when confidence is weak. In reverse, even reductions in the cash rate to zero per cent (as in Japan between 2001 and 2005) are almost powerless to raise spending when confidence is really low. The point here is that long impact lags involved with changes in interest rates, may sometimes cause counter-cyclical policy to become pro-cyclical. This would destabilise the economy. Sometimes monetary policy is undermined by budgetary policy On some occasions, successful monetary policy can be undermined by budgetary policy. An obvious instance of this was the conflict that appeared to exist between these two policies during 2005 and 2007. As shown in table 6.3, budgetary policy involved a significant cut in the size of the budget surplus from $15.8 billion (2005–06) to $13.6 billion (revised estimate) for 2006–07 to only $10.6 billion for 2007–08 (budget estimate). The budget also included very large discretionary cuts in personal income tax and rises in infrastructure spending. Strangely, this less contractionary fiscal stance came on top of contractionary RBA rises in interest rates in March 2005 and May 2006. The Treasurer was also blamed for two further rises in the cash rate target announced in August and November 2006. Some commentators even suggested that political considerations played a role in the tax cuts during this instance. The conflict between the directions of budgetary and monetary policies BUDGETARY POLICY STANCE 2005–07 MONETARY POLICY STANCE 2005–07 The 2005–06 budget (announced in May 2005) Contractionary surplus of $15.8 billion March 2005 Cash rate target = 5.5 per cent The 2006–07 and 2007–08 budgets (announced in May 2006 and May 2007) Less contractionary surpluses of $13.8 billion (2006–07) and $10.6 billion (2007–08) (including large tax cuts and extra G2 spending on infrastructure) May 2006 A more contractionary rise in the cash rate target to 5.75 per cent A more contractionary rise in the cash rate target to 6 per cent A more contractionary rise in the cash rate target to 6.25 per cent August 2006 November 2006 Source: Data derived from RBA Bulletin, November 2006. CHAPTER 6 Economic management using macroeconomic monetary policy 217 There are also other aspects of conflict between budgetary and monetary policies. For example, conflict can occur when governments run large budget deficits to stimulate activity and employment. Financing these deficits typically requires increased government borrowing, often locally. With limited savings or credit available, upward pressure could unintentionally be exerted on domestic interest rates. This crowds out private sector borrowers, thus contradicting the original expansionary aims of budgetary policy. It also undermines the RBA’s efforts to lower interest rates and stimulate the economy. In reverse, contractionary surplus budgets may tend to cause interest rates to fall or rise less quickly than otherwise (e.g. perhaps 2001–02 to 2006–07). This may result in crowding in by borrowers and increase spending, undermining the RBA’s monetary stance. Conflict between objectives can create problems In pursuing one economic objective, monetary policy can undermine the achievement of other government goals. Take the following situations: ■ Higher interest rates may well slow expenditure and reduce demand inflation. However, as a supply-side factor, rises in interest rates on business overdrafts also add to the production costs for firms. In order to cover higher costs and protect profit margins, some businesses may be forced to increase the price at which they sell their goods and services, adding to cost inflation. This reduces the effectiveness of monetary policy. Additionally, higher interest rates may discourage business investment, reduce business expansion, undermine profitability and lead to the closure of some firms. This slows economic growth and reduces AS. Furthermore, when firms close down or try to cut staff costs, structural unemployment rises. Clearly, higher interest rates also have negative effects on domestic stability. ■ A decision to raise domestic interest rates relative to those overseas in order to slow inflation, may attract a flood of capital inflow, cause the A$ to appreciate, lead to a rise in the CAD and NFD, and undermine the achievement of external stability (e.g. 2002–06). In reverse, a cut in interest 218 Economics Down Under Book 2 rates to stimulate economic and employment growth, may cause an exodus of investment funds seeking higher returns abroad, weaken the currency’s exchange rate and add to inflation. Consideration of the conflict that can exist between some government objectives, may limit the ability of the RBA to use monetary policy to pursue domestic stability. Monetary policy works less directly than budgetary policy Critics note that monetary policy is less effective in overcoming recessions. This is because cutting interest rates only works very indirectly on the level of spending, by making interest repayments cheaper. People are not forced to spend more. Indeed, even rates of zero per cent, as in Japan between 2002 and 2005, hardly whipped pessimistic borrowers into a spending frenzy. At this rate, Japanese monetary policy was powerless to do any more to aid recovery and so reliance was placed on expansionary budgets. Monetary policy is a blunt and imprecise instrument Unlike budgetary and microeconomic policies that can surgically target particular sectors, industries or areas (e.g. rural sector, textile producers) that are causing problems, monetary policy is blunt and imprecise. For example, it treats all borrowers of credit in the same way, whether it be to finance household consumption or for business investment in new equipment. The failure to make this distinction makes it rather clumsy. In addition, it is possible that only some (not all) Australian states need their expenditure restrained, at a point in time. This was the case in 2006 and 2007 when unemployment in the booming economies of WA and the ACT was around 3 per cent, but it was above 6 per cent in Tasmania where economic growth was quite slow. Here we have a two-speed Australian economy. Tasmania could probably do without the recent rises in interest rates, but it will not get any choice about the matter. TRY SHORT ANSWER EXERCISE 1, pp. 4, p. 000 230–31 6.5 Using monetary policy to improve external stability For Australia, external stability means paying our way in international financial transactions without this impacting adversely on the exchange rate or on the size of the CAD and NFD. Specifically, the objective means aiming for: ■ a relatively small CAD:GDP ratio (around 3–4 per cent) ■ a sustainable NFD where heavy interest repayments abroad are avoided ■ helping to ensure that the dollar behaves predictably and preferably retains its purchasing power. Although monetary policy can affect the exchange rate, the size of CAD:GDP ratio and even the NFD, its impact is less direct and overall. It is not the most effective policy available to promote external stability. Budgetary and microeconomic policies are probably more effective. Even so, we will now take a look how RBA measures might try to operate in this area. interest rates are also a production cost for most local firms. This pushes up domestic costs and prices, relative to imports coming from countries where interest rates are lower. Exports are depressed and imports rise. In addition, higher domestic interest rates attract foreign capital inflow and tend to push up the A$, making our exports less attractive relative to imports. In turn this also tends to worsen the CAD, increase the NFD and weaken external stability. Having noted these weaknesses throws some doubt on how effective monetary policy is in promoting external stability. This may be why budgetary or microeconomic policies seem to have been the preferred strategies for promoting external stability during the past 10 years to 2007. Limiting cyclical rises in AD might reduce external instability Perhaps the main way monetary policy can be used to promote external stability is by using it to improve internal stability. If AD and economic activity grow too quickly in an economy operating at its capacity (i.e. during a boom), external stability quickly deteriorates. Typically, this is reflected in a cyclical rise in the CAD:GDP ratio and a fall in the exchange rate. This is because when AD grows too fast and outstrips production or AS, there are widespread shortages of goods and services and excess expenditure spills over onto imports. As a result, there is a cyclical rise in the CAD and weakening of the A$. In addition, cyclically strong spending locally means that there are fewer goods and services available for export, again pushing up the CAD. However, by applying a more contractionary monetary stance, this cyclical problem, externally, may be reduced. For instance, if the RBA increased interest rates, this would tend to reduce spending and economic activity, in turn causing imports to grow more slowly and releasing extra production for export. In addition, higher interest rates help slow inflation and, in one way, make our exports relatively more competitive against imports. This too should help to reduce the CAD. The RBA certainly has raised interest rates on several occasions over the past 10 years. For instance, there were eight consecutive rises in the cash rate target from 4.75 per cent in late 2001, to 6.25 per cent in late 2006. This occurred at a time when there was strong spending growth and the economy was approaching its productive capacity. National expenditure was tending to run ahead of the total production supplied, causing a blowout in the CAD. Hence the use of contractionary monetary policy may have helped to promote external stability and curb the cyclical rise in the size of the CAD. Even so, there are real problems of using higher interest rates (e.g. as between 2001 and