chapter Economic management using microeconomic policy 7 7.1 Definition of microeconomic policy Microeconomic policy has to do with a wide range of supply-side, cost cutting, efficiency measures designed to improve the way in which particular enterprises, industries and sectors within the Australian economy undertake and organise production. In essence, microeconomic policy includes reforms designed to increase output from available resources. Reforms may include structural change, better productivity, cost cutting in production and the application of the best international practices by business managers and workers. In turn, these reforms should collectively improve profits, bolster national productive capacity and increase aggregate supply. CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 237 7.2 Aims of microeconomic policy Although microeconomic policy can be used to pursue all the government’s economic objectives, its main aim is increased efficiency in resource allocation. Indeed, microeconomic reform is almost entirely about lifting productivity by cutting costs, promoting competition and restructuring the way production is organised in both the private and government sectors. These measures involve allocating resources to get more output from the same quantity of inputs, in order to raise real incomes and raising material living standards. Microeconomic reform aims to improve four aspects of efficiency in resource allocation: 1. Microeconomic reform tries to increase allocative efficiency by ensuring that resources are directed into areas where they best help to satisfy society’s needs and wants. Often allocative efficiency may be improved if there is strong competition between producers and sellers in the market. This ensures that resources are directed into areas of comparative cost advantage. However, on some occasions, government intervention may be needed to ensure there is allocative efficiency. 2. Microeconomic reform may aim to increase productive (technical) efficiency by encouraging businesses to use the least cost method of production. Firms need to cut costs and purchase fewer resources. This entails employing the best international practices available along with savings reforms to lower the cost of firms purchasing new equipment. 3. Microeconomic reform seeks to increase dynamic efficiency by encouraging firms to be adaptive and creative in response to changing economic circumstances. Policy needs to encourage firms to use the latest technology, upgrade employee skills and incentives for efficient work, promote market research and product development, and encourage innovation among firms so that they better meet the changing tastes of consumers. 4. Microeconomic reform aims to improve intertemporal efficiency by ensuring there is a suitable balance between resources 238 Economics Down Under Book 2 being allocated towards current consumption on the one hand and, on the other, adequate saving for financing future investment. By improving efficiency in resource allocation, ultimately microeconomic reform promotes all other government economic objectives. For instance: ■ Domestic economic stability is helped by increased efficiency. This is because greater efficiency raises the economy’s speed limit or sustainable rate of economic growth. More output can be gained from the same inputs. Increased efficiency also helps to cut costs and slow inflation. This leads to increased profits, improved competitiveness and better sales. As a result, over the medium to long term, the total level of employment should grow more quickly and structural unemployment should be reduced by fewer business closures. ■ External stability should be improved through increased international competitiveness that follows better structural efficiency and lower production costs. Efficiency should lift our exports relative to imports, help slow the rise in the CAD and rein in the foreign debt. ■ Increased equity in the distribution of personal income may occur in the long-term, when greater efficiency leads to higher levels of real incomes and production available for distribution among the population. Here, efficiency boosts the value of government tax revenues collected, thereby making the welfare system and the provision of community services for the poor much more affordable. Greater efficiency also leads to the creation of more jobs and helps eventually to lower structural unemployment caused by a lack of competitiveness and business profitability. This improves equity too. Moreover, increased efficiency helps to slow inflation that would otherwise undermine the purchasing power of lower income earners. Overall, material living standards are promoted through increased efficiency in the allocation of resources. THE REASONS FOR USING MICROECONOMIC POLICY The 1950s and 1960s represent the golden age for Australian productivity. However, during the 1970s, 1980s and early 1990s, our economic performance lagged behind that of many countries: ■ Our sustainable growth rate was often slower ■ The inflation rate was generally higher ■ Unemployment levels were excessive ■ The CAD:GDP ratio mostly was large (limiting our sustainable rate of economic growth) and overall, our dollar depreciated badly ■ ■ Efficiency grew very slowly Australia’s material living standards fell from first place in 1901, to fourth in 1950 to around fifteenth in the early 1990s. Because government macroeconomic measures on their own had failed to provide the necessary solutions to this economic decline, there was renewed interest in the possibilities offered by effective microeconomic reform. TRY SHORT ANSWER EXERCISE 1, p. 276 7.3 Specific instruments of microeconomic policy During the 1980s, 1990s and 2000s, federal governments were keen to pursue microeconomic reform. Let us now take a look at some of the most important ones. 3. abolition of import quotas 4. increased number of free trade agreements with other countries. TRADE LIBERALISATION Tariff cuts Until the 1970s, Australian governments strongly protected local industry from competition. They did this mainly by using high tariffs (taxes on imports to make them dearer than the local item), generous subsidies (cash payments to exporters or import competing firms to help them cover their production costs to allow them to sell more cheaply), and restrictive import quotas (legal restrictions on the quantity and type of imports permitted). Assistance like this sought to help local firms (often infant industries) survive foreign competition and, supposedly, to create more jobs for workers. However, starting in the early 1970s, the Australian Government signalled the start of a change in its policy of protecting local industry from foreign competition. Increasingly, it liberalised international trade. This involved the progressive reduction of tariffs, subsidies and import quotas, and a shift towards the idea of free trade. Increasingly, national borders no longer restrict the movement of goods, services and money capital between countries. With freer trade (associated with globalisation), we are forced to allocate resources into areas of production where Australia has a comparative cost advantage (or least disadvantage). In other words, resources will flow into areas where we are most efficient. It will mean that more national output (or GDP) can be gained from the same inputs of resources. This leads to higher incomes and material living standards. In addition, in the long-term, greater efficiency also leads to lower inflation, improved international competitiveness and increased employment. Our investigation here will focus on the four key aspects of trade liberalisation policies: 1. tariff cuts 2. reduced subsidies and other assistance Especially during the past thirty-five years, a debate has raged about the appropriate level of tariff protection for Australian industry. Tariffs or import duties represent an indirect tax levied on selected imported goods. In general, tariffs are added on to the price of imports to make them dearer, or less attractive, to local consumers. Because this limits foreign competition in local markets, economists agree that high tariffs cause resources to be allocated inefficiently into industries where we have a comparative cost disadvantage. The existence of high tariff rates means that local households and businesses consuming Australianmade goods and services must pay higher prices or costs for these items. This offsets any possible increase in income and employment in the short term arising from having tariffs. Additionally, when one country raises its tariffs, this becomes a justification for other nations to retaliate. As a result, world trade volumes and domestic economic activity contract. Figure 7.1 (p. 240) shows that there was a huge reduction in the general tariff rate on most manufactured items from 36 per cent in 1968–69, to effectively zero by 2005–06. It all started with a 25 per cent overnight tariff cut in 1973. However, reductions continued in different industries, at different rates. Effectively by 2007, most goods were tariff free. Of the few remaining imports still protected, around 90 per cent were at a rate of less than 5 per cent. Even so, tariffs are still applied to local industries making passenger motor vehicles, textiles, clothing and footwear. Traditionally, these areas were starting off from much higher levels of protection and to suddenly remove tariffs would have meant certain collapse. However, for these special industries, scheduled tariff reductions are continuing so firms know that efficiency must continue to rise, if they are to survive. CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 239 Effective tariff rate (%) 200 General ma 180 Passenger motor vehicles (PMV) 160 Clothing apparel 140 White goods Agriculture 120 100 80 60 40 INDUSTRY AREA 1980– 81 1985– 86 2010–11 2005–06 2000–01 1995–96 1990–91 1985–86 1980–81 1970–71 0 1968–69 20 1968– 69 1970– 71 1990– 91 1995– 96 2000– 01 General manufacturing 36 35 23 20 16 5 Passenger motor vehicles (PMV) 50 50 96 125 60 25 15 10 Clothing apparel 97 91 140 148 176 35 25 17.5 White goods 55 55 30 19 8 5 Agriculture 32 28 12 12 13 10 4.2 2005– 06 2010– 11 0 2.5 2.5 6 0 Figure 7.1 Changes in estimated effective rates of tariff protection of selected Australian industries, 1968–69 to 2005–06 Sources: Data derived from the Industry Commission, Productivity commission reports, ‘Trade policy review, Australia, 2002’, AGPS and other sources. Reduced subsidies and other assistance to local producers Subsidies are government cash payments made to local producers to help them cover some of their production costs. They can enable Australian firms to export at a more competitive price. Some even involve special assistance to accelerate industry restructuring. For example, there is the one billion dollar ‘Automotive competitiveness and investment scheme’ for 2000–05 to help car firms upgrade plant, equipment and technology, and an $800 million grant to help textile firms restructure, with tax rebates as high as 45 per cent offered for 240 Economics Down Under Book 2 companies with significant export orientation. However, there are problems with giving government subsidies. For example, they tend to increase inefficiency in resource allocation among firms that come to depend on their continuation. There is also the extra cost of subsidies to taxpayers who have to foot the bill. As part of its trade liberalisation measures, the Australian Government has increasingly reduced subsidies or used them to help restructure the industry more efficiently. Figure 7.2 shows us that in the period between 1971–72 and 2006–07, there was a general reduction in gross subsidies, from around $25 billion in 1971–72, down to an estimated $4.3 billion or less by 2006–07. In addition, by 2006–07, negotiations were underway for striking FTAs with China, Malaysia, ASEAN and Japan. The aims of this type of trade reform include lifting the competitiveness of our exporters, establishing a business presence abroad, expanding Australia’s market share in overseas countries, delivering stronger economic growth, reducing costs paid for imports by local firms and prices paid for imports by households, and making Australia a more attractive destination for overseas investment. 30 $ billions 25 20 15 10 2006–07 2000–01 1996–97 1989–90 0 1971–72 5 Figure 7.2 Estimated gross federal government industry subsidies, 1971–72 to 2006–07 ($ billion) Sources: Data calculated using information derived from Industry Commission, Productivity commission reports, 2006–07 budget overview and other sources. Again, this reform is consistent with the government’s belief in the benefits of strong competition and trade liberalisation. Abolition of import quotas Import quotas are designed to restrict the quantity of specific types of imports permitted into the country. In order to achieve a stated volume target, prospective importers must obtain a licence that gives them permission to import a certain maximum number of articles of a particular description. Quotas were commonplace in the 1970s and early 1980s, especially on cars, textiles, footwear and clothing. However, these were progressively abolished. The last of these quotas, applying to cheese, was terminated in 2000–01. Again, this reform is part of the belief in the long-term efficiency benefits of freer trade and stronger competition. Increased number of free trade agreements (FTAs) Australia has membership of various multinational (i.e. involving many countries) trading groups like the World Trade Organization (WTO). Through the Doha rounds of trade negotiations with the WTO (called the Doha rounds because negotiations took place in Doha, the capital of Qatar), Australia has been pushing hard for general reductions in global tariffs and the abolition of subsidies, along with increased international access to agricultural, manufacturing and services markets. Indeed, Australia was instrumental in setting up the Cairns group of fair agricultural traders bent on eliminating agricultural subsidies. Despite these efforts, progress has been slow due to significant opposition from groups in the US, Japan and Europe. Given this slow pace of multilateral trade reform, Australia has increasingly tried to negotiate bilateral free trade agreements (FTAs) with two or more individual countries. For example, by early 2007, we had four FTAs in place: ■ Australia–New Zealand FTA (also known as ‘Closer economic relations’) in 1983 ■ Australia–Singapore FTA in 2005 ■ Australia–Thailand FTA in 2005 ■ Australia–United States FTA in 2005. DEREGULATION AND OTHER REFORMS OF THE LABOUR MARKET The labour market is an institution dealing with matters affecting all workers such as wages, incomes and other conditions of employment including work hours. During the 1990s and, especially, between 1996 and 2007, the federal government introduced major microeconomic reforms in this area. These changes were based on the belief that the quality, efficiency, training, health and skill of a nation’s labour force are vital in determining Australia’s productive capacity, sustainable rate of economic growth, adaptability to changing circumstances and our international competitiveness. Most importantly, labour market reform has involved a gradual shift from the centralised minimum wage (prior to November 2006 this was called the minimum award wage), to a system involving greater deregulation of wages based on enterprise or workplace agreements. Although both these wage systems are still used today, by late 2006, only about 10 per cent of all workers were covered by the minimum wage, with the remaining 90 per cent on workplace agreements. Let us now consider the details of these two wage systems. Australian Fair Pay Commission and the centralised system of minimum wages Traditionally, Australia has relied very heavily on a centralised wage fixing system which, since November 2006, is under the control of the Australian Fair Pay Commission (AFPC) (previously controlled by the Australian Industrial Relations Commission (AIRC) the main role of which is to settle industrial disputes). The AFPC is responsible for determining the federal minimum wage for low paid workers not covered by various enterprise or workplace agreements. In particular, the commission is guided by a new set of criteria to those used previously by the AIRC. In particular, the AFPC sets its minimum wage taking into account: ■ the promotion of the economic prosperity of the people of Australia ■ the capacity for the unemployed and low paid to obtain and remain in employment ■ employment and competitiveness across the economy ■ providing a safety net for the low paid ■ providing minimum wages for junior employees to whom training arrangements apply and employees with disabilities that ensure those employees are competitive in the labour market. In addition, under Australia’s Corporations Act (recently tested in an appeal to the High Court), the federal government CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 241 has successfully overridden much of the various state governments’ wages system, thereby increasing its power to determine wages. This means that now the minimum wage is applied fairly uniformly to particular workers across Australia, who are not covered by enterprise or workplace agreements. In its first decision in November 2006 (to apply from 1 December 2006 to about 1.4 million workers), the AFPC announced: ■ an increase of $27–36 per week in the standard federal minimum wage taking it up to nearly $512 per week ■ an increase of $27–36 per week in all Australian Pay and Classification (pay) scales up to $700 per week ■ an increase of $22.04 per week in all pay scales above $700 per week. The next annual wage review for these workers will occur in mid-2007. Increased reliance on workplace agreements In Australia nowadays, decentralised or firm-by-firm workplace agreements (also called employment contracts and enterprise agreements), are a far more popular alternative to the traditional centralised wage system. The main features of enterprise agreements are as follows. Wage agreements are negotiated on a firm-by-firm basis Under workplace agreements, wages and conditions are usually set on a firm-by-firm basis and more closely reflect the freer operation of the forces of demand and supply in the labour market. This allows businesses to have greater flexibility in setting wages, so they better mirror worker performance, local market trends, the firm’s profitability and other unique circumstances for the business, thus helping to improve competitiveness. However, a no disadvantage test is applied. This requires that enterprise 242 Economics Down Under Book 2 agreements match or exceed, minimum conditions or standards including those relating to wage rates, long service leave entitlements, unpaid parental leave and four weeks annual leave. Importance of productivity for wage rises An important and common feature of most enterprise or workplace agreements is that wage rises are based on actual improvements in worker efficiency or productivity (i.e. increases in output per worker per hour). Pay rises are usually performance-based. Agreements are renegotiated regularly At fairly regular intervals (i.e. up to 3 years), workers and their particular boss, renegotiate wages and conditions so that the workplace agreements can be updated to reflect changing circumstances, both inside and outside the firm. Two types of enterprise agreements Today there are two possible types of enterprise agreement: Certified agreements and Australian workplace agreements. Certified agreements (CAs) can only occur between unions and employers. Australian workplace agreements (AWAs) provide an alternative to CAs. An AWA can exist between an employee and his or her employer. These are individual employment contracts that can apply even to salaried employees such as executives and professionals. Recent industrial relations reforms In 1996 and 2005, the federal government passed two important reforms in the area of industrial relations: 1. the Workplace Relations Act 1996 2. the Workplace Relations Amendment (Work Choices) Act 2005 (effective March 2006). Table 7.1 sets out the details of these two important reforms designed to further deregulate Australia’s labour market: Table 7.1 Recent changes to Australia’s industrial relations laws WORKPLACE RELATIONS ACT (1996) 1. The role of the AIRC The Act scaled back the responsibilities of the AIRC (whose wage-setting role was later taken over in 2005 by the AFPC). Its most important duty was presiding over the annual National wage case that determines the minimum or safety net wage (i.e. the idea of a living wage where workers earn enough to live and not just survive). For example, from 1997–98 to 2005–06, the AIRC’s annual safety net award wages were increased by between $8 and $18 a week, so that its last minimum weekly award wage was set around $484. However, these days the key role is settling industrial disputes. Another current responsibility of the AIRC is the enforcement of awards. 