early 2007) to reduce the CAD and to lift the exchange rate. Unfortunately, higher rates have an adverse supply-side effect on local firms and reduce Australia’s international competitiveness. The reason is that Smooth out erratic changes in the A$ An unstable and unpredictable exchange rate means that the cost of international transactions is hard to determine until the last moment. This discourages export sales and may increase the CAD. However, you may recall that in these circumstances, the RBA may use a dirty float to help smooth out uninformed and erratic swings in the dollar. For example, an unpredictable, unwarranted and dramatic drop in the exchange rate could be partly steadied through intervention by the RBA involving increased buying of our currency in the foreign exchange market. In reverse, an upward surge that could worsen the CAD might be moderated by RBA selling off the currency. The RBA did just this on a number of occasions between 1996 and 2007. For instance, between 1999 and 2000, it was busy buying up Australian dollars in the foreign exchange market (assisted by higher interest rates) to try to stop the exchange rate plunging to an all time low (i.e. the TWI fell to 49.7 points in 2000–01). In reverse, there was intervention to slow the rise in the A$ in 2004–05 through sales of the currency by the RBA. CHAPTER 6 Economic management using macroeconomic monetary policy 219 HAS MONETARY POLICY SUCCESSFULLY PROMOTED EXTERNAL STABILITY? of Australian exports. These actions by the RBA should have helped to improve external stability. Given that monetary policy has been mainly used to promote domestic stability, it would be unfair to blame it for Australia’s external weaknesses shown in table 6.4. Besides monetary policy, there were also many other influences affecting external stability in the past 10 years. Despite doing what it could, commentators have highlighted the limitations of using contractionary monetary policy to pursue external stability. Some weaknesses Some strengths Certainly between 1996 and 2007, monetary policy did what it could to promote external stability. After all, it helped to achieve domestic economic stability, a situation where conditions are more favourable for achieving external stability. For instance, contractionary rises in interest rates (e.g. 2002–late 2006) helped to limit the increase in AD. This reduced the spillover of excess spending onto imports in an economy near its capacity. In addition, monetary policy successfully promoted price stability (i.e. the average annual inflation rate was only 2.6 per cent), thereby helping to maintain the competitiveness Table 6.4 Higher domestic interest rates can increase the CAD and NFD Foremost, when the RBA raised interest rates to slow spending, as it did between 2001 and early 2007, this had mixed effects on external stability. As already noted, although higher rates can reduce the cyclical rise in the CAD, they also add to external structural problems. Higher interest rates in Australia relative to those overseas, cause foreign capital to rush in and take advantage of relatively better returns here for foreign investors. This pushes up the A$, makes our exports less attractive relative to imports, and causes the CAD and NFD to become even bigger. This was generally seen between 2001–07. In addition, increases in interest rates for business overdrafts, drive up production costs for many local firms. This reduces the competitiveness of our exports against imports, further adding to Australia’s structural CAD. Monetary policy and Australia’s external instability 1996– 97 1997– 98 1998– 99 1999– 2000 2000– 01 2001– 02 2002– 03 2003– 04 2004– 05 2005– 06 1. CAD:GDP ratio for Australia (%) — the government’s target = around 3–4 per cent) 3.3 4.1 5.7 5.1 2.7 3.1 5.1 5.5 6.2 2.5 2. CAD ($ billions) 17.6 22.8 33.6 32.6 18.1 20.7 40.2 46.8 57.4 54.4 3. TWI for the exchange rate at June (1970 = 100 points) 56.7 57.9 58.4 53.3 49.7 52.3 59.4 59.1 64.5 62.2 4. A$ exchange rate with the $US 0.75 0.61 0.66 0.60 0.51 0.56 0.67 0.69 0.76 0.74 5. Ratio of NFD to GDP for Australia (%) 39.5 40.7 39.1 43.7 45.3 45.3 47.1 46.6 48.3 52.2 Changes in the RBA’s cash rate target (interest rates at July) 6.00 5.00 4.75 4.75 6.00 5.00 4.75 4.75 5.25 5.50 YEAR 2006– 07 2007– 08 5.75 Sources: Data derived from the ABS 1350.0, RBA Bulletin. 220 Economics Down Under Book 2 Pursuing external stability can conflict with other economic objectives If external stability is pursued using rises in interest rates for example, this may conflict with the achievement of other government economic objectives like efficiency in resource allocation. Higher interest rates discourage business investment spending on new plant and equipment, and thus slow rises in efficiency. In addition, increases in interest rates slow AD and may undermine economic and employment growth. This may even reduce equity in income distribution. Budgetary and microeconomic policies are more effective for external stability Another reason why external stability is not the main aim of monetary policy is that budgetary and microeconomic policies are far more effective and powerful. Contractionary monetary policy has problems, as we have seen. It is too blunt and only works indirectly by slowing expenditure levels and lowering inflation to improve our competitiveness. However, for the past decade, fiscal measures and microeconomic reforms (including the promotion of national savings, cuts in tax rates, labour market deregulation, the ACCC, privatisation and corporatisation of the public sector, and tariff cuts) have had a more powerful influence by tackling the on-going structural problems causing the large CAD and NFD, and the long-term depreciation of our currency. The ability to prop up the A$ is limited Nowadays, our exchange rate is determined by the forces of demand and supply for the A$ in the foreign exchange market. However, on some occasions when the exchange rate was falling very rapidly (e.g. 1999–2001), the RBA may decide to intervene using a dirty float to smooth out erratic or uninformed changes. However, there are limits to the support that can be given to the currency in the event of a serious collapse. For one thing, the RBA has only limited reserves of foreign currency or gold that can be used for purchasing A$. Even then, there is no guarantee that when the buying intervention has ended that the currency will not again decline. The market, not the RBA, makes the final judgement as to where the dollar comes to rest. The impact lag of interest rates may be long In the event of excess AD causing inflation, the spillover onto imports and a rise in the CAD, there is the problem of long time lags between the RBA increasing interest rates, and its impact. Higher rates can take up to 2–3 years to be effective, especially if consumer and business confidence are strong. TRY SHORT ANSWER EXERCISE 1, pp. 5, p. 000 231–32 6.6 Using monetary policy to improve efficiency in resource allocation A nation must use its resources efficiently in order to best satisfy society’s wants and maximise its material living standards. An annual rise in national productivity by 1.5 to 2 per cent is considered a good performance. There are four main types of efficiency that come to mind: allocative, technical, dynamic and inter-temporal. Although there are some general things that monetary policy can do to lift efficiency in resource allocation, it is probably not as effective as other measures like microeconomic reform or budgetary policy. There are three main ways that monetary policy can impact on efficiency in resource allocation. Stabilising AD and the level of economic activity We know that resources are not allocated efficiently if economic activity is either too weak (recession) or too strong (boom). CHAPTER 6 Economic management using macroeconomic monetary policy 221 In a recession, resources are not used efficiently: unemployment causes some resources to lie idle and be wasted ■ there is often labour hoarding and over staffing at the start of a downturn, so efficiency falls ■ recession undermines business confidence and investment spending needed to buy new equipment, and to increase worker productivity. Alternatively, resources are also allocated inefficiently if there is an inflationary boom: ■ Here, inflation causes resource owners to direct their inputs into more speculative and less productive uses (e.g. shares, property, antiques) that will maximise their returns. From the economy’s point of view, this is less desirable than capital resources flowing into setting up new companies and expanding productive capacity. ■ Moreover, if high inflation pushes up interest rates, this deters investment spending, and very low unemployment of say less than 5 per cent, may cause some workers to slacken off. In both cases, efficiency suffers. The point is that optimum efficiency is more likely to occur when there is domestic economic stability. As already noted, counter-cyclical monetary policy has been fairly effective in promoting internal stability. Certainly when the RBA reduces interest rates in a downturn as occurred in 1996–99 and 2001–02, this should have helped to increase efficiency in resource allocation. ■ Foremost, cheaper credit for businesses encourages confidence and promotes investment spending on new plant and equipment incorporating the latest technology. This leads to capital deepening and better worker efficiency (i.e. an increase in GDP per hour worked). ■ Lower interest rates not only cause a rise in investment, but also encourage household consumption spending (e.g. on new cars, construction of houses, holidays and electrical appliances). Together, these conditions lead to stronger AD. In an economy where there is some unused productive capacity, this reduces unemployment or idle resources and increases efficiency. By contrast there is a dilemma when the RBA decides to raise interest rates as in 2002–07 to check inflation. If not controlled, inflation encourages less productive, speculative investment. Eventually, too, continued inflation erodes consumer and business confidence, perhaps leading to recession. The RBA, therefore, feels compelled to lift its cash rate target. However, the problem of increasing interest rates to check inflation is that they encourage saving and also reduce the level of productive investment that is necessary to increase business efficiency. Indeed, when interest rates are lifted, it is possible that productive investment (where returns are often smaller) will be slowed even more than speculative investment (where returns are often higher). This has negative effects on productivity, perhaps as seen between 1999 and 2006. Despite this dilemma, the fact remains that the RBA has actually delivered price stability during the years, 1996–2006. Average inflation has been kept within the 2–3 per cent target. Because of this, firms have ultimately been able to enjoy the lowest real overdraft interest rates in over 30 years. In turn, this has helped to lift productive efficiency by directing more resources into investment in new technology. ■ 222 Economics Down Under Book 2 Boosting efficiency by deregulation of the financial sector Most economists believe that strong levels of competition in markets help to promote efficiency in resource allocation. Firms need to try and outdo their competitors through greater productivity. This does not usually occur when there are monopolies, oligopolies or restrictions in the market. In the twenty-five years to 2007, there has been ongoing financial sector deregulation. This has included: ■ issuing more operating licences to foreign banks ■ floating the exchange rate ■ converting of some building societies into banks ■ allowing non-banks to issue cheques ■ deregulating credit card operations ■ introducing prudential supervision of financial institutions to replace inflexible liquidity ratios ■ privatising government banks. While this is more accurately classified as a microeconomic reform rather than a monetary policy, it has affected the operation of the financial sector, and has sought to stimulate competition, keep interest rates for borrowers lower than otherwise and increase the efficiency of Australia’s capital market. The exchange rate’s effects on efficiency The exchange rate alters how competitive local goods and services are against those imported from overseas. ■ If the exchange rate falls, as happened between 1999–2001, for example, it is easier for Australian producers to compete, and there is less pressure to cut costs and boost efficiency in order to survive. Even so, a lower A$ means that some firms that import materials and equipment used in manufacture, find that they have higher production costs making them less competitive. ■ In reverse, when the exchange rate appreciates, as occurred between 2002–07, this makes it far more difficult for local firms to survive. They have to make even greater efforts to lift their efficiency, although they are helped by the fact that a higher A$ makes it cheaper for them to import inputs (e.g. equipment) used in production. Although the RBA no longer directly regulates the exchange rate (i.e. we have a floating exchange rate), changes in interest rates and its decisions to intervene in the foreign exchange market through a dirty float, also affect the pressures on firms to improve their productivity. HAS MONETARY POLICY SUCCESSFULLY PROMOTED EFFICIENCY IN RESOURCE ALLOCATION? The trends in how efficiently Australia uses its resources shown in table 6.5 are affected by hundreds of local and international factors, not just monetary policy. It is simply not possible to accurately link cause and effect. Besides, of all government policies, RBA strategies are probably the most indirect and least important. Table 6.5 Trends in Australian productivity PHASE AND YEAR Annual average change in labour productivity by cycle — Australia Annual change in multifactor productivity by cycle — Australia 1985–89 PHASE 1 1989–94 PHASE 2 1994–99 PHASE 3 1999–2004 PHASE 4 0.8 2.2 3.2 2.2 0.7 0.9 2.1 1.0 2004–?? PHASE 5 Sources: Data derived from B Dolman, L Rahman and J Rahman, ‘Understanding productivity trends', pp. 40–41, calculated from ABS national accounts and from Groningen Growth and Development Centre and the conference board, January 2006. Some strengths Some weaknesses Looking at the data, it is clear that there are cyclical phases in Australian productivity. After record efficiency levels in phase 3 between 1994 and 1999, there was a significant slowdown during phase 4 to 2004. Even so, the conduct of monetary policy is unlikely to be the main cause of this trend because, generally, the RBA has created near record domestic economic stability (i.e. price stability, sustainable economic growth and full employment) where conditions were very favourable for efficiency in resource allocation. It reduced interest rates to stimulate economic growth and cut unemployment or idle resources, when there was unused productive capacity and no risk of inflation. The RBA only increased interest rates when its hand was forced by rising prices (e.g. 1999–2000, 2002–06). Despite this, however, interest rates were still far lower than in the previous 30-odd years. For instance, in the past 10 years, the average business overdraft rate was only 8.6 per cent, against about double this rate in the late 1980s. Recently, this encouraged higher levels of investment in new equipment and technology. In addition, the on-going deregulation of the financial sector helped to spur on competition and greater allocative efficiency in the use of Australia’s money capital. There is little else that monetary policy could have been expected to do in this regard. Although the RBA has generally done what it can to improve efficiency in resource allocation, monetary policy has weaknesses. Higher interest rates can control inflation but may discourage investment When inflation approaches 3 per cent a year or more, the RBA is forced to lift interest rates. It did this eight times in the period, 2002–07. Unfortunately, higher interest rates discourage investment spending, which is essential for lifting technical efficiency. In turn, this may also lead to higher unemployment and idle resources, and it adds to the production costs of some firms (who have borrowed credit from the bank in order to produce). Limited efficiency from deregulation The continued deregulation of the financial sector in the years to 2007, probably lifted efficiency in allocating Australia’s capital resources and meant lower interest rates than otherwise. This helped to promote higher levels of investment. However, critics claim that only limited efficiency benefits have been actually passed on to consumers of financial services. In supporting these claims, mention is made of the extraordinarily high profit margins and returns in the banking sector, along with greedily high bank fees and charges by some international standards. Monetary policy works only indirectly to increase efficiency Unlike microeconomic policy that very directly cuts costs and encourages efficiency, monetary policy operates in less direct ways. It works mainly by creating a better domestic economic stability where resources are more likely to be used efficiently. Monetary policy is a blunt and imprecise instrument Budgetary and microeconomic policies can accurately target specific areas where efficiency is weak. For example, there could be reduced tariffs for the car industry, special assistance to sugar producers or lower rates of company tax. However, RBA measures are not surgically precise and cannot single out particular problems for attention. Cuts in interest rates, for instance, do not just stimulate investment in new equipment, but they also direct more resources into speculative areas and into consumer goods, housing and services, not all of which are as beneficial for efficiency. TRY SHORT ANSWER EXERCISE 1, p. 232 6, 000 CHAPTER 6 Economic management using macroeconomic monetary policy 223 6.7 Using monetary policy to improve equity in personal income distribution The government’s objective of an equitable income distribution means that everyone has access to basic goods and services needed to maintain reasonable living standards. Monetary policy is not nearly as useful in promoting equity as say budgetary policy. It can only work indirectly by keeping both unemployment and inflation at low levels. In other words, when domestic economic stability is well achieved, conditions are most favourable for achieving an equitable distribution of income. So how might the RBA’s measures actually work? HOW MONETARY POLICY MIGHT REGULATE AD TO KEEP INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT DOWN Equity is unlikely to exist when there is rapid inflation or high unemployment. Keeping inflation low High inflation rates averaging above 2–3 per cent, reduce equity for several reasons. For one thing, the prices of basic goods and services (the cost of living) often rise faster than the incomes of ordinary families. Their real purchasing power is reduced. For the poor, food, rental accommodation, home ownership, cars, transport, electrical goods, education, health care, entertainment, access to the law and childcare, for example, often become less affordable and accessible, so their living standards fall. By contrast, some individuals, like speculators in shares and property, find that their incomes rise faster than inflation generally, so that their purchasing power is increased. Inflation arbitrarily lowers equity for some individuals, but improves it for others. Fortunately, the RBA’s monetary policy involving higher interest rates (via increased net sales of government securities in the short-term money market) has