2. Simplification of the award system The traditional system of minimum award wages was complex, expensive and clumsy. Under this Act, award simplification occurred so that any award decision could only cover twenty allowable matters (e.g. classification of skills of employees, hours of work, pay rates, incentives, long-service leave, holidays, pay loading for overtime, redundancy pay, dispute settlement procedures, stand-down provisions and superannuation). 3. The no disadvantage test The Act requires that all enterprise or workplace agreements meet the minimum standards set out in relevant awards. This is called the no disadvantage test so that workers could not be worse off than they would be under an award. 4. Role of trade unions The Act reduces the direct role of trade unions in some wage negotiations. It restated the principles of voluntary unionism and illegality of compulsory unionism. It also confirmed that a worker could not be discriminated against on the basis of union membership and established the general right to strike (72 hours notice is needed for lockouts and strikes that are only allowed during the negotiation period for a new agreement). In addition, the legislation covers the illegality of secondary boycotts (e.g. ‘sympathy strikes’ where other unions go out on strike to support a cause not directly their own) as well as strike pay (when workers receive payment while undertaking industrial action). 5. Unfair dismissal provisions The Act changed the unfair dismissal laws to instances where dismissal was seen as harsh, unjust or unreasonable. However, adequate notice had to be given or pay offered in lieu of notice. 6. The Employment advocate The Employment advocate was set up to enforce AWEs and to protect vulnerable groups (e.g. the young, females, apprentices, non-English speaking migrants). WORKPLACE RELATIONS AMENDMENT (WORK CHOICES) ACT (2005) 1. Setting up the Australian Fair Pay Commission After nearly 100 years, the AIRC’s minimum wage setting role was handed over to the newly set up, Australian Fair Pay Commission (AFPC). Depending on the results of the federal election scheduled for late in 2007, this situation may change. 2. The reduced role of the Australian Industrial Relations Commission The old AIRC was to concentrate on industrial relations dispute resolution, the simplification and rationalisation of awards (i.e. reducing the number of awards and the allowable matters) and dealing with applications about industrial action (e.g. strikes). 3. Creating a more national wage system The Corporations Act is used to give the WorkChoices legislation its national power to override the state government industrial relations system (but unincorporated employers and their employees will remain within the state industrial relations system in WA, NSW, SA, Queensland and Tasmania). The challenge to the constitutional legality of this power failed to get support in a landmark decision in late 2006, thereby increasing the power of the Commonwealth in this and perhaps other areas (e.g. water, nuclear power). 4. Creating the Australian fair pay and conditions standard The Act establishes certain minimum, statutory, standard working conditions. For example, the 38-hour week, four weeks annual leave, and sickness, parental, personal and carers leave. In addition, individual can cash in up to two weeks of annual leave. These conditions form the universal Australian fair pay and conditions standard. (continued) CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 243 Table 7.1 (continued) WORKPLACE RELATIONS AMENDMENT (WORK CHOICES) ACT (2005) 5. Allowable matters Award wage agreements struck prior to 2006 will continue to apply but the list of allowable matters (e.g. incentive-based payments, hours of work, leave loadings, public holidays) has been reduced to 13, and non-allowable matters (e.g. union picnic and training days) are now no longer legally enforceable. 6. Types of Australian workplace agreements Work Choices distinguishes four main types of Australian workplace agreements (AWAs) or individual contracts: 1. non-union negotiated collective agreements 2. union negotiated collective agreements 3. employer negotiated greenfield agreement (where the employer makes a wage agreement with themselves before any person is hired, that employees will become subject to the agreement, thus giving the employer total control over staff wages and conditions) 4. union negotiated greenfield agreements. Under these arrangements, it is possible that particular staff might be singled out, one at a time, and pushed onto AWAs with reduced conditions of work (e.g. relating to weekends, shift work, and special pay rates for overtime rates, public holidays and shifts). 7. Exemptions from unfair dismissal laws There have been changes to some of the provisions of the unfair dismissal laws. These have increased the power of employers with fewer than 100 staff to sack workers. This further erodes the rights of employees. The claim in support of this change is that it will help lower unemployment since firms are more likely to hire extra staff if they know that they can more easily dismiss them if they prove to be unsatisfactory or even if they are unnecessary, given operational developments. Contested claims for unfair dismissal are still possible, but they are expensive. 8. The Minister for Industrial Relations The Minister for Industrial Relations has the power to terminate agreement negotiations, even if there is only the possibility of a strike (it does not even have to be an actual strike). 244 Economics Down Under Book 2 Other labour market reforms Apart from changing the nature of Australia’s wages system through the Workplace Relations Act, there have also been other important labour market reforms. Multiskilling and multitasking Multiskilling of workers has become more common and wage awards have been simplified and combined to cover those workers with broadly similar skill levels. Competency based vocational education and training, where people demonstrate skills, knowledge and understanding against set standards, has also encouraged multitasking by employees. These changes have helped to improve labour efficiency and make workers more employable. Job demarcation During the late 1980s and 1990s, job demarcation boundaries (where workers have set tasks they perform that cannot be transferred to other areas) were radically reduced, creating wider, less traditional employment areas. This shift was believed necessary to help reduce strikes, lower production costs and improve employment flexibility. Union amalgamation Thanks to changed guidelines developed in the early 1990s, there has been a significant level of union amalgamation (i.e. combining smaller unions to form larger unions). In addition, union amalgamation partly reflected the huge decline of unionism, the advance of multiskilling and reduced job demarcation. One benefit of encouraging fewer unions is that it simplifies industrial bargaining and reduces delays caused by demarcation or inter-union disputes. Table 7.2 Retraining of workers Over the past 10 years or so, there have been many schemes introduced by the government to improve the skills and training of workers. For instance, there was the 1994 Working nation scheme, the 1997–98 Modern apprenticeship and traineeship scheme, the creation of the Green corp, expansions of the Work for the dole scheme (1998–99 to 2005–06), and the 2001–02 Australians Working Together package. The Australians Working Together scheme, for example, included new requirements for recipients of parenting payments to undertake job searching, education, or training to develop their work skills and prepare them for a return to work. These activities need to involve 150 hours in each six-month period (or approximately six hours on average per week). In addition to these government schemes, 24 new Australian technical colleges were established between 2005 and 2007. Job placement agencies replaced the Commonwealth Employment Service (CES) Until 1998, the CES was responsible for finding jobs for the unemployed. Since then, Private employment placement enterprises (PEPE) have been responsible for connecting the unemployed with prospective employers. Centrelink facilitates this process and the government pays these job broking agencies, only when they find real employment for an unemployed individual. Some strengths and weaknesses of recent labour market reforms Labour market deregulation and other reforms have been undertaken to help improve Australia’s economic performance. Some of the strengths and weaknesses of these changes are listed in table 7.2. Some strengths and weaknesses of recent labour market reforms in Australia SOME STRENGTHS OF LABOUR MARKET REFORMS SOME WEAKNESSES OF LABOUR MARKET REFORMS Reforms help to reduce inflation Under workplace or enterprise agreements (i.e. since 1991) and other labour market reforms, pay rises increasingly reflect improved performance or worker productivity, thereby keeping down RULCs. In turn, better efficiency and lower costs reduce inflation (e.g. as occurred generally during 1992–2007). This was not usually the case under the old system of award wages where pay rises occurred irrespective of worker efficiency or the ability of particular firms to pay. Reforms have increased income inequality in the short term and reduced the power of workers The growth of enterprise agreements has contributed to the rise in inequality in the initial distribution of market incomes (i.e. income before government tax and outlays). This is partly because increasingly, workers in different firms in various parts of Australia get paid different wages. Another worry is that some workers are relatively disadvantaged in workplace negotiations (e.g. the inarticulate, non-English speaking, unskilled, unproductive, young people, non-unionised, rural workers, part-timers) as compared with, say, senior executives in profitable firms. Additionally, those workers remaining on the old centralised wage system, have not generally gained such rapid pay rises as those using the new system of workplace enterprise agreements, and increasingly, trade union scrutiny of pay rises is disappearing due to falling membership. (continued) CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 245 Table 7.2 (continued) SOME STRENGTHS OF LABOUR MARKET REFORMS SOME WEAKNESSES OF LABOUR MARKET REFORMS Reforms help to accelerate productivity and the sustainable rate of economic growth Workplace or enterprise agreements (used since 1991) offer pay rises in exchange for improved efficiency by workers. With increased efficiency of labour resources, more output can be gained from the same or fewer inputs, thereby accelerating economic growth and raising average incomes (e.g. generally between 1992– 2007). Additionally, locally made goods and services become more competitive, raising sales and production levels. Reforms may have increased unemployment in the short-term The growing popularity of performance-based, firm-byfirm enterprise agreements dramatically accelerated worker productivity against 1980s levels. This meant that many local businesses have been able to produce more output with the same or fewer staff. As a shortterm result, this may have tended to slow employment growth and add to structural unemployment. Reforms help to create fuller employment in the long term In the long term, labour market reforms have increased worker efficiency, improved worker competitiveness, lowered business costs and reduced business closures that cause structural unemployment. Additionally, the traditional minimum wage system sets pay rates at levels above the free equilibrium in the labour market, thereby contributing to a glut of workers (supply exceeds demand) or structural unemployment. By reducing emphasis on this system, structural unemployment should be cut. Furthermore, estimates suggest that the recent changes to the unfair dismissal laws may help create between 40 000 and 50 000 extra jobs by making employers more willing to hire full-time workers, knowing that they can be dismissed more easily if they prove to be unsatisfactory. Incomplete reforms Some claim that the government has not gone far enough with labour market reforms to ensure that Australian firms and their employees are sufficiently competitive against even more deregulated labour markets abroad in Asia, the United States and New Zealand. For instance: Reforms help to improve external stability By reducing labour costs, reforms have helped to make Australian workers and firms operating in local and overseas markets more competitive, thereby helping to increase exports relative to imports, thereby tending to reduce the CAD. Reforms help to promote equity in the long term Equity may be protected by the retention of safety net wages and initially, the no disadvantage test. Additionally, in the long term, labour market reforms have helped to accelerate economic growth, lift average per capita incomes (including those from exports), slow inflation so necessities are cheaper and more affordable, reduce unemployment by improving local business competitiveness and lift tax revenues to pay for the expensive welfare system. These developments help equity. Reforms help to encourage cooperation and reduce strikes Labour market reforms involving workplace and enterprise agreements have promoted cooperation and discussion between workers and their management. Employees are encouraged to be more accountable, and to show greater initiative and self-management. This approach is believed to have dramatically reduced industrial unrest including strikes (e.g. as seen during 1992–2007), absenteeism and poor product quality. 246 Economics Down Under Book 2 – Some people (even discussed by the Opposition) argue that safety net wages should be replaced with a tax credit scheme for low-income employees. Here, tax cuts would replace the need for rises in the minimum wage. This proposal would protect workers’ purchasing power, keep real wage costs for firms stable and reduce the structural unemployment rate. – Unfair dismissal laws may need to be relaxed further so that firms employing more than 100 staff are more likely to hire extra full-time employees. – The income gap between having a part-time job and being on government welfare is too small and distorts the efficient operation of the labour market. – Real wages (especially for youths) are perhaps still too high, causing higher unemployment. Estimates suggest that a 10 per cent fall in real wages could lift employment by possibly 4–7 per cent. Lack of coverage by agreements limits the impact Workplace or enterprise agreements were formally endorsed in 1991. However, even by 2006, around 10 per cent of all workers (higher for women) were still not covered by this system. Instead, these employees continued to rely on an inflexible and inefficient centralised approach to wage determination. SOME STRENGTHS OF LABOUR MARKET REFORMS SOME WEAKNESSES OF LABOUR MARKET REFORMS Change was essential and there was little choice Whether we like it or not, Australia was forced into labour market deregulation by similar developments abroad. Given the need to be competitive because of globalisation, there was little choice if we wanted local firms to survive and workers to have jobs in the future. Productivity is hard to measure under enterprise agreements The system of workplace or enterprise agreements bases pay rises on productivity gains. However, it is very difficult to accurately measure efficiency improvements attributable only to workers (i.e. as opposed to capital equipment). Moreover, the encouragement of productivity may even worsen structural unemployment in the short term. ■ efficiency in resource allocation (by affecting savings, consumption and investment levels) ■ the size of the CAD, NFD and our external competitiveness ■ equity in the distribution of personal income. However, of all these, most of the recent tax reforms that emphasised reductions in rates, were driven by the government’s push to improve efficiency in resource allocation by encouraging savings, lifting investment, increasing the motivation to work hard, rewarding personal effort, and extending international competition. In turn, greater efficiency also promotes economic and employment growth, lower inflation, external stability, rising incomes and the potential for greater equity in income distribution. TAX REFORMS To assess the quality of a tax system, economists often apply four criteria. A tax should be: 1. Simple Is it easily understood and simple to administer? 2. Fair Does it promote an equitable income distribution? 3. Efficient Does it promote an efficient use of resources? 4. Adequate Can it raise the necessary revenue so that governments can pay for their budget outlays without going into debt? Given changing circumstances and, with these four guidelines in mind, by the late 1990s it became especially clear that Australia’s tax system was in need of a good overhaul. Table 7.3 (p. 248) sums up some of the key tax reforms introduced in the years to July 2007. Tax reform will have many impacts on the economy. For example, the changes will affect: ■ the sustainable rate of economic growth by altering both AD and AS (including the levels of employment, production costs, business profitability and prices) REFORMS TO PROMOTE NATIONAL SAVINGS In 1993, the National savings strategy was first released. It attempted to address the problems of relatively high domestic interest rates (which disadvantage local firms that borrow for expansion) and the large national savings–investment gap currently filled by heavy foreign borrowing (which worsens the CAD through interest payments abroad). Between 1993 and early 2007, a number of microeconomic reforms were used to try and encourage national savings, often involving initiatives announced in the annual budget. CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 247 Table 7.3 Key federal government tax reforms REFORM OF TAXATION TOP RATE (2006) HISTORICAL TOP RATE PAYG income tax Between 2000 and mid 2007, the tax-free threshold for personal incomes was increased, the entry points into higher marginal tax brackets were moved up considerably (e.g. until July 2008 the 45 per cent tax rate cuts in at $150 000 per year but this will rise to $180 000), and the top marginal rate was cut from 47 to 45 per cent. 45 per cent (Plus 1.5 per cent Medicare levy) 75 per cent (<1951–52) CGT In 1986, the tax rate on capital gains (other than the family home that is exempt) was effectively halved. Only 50 per cent (not 100 per cent as previously) of the capital gain was to be taxed. The family home is normally exempt. 