successfully controlled inflation by slowing excess AD and easing shortages of goods and services. Indeed, inflation targeting has meant that Australia’s average annual inflation rate has been only 2.6 per cent for the period, 1996 to 2006. This should help to promote equity. Keeping economic activity up and unemployment low You may recall that there are many reasons why both cyclical and structural unemployment undermine equity and people’s access to basic goods and services. Unemployment causes families to suffer from the awful effects of a sudden drop in disposable income and purchasing power. As individuals move from average weekly earnings of around $1050 or from the minimum weekly wage of around $512 (for early 2007), on to inadequate welfare benefits for the unemployed of perhaps $200–250 a week for a single, access to basic goods and services is dramatically reduced, and increased poverty is likely to occur. The wealth of the unemployed also tends to shrink because assets like property, pos- 224 Economics Down Under Book 2 sessions, savings and shares are sold to pay bills, leading to greater inequality. However, by cutting interest rates and adopting a more expansionary stance that stimulates spending, monetary policy can help reduce cyclical unemployment and improve equity. With lower interest rates, households and firms increase their borrowing and spending. In turn, this lifts national production, employment and incomes. Moreover, on the supply-side, reducing interest rates tends to ease cost pressures, improve profitability, encourage business expansion and results in the fewer closures of firms. This helps to lower structural unemployment, again promoting equity. Overall, it should be noted that the RBA’s policies have recently helped to get unemployment down to its lowest level in around 32 years (i.e. only 4.4 per cent in April 2007). Again, by promoting domestic stability, monetary policy has helped to promote greater equity. By keeping inflation and unemployment down, the RBA is helping to increase the real purchasing power of market incomes received by the poor. By contrast, government redistribution measures in the budget (e.g. progressive taxes, welfare benefits) alter the final distribution of income. HAS MONETARY POLICY SUCCESSFULLY PROMOTED EQUITY IN INCOME DISTRIBUTION? For the past 10 years to early 2007, it is hard to prove the precise causal connection between monetary policy and any change in the distribution of Australia’s personal income. This is because there are lots of other important domestic and international variables that have also had an impact. Some strengths Certainly it would appear that monetary policy has helped to create general economic conditions domestically, that are very favourable to an equitable income distribution. As noted, the RBA has applied interest rates in a counter-cyclical way, successfully regulating AD and economic activity. In the past 10 or so years to early 2007, booms and recessions have been avoided. Monetary policy has helped to maintained strong economic growth, low unemployment (this is at a 32-year low) and rising incomes, while at the same time delivering low inflation (average of 2.6 per cent). Although it is undeniable that inequality in personal incomes has increased as shown in figure 6.9, this does not necessarily mean that equity has decreased. In fact it is likely that the poor have never been so rich or as able to afford as many basic goods and services, as at present. However, by contrast, it would be hard to imagine that equity would be as strong if there were high inflation rates averaging over 8 per cent (as it did in the 1980s) or if unemployment was at 11 per cent (as it was in 1992–93). disposable household income — 1996–97 to 2002–03 Australia’s changing level of equivalised mean disposable income ($) per week by quintile — 1996–97 to 2002–03 Gini coefficient of equivalised household disposable income Linear (Gini coefficient of equivalised household disposable income) 1996–97 — Mean level of equivalised disposable income ($ per week) 0.315 0.31 2006–07 2005–06 2004–05 2003–04 2002–03 2001–02 Quintile 5 0.28 Quintile 4 0 Quintile 3 0.285 Quintile 2 200 2000–01 0.29 1999–2000 400 0.295 1998–99 600 0.3 1997–98 800 0.305 1996–97 Gini coefficient 1000 Quintile 1 Mean weekly income ($) by quintile 2002–03 — Mean level of equivalised disposable income ($ per week) Figure 6.9 Trends in Australian income distribution Source: Data derived from ABS, 6523.0 (2003–04). Some weaknesses Although acknowledging the general contribution of monetary policy to improving equity between 1996 and 2007, economists recognise its weaknesses. Monetary policy is less effective than budgetary policy Monetary policy is certainly not the most efficient or precise means of redistributing final incomes equitably. RBA measures can help to create general economic conditions (i.e. low inflation and unemployment) where equity is likely to be maximised, and the poor can better afford to access basic goods and services. However, budgetary measures are far more powerful in reducing the Gini coefficient. Here we think of the effects of direct progressive taxes that are used to help pay for direct welfare support and indirect benefits for the poor (e.g. free or cheap health, education). Budgetary measures can also better target specific groups of individuals who are in need of help. Monetary policy failed to control asset speculation Between the late 1990s and early 2007, there was a remarkable growth in share and property prices. This enabled many among the richer quintiles, to increase their share of household wealth and make considerable capital gains. The rise in asset prices was driven by cheap credit, confidence and strong economic growth, in part, the by-products of successful monetary policy. However, for ordinary families, the affordability of home ownership has been reduced by house prices rising faster than their incomes. Indeed, research released in 2006 shows that average mortgage repayments as a percentage of household income, are now higher than when interest rates were double back in the latter 1980s. This is because the size of the mortgage is now much bigger due to inflated house prices. This has tended to diminish equity and deprive lower income families of home ownership. Financial sector deregulation has done little for the poor Critics of deregulation draw attention to the dramatic rise in bank fees and charges, especially on small accounts held typically by the poor. In addition, these people have little bargaining power when trying to negotiate low-interest loans. On the other side, one cannot help but notice the unusually high profits made by banks in the 1990s and 2000s. In general, the main beneficiaries of these profits are shareholders who are mostly drawn from middle and upper income groups. Moreover, deregulation and stiffer competition has caused banks to cut staff, adding to structural unemployment and hence inequity. TRY SHORT ANSWER EXERCISE 1, p. 232 7, 000 CHAPTER 6 Economic management using macroeconomic monetary policy 225 6.8 School Assessed Coursework There are two SACs to be completed for VCE Economics Unit 4, one for each of the two outcomes. SAC 1 is about macroeconomic policy and SAC 2 covers microeconomic policy. Assuming that you have completed chapters 5 and 6 about budgetary and monetary policy (i.e. macroeconomic policy), you are now in a position to tackle SAC 1. With this in mind, your teacher must eventually select one of the following assessment tasks: ■ an essay ■ a written report ■ problem-solving exercises. ■ a test with multiple-choice and short-answer questions ■ an evaluation of print and/or electronic media. This SAC will be marked out of 50. Teachers are also urged to check the latest VCAA’s Assessment guide to ensure that all assessment requirements are met fully. To help prepare you for the end-of-the-year examination and to provide some guidance for SAC 1, several sample tasks have been included in this section of your text. For instance, chapter 6 (about monetary policy) contains: ■ multiple-choice test items ■ short-answer test questions ■ an essay question ■ some possible questions relevant for completing a written report. Finally, this section of your text also contains a wide range of other learning activities (e.g. web quests, debates, concept maps, quiz, etc.), to help make learning more effective, interesting and relevant. MULTIPLE-CHOICE test questions school assessment tasks and learning activities Instructions: You may like to complete the following revision questions. Using the multiple-choice answer grid below, select the letter (A, B, C, D) that represents the most appropriate answer for each question by marking this with a tick (✓). Question 1 Monetary policy relates to: A macroeconomic measures introduced by the Treasury B macroeconomic measures of the RBA C measures that mostly affect the flows of credit between borrowers and lenders D both (B) and (C). Question 2 Higher domestic interest rates will tend to: A accelerate demand inflation B raise the production costs of some businesses and the cost of living for many households C discourage overseas borrowing and weaken the exchange rate for the Australian dollar D increase employment. Question 3 Despite some RBA efforts to support the currency, there was a 20 per cent depreciation of the Australian dollar against the US dollar between December 2000 and March 2001. Answer grid QUESTION 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 A B C D QUESTION A B C D 226 Economics Down Under Book 2 B The RBA increases its net repurchases of government securities in the short-term money market as part of its market operations. C There should be discouragement of lending by the financial sector. D The RBA buys the A$ in the foreign exchange market. Question 4 Which combination of monetary strategies is most expansionary? A