22.5 per cent (Plus Medicare levy) NA (Before 1986) Superannuation For many years, the government has made superannuation contributions very attractive (as a way to save for retirement) by offering tax concessions on both contributions and end benefits. These arrangements were frequently altered, with the most significant changes announced in the 2006 budget that allows a tax-free withdrawal of end benefits from aged 60 years from July 2007. zero (For endbenefits withdrawn after aged 60 years from July 2007) 30 per cent (1983 on lump sum payments above a threshold) Company tax Between 2000 and 2002, the tax rate on company profits was lowered from 36 to 34 per cent and finally to 30 per cent. 30 per cent 49 per cent (1986–88) Changes in some excise taxes As an anti-inflationary measure, the automatic indexation of the fuel excise tax ceased in 2001–02. Previously, as the price of fuel increased, the amount of tax collected increased without discretionary decisions being made by the Treasurer. This policy added to inflation and grew government revenues. Additionally, there were modifications made to other excise taxes (e.g. on light beer). NA NA Tariffs By 1996, the general tariff rate on most manufactured imports had been reduced from nearly 40 per cent in 1968–69 to only 5 per cent. In 2005, the 3 per cent tariff on business inputs was abolished where there is no local substitute (business inputs, for example, are natural resources, labour and capital purchased by firms to allow them to make final goods and services or output production). Today most imports are tariff free, except for motor vehicles, and textiles, clothing and footwear. zero (General tariff rate effectively) 38 per cent (General tariff rate, 1968–69) Indirect taxes In July 2000, the 10 per cent GST replaced the Wholesale Sales Tax (that had rates between 12 to 45 per cent). Unlike the WST, the GST is a broad-based tax applied to most (non-essential) goods and services and was levied on behalf of the states. 10 per cent GST 45 per cent WST (Before July 2000) Source: Data derived from the Treasury Economic roundup, Winter 2006. Acceptance of ‘fiscal balance’ as a guiding principle for budgets Between 1991–92 and 1996–97, the federal government ran up many budget deficits totalling nearly $60 billion. Unfortunately, these deficits required financing. Local borrowing by the government pushed up domestic interest rates relative to those overseas. This encouraged the private sector to borrow even more from overseas and attracted foreign capital inflow. In 248 Economics Down Under Book 2 turn, overseas borrowing to finance government budget deficits, also led directly to a structural rise in the CAD and NFD. In contrast to this, recent budgets have been based on the principle of fiscal balance over the medium term, so that budget surpluses in some years pay for deficits in others. Here, there is no need for federal government borrowing. Indeed, between 1996–97 and 2007–08, budgets were mostly surpluses (only two out of 11 were deficits) totally over $80 billion. This is shown in figure 7.3. In addition, by 2005, the government’s previous debt was completely repaid. Fiscal consolidation like this abolished one of the structural problems causing Australia’s NFD. It can also be argued that the many budget surpluses (i.e. government savings) helped to keep down domestic interest rates, making overseas borrowing by the private sector relatively less attractive. This too, helped to reduce income payments abroad, thus tending to lower our CAD. Establishment of the Future Fund In 2005, the Future Fund was created to lift national savings, improve the government’s long term financial position and its ability to meet unfunded public sector superannuation liabilities of around $100 billion. It was started using seed capital (as discussed in chapter 5) of around $18 billion, contributed by the government. The money has been used to create a giant investment portfolio that should grow over time through the generation of income, topped up with extra capital from further asset sales (e.g. Telstra 2006) and future budget surpluses. Promotion of household savings Microeconomic reforms (implemented through the federal budget), have also tried to encourage private sector savings. For example: ■ Superannuation guarantee charge (SGC). Starting in 1991, superannuation was made compulsory for all employees through the introduction of the Superannuation guarantee charge. This is a compulsory levy on a company’s payroll and was originally equal to an extra 3 per cent of wages paid into a worker’s superannuation account. However, as from 2002, it was increased to 9 per cent. ■ Generous tax advantages for voluntary contributions to superannuation. The government encourages private super- annuation contributions by offering very generous tax concessions. For instance, marginal tax rates on income might be as high as 45 per cent (plus the Medicare levy) but for those involved with salary sacrificing (i.e. using some of your pre-tax earnings to pay for benefits such as a car), there is only a 15 per cent tax on contributions. Also from July 2007, individuals can withdraw their superannuation tax free once they reach the age of 60 years. Again this provides further incentive to save. ■ Superannuation co-contributions scheme. The Superannuation co-contributions scheme commenced in 2002–03. Basically, the government matches low income after-tax superannuation contributions at the rate of up to $1.50 for every $1 (up to a limit) put into an approved superannuation account by an individual. For 2007–08, this will rise to $3 for every $1 contribution. This increases the incentive to save. – Reductions in tax rates. Between 1999 and 2007, there were significant tax reforms involving cuts in tax rates. Many of these changes should help to increase national savings. For example, the 50 per cent reduction in the rate of capital gains tax (1999) effectively lowered the maximum current rate to only 23.25 per cent. Reforms in 2000 and 2002 also cut the rate of company tax from 36 to 30 per cent. This should help to boost business savings via increases in retained profits. In addition, lower PAYG tax rates should provide temporary relief from the effects of bracket creep (where individuals find that over time, they end up moving into higher tax brackets with a heavier tax burden). In turn, this may help to lift household savings. Similarly, the 10 per cent GST (introduced in 2000) is a tax that discourages consumption and indirectly encourages savings. It also broadened the tax base to include both goods and services (relative to the old and narrow WST on goods only), perhaps adding further to public sector savings. 10 5 0 –5 –10 2009–10 2008–09* 2007–08* 2005–06 2006–07 2004–05 2002–03 2003–04 2001–02 2000–01 1998–99 1999–2000 1997–98 1996–97 1994–95 1995–96 –20 1993–94 –15 1992–93 Underlying budget outcome ($ billions) 15 Figure 7.3 Federal underlying budget outcome 1992–93 to 2006–07 and 2007–08 ($ billions) Sources: Data derived from RBA Bulletin, various editions; 2006–07 budget overview. Note: *represents latest estimate CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 249 By encouraging higher levels of national saving (i.e. an increase in the supply of savings relative to the demand for savings), these reforms should tend to lower domestic interest rates, slow cost inflation, improve long-term economic and employment growth, raise dynamic and intertemporal efficiency, reduce the NFD and CAD, and possibly help improve equity in the distribution of personal income. REFORM OF THE PUBLIC SECTOR Reforms of government businesses and the public sector have involved eight key aspects. Privatisation of selected government business enterprises (GBEs) Many claims have been made about the supposed inefficiency of government businesses. One response to this was to partially or fully privatise selected GBEs. Figure 7.4 shows that there was much privatisation between 1995–96 and 2005–06, especially in the earlier years (although the sale of Telstra in late 2006 should see a jump when the 2006–07 final figures are released). 16 000 12 000 8 000 2007–08 2006–07* 2004–05 2005–06 2003–04 2002–03 2000–01 2001–02 1999–2000 1996–97 0 1998–99 4 000 1997–98 Value ($ millions) 20 000 Figure 7.4 Estimated value of federal government privatisation ($ million) Sources: Derived from budget papers and other sources. Note: data represent estimates only based on asset sales and other smaller items. Note for 2006–07: this figure should be very large given the success of the Telstra 3 share sales. The justification for privatisation as an efficiency measure, is often based on three main arguments: 1. Private owners and shareholders demand greater efficiency and cost cutting in order to maximise their profits or returns. 2. Private owners often have better access to the huge amounts of capital needed for investment in new equipment and technology. This helps them to grow their efficiency more quickly. 3. Private owners may be able to recruit and appoint management and staff of superior quality, ambition and creativity, than would be the case if the business remained in the public sector. Examples of partial or full privatisation include the complete sale of the Commonwealth Bank (1996), Aussat (which became Optus with 49 per cent foreign ownership), the NSW Government Insurance Office (GIO), Qantas, TABCORP, some roads (e.g. Melbourne’s City Link), many ports (e.g. Geelong, Portland), some airports (e.g. Melbourne, Brisbane), parts of Sydney’s water supply, PowerCor and Telstra. 250 Economics Down Under Book 2 Corporatisation of some remaining government operations Corporatisation involves full government ownership of the business enterprise. However, the GBE is run more like a private enterprise (e.g. Australia Post, Australian Airlines in the 1980s, and the Port of Melbourne Authority). Providing there is no service obligation (e.g. Telstra has an obligation to provide some public telephone access in the community even though it may not be profitable), the main goal is usually to make a profit by minimising costs and by applying the user pays principle. There is also independence of management and corporatised government businesses are not given special commercial favours (i.e. there is competitive neutrality). Sometimes this can bring benefits and cost savings to the users of government services and, in particular, reduce the financial burden of these GBEs for governments and taxpayers. Commercialisation of some government activities Commercialism also involves government ownership of businesses but, unlike corporatisation, the enterprise is not expected to actually make a profit. Often this feature reflects the existence of community service obligations. Instead, the enterprise is expected to help cover its running costs by generating at least some revenue. It also seeks to reduce losses, lower the tax burden and raise efficiency (e.g. some rail operations, aspects of the ABC and some water boards). Public-private partnerships in infrastructure Between 2000 and 2007, some state governments tried the idea of private funding of public infrastructure (e.g. schools, roads, tunnels, water treatment, public housing and hospitals). These are often called, public–private partnerships. Here, private money would build, maintain and operate the facility but the government would lease these facilities back for periods up to 30 years. The questionable success of these ventures in Europe has not stopped over $9 billion worth of projects being earmarked by Victoria and New South Wales for the period 2003 to 2007. Public sector staff cuts Structural change (1987–2007) initially involved dramatic public sector staff cuts of around 35 per cent designed to reduce costs and raise worker efficiency. In part, staff downsizing reflects the impacts of fiscal balance, as well as privatisation and corporatisation. Although there has recently been a 25 per cent rise in public sector staff numbers in the six years to 2005–06 due to national security concerns and government reforms, staffing levels are still well below the peak of 1987–88. Reform of Commonwealth–state relations During the period 1992 to 2007, the Council of Australian Governments continued reforms in Commonwealth–state relations. It aimed to reduce the degree of inefficiency caused by service duplication. Problems in this area are not only costly to taxpayers and business, but they represent a misallocation of the nation’s resources. As a consequence of these changes, by 2007 there was good progress on reducing railway duplication, the creation of a single eastern electricity grid, centralisation of TAFE education, water trading, and uniform product and road laws applying to all states. National Competition Council (NCC) The NCC is an organisation providing advice, conducting research, making recommendations and evaluating state government microeconomic reforms. This forms the basis of the National competition policy. In particular, the NCC scrutinises the changes with regard to road transport, power generation and the creation of a national electricity grid, gas and water supply, standardisation of regulations and laws between states, the promotion of interstate trade and competition, and pricing reforms undertaken by government monopolies. WELFARE REFORMS Deregulation of agricultural markets During the past 10 to 15 years to 2007, there have been significant reforms involving deregulation of markets for primary products, along with other measures to accelerate structural change. For instance: – Wool pricing. Some years ago, the minimum or reserve price scheme for wool was abandoned. – Egg marketing. Victoria, New South Wales, South Australia and Queensland, have deregulated egg marketing. – Milk marketing. Between 2001 and 2005, milk marketing was deregulated, along with dairy farm-gate prices. In addition, there has been compensation to dairy farmers for the loss of milk quotas designed to encourage structural change in the industry. – Grains. There has been extensive deregulation of grain sales and especially following the scandal surrounding the Australian Wheat Board’s (AWB) behaviour in its wheat dealings with Iraq. The single desk, international marketing system is to be reviewed during 2007. – Sugar industry restructuring. In late 2002, the government was forced to announce a levy of between 16 and 18 cents a kilogram on sugar consumers to raise money to promote structural change and help farmers to leave the industry. This was aimed at relieving the problems of over supply and low prices. – Cheese quotas. During 2000–01, import quotas on cheese were finally abolished. Between 1996–97 and 2006–07, reforms (again announced through the budget) made welfare less accessible to some people. For example, measures included: ■ working for the dole ■ maintaining a jobs interview diary ■ forcing the unemployed to turn up to job interviews by suspending the payment of benefits ■ tightening the work test ■ requiring some on disability benefits and single parents (whose children have reached school age) to do at least 15 hours of work a week ■ encouraging the aged to defer retirement and build up their superannuation ■ setting up a hot line to report welfare fraud ■ allowing welfare recipients to earn more income before benefits are lost (so as the reduce the welfare trap as recipients start work). Welfare reform has been seen as an opportunity to increase efficiency in resource allocation. Some people felt the original system was over generous. Claims were made that it encouraged welfare dependence, and discouraged work and financial independence. It was also seen as a burden on taxpayers, a limitation on high rates of labour force participation and a constraint on the rate of economic growth. Deregulation of transport markets In the past two decades there have been numerous examples of changes in the Australian transport system. ■ Airline deregulation. In 1990 the government’s two airline or duopoly policy for domestic flights (i.e. Ansett Airlines and Australian Airlines) was ended. In addition, Qantas was allowed into the domestic market and was privatised. This cleared the way for new competitors like Virgin Airlines, Jetstar and foreign carriers, to compete on both domestic and international routes. ■ Unifying state railways. Some years ago, the National Rail Corporation was set up, owned jointly by the Victorian, New South Wales, Western Australian and federal governments. This reform was designed to improve efficiency and cut waste and duplication. ■ Waterfront and shipping reform. These included the privatisation of some ports (e.g. Geelong), allowing competitors into freight handling to help improve worker productivity on the waterfront (helped by the extension of workplace agreements) and an end to the closed or union shop for waterfront workers. ■ Road reforms. Much money has been spent on upgrading national highways. In addition, the level of motor registration charges more closely reflect the damage to roads caused by various types of users. Contracting out and competitive tendering Contracting out (also called outsourcing) is where agreements are made for the supply of goods and services, between the government and private business. In order to cut costs, firms are invited to respond to government advertisements by submitting quotes or tenders. This approach has been widely used in garbage collection, cleaning and maintenance of government buildings, fleet management, information technology, legal services and public works. Sometimes this can be more cost efficient than having these goods and services provided by fulltime government employees and departments. All up, reforms of the public sector will affect unemployment, inflation, economic growth, external competitiveness, allocative, productive and dynamic efficiency, and the distribution of personal income. GENERAL DEREGULATION OF MARKETS Economists generally believe that resources are most efficiently allocated where there is strong competition. Sometimes, this can only occur if governments reduce regulations that restrict competition. During the 1980s, 1990s and 2000s, market deregulation has been a focus of many of the government’s microeconomic reforms. Financial sector deregulation The main microeconomic financial reforms have already been covered in chapter 6 (p. 206). You may recall that these focused on reducing government controls. It exposed the banking sector to more competition so that efficiency improved and interest rates on loans became cheaper. Deregulation of telecommunications Between 1990 and 2007, there were some significant changes in telecommunications to allow more competition in the industry. CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 251 Optus and Telstra, for example, were locked in a battle for customers and the cost of some telephone services has come down. Telstra downsized its staff to cut costs and was progressively privatised between 1997 and 2006, after the Coalition government gained a majority in the Upper House that allowed it to pass the necessary legislation. REFORMS TO STRENGTHEN COMPETITION Strong competition usually results in greater efficiency, lower costs of production, cheaper prices, and better quality of service and product. Unfortunately, in some markets, competition between rival firms is weak due to the existence of monopolies, oligopolies, takeovers, mergers, and price collusion. For these reasons, the government undertook reforms to strengthen competition. In 1995, the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) was