The RBA increases sales of government securities in the short-term money market and increases sales of the Australian dollar in the foreign exchange market. B The RBA dramatically increases its buying back of government securities in the short-term money market and tries to persuade the financial sector to increase lending. C The RBA cuts its net sales of government securities in the short-term money market and increases its support of the Australian dollar in the foreign exchange market. D There were attempts by the RBA to discourage lending by the financial sector. Question 9 In 2002–06, the RBA sought to achieve a higher official cash rate target. During this time, it increased official interest rate target on eight separate occasions because: A demand inflation was low B the unemployment rate was rising C economic activity was slowing D significant unused productive capacity did not exist in the economy. Question 5 Nowadays, public confidence in and the security of household savings which are deposited in the financial sector are partly protected by: A RBA variations in liquidity ratios B the Australian Prudential Regulation Authority (APRA) which monitors capital adequacy and the management of liquidity C both (A) and (B) D neither (A) nor (B). Question 6 Measures involving the financial sector which can have a beneficial supply-side effect on cost inflation may include: A a dirty float to support or drive up the Australian dollar B the extension of competition in and continued deregulation of the financial sector C neither (A) nor (B) D both (A) and (B). Question 7 Faced with high and rising cyclical unemployment and no threat of inflation, the RBA would most likely: A undertake operations in the short-term money market designed to achieve a lower cash rate target B increase support for the Australian dollar involving buying our dollar in the foreign exchange market C talk down financial sector lending D try all of the above measures. Question 8 In itself, which one of the following measures would not be appropriate for the Australian economy experiencing 5 per cent economic growth and 8 per cent inflation? A The RBA increases its net sales of government securities in the short-term money market as part of its market operations. Question 10 In 2004–05, the RBA was involved with intervention in the foreign exchange market involving net sales of Australian dollars. Externally, this would tend to: A increase the CAD B improve the terms of trade C help exporters D force local firms to become even more efficient and cut costs in order to compete internationally. Question 11 Which of the following would be a constraint on the effectiveness and introduction of a contractionary monetary stance in promoting domestic economic stability during a period of rapidly rising economic activity? A The existence of very strong consumer and business confidence B A forthcoming election which is tipped to be very closely contested C Already high levels of structural unemployment D All of the above Question 12 Which of the following is unlikely to be a constraint on the effectiveness of an expansionary monetary policy during a recession? A Monetary policy is usually regarded as being less direct in its impact on household spending than budgetary measures such as tax cuts, increased welfare outlays or public works. B Monetary policy may be weakened by crowding out in a recession typically caused by budget deficits financed by domestic borrowing. C Monetary policy is subject to the same financial constraints in boosting AD as large budget deficits. D Monetary policy is subject to time lags in recognition, implementation and impact. Question 13 When the RBA sets out to achieve a higher cash rate target in the short-term money market, this might have an adverse impact on the efficiency in resource allocation due to the fact that higher interest rates: CHAPTER 6 Economic management using macroeconomic monetary policy 227 school assessment tasks and learning activities This depreciation would tend to: A make Australian exports cheaper in the US relative to the price of imports in Australia B decrease the burden of repaying interest on the foreign debt C cause a rise in the unemployment rate in the export sector D slow the rate of domestic economic activity. A worsen demand inflation pressures B cause the wasteful unemployment of labour and capital resources to decrease C Australian firms will become more cost competitive abroad D have an adverse supply-side impact and discourage investment in new plant and equipment incorporating the latest technology. Question 14 Concerning monetary policy, which statement is generally false? A Financial sector deregulation may raise efficiency in resource allocation by promoting greater competition. B Contractionary monetary policy may lead to idle resources, causing greater income inequity through reduced access to basic goods and services. C The failure of the RBA to effectively control inflation (e.g. in the 1980s) could cause an arbitrary redistribution of income away from buyers and sellers of assets in favour of exporters. D The RBA is required by government to deliver an annual average inflation rate of around 2–3 per cent (as measured by the CPI) over the economic cycle. school assessment tasks and learning activities Question 15 Concerning the RBA’s monetary policy stance between 1996–97 and 2006, which of the following is correct? A Policy was relatively contractionary between 1996 and 1998. B Policy was relatively expansionary between late 1999 and mid 2000. C Policy was relatively contractionary between 2002–06. D Overall, policy gave a lower priority to the control of inflation over the achievement of full employment. Question 16 Monetary policy is usually regarded as being most effective in directly helping to achieve: A improved equity in the distribution of income B strengthening efficiency in the allocation of resources C price stability and then perhaps fuller employment D external stability. Question 17 The main reason for the RBA conducting a dirty float is usually: A smoothing out unwanted and uninformed changes in the Australian dollar B to achieve a particular target level for the exchange rate C to curb spending on imports D to encourage exports. Question 18 If the RBA takes action to increase domestic interest rates, this will not tend to cause: A structural unemployment B cost inflation C demand inflation D increased overseas borrowing and reduced price competitiveness of our exports. 228 Economics Down Under Book 2 Question 19 Regarding monetary policy’s general application, which statement is incorrect? A A tighter monetary policy during periods of rapid demand inflation may in some ways increase equity in the distribution of income. B A tighter monetary policy can slow household and business spending on imports, thereby helping in some ways to reduce the CAD. C In the long term, using monetary policy to improve price stability provides an economic climate where there is better business confidence, increased productive investment and greater competitiveness to enhance the sales of locally produced goods and services. D When the RBA undertakes market operations designed to increase domestic interest rates, the exchange rate for the Australian dollar usually tends to depreciate. Question 20 Which of the following reforms involving regulation of the financial sector has not occurred since 1990? A The fixed exchange rate for the Australian dollar was replaced with a floating exchange rate. B The PAR for liquidity was abolished. C There was some extension of banking licences to increase competition. D The Australian Prudential Regulation Authority was set up and supervision was extended to cover both banks and other major financial institutions. Question 21 Given the following information, what combination of monetary policies (Nos 1–IV) may be most effective in promoting better domestic and external stability? ECONOMIC INDICATOR ANNUAL % CAD:GDP ratio (%) 4 CPI (%) 9 GDP growth (%) 6 Unemployment (%) 3 II(I) Increased RBA net sales of government securities in the short-term money market I(II) Increased RBA net repurchases of government securities in the foreign exchange market (III) Increased purchases of Australian dollars by the RBA in the foreign exchange market (IV) Persuasion by the RBA to encourage financial sector lending A Answers (I) and (III) B Answers (II) and (IV) C Answers (II), (III) and (IV) D None of the above. B the conflict with equity in income distribution C a generally adverse political reaction D the decline in the RBA’s holdings of overseas reserves of currencies. Question 23 If the RBA sold Australian dollars in the foreign exchange market to affect the exchange rate, this would be likely to cause: A increased exports B increased imports C increased Australian investment abroad D all of the above. Question 24 If the RBA’s policy fails to keep Australia’s inflation rate below that of our major overseas competitors, the likely result could be: A a worsening CAD and a depreciating exchange rate B a rising NFD and a reduced credit rating C both A and B above D neither A nor B above. Question 25 The measure of the volume of money called broad money refers to: A coins and notes in the hands of the non-bank public B the value of all bank deposits and cash C the measure, M3 D the value of all cash in the hands of the non-bank public, bank deposits and net deposits held in non-bank financial institutions. Question 26 The most severe constraint which operates when the RBA cuts interest rates to stimulate domestic economic activity is: A a likely weakening of the exchange rate and a rise in inflation Question 27 Which of the following is false, following a rise in interest rates? A The A$ will tend to appreciate. B Efficiency may fall due to reduced investment. C Cost inflation will fall. D Unemployment will tend to rise. Question 28 Competition between banks and other financial institutions during the mid to late 1990s and early 2000s saw: A generally reduced profit margins on each dollar of bank lending than in some periods B lower interest rates and a lending war on home loans C increased trading hours by some financial institutions to improve customer service D all of the above. Question 29 Following market operations by the RBA, increased interest rates are most likely to: A increase domestic savings but reduce investment spending B increase consumption and unemployment C reduce the inflow of foreign investment recorded initially as a credit on the financial account of the balance of payments D cause all of the above. Question 30 If economic growth was at 2 per cent and the inflation rate was rising by 1.2 per cent, the RBA would probably: A tighten its monetary policy stance B loosen its monetary policy stance C not change its monetary policy stance D start by tightening its policy stance before easing it. SHORT-ANSWER test questions Instructions: Your teacher may direct you to complete a selection of the following questions. These questions should be useful preparation for the end-of-year examination. Question 2 A Read the following extract taken from a RBA Statement on monetary policy in November 2001: Question 1 A Define monetary policy. (2 marks) B Briefly outline the economic role played by Australia’s financial institutions. (2 marks) C Explain what is meant by financial deregulation and identify its main aim. (2 marks) D List and briefly describe two important changes associated with financial deregulation in Australia. (2 marks) E Identify and outline one constraint that has limited the effectiveness of financial sector deregulation. (2 marks) ‘. . . as always, the Bank continues to assess the available information and will adjust as necessary, the stance of policy in pursuit of sustainable economic growth, consistent with the inflation target.’ Source: RBA Bulletin, p. 4, November 2001. Referring to this statement by the RBA: (a) Explain the meaning of the term policy stance. (2 marks) (b) What is the RBA’s current operational objective for its monetary policy? (2 marks) CHAPTER 6 Economic management using macroeconomic monetary policy 229 school assessment tasks and learning activities Question 22 A budget surplus is likely to help: A reduce interest rates B cause the Australian dollar to depreciate C reduce unemployment D ‘crowding out’ of private sector borrowing. B Read the following media release about monetary policy from the RBA in August 2006. C Assume that the RBA decided to increase its cash rate target. Clearly explain the process used by the RBA to push up interest rates. Illustrate this approach using a labeled demand–supply diagram representing the short-term money market showing the ‘before’ and ‘after’ situations. (3 marks) D How is the exchange rate determined for the A$? (2 marks) E Under what domestic economic circumstances might the RBA undertake a dirty float involving the selling of the A$ in the foreign exchange market? Show the ‘before’ and ‘after’ effect of this policy in the foreign exchange market. (3 marks) F What is the RBA’s policy of persuasion? How might it be used? (2 marks) Question 4 A Examine figure 6.10 showing recent rises in the RBA’s cash rate target. Describe what has happened to the cash rate target over these years. (2 marks) B The RBA uses a checklist approach to help determine its policy stance. List and briefly explain three important factors on this checklist, that the RBA may have taken into account before making its decision to lift the cash rate target between 2002–07. (4 marks) C Assume that the RBA decided to raise its cash rate target because of its concerns about rising inflation. (a) Explain how the RBA would achieve a higher cash rate target. (b) Explain how the achievement of a higher cash rate target would help to slow inflation, referring to the transmission mechanism. (c) Explain one disadvantage of the RBA’s decision to increase interest rates. D Referring to the previous question, discuss the main economic advantage and the main disadvantage of the RBA’s decision to raise its cash rate target during these years. (3 marks) E Identify and explain an alternative to monetary policy that could be used to reduce the inflation rate. F Explain how a rise in interest rates by the RBA would tend to affect any three of the following. (1 + 1 + 1 = 3 marks) (a) the level of business investment spending (b) residential building approvals (c) cost inflation (d) imports of consumer goods and services (e) the level of cyclical and structural unemployment. Referring to this statement by the RBA: (a) What specific demand-side factors at this time (extra research needed here using the RBA website) were causing domestic and international spending to rise so strongly? (4 marks) (b) Explain how these domestic and international factors were contributing to inflationary pressures in an economy where there was little spare productive capacity. (2 marks) (c) How would the rise in the cash rate target by 0.25 per cent to 6 per cent, help to slow inflationary pressures coming from domestic and international sources? (4 marks) (d) Outline two constraints or weaknesses of increasing the cash rate target in this way. (4 marks) (e) In determining the stance of monetary policy, outline the main reason why priority is given to fighting inflation. (2 marks) Question 3 A What are interest rates? Outline the general factors that affect the level of interest rates in Australia. (2 marks) B Explain the meaning of the cash rate target. (2 marks) 8 6 4 2002 2003 Figure 6.10 RBA official cash rate target Source: Data derived from RBA Bulletin. 230 Economics Down Under Book 2 2004 2005 July August September October November December January February March April May June July August September October November December January February March April May June July August September October November December January February March April May June July August September October November December January February March April May June July 0 August September October November December January February March April May June 2 January February March April May June Cash rate target (%) school assessment tasks and learning activities Following a decision taken by the Board (of the RBA) at its meeting yesterday, the Bank will be operating in the money market this morning to increase the cash rate by 25 basis points to 6 per cent. The decision reflects the Board’s assessment that economic activity remains strong and that inflation pressures have increased. Growth of the Australian economy is taking place against the background of strong international conditions. Despite regional differences, most indicators suggest that demand and output in Australia have strengthened over recent months . . . The growth of demand, against the backdrop of an economy operating with limited productive spare capacity, has contributed to increased inflationary pressures this year, and businesses report that labour market conditions are tight . . . Given these circumstances, the Board judged that an increase in the cash rate was warranted in order to contain inflation in the medium term. Source: RBA media release No. 2006–05, 2 August, 2006. 2006 2007 Statistical data relating to Australian domestic conditions 1999– 2000– 2001– 2002– 2003– 2004– 2005– 2006– 2007– 2000 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 YEAR RBA cash rate target at 1 July each year (%) 4.75 6.00 5.0 4.75 4.75 5.25 5.5 Inflation rate (annual CPI %) 2.40 6.00 2.80 2.70 2.80 2.50 4.00 Unemployment rate (% labour force) 6.60 6.40 6.70 6.10 5.80 5.30 5.10 5.75 Sources: Data derived from ABS 1350.0, RBA Bulletin. Question 5 A Examine table 6.7 before answering the questions that follow. What relationship appears to exist between the cash rate target and the exchange rate for the A$? Explain your reasoning Table 6.7 and quote supportive examples drawn from the table above. (4 marks) B Examine figure 6.11 showing trends in the TWI before answering the questions that follow. 70 65 60 55 50 2007–08 2006–07 2005–06 2004–05 2003–04 2002–03 2001–02 2000–01 1999–2000 1998–99 40 1997–98 45 1996–97 TWI index for the A$ G Select one of the following events and explain why this would cause the RBA to tighten its monetary policy stance, and one that would cause the RBA to loosen its stance. (2 + 2 = 4 marks) (a) a fall in Australia’s unemployment rate to 4.6 per cent (b) large tax cuts and rises in budget outlays as in 2006 (c) higher inflation rates and official interest rates overseas (d) a fall in the value of GDP and a rise in unemployment to 6.1 per cent (e) rising prices for oil, fruit and vegetables (f) a property and share market boom (g) a very large depreciation of the A$. H Examine table 6.6, before answering the questions that follow. Quoting supportive statistical data from table 6.6, answer the following questions. (a) What is the apparent relationship between the inflation rate and the cash rate target? (2 marks) (b) What is the apparent relationship between the unemployment rate and the cash rate target? (2 marks) I Imagine that Australia was faced with both strong international rates of economic growth on the one hand, and very weak domestic spending on the other. Explain how these developments might influence the RBA’s monetary policy stance or settings. (6 marks) Figure 6.11 Trade weighted index (TWI) Source: Data derived from RBA Bulletin. (a) What is a floating exchange rate? (2 marks) (b) Giving reasons, how would the generally higher exchange rate for the A$ (e.g. in recent years to 2005), tend to affect each of the following? (2 + 2 = 4 marks) (i) the size of the CAD (ii) the level of our NFD. Statistical data relating to Australia’s economy YEAR RBA cash rate target at 1 July each year (%) Exchange rate for the A$ at July each