set up to take over the roles previously covered by the Trade Practices Commission (TPC) and the Prices Surveillance Authority (PSA). As such, the ACCC now enforces the TPA, which is designed to help prevent powerful companies (i.e. price makers) from artificially raising prices to exploit consumers. Under the Act, a number of practices are illegal such as: ■ Price fixing, for example, where firms collaborate to set prices. ■ Exclusive dealing, for example, where companies refuse to supply their products or services to one or more firms. ■ Collusive bidding, for example, in submitting a tender or quote for the completion of works or to supply goods or services, supposedly competing firms meet secretly beforehand to agree whose tender should be most attractive, cheapest and likely to win the contract. ■ Price leadership, for example, where the dominant or leading firm takes a lead in setting prices that others follow. ■ Predatory pricing, for example, where the dominant firms conduct a price war involving big cuts in prices with the intention of driving rival firms bankrupt, and then later enjoying the market without competition. ■ Market zoning, for example, where competing firms in a region divide up the market into zones, areas or regions within which they agree not to compete with each other over prices. ■ Interlocking directorships, for example, where a person acting as a member of the board of directors for one company, is also on the board as a director of a supposed rival company. If a company is found guilty of these offences, fines of up $500 000 for individuals or $10 000 000 for companies may be imposed, along with possible jail sentences for company directors. The ACCC also performs other functions. For example, it supervises company mergers and takeovers to ensure that they do not reduce competition and that they are in the public interest. In addition, it monitors pricing (prices surveillance) and other arrangements (e.g. false advertising claims) in industries where competition is weak including the utilities, aviation and airports, insurance, petrol, postal, rail, waterfront and communications. Recently, between 2000 and 2007, the ACCC has adopted a high profile and aggressive stance to promote competition. It took legal action against Coles which owns Liquorland. There were allegations that Coles had engaged in anti-competitive behaviour in New South Wales by entering into contracts with outlets licensed to sell liquor. One of the terms of the contract prevented these licensed operators from supplying packaged takeaway liquor to consumers and, therefore, restricting competition. The ACCC also considered cases involving the companies and industries listed below (but it should be noted that not all of these firms have been found guilty of breaching the Act). Qantas Major banks Archem Australia Telstra Seven Network Hutchison Australia Foxtel Berri Fruit Juice Advanced Medical Institute Optus ABB Power Transmission Australian Gaslight Limited Mobil, BP, Shell and Caltex Darwin Radio Taxis Chubb Security Coles–Myer, Liquorland, Woolworths Coopers & Lybrand and Price Waterhouse (Price WaterhouseCoopers) Nissen Source: Data derived from the ACCC. 252 Economics Down Under Book 2 ENVIRONMENTAL REFORMS Environmental reforms cover issues related to environmental change, energy and water use. Energy For some years now, concern has been expressed about the impact of burning fossil fuels (e.g. by cars, trucks, power generators, industry and waste disposal) on greenhouse gas emissions and global climate change. This gave rise to a summit that proposed the Kyoto protocol or convention that commenced in 2003. The aim was to limit carbon emissions by industrialised nations to specific target levels. Emissions by firms would need to be offset by firms purchasing carbon credits in the marketplace. This scheme gives pollution emissions by a firm a cost, or money value, that affects company profits and hence their resource allocation. For Australia, the target for the 2008–12 commitment period, was to slow the emissions rise to only 108 per cent of the 1990 benchmark level. Clearly, if Australia had signed up to this agreement, it would have had significant effects on the structure and operations of some local industries and firms, relative to others (e.g. brown coal power generation, road transport, the smelting of aluminium and other metals). The government did not sign this protocol, but did set renewable energy targets. More recently, the rise in oil prices (2004–06) and growing concern about climate change (in the context of the current drought) caused by greenhouse gases, has led to the federal government’s renewed interest in the problem. Reports were commissioned in 2006 into nuclear energy and a possible system for trading carbon credits (i.e. licences to pollute, the market price of which would place a cost on firms that pollute). Water trading There is growing concern also about water. The current drought and, for farmers, the string of dry seasons that stretches back to 2003–04, have prompted this. Many of our largest cities are on stage 4 (or higher) water restrictions and our productive capacity has been reduced. The matter has also raised debate about using irrigation for growing crops like rice in almost desert conditions and how to maintain environmental river flows. In late 2006 and again in 2007, the Prime Minister called a summit of state premiers to discuss the matter and to commence work on reforms including a water trading scheme. SOCIAL INFRASTRUCTURE The social infrastructure includes the government’s provision of adequate health, education and housing. This task is made more difficult because of financial constraints in the budget, an already high direct tax burden, tax avoidance, growing welfare dependency, a drop in the growth rate for the labour force, and an ageing population that is expecting higher standards of welfare and health care (as highlighted in the Treasurer’s 2002–03, Intergenerational report). These developments have forced efficiency improvements in the government’s delivery of services. Additionally, other reforms have involved the following. Funding cuts and user pays During the past 10 years, there have been cuts in the government staffing and funding of departments, and in some cases, increased application of the user-pays principle. Public–private partnerships Public–private partnerships involving the private financing of social infrastructure (e.g. schools, welfare housing and hospitals) have expanded, where the government leases these facilities back from private-sector owners. Health insurance rebate There has been the introduction of the 30 per cent rebate to help offset some of the cost of private health insurance (to relieve the pressure on Medicare), along with the use of casemix funding in public hospitals. Education A review of education has taken place. This has included federal funding of public and private schools and the application of national literacy standards. MICROECONOMIC POLICY RESULTED IN PRIVATE–SECTOR REFORM Government microeconomic reform, especially market deregulation and trade liberalisation, have a knock-on effect. They force the private sector to restructure the way it goes about producing goods and services. No longer can local firms coast along if they want to survive foreign competition. In their battle to increase efficiency, privately operated firms must keep on reviewing their business practices. Often this has involved the following changes. Rationalisation of operations Local firms must rationalise their operations, closing down unprofitable or less viable branches. For example, BHP closed its Newcastle plant, Email ceased its dishwasher and other operations in Victoria, Mitsubishi closed its engine plant in South Australia, banks including the ANZ, the Commonwealth, NAB and Westpac have reduced branches and shed over nearly 20 per cent of their staff. Benchmarking against best practice Benchmarking has been widely introduced and involves setting time targets for particular processes and work tasks, using the standards set by leading international plants. Costs There has been an increased focus on recycling, reducing production times, operating with fewer staff, and cutting costs, waste and delivery delays. Technology Technology has been applied more widely and is updated more frequently. Management Many firms have used a flatter management structure. This involves fewer levels of middle management and increased responsibilities and performance targets for ordinary workers. Training There has been the promotion of continuous learning, multiskilling, teamwork and encouragement of adaptability by staff. CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 253 Stocks Keeping large stocks of components or finished product is expensive so, increasingly, firms employ the idea of ‘just in time’ (JIT) (when new stock is only ordered when stocks are running low). Marketing During the 1990s and 2000s, there has been a broadening in the approach to product marketing from having a local orientation, to greater emphasis on e-commerce and global markets. Wage system Most firms use a performance-based pay system from CEOs down. This involves workplace agreements that link wage rises to the achievement of productivity and other targets. Some of the results of reform have been nothing short of staggering. For example, at Rio Tinto’s Hamersley mining operations, wage, industrial relations and other changes reduced the number of hours lost to industrial disputes by around 98 per cent over a recent 10-year period, and at the same time, grew productivity by nearly 90 per cent in terms of tonnes of ore mined per employee a year. These outcomes meant a huge cost saving that translated into increased output, higher profits, business expansion, increased employment and rises in real incomes. Communication Businesses have sought to improve communication between staff, since this helps to lift efficiency. Increasingly, the top-down command system of management has been replaced by a twoway system of communication. This gives employees greater responsibility for their performance and may improve the level of cooperation between workers and management, leading to lower rates of strikes and industrial conflict. TRY SHORT ANSWER EXERCISE 2, pp. 276–77 7.4 Using microeconomic policy to improve domestic economic stability 254 Economics Down Under Book 2 side conditions aimed at encouraging an increase in AS, all three aspects of economic stability should eventually improve. Economic growth should be stronger, inflation slower and unemployment lower than would otherwise occur. Let us see why these improved outcomes should occur. AS1 = original supply-side conditions General price level Remember that internal or domestic economic stability entails the government simultaneously achieving the objectives of: ■ price stability (an average annual inflation rate over the cycle of 2–3 per cent) ■ sustainable economic growth (average annual GDP growth of around 4 per cent) ■ full employment (an unemployment rate of around 5–6 per cent of the labour force). During the past two decades, microeconomic reform has become an increasingly important part of the overall policy mix or combination. While monetary and budgetary policies act as shorterterm stabilisers of the level of AD, microeconomic policies help to improve stability in the longer term by growing Australia’s productive capacity and boosting our AS. Supply-side microeconomic reforms like labour market or wage deregulation, trade liberalisation, cuts in tax rates, improved public-sector efficiency, growing the level of national savings and competition reforms, all help us to produce a greater level of national output from fewer inputs, and at a lower cost or general price level. These beneficial impacts of reforms are illustrated on the AD–AS diagram shown in figure 7.5. Notice that, as a result of microeconomic efficiency policies, the economy’s productive capacity has grown from AS1 to AS2 (i.e. the AS line has shifted outwards). As a result, the equilibrium level of national output has grown from GDP1 to GDP2, and the general level of costs and prices has fallen from P1 to P2. This is more or less what has happened in Australia following microeconomic reforms, especially during the past 20 years to 2007. Because microeconomic policies try to promote better supply- P1 Cost inflation AS2 = increased productive capacity following macroeconomic, supply-side efficiency reforms P2 AD1 = ideal levels of spending GDP1 = original sustainable rate of economic growth and employment GDP2 = increased sustainable rate of economic growth Real GDP (national output) Figure 7.5 How microeconomic supply-side reforms can help improve domestic economic stability Microeconomic reforms have helped ‘price stability’ Through various efficiency reforms (i.e. productive, allocative, dynamic and intertemporal efficiency) involving structural change, the use of positive incentives, and stronger competition, firms have lowered their production costs. If goods and services Table 7.4 cost less to produce, businesses can keep their prices down and still make good profits. This slows cost inflation and greatly improves price stability. In the long term, improved price stability and international competitiveness also help GDP and employment growth and, hence, general economic stability. Six of the most significant microeconomic reforms designed to slow cost inflation pressures are reviewed in table 7.4. The top six microeconomic reforms that fight inflation 1. Tariff cuts and trade liberalisation There were progressive cuts in general tariff rates from around 40 per cent in 1968–69, to zero for most items by 2005–06, along with ongoing reductions in those for cars, textiles, clothing and footwear. Additionally, subsidies were reduced, import quotas abolished and four FTAs were in operation by early 2007 (with four more in the pipeline). Tariff cuts helped to keep inflation down. This happened in several ways. ■ Reduced tariffs increased the level of competition forcing local firms to slash their costs and prices. ■ Lower tariffs and freer trade made imports cheaper. This meant a significant reduction in production costs for firms using imported equipment. Goods were also less expensive for households purchasing imports such as cars, footwear, clothing and electrical goods. ■ Cheaper imports helped to siphon off excess AD, thereby slowing demand inflation. ■ Lower tariffs forced businesses to allocate resources more efficiently to areas where our comparative cost advantage was greatest. This too helped to keep inflation down. 2. Labour market deregulation The past decade and a half has seen the extension of efficiency or performance-based workplace wage agreements. These and other labour market reforms helped to actually reduce RULCs during the 10 years to 2005–06. Being the main cost of production for many firms, lower RULCs in turn slowed cost inflation. In addition, these reforms also contributed greatly to reducing costly industrial strikes. 3. Competition reforms Changes were made to improve the level of competition between sellers of goods and services. These included the creation of the ACCC, the strengthening of the TPA, widened surveillance of prices, and closer scrutiny of mergers and takeovers. Economists believe that strong competition between rival firms is a precondition needed for efficiency and lower inflation rates. 4. Public sector efficiency reforms Public sector efficiency reforms helped to reduce production costs and hence inflation. These included privatisation, corporatisation, contracting out and competitive tendering, and public service staff cuts. As a result of reforms, the cost to users of many government services actually fell in real terms. 5. Tax reforms The reductions in most tax rates (e.g. on personal incomes and company profits) between 2000 and early 2007, helped to slow inflation. Companies had higher after-tax profits allowing them to absorb some of the cost rises without putting up their prices. This helped to accelerate investment in more efficient new equipment. Individuals were also encouraged to work harder, knowing they would get to keep more of their income. This helped productivity and lowered inflation. 6. Promoting national savings Measures (e.g. encouragement of superannuation, budget surpluses, the Future Fund) were put in place to try and promote national savings. With more savings available for lending, the cost to firms of borrowing credit used to finance investment in new equipment and technology tended to become cheaper than otherwise. Indeed, current interest rates are at a 30-year low. This helps to reduce cost pressures on firms and slow inflation. CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 255 Microeconomic reforms have promoted higher sustainable economic growth There are two ways supply-side microeconomic reform can help accelerate the rate of economic growth that an economy can sustain, without jeopardising price stability: 1. Microeconomic policy can increase Australia’s sustainable rate of economic growth by expanding our productive capacity. This occurs because greater efficiency allows businesses to produce a bigger output from the same inputs, simply by cutting costs or using the available resources more efficiently. 2. Cost-cutting efficiency reforms (e.g. industry assistance, cuts in tax rates, labour and capital market deregulation, modifications to welfare access and R&D schemes) lift the sustainable rate of GDP growth by boosting business profits and creating incentives for individuals to work harder. This improves worker motivation and makes firms more willing to expand their output. Table 7.5 shows some of the more important microeconomic reforms used to help increase Australia’s sustainable rate of economic growth during the past 10–20 years to 2007. Table 7.5 The top four microeconomic reforms that promote sustainable economic growth 1. Tax reforms In general, lower tax rates (as in Australia, 1999–2007) help to boost economic growth and productive capacity. From the supply-side point of view, reduced rates of company and capital gains taxes help to grow the after-tax profits of investors and firms. This motivates business expansion through increased investment spending on new equipment and technology. Capital deepening (i.e. more investment or capital per worker) leads to better efficiency. Similarly, lower rates of PAYG help to encourage hard work since individuals can retain a larger percentage of their income. This may also lead to higher rates of saving and investment. 2. Labour market deregulation Australia’s labour market reforms have mainly been about boosting worker productivity and using resources more efficiently. For instance, workplace agreements represent a performance-based wage system. Typically, these agreements only pay higher wages when there is increased worker efficiency. In addition, the relaxation of the unfair dismissal laws (see Work Choices, 2005) might mean that more workers are employed than previously, contributing to increased national production. 3. Public sector reforms Australia’s public sector produces almost 20 per cent of GDP. As a result of efficiency reforms including cost cutting, contracting out, privatisation and corporatisation, our productive capacity and sustainable rate of economic growth should tend to increase. 4. Reforms to promote national savings Australians save too little to finance national investment. Among other things, this leads to higher interest rates that discourage business expansion in plant and equipment. In turn, this slows our sustainable rate of economic growth. However, the savings reforms between 1991 and 2007 including many surplus budgets, the creation of the Future Fund, the introduction of compulsory superannuation and other incentives to encourage private superannuation, should help to correct this problem. 