year (TWI, 1970 = 100) 2002– 03 2003– 04 2004– 05 4.75 4.75 5.25 50.9 58.3 60.2 2005– 06 5.5 64.3 2006– 07 2007– 08 5.75 63.9 Source: Data derived from RBA Bulletin. CHAPTER 6 Economic management using macroeconomic monetary policy 231 school assessment tasks and learning activities Table 6.6 (c) Suggest two likely reasons for the general rise in the TWI since 2000–01. (2 marks) (d) Suggest one likely reason for the depreciation of the A$ between 1998–99 and 2000–01. (2 marks) (e) What is meant by the RBA’s policy of smoothing the A$? Suggest one constraint that would weaken the RBA’s attempts to artificially push up the exchange rate. (4 marks) C Explain how higher interest rates might on the one hand improve the CAD, but on the other hand, worsen it. (4 marks) D Suggest and outline one alternative government policy (other than interest rates) that is more effective at reducing the size of Australia’s CAD. (4 marks) Question 6 A What is an efficient allocation of resources? How might the recent rise in interest rates by the RBA (e.g. 2002–06), affect efficiency in Australia’s allocation of resources? (4 marks) B Why might a reduction in interest rates by the RBA, help to increase efficiency in resource allocation? (2 marks) C Identify and explain one important constraint of using monetary policy to improve efficiency in resource allocation. Suggest a more effective type of policy. (2 marks) D What is the likely effect of a stronger A$ on Australia’s efficiency in resource allocation? (2 marks) Question 7 A ‘Individuals are affected differently by government policy’. Explain how the distribution of income would be affected by each of the following decisions by the RBA: (a) rises in the cash rate target by the RBA (e.g. 2006) designed to lower inflation (2 marks) (b) the decision by the RBA to allow the A$ to appreciate (e.g. generally between 2001–2007) (2 marks) (c) a reduction in interest rates by the RBA. (2 marks) B Explain how the RBA’s pursuit of domestic economic stability also helps to promote equity in income distribution. (6 marks) C Monetary policy in general and interest rates in particular, is not the most effective policy to improve equity. Outline a more effective policy. (6 marks) school assessment tasks and learning activities AN essay As noted already, SAC 1 for Unit 4 could require students to complete an essay about the nature and operation of a government macroeconomic policy. Having just completed chapter 6, you are now in a position, if directed by your teacher, to write an essay about how monetary policy can be used to manage the economy. A research essay about monetary policy may be structured as follows: ■ provide a clear definition of monetary policy ■ define domestic economic stability and then discuss how monetary policy can help achieve this objective, illustrating this by reference to recent monetary policy ■ define what is meant by external stability and then discuss one important strength and one important weakness of recent monetary policy in helping to achieve this objective ■ define efficiency in resource allocation and then discuss one important strength and one important weakness of recent monetary policy in helping to achieve this objective ■ define equity in the distribution of income and then discuss one important strength and one important weakness of recent monetary policy in helping to achieve this objective. Students should be encouraged to use tables and graphs, and quote recent supportive evidence including that from recent RBA Monthly bulletins and Annual reports (see RBA’s website), the publications of major private banks, the media and other sources. OR ■ ■ ■ ■ Define internal and external stability for the Australian economy. Explain what is meant by macroeconomic policy. During the last three years, how has macroeconomic policy been used to try and promote domestic stability in the Australian economy? What effect would recent changes in macroeconomic policy have on external stability and the size of the CAD? A WRITTEN report As noted already, SAC 1 for Unit 4 could require students to complete a structured report about the nature and operation of a government macroeconomic policy. Having just completed chapter 6, you are now in a position, if directed by your teacher, to write a report about how monetary policy can be used to manage the economy. The report could perhaps be structured along the lines of one of the following. Using monetary policy to promote internal and external stability 1. Clearly define what is meant by internal and external stability for Australia. 2. In theoretical terms, explain how monetary policy can be used to pursue domestic (internal) stability in an economy. How 232 Economics Down Under Book 2 does the achievement of domestic (internal) stability help the achievement of external stability? 3. Explain clearly how the RBA changed its monetary policy stance between 2002 and late 2006 to help improve domestic economic stability in Australia. Illustrate your answer by including and referring to tables and graphs of (e.g. official interest rates), diagrams, quotes from the RBA Bulletin’s ‘Statement on Monetary Policy’ and newspaper reports, etc.). 4. Briefly explain what is meant by Australia’s objective of external stability. How might the decision to lift official interest rates several times in 2006 be expected to affect the achievement of external stability? OR Using monetary policy to promote efficiency in resource allocation 1. Clearly define what is meant by an efficient allocation of resources, noting how this is measured. 2. Identify in general theoretical terms, how monetary policy may help increase efficiency in the allocation of Australia’s resources. 3. Identify and explain the important means whereby monetary policy tended to increase efficiency in Australia’s resource allocation between 1996 and 2007. 4. Identify and explain two important constraints that may have limited the effectiveness of monetary policy in promoting greater efficiency in the allocation of Australia’s resources between 2002 and early 2007. Illustrate your answer by reference to actual examples of monetary policy. OR Using monetary policy to promote greater equity in personal income distribution 1. Clearly define what is meant by an equitable distribution of income for Australia. 2. Indirectly, monetary policy helps to create a more equitable distribution of personal income in Australia. By referring to actual details of recent monetary policies, explain theoretically how this can occur. 3. Between 2002 and early 2007, the RBA increased the cash rate target eight times. Explain clearly how these rises in interest rates would be likely to affect the distribution of income from the point of view of the following groups of individuals in Australia: ■ the unemployed ■ self-funded retirees ■ businesses and exporters ■ ordinary families ■ asset speculators. 4. Compare the likely effectiveness of monetary policy with budgetary policy for promoting a more equitable distribution of income in Australia. OTHER learning activities Have you tried the following learning activities in your class recently? ■ 1. Web Quest Visit the website for this book and click on the weblinks for this chapter (see Weblinks page 310). Use the Internet for researching some of the following: ■ The reasons for the latest changes in the cash rate target by the RBA. ■ Statements by the Governor of the RBA. ■ Changes in exchange rates. ■ The RBA’s Annual report on trends in the Australian economy. ■ Media reports about the RBA’s recent changes in monetary policy. ■ Want to be Governor of the RBA for the day and see the effects of changes in central bank interest rates? Try the interactive game or set up a competition where the aim is to maximise economic stability in a virtual economy. As always, teachers are strongly advised to check all website addresses listed in this text for suitability, appropriateness of content, operation and accuracy, before asking students to conduct research. 2. Class debate Select one of the following topics: ■ ‘That the main economic priority of the RBA should be full employment not price stability.’ ■ ‘That monetary policy should leave the promotion of equity in the distribution of income to budgetary policy.’ ■ ‘That deregulation has made the piggy banks even fatter and ordinary households thinner.’ 3. Data show ■ Ask students to prepare a PowerPoint presentation about how the RBA can change domestic interest rates OR the exchange rate for the A$. These can then be used for making a class presentation. Get students to prepare a set of PowerPoint slides about the nature and origin of money. Use these for a class presentation. 4. Newspaper reports Photocopy or go onto the Internet to source a newspaper report about a recent change in monetary policy. Students could summarise the report, make a checklist of indicators affecting the decision, possibly identify bias in the report, or expand on what has been said in the article. 5. Graphs as wall charts On a regular basis, students could be asked to prepare and then update wall charts showing trends in monetary variables including: ■ M3 or broad money measures of the volume of money ■ the exchange rate for the A$ reflected in the TWI, US$ or Indonesian rupee ■ official and other interest rates. 