256 Economics Down Under Book 2 Microeconomic reforms have helped encourage fuller employment There is little doubt that microeconomic reform increased structural unemployment over the short and medium terms. Often, cost reductions by firms, the promotion of efficiency and the rationalisation of production by the private and public sectors, resulted in the downsizing of staffing levels. Although this is very distressing for those involved, theoretically, if there is improved efficiency, product quality, price competitiveness and business profitability, in the longer term, fewer firms should close down. Structural unemployment should drop. Indeed, reforms should eventually help to grow employment opportunities more than would be the case if industries were inefficient. In addition, local efficiency reforms help to grow domestic and international sales of goods and services, generating even more jobs. Table 7.6 summarises some stand out microeconomic reforms affecting employment. Some other advantages of microeconomic policy Microeconomic reforms have other advantages. effective in dealing with supply-side structural causes of economic instability. ■ While contractionary monetary and budgetary measures work well to slow demand inflation, they often worsen cost inflation. This is not a problem with microeconomic reforms. These actually reduce costs and do not depend on stopping the economy to check inflation. ■ Similarly, expansionary budgetary and monetary policies work quite well by boosting AD to counteract a cyclical slowdown economic activity and employment. However, microeconomic measures are far more effective than macroeconomic strategies in actually lifting the sustainable rate at which the economy can grow. Microeconomic policies are consistent with achieving most other government economic objectives In promoting domestic stability through greater efficiency, this helps the government achieve its other economic objectives. For instance, external stability should be improved as firms become more internationally competitive and we are less dependent on financing national investment through overseas borrowing and debt. Certainly there will be greater efficiency in resource allocation and, in the long term, this may even lead to improved equity in income distribution. Microeconomic policy is more effective than macroeconomic policy in some situations Unlike macroeconomic policy in general, and especially monetary policy in particular, microeconomic reforms are very Table 7.6 The top five microeconomic reforms that can lower unemployment in the long term 1. Tax reforms Tax rates were cut (especially during the years 1999 and 2007) partly because lower rates help to create more jobs and less unemployment. Reduced company and capital gains taxes encourage higher levels of business investment and expansion because after-tax profits are higher and firms are more internationally competitive. This generates jobs whereas low or falling company profits destroy employment. 2. Welfare reforms Reforms (especially 1996–2007) have made it more difficult to access welfare and have removed some of the disincentives to work. The welfare trap has been reduced. New policies have also aimed to increase labour force participation rates and get more individuals to accept responsibility for their personal financial situation. 3. Trade liberalisation Over 20 per cent of Australian jobs result from international trade. Trade reforms in the years to 2007 focused on cutting the level of tariff and other protection, and expanding FTAs. In the short term, it is likely that the move towards freer trade caused structural unemployment to rise as local firms closed down due to import penetration of the domestic market. However, some research confirms that employment grows fastest in more globalised industries where, due to lower tariffs, resources are allocated efficiently into areas of comparative cost advantage. 4. Labour market reforms Employment grows and unemployment shrinks if Australian firms are profitable due to lower production costs. One of the key costs is wages for labour. Over the past 15 years to 2007, there has been extensive deregulation of our labour market and wages, with the extension of workplace agreements to cover around 90 per cent of workers. This has been the main reason for the actual fall in RULCs (by around 0.44 per cent per year during 1996–2006), and record levels of business profitability experienced in recent years. 5. Reforms to lift national savings Business can only expand if it has access to cheap finance and low interest rates. Recent reforms have tried to grow the pool of national savings via surplus budgets, the Future Fund and inducements for superannuation. As a result, interest rates are lower than would have otherwise been the case. CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 257 HAS MICROECONOMIC POLICY PROMOTED DOMESTIC STABILITY? Conclusive evidence of the success (or otherwise) of these microeconomic reforms is difficult to find. This is because there are so many local and international factors other than microeconomic policy, that affect how well the economy performs. Even so, it is interesting to compare data for two periods of time — first, for the years 1980–1992 (prior to the acceleration of reform), and second, for the period from 1992–93 to 2005–06 (when changes in microeconomic policy were much faster). Table 7.7 attempts to do this using a scorecard. Table 7.7 Notice for example: ■ Productivity is growing much more strongly. ■ RULCs for firms have actually decreased. ■ Strike rates are greatly reduced. ■ The cost of overdraft interest rates is much cheaper for firms borrowing credit. ■ Tax rates on companies are significantly lower. ■ The labour force participation rate has increased. ■ Tariff protection of local manufacturing industry is now almost non-existent. ■ Many goods and services (e.g. electrical appliances and air travel) are now cheaper for households and firms. These trends have implications for the achievement of domestic economic stability. A scorecard for government microeconomic policy for domestic economic stability INDICATOR OF THE SUCCESS OF MICROECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS AVERAGE 1980– 92 AVERAGE 1992– 2006 NOTES ABOUT THE CHANGE IN AVERAGES (1992–06 COMPARED WITH 1980–92 AND OTHER YEARS) Price stability: Inflation (average annual percentage change in CPI) 8.1 2.6 Inflation down by 67.9 per cent Sustained economic growth: GDP growth (average annual percentage change) 3.4 3.7 Sustainable rate of economic growth faster by 8.8 per cent Full employment: Unemployment rate (average percentage of labour force) 7.7 7.1 Unemployment down by 7.8 per cent (October 2006, a 30-year low figure of 40.3 per cent down on 1980–92) 1. Productivity (average percentage change in GDP per hour worked) 1.2 2.1 Average labour efficiency increased by 75 per cent –0.3 –0.4 Average RULCs for firms are falling and cheaper by 33 per cent 65 Estimate down by 81.5 per cent (2005–06 figure down an estimated 97 per cent on 1970s average) 2. RULCs (average annual percentage change) 3. Strikes level (average working days lost per 1000 employees) 352 4. Gross profit growth (average annual percentage change) 11.2 8.5 5. Rate of company tax (average percentage of profits) 44 6. Interest rates on overdrafts (average percentage a year) 16 9.1 7. Labour force participation rate (average percentage of total persons) 61 63.4 Average is up by 3.9 per cent (October 2006 figure down 6.7 per cent) 8. General manufacturing tariff rate (average annual effective percentage) 19 2 A fall in the average annual level of tariff protection by 89.5 per cent 33 Sources: Data derived from ABS 1350.0; RBA Bulletin; RBA Occasional Paper, No. 8A. 258 Economics Down Under Book 2 Down by 24.1 per cent Down by 25 per cent (2005–06 rate 39.9 per cent down on 1980 rate) Down by 43.1 per cent (2005–06 rate down 54 per cent on 1989 rate) Some possible successes of reforms Based on table 7.7 and other data for the past 25 or more years to 2005–06, many commentators believe that recent microeconomic policies generally have been very effective in promoting domestic stability in three ways. 1. A faster sustainable rate of economic growth Economic activity rose in all years at an annual average of around 3.6 per cent. This higher sustainable rate of economic growth was the result of good profits, greater productivity, increased labour force participation rates, fewer strikes, lower tax rates and cheaper credit. Although the average rate was just short of the government’s 4 per cent target, it was held back in the past 3–4 years to 2007, because the economy had little unused productive capacity. 2. Better price stability Overall, inflation was within the government’s 2–3 per cent target (unlike the years 1980–92), thanks partly to stronger productivity of over 2 per cent a year, falling RULCs, lower tariffs and cheaper credit for firms. The price of some goods and services actually went down. Even so, there were two spikes in Australia’s inflation rate in 2000–01 and 2006–07. These were partly provoked by once-off events, and more recently, by the fact that the economy was close to its productive capacity. for whatever reason, equity in income distribution also tends to suffer in the short term. This is because unemployment causes incomes, purchasing and access to basic goods and services to be reduced. When assessing the short-term effects of microeconomic policy on the level of structural unemployment and equity, the following reforms have proved to be the most damaging. ■ Reduced tariffs and protection. Import duties have been progressively reduced. The general tariff rate was cut from 15 per cent in 1992 to zero by 2005–06. In addition, in the 14 years to 2005, tariffs on cars fell from 35 to 10 per cent, and, for the textiles, clothing and footwear industries, from 47.5 to a maximum of 15 per cent. This caused business closures and structural unemployment in the manufacturing sector. ■ Labour market reforms. Labour market reforms (especially the extension of enterprise agreements) have increased worker productivity. In many cases, more work is now completed using fewer staff, temporarily causing a slower growth in employment. ■ Reforms to the government sector. Initially between 1987 and 1999, there was a 35 per cent reduction in public sector staff levels due to the effects of privatisation, corporatisation, commercialisation, contracting out and the government’s fiscal consolidation. However, between 1999 and 2006, numbers have again grown, although not to previous levels. 3. Fuller employment This period eventually saw the achievement of the full employment target (i.e. 5–6 per cent unemployment). Except for a slight rise during the slowdown of 2000–01, unemployment fell fairly steadily from 8.3 per cent in 1996, to a 30-year low of only 4.6 per cent in late 2006. This may be partly attributed to the increased competitiveness of local firms following effective microeconomic reforms (e.g. labour market deregulation, tax cuts and savings reforms). Some areas of weakness in reforms Despite this apparent success, critics of recent microeconomic policy draw attention to some areas of weaknesses. The pace of microeconomic reform slowed down between 2001 and 2005 Microeconomic reform appears to have moved in waves with peaks in the early 1990s, 1996, 2000 and perhaps 2005. Despite some renewed interest in 2005, the pace of change did seem to slow and the federal opposition believed that the government had run out of new ideas. Possible conflict with other government objectives in the short term Perhaps the most severe weakness of many microeconomic policies in Australia is that, in the short term, they are likely to weaken the achievement of full employment and equity. For example, in the 1990s and 2000s, structural change has meant that most firms have produced more output with fewer workers. Indeed, ABS data shows that while manufacturing output rose 36 per cent between 1996–97 and 2005–06, this sector provided nearly 7 per cent fewer jobs. This was only possible because there has been a 19 per cent rise in labour productivity (i.e. GDP per hour worked). In addition, when unemployment rises, ■ Structural change by businesses. There has been massive restructuring, especially in the car, textiles, aviation, transport, farming, telecommunications and banking industries. This has often been associated with the accelerated use of new technology (e.g. robots, computers and the Internet, and R&D), the rationalisation of company branches (i.e. sometimes caused by integration, mergers, takeovers), and the introduction of new worker–management systems designed to cut costs. Political constraints slow or weaken reform As we saw between 1996 and 2007, many microeconomic reforms (e.g. the Workplace Relations Act, the privatisation of Telstra, and the introduction of the GST) initially failed to gain approval in the Upper House where federal governments lacked a majority until 2005. In addition, WorkChoices (2005–06) the proposed sale of Medibank Private (perhaps 2007) and the Snowy Mountains Hydro Scheme (the idea was scrapped in 2006), proved CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 259 unpopular with some sections of the community. Political constraints like these, slow the speed of reform and may sometimes result in them being watered down and made less effective. a short-term stabiliser to iron out fluctuations in the business cycle. Instead, microeconomic measures are more aimed at the longer term where they are limited mainly to raising efficiency and the sustainable rate of economic growth, cutting business costs and inflation, and improving the international competitiveness and profitability of Australian firms. Implementation lags are often long Microeconomic policy can involve enormous time lags or delays in policy implementation. Reform of the car industry, for instance, commenced in 1983 but the tariff cuts associated with it, will still not be complete until some time after 2010. Another example of implementation delays is labour market deregulation. This was designed to slow the growth in wages, reduce cost inflation and improve external competitiveness. Workplace agreements were first approved in 1991, but even by 2006, over 10 per cent of the labour force was still regulated by the old minimum wage system. This long implementation lag also reduced the ability of reform to improve domestic stability. Institutional constraints slow the pace of reform While some people are critical of change, others believe that our pace of reform has been too slow. One reason for this is the institutional constraints that limit progress. There does seem to have been a lack of real commitment to reform across a wide range of institutions from unions, to business and to government at all levels. In addition, greater determination to implement reform overseas has meant that relatively, Australia may still be losing ground. Inability to use microeconomic reforms as a short-term stabiliser Unlike macroeconomic policies that can help reduce the severity of booms and recessions, microeconomic reform cannot be used as TRY SHORT ANSWER EXERCISE 3, pp. 277–78 7.5 Using microeconomic policy to improve external stability For Australia, the government’s objective of external stability means that we should be able to pay our way in international transactions, without undue downward pressures on the A$ or an excessively large CAD or NFD. Figure 7.6 shows, hypothetically, that there are two sets of factors currently causing Australia’s external problems. 1. From time to time, excessively strong AD and economic activity can cause a cyclical rise in our CAD. 2. There are ongoing or long-term structural problems that cause the CAD to seldom fall below 3 per cent of GDP. As supply-side efficiency measures, microeconomic reforms are very well suited in the long term, for dealing with Australia’s external structural problems, namely: ■ the large saving–investment gap that is currently filled by borrowing overseas ■ our relatively high production costs that reduce our international competitiveness. Let us now consider each of these two areas to see what macroeconomic policy is doing to correct the problem. CAD:GDP ratio (%) 6 2. A large CAD:GDP ratio of around 6% shows that there is excessively strong AD and economic activity. National expenditure is running ahead of our productive capacity. Contractionary macroeconomic measures might help to reduce this problem. 3 1. This area represents ongoing structural causes of external instability including our poor competitiveness and our big NFD due to a lack of domestic savings to fill the S–I gap. This problem can be reduced by microeconomic reforms that improve our competitiveness and close our national S–I gap. 0 A figure of around 3–4% for the CAD:GDP ratio is the government’s target for the objective of external stability. This is most likely to be achieved when there is domestic economic stability (rather than a boom). Years Figure 7.6 The causes of external instability and its reduction using microeconomic policies 260 Economics Down Under Book 2 Reducing the large ‘gap’ in national savings and investment Australians do not save enough to finance their high level of investment in new plant and equipment. We have come to depend very heavily on overseas borrowing and debt, in order to make up the difference. This problem then adds to Australia’s CAD (especially the huge net income deficit) and has contributed to the long-term decline in the A$. In addition, poor savings mean that domestic interest rates paid by businesses borrowing credit, are often higher than those faced abroad. This further encourages overseas borrowing. It also represents a cost disadvantage by discouraging local firms from purchasing the latest technology needed to lift efficiency, and it lowers the competitiveness of our exports relative to imports. Table 7.8 reviews some of the key microeconomic reforms used to try to increase domestic savings. companies have to contend with relatively high tax rates. Because it often costs more to produce goods and services here, it is difficult for local firms to keep prices down and still make reasonable profits. Regrettably, high domestic costs and prices undermine export sales and encourage imports. They also prevent our firms from adding greater value to exports through further processing or manufacture. Together, these problems contribute directly to Australia’s ongoing structural CAD, rising NFD and overall declining value of the A$. Microeconomic policy has tried hard to improve Australia’s international competitiveness through the cost-cutting efficiency measures shown in table 7.9 (p. 262). Coverage here will be brief because these measures have been mentioned already in connection with slowing inflation. Lowering our high costs and improving our international competitiveness Often due to low efficiency and our particular endowments of resources, Australian firms often face higher production costs relative to those overseas. Costs here include wages, interest rates on borrowed credit, utilities (i.e. energy, water, telecommunications), transport, imported materials and equipment, and high fixed costs caused by the local market being comparatively small in size (this reduces economies gained from large-scale production where costs can be spread more thinly). In addition, Table 7.8 Five microeconomic reforms that may help increase national savings 1. Surplus budgets and pursuit of fiscal balance Since 1996, the Treasurer has accepted the idea of fiscal balance in the medium term, where budget surpluses pay for deficits. This means that there is no Federal public sector borrowing requirement and, by 2005, all Commonwealth debt had been repaid. This helped to reduce the size of the NFD and CAD. It also meant that interest rates were lower than otherwise, stimulating private sector investment in new technology and helping to improve our international competitiveness. 