6. Role play Set up a mock board meeting for the RBA. Work out subcommittees where board members (students) have to research, beforehand, trends in the key checklist indicators for monetary policy during the past 12 months. In the actual meeting, each student or group should present a 2–3 minute report about their particular indicator, followed by general discussion by all board members of the case for and against a change in the cash rate target. The indicators include: ■ trends in CPI inflation ■ indicators of changes in AD spending, confidence, retail sales and quarterly GDP ■ trends in wage growth, RULCs and other production costs CHAPTER 6 Economic management using macroeconomic monetary policy 233 school assessment tasks and learning activities 5. Identify and clearly explain two important constraints of monetary policy involving higher interest rates in 2006. ■ ■ unemployment and other labour market indicators changes in overseas economic activity, the exchange rate and other international events ■ recent changes in the stance of budgetary policy. Finally, individual students should work out a Statement of Monetary Policy (giving reasons for the board’s decision) for release to the media. Source: The basic idea for this role-play came from Economics, VCE Study design. school assessment tasks and learning activities 7. Crosswords Construct a crossword using terminology and knowledge about recent monetary policy and how it may help to promote 234 Economics Down Under Book 2 internal stability, external stability, efficiency in resource allocation and equity in personal income distribution. Use the Internet for software that makes this task easy. 8. Team quiz Divide the class into teams. Within a team, members can consult each other when it is their turn to answer questions about monetary policy that the teacher (or students) has previously written. The winning team may be awarded a prize. A variation of this is the Economics Wheel of Fortune, using numbered questions and token prizes. summary Summary chapter 6 What is monetary policy? Using monetary policy to promote external stability Monetary policy relates to measures of the RBA involving the regulation of the nation’s money and the rate at which credit flows between the financial sector and the rest of the economy. The main instrument of monetary policy is changes in the cash rate target implemented using market operations, but the RBA also has the capacity to influence/smooth out the exchange rate using a dirty float and to use persuasion to affect the general level and direction of lending by the financial sector. Monetary policy is normally classified as a macroeconomic policy since it is mainly aimed at regulating AD. Theoretically, monetary policy can help improve external stability in several ways. Most importantly, a more contractionary stance (i.e. higher interest rates) during a cyclical upswing in economic activity can help avoid a blow-out in the CAD by slowing excessive expenditure and controlling domestic inflation. There is also the added bonus (once inflation is controlled), that cuts in domestic interest rates make overseas borrowing relatively less attractive helping to slow the NFD and CAD. Recent policy has generally been applied in this way. However, its effectiveness has been limited by external constraints and the existence of conflicts between the various government objectives. Higher domestic interest rates push up the A$. While this slows inflation, it increases the CAD by making imports relatively cheaper and exports dearer. For some firms, higher interest rates add to production costs and make exports less competitive. Aims/priorities of monetary policy In recent times, the main aim of monetary policy is inflation targeting or the pursuit of price stability (CPI target of 2–3 per cent a year). However, once this goal is achieved, other aims including economic growth, full employment and external stability can become a focus for RBA policy. Using monetary policy to promote domestic stability Theoretically, monetary policy can help increase domestic economic stability if it is applied as a counter-cyclical measure designed to steady the increase in AD. Hence, the monetary policy stance is usually tightened to slow AD when inflation approaches or starts to exceed the inflation target (e.g. eight rises in the cash rate target between 2002 and early 2007), but then it is often eased to stimulate AD when inflation falls below the target and growth and employment slow excessively (e.g. six cuts in official interest rates during 2000–01). In this way, commentators note that there have generally been improved levels of domestic economic stability (with good growth, fairly stable prices and fuller employment) recently between 1996–97 and early 2007. Using monetary policy in these ways depends on transmission mechanism. These have to do with the way a higher or lower cash rate target/interest rate affects the economy. For example, a rise in the cash rate target by the RBA will slow inflation by increasing saving, reducing C and I spending, AD, shortages of goods and services and general prices. Higher interest rates also reduce inflation by pushing up the exchange rate and depressing inflationary expectations. However, monetary policy faces constraints including time lags in impact, indirectness, bluntness/ imprecision, overseas events, the psychological outlook and the conflict between government objectives. Using monetary policy to promote efficiency Theoretically, monetary policy can help improve efficiency in resource allocation. First, it can help regulate AD in an attempt to limit inflation and unemployment, so that these problems do not result in inefficiency. Second, when it is possible to reduce interest rates because inflation and expectations have been subdued, the cost to business of purchasing new and more efficient plant and equipment, involving better technology, is made more attractive, encouraging stronger productivity. Again in recent years between 1992–93 and 2007, monetary policy generally has done these things. While not really a monetary policy, financial deregulation has also been an important efficiency development involving the financial sector. Unfortunately, there are constraints on monetary policy’s effectiveness including the conflict between some objectives, time lags and external events. Using monetary policy to promote equity Theoretically, there are only indirect ways whereby monetary policy can promote equity. Most importantly, the counter-cyclical application of monetary policy can help curb inflation and unemployment, both of which are really detrimental to equity in the distribution of income and wealth. In recent years, monetary policy has done this fairly well. However, monetary policy suffers from constraints including long impact time lags, external events and its inability to redistribute income in a specific way relative to the precision and directness of budgetary policy. CHAPTER 6 Economic management using macroeconomic monetary policy 235 CONCEPT MAP 6 Economic management using macroeconomic monetary policy Monetary policy Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA) measures that mainly affect the demand and supply of credit 1. Aims of monetary policy: Recent measures largely emphasise the following objectives — Domestic economic stability (especially price stability, inflation targeting and then, economic growth and full employment) by using interest rate variations to regulate the growth in AD and economic activity — Indirectly, other aims including equity in income distribution, efficiency and external stability are promoted by improving domestic economic stability. 2. Instruments/aspects of monetary policy: — RBA (open) market operations (i.e. the buying and selling of government securities in the short-term money market) are used by the RBA to alter interest rates (i.e. to alter the cost of credit used to finance spending) — Intervention in the foreign exchange market via a dirty float (RBA buying and selling A$) to smooth the exchange rate for the A$ — Persuasion involving talking up/talking down spending levels. 3. Using monetary policy to promote internal/domestic economic stability: — The key aim of RBA monetary policy is the pursuit of price stability, and only then, sustainable economic growth and full employment. Policy is applied in a counter-cyclical way to regulate AD — The RBA raises interest rates (by net sales of government securities) to slow excess AD (by encouraging savings, and by discouraging borrowing and spending by making credit cheaper) and thus reduce shortages and ease demand inflation. Note transmission mechanisms. — The RBA lowers interest rates (by net buying back of government securities) to boost deficient AD (by encouraging borrowing and spending using cheaper credit), and thus soften the downswing/recession. Note transmission mechanisms. 4. Using the monetary policy to promote external stability: — RBA policy could increase interest rates to slow AD during a cyclical upswing/boom, thus reducing spending on imports and making exports more competitive. This would perhaps reduce the cyclical CAD. — The RBA can use a dirty float to smooth out erratic and uninformed changes in the A$/exchange rate, promoting more international trade. 5. Using monetary policy to promote efficiency in resource allocation: — Monetary policy is less effective than some policies to lift efficiency — Inflation results in the misallocation of resources into speculative areas, reduced labour efficiency and lower investment while unemployment results in wasted capacity and lower investment — Counter-cyclical monetary policies can minimise both inflation (by increases in interest rates) and unemployment (by reducing interest rates) by creating favourable internal economic conditions (e.g. strong economic growth, low inflation and low unemployment) that promote greater efficiency. 6. Using the budget to promote a more equitable distribution of personal income: — Monetary policy is not as effective as budgetary policy in promoting an equitable distribution of income — However, counter-cyclical monetary policy can lower unemployment and inflation that worsen inequality in personal incomes and or reduce the purchasing power of family incomes — Lower interest rates can lower unemployment, while higher interest rates can lower inflation. Both these outcomes can improve the purchasing power of those on lower incomes. 236 Economics Down Under Book 2