2. The Future Fund In 2005, the Future Fund was created. It used proceeds from asset sales and surplus budgets to try to grow national savings and capital through wise investments. 3. Tax concessions for private superannuation contributions The government encourages private superannuation contributions by offering very generous income tax concessions for those sacrificing their salary and, from July 2007, individuals can withdraw their superannuation tax-free, once they reach the age of 60 years. 4. Introduce the compulsory national superannuation guarantee charge Starting in 1991, national superannuation was made compulsory for all employees through the introduction of the Superannuation guarantee charge (SGC). This levy on business originally started at 3 per cent, but in 2002, was increased to 9 per cent of an employee’s pay. 5. The co-contributions superannuation The Superannuation co-contributions scheme commenced in 2002–03. Basically, the government matches low-income after-tax superannuation contributions at the rate of up to $1.50 for every $1 (higher for 2007–08) put into an approved superannuation account. 6. Tax reform involving lower tax rates Between 1999 and 2007, there were significant reforms involving cuts in tax rates. Many of these changes should help to increase disposable incomes and national savings by individuals and companies. CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 261 Table 7.9 Six microeconomic reforms that help increase our international competitiveness 1. Tariff cuts and trade liberalisation In the 30 or more years, to 2007, local industry has been exposed progressively to much stronger competition from imports following reductions in tariffs and subsidies, the abolition of import quotas and the growing number of FTAs. This has forced Australian firms to cut costs by restructuring their production, improve product quality and service, and to allocate resources more efficiently into areas where our comparative cost advantage is greatest. 2. Labour market deregulation Under workplace agreements, wage rates paid by firms now, more closely reflect market conditions of demand and supply than was the case when the traditional centralised minimum wage system was more dominant. Reforming the wage system, changing legislation about unfair dismissal, and encouraging union amalgamation and multiskilling, have all helped to lower RULCs. This has made local exporters more competitive. 3. Deregulation of other markets The government also has deregulated many other markets (e.g. including aviation, power, communications, primary products, and financial markets) to stimulate competition, improve efficiency and strengthen the international competitiveness of local firms. The floating of the A$ in particular has helped to ensure that the A$ trades at an appropriate level that reflects global demand and supply conditions. This acts as an automatic device to help correct the size of our CAD. 4. Competition reforms The promotion of stronger competition through the Trade Practices Act and its enforcement by the ACCC has helped to keep business costs and prices down. This makes local firms more competitive. 5. Public sector efficiency reforms There has been significant privatisation of government business enterprises during the past 20 years to 2007. Supporters claim that this lifts efficiency, cuts production costs for firms using these services, and allows them to sell profitably at lower prices. In addition, corporatisation of some government businesses and overall reductions in the size of the public sector have contributed to lower costs of government and a more competitive economy. 6. Tax reforms Reforms here have especially focused on lowering tax rates on individuals and firms. For example, reductions in taxes on company profits and capital gains, allow firms to enjoy better after-tax profits. Local exporters can also sell at a lower more competitive price, encouraging better sales. HAS MICROECONOMIC POLICY PROMOTED EXTERNAL STABILITY? It is hard to prove the success or otherwise of microeconomic policies. This is because there are so many local and international factors affecting Australia’s ability to ‘pay its way’, and 262 Economics Down Under Book 2 in turn, influencing the CAD, NFD and exchange rate for the A$. Isolating cause and effect accurately, is almost impossible. Even so, the data in table 7.10 helps to cast light on the situation. It compares statistics for the years spanning 1996–97 to 2005–06 (when microeconomic policies were at their peak), with those for 1980–1992 (before microeconomic reforms gained popularity). Table 7.10 A government microeconomic policy scorecard for external stability INDICATOR OF THE SUCCESS OF MICROECONOMIC POLICY REFORMS ANNUAL AVERAGE 1980– 92 ANNUAL AVERAGE 1992– 2006 NOTES ABOUT THE CHANGE IN AVERAGES (1992–06 COMPARED WITH 1980–92 AND OTHER YEARS) CAD:GDP ratio (percentage) 4.8 4.6 There was a slight reduction in the average size of the CAD:GDP ratio by about 4 per cent NFD:GDP ratio (percentage) 25.7 38.5 The average size of the NFD:GDP ratio ballooned by nearly 50 per cent TWI (1970 = base year = 100 points) 67.1 55.8 The average value of the A$ on a TWI basis fell by nearly 17 per cent 1. Productivity (percentage change in GDP per hour worked) 1.2 2.1 The average annual rate of growth in labour efficiency increased by 75 per cent 2. Household savings ratio (percentage of GDP) 7.8 1.6 Household savings as a percentage of GDP collapsed by nearly 80 per cent –0.3 –0.4 The average annual level of RULCs fell by 33 per cent 65 Estimates of the strike rate are down by over 80 per cent (with the 2005– 06 figure down 97 per cent on the 1970s average) 3. RULCs (annual percentage change) 4. Strike levels (estimated working days lost per 1000 employees) 1878 5. Gross profit growth (percentage) 11.2 8.5 6. Rate of company tax (percentage of profits) 44 7. Interest rates on overdrafts (percentage) 16 9.1 The average cost of business overdrafts was down by about 43 per cent (with the 2005–06 rate down 54 per cent on that for 1989) 8. General manufacturing tariff rate (estimated percentage) 19 2 A fall in the average annual rate of tariff protection by nearly 90 per cent 33 Annual rate of profit growth slowed by about 24 per cent The company tax rate is down by 25 per cent (with the 2005–06 rate down about 40 per cent on that for 1980) Sources: Data derived from ABS 1350.0; RBA Bulletin; RBA Occasional Paper, No. 8A. Some strengths of microeconomic policies Supporters of Australia’s microeconomic policies point out that there are limits to what the government can do to strengthen external stability. As we have seen, a host of reforms certainly tried to improve national savings and our international competitiveness, without which, it could be argued, the results would have been much worse. Microeconomic policies have helped external stability by: ■ increasing worker productivity ■ lowering RULCs for export firms ■ reducing strike rates that are costly to firms and disrupt export trade ■ pushing down interest rates on business overdrafts to a 30-year low, thus cutting production costs and improving competitiveness ■ improving after-tax company profits thereby allowing firms to absorb rising costs and sell exports more cheaply. Some weaknesses of microeconomic policies However, despite these claims, on the face of it, microeconomic reforms appear to have failed to deliver external stability. Table 7.10 supports this. For instance, it can be seen that, for 1996– 2006, the CAD:GDP ratio averaged 4.6 per cent. This exceeds the government’s 3–4 per cent target and, overall, it looks like CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 263 efficiency and savings measures to reduce the CAD have not yet worked. It is also clear that the average size of the NFD as a percentage of GDP has ballooned by nearly 50 per cent. This is despite reforms to close the savings–investment gap. In fact, household savings as a percentage of GDP have actually fallen and are now negative. In addition, despite a much stronger A$, recently, since the low of 2000–01, overall the currency has lost a lot of ground against where it was in 1970, or during the period 1980–92. The picture is even worse taking an even longer-term view. In 1901, for example, A$1 would buy over 70 per cent more in terms of the US$ than at present. Although most commentators acknowledge the usefulness of the government’s microeconomic policies in helping Australia control its external problem, there are several reasons why success appears to be rather limited. Some negative effects of trade liberalisation on external stability On the one hand, tariff cuts can help reduce the cost of imported equipment for local firms and make our exporters more competitive. However, it is also true that lower tariffs can worsen the CAD and weaken the A$. This is because imports become cheaper, thereby encouraging Australians to buy more items made abroad. Conflicts with some other government goals Improving efficiency and international competitiveness through microeconomic policy can conflict with the achievement of other goals. For instance, in the short term it appears that efficiency reforms (e.g. tariff cuts, privatisation, deregulation) often cause structural unemployment. In turn, unemployment usually results in a lower level of disposable income for an individual that limits his or her access to basic goods and services. Typically, living standards are reduced. Policy time lags are usually long The fact that microeconomic policies often have large time lags for implementation and impact, is one reason why the gains may not be all that apparent in the short term. For instance: ■ tariffs cuts commenced in 1973 are still going ■ labour market deregulation involving performance-based workplace agreements started in 1991 yet some workers are still covered by this system. ■ the privatisation of Telstra began in 1998, but all shares will not be sold until at least 2007 ■ the Superannuation guarantee charge commenced in 1992, but savings still only represents 9 per cent of payroll and is insufficient for retirees to have reasonable living standards ■ despite significant changes in 2000 and 2007, tax reforms have a significant way to go to make local firms more internationally competitive. Political constraints One reason for Australia’s cautious approach to reform is the adverse political impact on voters at election time. Tariff cuts, workplace relations and privatisation for instance, have hardly been popular in some electorates with manufacturing industries. This is because some of these microeconomic policies cause structural unemployment in the short term. There is also the added problem for the federal government if it does not have a majority in the Upper House that allows it to ram legislation through parliament. Institutional constraints Microeconomic measures such as tariff cuts and labour market deregulation have sought to create an export culture and sharpen our focus on the need to be more internationally competitive. Business and union organisations were initially slow in responding. This reduced the success of reforms. Overseas constraints Effective microeconomic policy can be undone by overseas factors. For instance, protectionist measures adopted by some foreign governments (e.g. EU, Japan and the US) have undermined our improved competitiveness resulting from domestic reforms. Clearly, not all countries believe in the level playing field as a basis for international trade. TRY SHORT ANSWER EXERCISE 4, p. 278 7.6 Using microeconomic policy to improve efficiency in resource allocation Nations that use resources efficiently enjoy better material living standards. These productivity improvements can arise from many sources including allocative, technical, dynamic and intertemporal efficiency. As we have seen on previous occasions, allocating resources more efficiently mostly involves cost-cutting policies designed to improve structural or supply-side conditions, rather than measures to regulate the demand-side of the economy. With this in mind, let us briefly review the top five microeconomic reforms that have perhaps made the largest contribution to improving efficiency in resource allocation. 264 Economics Down Under Book 2 Labour market reforms to lift allocative efficiency Microeconomic reforms have increasingly deregulated the labour market. Between 1991 and 2007, this involved mainly the extension of workplace agreements and the reduced influence of the minimum wage system. It means that rather than most wages being set by government regulation, workers are increasingly paid according to the market value of their services (reflecting demand for staff relative to their supply). Also, workers are increasingly rewarded according to their perfor- mance or productivity, and the profitability of the particular business. This means that allocative efficiency is increased and there is more incentive for staff to work hard. Also, other labour market reforms involving the encouragement of union amalgamation, the extension of multiskilling, and the easing of unfair dismissal laws, may have helped to significantly reduce industrial strikes, again improving worker efficiency (i.e. more GDP per hour worked). Commercialisation and corporatisation Many of the remaining GBEs have been corporatised so that they operate more along the lines of a private company. Some are expected to contribute to their own operating costs by the commercialisation of their services (e.g. the ABC, ABS). Other measures to reform government efficiency Other measures to reform government efficiency include contracting out, competitive tendering, changes to Commonwealth– state relations and the establishment of the National Competition Council to oversee the National competition policy. Trade liberalisation to lift allocative and technical efficiency During the 1970s, 1980s, 1990s and 2000s, significant tariff cuts and trade liberalisation forced local firms to use resources more efficiently. During the 40 years between 1967 and 2007, general tariff rates have come down from around 40 per cent, and are now effectively zero for most items. What this has done is cause natural, labour and capital resources to be allocated into areas of comparative cost advantage. Clearly, this would strengthen allocative and dynamic efficiency. Moreover, not only do tariff cuts force local firms to reduce costs to remain competitive, but also they make imported capital equipment relatively cheaper. This promotes technical efficiency by improving local access to new, more efficient technology that may reduce time and waste in production. There are also the efficiency benefits associated with the development of an export culture or orientation among firms exposed to international competition. Businesses, which succeed in breaking into overseas markets, can also gain from improvements in economies of larger-scale operation (i.e. their fixed costs per unit produced are lower because these are spread over a bigger volume of output). National savings reforms to promote intertemporal and technical efficiency Public sector reforms to lift efficiency In Australia, the public sector produces about 20 per cent of GDP. It is, therefore, important that governments are efficient users of resources. In this area, there have been numerous microeconomic reforms. Privatisation Some government businesses enterprises (GBEs) have been partially or fully privatised (e.g. the Commonwealth Bank, Qantas, Telstra, some shipping ports like Geelong and airports). Various arguments have been used to justify privatisation. For example, it is often claimed that: ■ the private sector is a more efficient user of resources than the public sector because it tries to maximise profits by minimising costs ■ private firms have superior management and more committed staff ■ private shareholders demand increased efficiency to raise their share price and dividends or returns ■ private firms put more emphasis on R&D and marketing ■ private firms have better access to capital and technology ■ private firms are exposed to greater competition. Without adequate national savings, Australian firms would lack access to cheap credit or finance. Interest rates would be higher than those overseas, discouraging vital investment spending on new plant and equipment incorporating the latest technology. With this problem in mind, the federal government initiated savings reforms, including the pursuit of fiscal balance, creating the Future Fund, lowering tax rates and encouraging superannuation using a range of strategies. This should tend to increase intertemporal efficiency. In addition, local businesses are currently enjoying some of the lowest interest rates since the early 1970s allowing them to more readily purchase new equipment, bringing about capital deepening, and improving productive efficiency. Financial sector reforms to improve allocative efficiency Since 1982, there has been considerable deregulation of Australia’s financial system. This reform involved removing unnecessary government restrictions and other impediments to allocative efficiency by creating a more competitive financial system. For example, deregulation has meant floating the A$, removing controls on interest rates, and encouraging the entry of more local and foreign banks to stiffen competition between lending CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 265 institutions. There is some evidence that these reforms have narrowed bank profit-lending margins by 1–2 per cent, making local credit more affordable to firms needing to borrow funds for investment. Tax reforms to improve efficiency Lower rates of personal, company and capital gains taxes have been introduced as part of government reforms. The idea is that cuts in PAYG rates create greater personal motivation and incentive to work hard. In addition, lower rates of capital gains and company taxes, for example, mean higher returns and bigger after-tax profits. This should mean there is a greater willingness and ability to increase investment in new plant and equipment. This could lead to capital deepening (i.e. a rise in the value of equipment per worker) and better labour productivity. HAS MICROECONOMIC POLICY PROMOTED EFFICIENCY IN RESOURCE ALLOCATION? An obvious question to ask is, how effective has microeconomic reform been in improving Australia’s efficiency in resource allocation during the past 10 to 15 years to 2006–07? Unfortunately, we cannot be absolutely certain. There are statistical limitations to our data, and there are so many local and international factors affecting efficiency, other than government policy. Even so, let us start by looking at figure 7.7 that compares statistical data for two periods of time: one before the pace of microeconomic reform accelerated (i.e. 1982–92), and one after (i.e. 1996–2006). Labour productivity (GDP per hour worked) Multifactor productivity 3.5 Annual % change 3 2.5 2 1 0.5 1982–92 (before microeconomic reforms accelerated) 1996–2006 (after microeconomic reforms accelerated) Figure 7.7 Comparisons of labour and multifactor productivity in Australia, 1982–92 (before accelerated microeconomic reforms) and 1992– 2006 (after acceleration of microeconomic reforms) Source: Data derived from ABS 5204.0 for multifactor (national accounts), 2004–05 (November 2005), p. 37. 266 Exponents of microeconomic policy are quick to seize on the upward productivity trends shown in figure 7.7. Notice that both labour and multifactor efficiency grew faster in the more recent years between 1996 and 2006 (i.e. during and after the full impact of accelerated microeconomic reforms), than in the earlier period, 1982–92 (i.e. before reforms gathered pace). In addition, commentators note: ■ there was greater allocative efficiency across many specific markets (e.g. labour, capital, raw materials) ■ a dramatic cut in the level of disruption to production caused by industrial strikes (as shown in figure 7.8) after labour market reforms. 1980–1992 — before labour market reforms 1992–2006 — during and after labour market reforms 0 100 200 300 400 Number of working days lost per 1000 employees Figure 7.8 Average annual strike levels in Australia (working days lost per 1000 employees) Sources: Data derived from ABS 1350.0; RBA Occasional Paper, No. 8A. ■ much lower inflation rates due to greater efficiency and reduced cost pressures ■ the 32-year low in unemployment or idle resources ■ quite strong rises in company profits ■ lower production costs including interest rates and RULCs ■ a rise in the sustainable rate of economic growth ■ near record rises in material living standards (i.e. GDP per head). In addition, microeconomic reform is the government’s preferred policy when it comes to measures to increase efficiency. It certainly has the edge over budgetary and, especially, monetary policies for its directness in tackling the structural supply-side of the economy. Some weaknesses of microeconomic policies 1.5 0 Some strengths of microeconomic policies Economics Down Under Book 2 Despite its apparent success in improving efficiency, microeconomic policy has its limitations. Critics note that some of the claimed benefits of reforms have been exaggerated, while others have failed to appear. Australian productivity peaked and is slowing Data show that, after the cyclical peak between 1994 and 1999, average productivity slowed towards 2006 and is now only marginally above our long-term average. Perhaps this reflects: ■ the reduced pace of microeconomic reform between 2001 and 2004 ■ the limits to microeconomic policies and the fact that the easiest and most obvious reforms were completed some years ago ■ the effects of previous reforms are now wearing off ■ the fact that large improvements in efficiency require far more investment in new technology than has occurred to date ■ that domestic and international factors, other than government reforms, are now slowing efficiency. Overseas productivity is much stronger Perhaps one of the main criticisms of recent microeconomic policy from an efficiency standpoint is that it has been far too slow by comparison with developments overseas. This means that, today, we find that most sectors of the Australian industry have inferior productivity to levels abroad and, in some specific industries, efficiency has actually decreased. Figure 7.9 shows that in terms of GDP per hour worked (i.e. which has been adjusted in terms of purchasing power parity to reflect differences in the cost of living in different countries), Australia ranked only fifteenth amongst 24 OECD nations in 2004. This was well behind countries like Norway, Ireland, France, Germany, the United States and the United Kingdom. While recent policies may have helped to improve resource allocation, they have not made up for the decades of neglect, nor are they stimulating structural change as rapidly as in some countries. This is causing us to fall even further behind. 1 — Norway 2 — Luxembourg 3 — Belgium 4 — Ireland 5 — France 6 — Netherlands 7 — United States Index base 8 — Germany 9 — Denmark 10 — Sweden 11 — Austria 12 — United Kingdom 13 — Finland 14 — Switzerland 15 — Australia (80% of US) 16 — Spain 17 — Italy 18 — Canada 19 — Iceland 20 — Japan 21 — Greece 22 — New Zealand 23 — Portugal 24 — Korea 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 Index (US base = 100 points) Figure 7.9 International comparisons of labour productivity (Index number, US = 100 points) Source: OECD Productivity Database, January 2006. The conflict with other government objectives in the short term Especially in the short term, the pursuit of greater efficiency through government microeconomic policies like tariff cuts, privatisation and market deregulation, has been in conflict with the achievement of some other government economic objectives like full employment and equity in income distribution. For instance, tariff cuts certainly decimated some areas of manufacturing industry and caused some firms to close down or scale back Australian operations. This added to structural unemployment. Likewise, performance-based workplace agreements have enabled some firms to produce more output with fewer staff, again swelling structural unemployment in the short term. The knock-on effect is that unemployment typically lowers the income and purchasing power of individuals, making some goods and services less affordable. However, hopefully in the long term, greater efficiency and competitiveness should lower unemployment and even improve equity. The other conflict issue is that the non-economic well-being of some workers has been undermined by the pursuit of greater efficiency. It has come at a cost. The downside is that average hours of work have increased and leisure time with families has diminished. Furthermore, it is likely that staff stress levels have increased and unions no longer act to counterbalance the increased power of employers. So, although workers may now be richer, they may not necessarily have a better quality of daily life. Time lags caused by resource immobility It is unrealistic to believe that resources can be moved or redeployed from one use to another, more efficient one, in a short space of time. Some resources are immobile, such as specialised machinery. In order to respond to microeconomic policy, time (perhaps five, 10 or even 20 years) may need to be allowed. The gains from reform may take years to emerge fully. A related problem is that of the reluctance by some institutions (e.g. business, unions, governments) to move with the times. In some ways, Australian production methods and work practices have changed only slowly relative to the pace overseas. Political restraints Many things could be done to reform the production process. However, adverse voter reaction and the short time between elections, prevents some of the harder reforms from being tried. This was especially the case when a government lacked a majority in both Houses of Parliament. For example, the Howard Government initially found it very difficult getting the Workplace Relations Acts passed. Well over 160 amendments were required in 1996 to get Democrat support in the Upper House. Another obstacle to the privatisation of Telstra, which was designed to further lift efficiency, was the lack of Senate numbers between 1996 and 2005. Similarly, the introduction of a GST and other tax reforms in 1999–2000 proved difficult at the time because of the Coalition’s absence of an Upper House majority. The limitations of specific policies Some specific policies have limitations and have not fully achieved their aims. CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 267 ■ Reforms to increase national savings. Although the government has done what it can to increase national savings (to help keep domestic interest rates and foreign borrowing lower than otherwise), the measures do not appear to have prevented the continued slide in the household savings ratio to negative 2.9 per cent of GDP (2005–06). While this may have been worse without savings policies, success has been limited. ■ Labour market reforms. Labour market reforms have probably helped to lift worker efficiency by extracting greater personal effort and motivation from employees. However, there are physical limits to how much further this can go and how much more leisure time staff are prepared to sacrifice, given the substantial rise already, in average hours worked during the past 10 years. Ultimately, greater staff efficiency now depends on higher levels of investment in new equipment, along with greater emphasis on education, skills and training. These, rather than the labour market reforms we have seen recently, would help to bring about capital deepening and even larger rises in labour efficiency. ■ Deregulation of other markets. Up to a point, free and deregulated labour and other markets can bring about greater efficiency in the allocation of resources. Sometimes, however, market failure occurs and this can only be corrected by government regulation or intervention. For instance, some aspects of the operation of the financial market involving prudential supervision of non-bank financial institutions have been reregulated to help ensure stability and efficiency. In addition, the government attempts to regulate the level of economic activity because improved stability also helps to increase efficiency. Adopting a non-interventionist approach 268 Economics Down Under Book 2 ■ ■ ■ ■ in this area was shown to be dangerous during the Great Depression of 1929–33. Tariff cuts and trade liberalisation. For most industries, cuts have reduced tariffs to zero. They have gone as far as they can to promote greater efficiency. In addition, trade liberalisation by our government is partly frustrated or made less effective by the failure of other countries to do likewise. Some claim that while reduced protection may make surviving Australian industry more efficient, the continued use of tariffs and subsidies by some overseas nations (e.g. Japan and some members in the European Union) has not opened up the new markets we expected, nor delivered such huge benefits. Reform of the public sector. Privatisation of some government business enterprises is seen as an efficiency measure. During the 1990s and 2000s, this has been extensive but, by 2007, few possibilities remain for the government. Competition policies. Promoting competition generally helps to lift efficiency among rival firms. However, preventing price collusion and other tactics is very difficult and there are some who feel that preventing company mergers and takeovers in particular circumstances might actually reduce efficiency by preventing firms from gaining economies of large scale where fixed costs can be spread more thinly over bigger output volumes. Tax reform. Cutting personal, capital gains and company tax rates can help lift the incentive to work hard and expand investment. However, given the acceptance of fiscal balance as a medium-term aim of budgetary policy, further reductions are limited by financial constraints. TRY SHORT ANSWER EXERCISE 5, p. 278 7.7 Using microeconomic policy to improve equity in income distribution The Australian Government’s objective of an equitable distribution of income means that everyone should have access to basic goods and services (e.g. food, housing, clothing, health and education) and enjoy reasonable living standards. Normally, we think of budgetary policies as the main instrument to promote equity. This is because fiscal measures like progressive taxes, direct welfare benefits and indirect benefits or services (e.g. free or cheap public health and education), redistribute final income from the rich to the poor very efficiently, directly and precisely. However, it is still important not to underestimate the vital role played by microeconomic reform in helping individuals enjoy improved access to goods and services, and better material living standards. In the long term, there are at least four main ways that this can happen (even though in the short to medium terms, structural unemployment caused by these policies can reduce purchasing power and equity). 1. Reforms can lift GDP and average incomes per head Cost-cutting efficiency reforms should mean that the Australian economy can produce a bigger level of national output from the same resources. Put another way, these strategies grow Australia’s capacity to produce goods and services and, hence, grow our production possibility frontier. Providing that our GDP expands at a faster rate than the growth in population, Australians should enjoy higher average material living standards (i.e. indicated by the average value of GDP per person a year) and improved access to goods and services, of which previous generations could only dream. 2. Reforms improve competitiveness, lift profits and create more jobs By lifting efficiency and cutting production costs for local firms, business profits grow faster than otherwise. Strong profit growth is vital for business expansion and survival. In the long term, fewer firms close down, resulting in a reduction in structural unemployment. With more individuals Table 7.11 1. Labour market reforms working, incomes are higher than on welfare, and goods and services are more affordable. For example, in late 2006, average full-time weekly earnings were around $1050 and the minimum weekly wage was $511, compared with, perhaps, $200–250 per week for a single person on government income support. 3. Reforms can lower production costs and slow inflation Greater efficiency in our use of resources means lower unit production costs. This helps to keep inflation down and the real purchasing power of incomes up. This improves general access to basic goods and services, along with equity in the distribution of income. 4. Reforms help grow the government’s income and the affordability of welfare and government services As explained already, improved efficiency helps to grow GDP and real incomes per head. In turn, this causes government tax revenues in the annual budget to grow faster. As a result, government outlays on direct welfare benefits (e.g. for the aged, sick, unemployed and families) and indirect services (e.g. public health and education) are much more affordable than otherwise. By contrast to these long-term benefits for equity, if efficiency fails to grow strongly because of the absence of effective microeconomic reforms, average per capita incomes fall, goods and services are dearer and less affordable, unemployment rises due to poor business profitability and the closure of firms, and falling budget revenues force the government to cut back even more on welfare and services for the poor. Clearly, income distribution in this case would become less equitable. During the past 10–15 years to 2007, table 7.11 shows some of the most important microeconomic reforms that have been especially important in improving equity and raising material living standards. Six microeconomic reforms that help increase equity in income distribution Australia’s labour market reforms have included the extension of the decentralised, productivity-based wage system, the reduced importance of the centralised minimum wage system that failed to encourage efficiency, the promotion of union amalgamation to reduce strike levels, and the exemption of small firms from unfair dismissal laws. These changes may have helped equity in several ways: ■ stronger productivity has meant that RULCs have fallen making goods and services cheaper and more affordable ■ employees on workplace agreements, have generally enjoyed bigger increases in their take-home pay than workers on the minimum wage, again making goods and services more affordable. (continued) CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 269 Table 7.11 (continued) 2. Trade liberalisation The past 15 years, to 2007 in particular, have seen most tariffs abolished and free trade extended. These changes have been important for equity in several ways: ■ freer trade has forced Australians to allocate resources more efficiently to areas of comparative cost advantage and away from industries where we have a cost disadvantage. This means that the same inputs can produce a bigger GDP leading to higher real incomes per person. ■ freer trade has meant much lower inflation for the period 1992 to 2007, than for the 1970s and 1980s. Many goods and services (e.g. clothing, appliances, cars) are now far cheaper and more affordable for ordinary households. It also means lower costs for local firms importing inputs and equipment, allowing them to enjoy better profits, improved competitiveness and stronger sales. Firms have expanded rather than closed down, again helping to lower structural unemployment that would otherwise undermine equity. 3. Tax reforms In general, the period 1999–2007 saw the introduction of significant reform involving lower tax rates on personal incomes, capital gains and company profits. This helped equity in several ways: ■ households are encouraged to work harder and end up with more disposable income. This increases their purchasing power and access to goods and services. ■ firms have larger after-tax profits. This encourages business expansion and investment, that creates even more jobs for the unemployed and higher incomes. Again, equity should benefit. 4. Competition reforms Competition reforms have involved the ACCC, tightening of the Trade Practices Act, increased prices surveillance, and the supervision of mergers and takeovers. This should help promote equity: ■ basic goods and services should be cheaper and more affordable if there is no price fixing and competition is fierce ■ businesses, buying inputs from other firms, find that their costs are lower if there is competition rather than if there is price collusion. This means better profits, the expansion of firms, reduced unemployment and, hence, higher real incomes. 5. Reforms to promote national savings Savings reforms introduced between 1991 and 2007 have included the creation of many surplus budgets, the launch of the Future Fund, the introduction and expansion of a compulsory superannuation scheme for employees and other incentives to encourage private superannuation. By promoting national savings and tending to increase the supply of credit in financial markets, interest rates (i.e. the cost of credit) have tended to be lower. This helps cut costs, increase profits and bring about business investment and expansion. If firms grow (and cause our GDP to expand) rather than close down, incomes will be higher and unemployment lower. This helps to improve equity. 6. Welfare reforms Although welfare reforms have had some negative effects, the tightening of access to government benefits and the extension of the idea that individuals must try very hard to be financially independent, may indirectly improve equity. For example: ■ unemployment benefits are only paid on condition that individuals are ‘actively looking for work’, working for the dole, or alternatively, are enrolled in education or training programs. Improving the skills of the unemployed should make them more employable and allow them, in the future, to gain better incomes. In addition, it helps to reduce welfare dependency that can sometimes lock them permanently into lower incomes. ■ the relaxation of rules relating to the amount of income that can be earned before welfare benefits are lost has allowed recipients to enjoy higher incomes. Again, it has also reduced the welfare trap that keeps some people on low incomes. 270 Economics Down Under Book 2 HAS MICROECONOMIC POLICY PROMOTED EQUITY IN INCOME DISTRIBUTION? ■ You may recall that, although there is evidence of growing income inequality between 1996 and 2005–06, it seems that the poor (and rich) have never been richer, and general living standards have increased. However, it would be interesting to know the extent to which microeconomic reform has brought about this trend. Unfortunately, this is not easy to judge because there are so many local and international events that could have played a role, other than government policies. All we can do here is to look at a few of the possibilities. Interestingly, part B of figure 7.10 shows that after taking inflation and rising costs of living into account over the eight years to 2002–03 when microeconomic reform was in full swing, even the poorest quintile gained a greater than 10 per cent increase in their real purchasing power (relative to the richest quintile with around 16 per cent). This should have allowed low-income earners to access more goods and services than previously and enjoy better material living standards. Of course, these observations may just be a coincidence, but supporters of reform dismiss the suggestion. In addition, relatively recent microeconomic policies have been associated with significantly lower unemployment and inflation rates than previously. Again these improved conditions are beneficial for equity. Some strengths of microeconomic policies Some weaknesses of microeconomic policies To establish the success of microeconomic reforms in promoting equity, we would expect to see a rise in the sustainable rate of economic growth leading to faster increases in average real GDP per head per year since the introduction of microeconomic reforms. In addition, individuals should now have higher incomes (purchasing power) and the benefits shared equitably so that all people can be better off materially (not just the rich). These outcomes can be seen in parts A and B of figure 7.10. ■ As indicated in part A of figure 7.10, it is clear that real annual incomes and GDP per capita have grown much faster in the 14-year period since government microeconomic reforms accelerated, than in the 14 years prior to reforms. It is difficult to hide from the observation that, especially in the short term, some aspects of microeconomic policy have not helped to promote equity. The conflict with full employment and equity in the short term In the short to medium term, structural unemployment rose following some microeconomic reforms. This tended to erode equity. For instance: ■ tariff cuts in the years up to 2005–06 caused business closures, especially in manufacturing (e.g. in the textiles, clothing, automotive industries and footwear — Blundstone Boots, 2007) ■ there were staff cuts in the federal public sector designed to lift efficiency following corporatisation, privatisation and contracting out Part A — Total % rise in real GDP or income per capita (% over the two, 14-year periods) before and after government microeconomic reforms Total % rise 1992–93 to 2005–06 (at the peak of reforms) Total % rise 1979–80 to 1992–93 (largely before reforms) 0 20 40 60 80 100 Total % rise over the period 120 Part B — Comparison of rise in annual real equivalised disposable income by quintile — Australia, 1994–95 to 2002–03 Total real % rise in equivalise median disposable household income for the ‘highest’ quintile Total real % rise in equivalise median disposable household income for the ‘lowest’ quintile 0 5 10 15 20 Total % rise in income over the period Figure 7.10 Indicators of improving equity in income distribution — Australia. Sources: Data derived from RBA Occasional Paper No. 8A; ABS, 1350.0 and 6523.0 for 2002–03. CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 271 ■ productivity-based workplace agreements (i.e. where higher wages were traded for improved worker efficiency) allowed some firms to downsize their staff numbers ■ industry restructuring was undertaken by most firms to cut costs (e.g. in banking, there was the closure of less efficient branches and cuts to staff levels) ■ many markets were deregulated to strengthen competition and reduce production costs, including labour. This caused some firms (e.g. Ansett Airlines, 2002) to close, leading to unemployment and reduced incomes. When there is a rise in structural unemployment, there is usually a dramatic cut in incomes for workers who are forced to survive on meagre welfare benefits. In turn, basic goods and services become even less affordable, despite the fact that some of these 272 Economics Down Under Book 2 items may now be cheaper due to microeconomic reforms. Unemployment also causes households to run down their stock of assets or wealth (e.g. sell their house or car, run up debts), further cutting living standards for the unemployed relative to those with jobs. The main hope in the long run is that microeconomic reforms will create more jobs in Australian industry through increased international competitiveness. Increasing wage differences in society A number of microeconomic policies tended to increase income inequality: ■ The extension of workplace agreements has meant that some workers are now in a relatively weaker position when negotiating pay rises. For example, wage rates among females, the unskilled and poorly educated, part-time workers, some nonEnglish speaking workers, employees in firms where productivity is low and the wages of workers where union membership is low, have often fallen behind those received by skilled, unionised, articulate, efficient, full-time workers in profitable businesses. ■ Tariff cuts and stronger competition have squeezed profits and wages in some manufacturing industries, relative to others. ■ For some families, the restructuring of private firms and the public sector has meant cutting staff, increasing structural unemployment and diminishing incomes. ■ In recent years, general pay rates for staff on workplace agreements have risen faster than those on minimum wages. This has increased inequality in the distribution of income. ■ The tax system has become less steeply progressive due to cuts in rates of capital gains, company and PAYG taxes. These changes have benefited the rich more than the poor. TRY SHORT ANSWER EXERCISE 6, p. 279 School Assessed Coursework As mentioned previously, there are two SACs to be completed for VCE Economics Unit 4, one for each of the two outcomes. You will recall that SAC 1 covered macroeconomic policy. However, SAC 2 will cover microeconomic policy (chapter 7) and the government’s current policy mix (chapter 8). With this in mind, you are advised to wait until you have covered the final chapter of this text (chapter 8) before tackling this last SAC for the year. This final task could involve one of the following: ■ an essay ■ a written report ■ a problem-solving exercise ■ a test with multiple-choice and short-answer questions ■ an evaluation of print and/or electronic media. To help prepare you for the end-of-the-year examination and to provide some guidance for SAC 2, several sample tasks have been included in this section of your text. For instance, chapter 7 (about microeconomic reform policy) contains: ■ multiple-choice test items ■ short-answer test questions ■ an essay question ■ some possible questions relevant for completing a written report ■ a problem-solving exercise. Finally, this section of your text also contains a wide range of other learning activities (e.g. web quests, debates, concept maps, quiz, etc.), to help make learning more effective, interesting and relevant. MULTIPLE-CHOICE test questions Instructions: You may like to complete the following questions. Using the multiple-choice answer grid below, select the letter (A, B, C, D) that represents the most appropriate answer for each question by marking this with a tick (✓). Answer grid QUESTION 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 A B C D QUESTION A B C D Question 1 The immediate and main priority of microeconomic policy is most probably: A full employment B increased equity C efficiency in resource allocation and more rapid and sustainable rates of economic growth D external stability and equity. Question 2 In the 1980s and early 1990s, microeconomic reform was desperately needed because: A Australia’s material living standards were falling relative to those of many other comparable countries and there was a severe problem with the CAD B Australia had a slower rate of economic growth than some countries caused by severe supply-side constraints on rises in productive capacity C Australia’s productivity was very poor and cost inflation was common D all of the above were applicable. Question 3 Concerning recent changes in tariffs, which statement is correct? CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 273 school assessment tasks and learning activities 7.8 A Australia’s general rate of tariffs is lower than most comparable Western nations but higher than most in Asia. B By 1996, Australia’s general tariff rate was only 5 per cent and has since been further reduced. C Tariffs on imported cars into Australia fell to zero by 2006. D Australia is yet to create a free trade zone with New Zealand. Question 4 Which statement about microeconomic policy in Australia is incorrect? A Import quotas still exist for the TCF and car industries. B Reforms of the public sector to increase efficiency in government include council amalgamation, contracting out and competitive tendering. C The operations of the ACCC help to increase price competition in various markets. D The National Competition Policy seeks to accelerate the pace and degree of microeconomic reform by state governments. school assessment tasks and learning activities Question 5 In order to promote greater efficiency in the government’s delivery of goods and services to the community, federal microeconomic reform has not involved: A the introduction of a scheme to boost and revitalise government business enterprises by massive capital spending to upgrade productive capacity B subjecting government business enterprises to prices surveillance and the payment of taxation like private corporations (competitive neutrality) C collaboration with state governments to reduce service duplication and to encourage the creation of national markets for some services such as power D the commercialisation and corporatisation of many remaining government businesses that have not been privatised. Question 6 Which statement is false? The federal government has moved to increase national savings by: A the delivery of a ‘fiscal balance’ over the economic cycle B the establishment of the Future Fund C the abolition of all taxes on superannuation contributions D the progressive extension of compulsory superannuation contributions by employers on behalf of their employees. Question 7 Currently, which Australian market is probably the least competitive and least deregulated market in Australia? A The labour market B The market for TCF C The capital market D Primary industry markets Question 8 Microeconomic reform mostly slows inflation by: A slowing AD and the pressures created by expenditure B reducing imported inflation C easing cost pressures on prices through greater efficiency D reducing inflationary expectations. 274 Economics Down Under Book 2 Question 9 Microeconomic reform is believed to encourage more rapid, long-term economic and employment growth by: A stimulating sales of Australian-made goods and services by making them more competitively priced in domestic and foreign markets B boosting the productive capacity of our resources through allocating them more effectively and using them to produce more output with fewer inputs C enabling firms to access cheaper inputs, thereby raising business profitability and supply D all of the above. Question 10 The most likely way that recent microeconomic reform should help to promote improved external stability in Australia is through: A restrictions on imports B controls on foreign borrowing C cuts in production costs which improve domestic and external competitiveness of local firms D all of the above. Question 11 Microeconomic policy designed to improve efficiency in resource allocation is unlikely to include the following constraint. A Increases in unemployment, especially in the short term B Reduced equity in the short term C An adverse impact on the rate of economic growth D Unpopularity among the voting public in some electorates Question 12 Especially between 1994 and 1999, Australian statistics show that: A labour, capital and multi-factor productivity were stronger than in the 1980s or early 1990s B industrial unrest has increased, slowing productivity C labour productivity has generally fallen but capital productivity has risen D productivity levels have remained fairly constant since the early 1980s. Question 13 The reasons for believing that microeconomic reforms may have been effective since the early 1990s include: A fairly low inflation and even falling costs for some goods and services B the attainment of fairly rapid economic growth without an inflationary breakout C an increase in GDP per head per year D all of the above. Question 14 The main constraint of recent microeconomic policy in Australia is: A large time lags in implementation and impact of policy B rising cyclical unemployment generated by the reforms C short-term inflationary consequences arising out of structural change D the financial constraints for government arising out of privatisation. Question 16 The main aim of labour market reform has been the promotion of: A external stability and efficiency in resource allocation B price stability and improved equity C full employment in the short term D political popularity for the federal government. Question 17 Which of the following is not normally seen as an advantage of workplace or enterprise agreements? A Uniformity in wages and conditions B Improved flexibility in staffing and cost cutting by firms C The maintenance of minimum safety net wages for low income earners D An emphasis on productivity-based pay rises to help avoid inflation Question 18 The extension of workplace agreements during the 1990s and 2000s is expected to improve price stability and external stability by: A lifting worker productivity by offering more incentive for hard work B promoting greater competition among workers in the labour market so that wages more closely reflect the market value of what is being produced by each employee C reducing the central role previously taken by unions in wage negotiations D all of the above. Question 19 Which of the following has not been a significant constraint of recent labour market deregulation? A The limited coverage of firms and workers in Australia by enterprise agreements B The time taken to successfully complete wage negotiations on a firm-by-firm basis C The political constraint until 2005, due to a lack of numbers in the Upper House to pass federal legislation D Opposition to reform caused by the strong growth in unionisation of Australia’s labour force Question 20 In general, the spread of enterprise agreements until 2007 as part of labour market reforms, may be expected to lead to increased income inequality because of: A the reduced role of trade unions in representing otherwise fairly powerless individual workers B the unequal bargaining strength of different types of workers in different firms, combined with unemployment rates in excess of 7 per cent C both (A) and (B) above D the removal of minimum legal wages and protection offered against unfair dismissal. Question 21 A constraint in using higher tariffs is: A they are politically difficult to remove B they are a handicap for other import-competing and export businesses which use foreign goods in their production process C they weaken competition and domestic efficiency, misallocate resources into areas of non-comparative cost advantage and cause higher demand and cost inflation D all of the above. Question 22 Which of the following is not a constraint of tariff cuts and reduced industry protection? A Adverse political consequences are likely in some regions of the country. B Increased bankruptcy levels are likely, due to import penetration. C Other nations will retaliate and raise their tariffs on our exports. D Income inequality will probably worsen for some individuals. Question 23 Which of the following is not a general constraint of reducing tariffs? A Cyclical unemployment rises. B Long time lags are needed to implement the cuts and to see the resulting benefits. C The CAD generally gets worse before it improves. D Government revenue falls, creating a financial limitation. Question 24 Reforms promoting freer international trade will tend to direct more resources into areas of comparative cost advantage. This necessarily means that: A surviving industries can produce more cheaply than any other producer in the world B resources should move into areas where, relatively, there is the least cost disadvantage in production C there will be full employment D there will be price and external stability. Question 25 Which of the following reforms is likely to help promote fuller employment in the long term? A The signing of bilateral and multilateral trade agreements which raise exports CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 275 school assessment tasks and learning activities Question 15 Reform of Australia’s labour market during the 1990s and 2000s has involved which combination of the following? (i) A reduction in the number of allowable matters covered in federal awards covering pay and conditions of work (ii) The splitting up of large unions into smaller ones with less power (iii) Making the AFPC (previously AIRC) less important in the regulation and supervision of wages and working conditions (iv) The encouragement of workplace or enterprise agreements on a firm-by-firm basis (v) Retention of minimum wages as a ‘safety net’ A Answers (i), (ii), (iii), (iv) and (v) B Answers (i), (iii) and (v) C Answers (i), (iii), (iv) and (v) D Answer (v) B The increased discouragement of foreign investment and takeovers of local companies C Cutting R&D grants and tax concessions D Abolishing import quotas and subsidies Question 26 Regarding the impact of microeconomic reforms involving the external sector, which statement is false ? A Reduced tariffs tend to redistribute incomes away from importers. B Trade agreements may lift the income share of exporters. C The existence of tariffs can cause some basic goods and services to be less affordable for low income families. D Bounties paid to local producers redistribute income in their favour, typically at the expense of taxpaying individuals and companies. Question 27 Which of the following statements about the Workplace Relations Act is generally false ? A It makes some strikes illegal, along with secondary boycotts. B It makes all employee dismissals fair, no matter what the circumstances. C It reduces the roles of the AFPC and unions and establishes an Employment Advocate to help improve fairness and settle disputes. D It restates the principle of voluntary unionism and makes closed shops illegal. Question 28 Concerning microeconomic as compared with macroeconomic policy, which statement is correct? A Microeconomic policy seeks to lift efficiency, cut costs and expand AS, while macroeconomic policy is about regulating the growth in AD. B Microeconomic policy helps affect the long-term capacity or speed limit for economic growth whereas macroeconomic policy helps affect the extent to which a nation’s productive capacity is utilised. C Both (A) and (B) are correct. D Neither (A) nor (B) are correct. Question 29 In relation to financial reforms, which statement is false ? A The supervision of financial sector liquidity needed for customer confidence and stability is now the responsibility of APRA. B The Wallis Inquiry recommended a substantial deregulation of the financial sector. C Licences were extended to allow some building societies to become banks in an attempt to increase competition. D Reforms have not meant efficiency rises and lower real interest rates. Question 30 A microeconomic policy solution to the worry of high structural unemployment which is currently running at perhaps 5–6 per cent of Australia’s labour force is: A expansionary monetary measures B budgetary tax cuts and increased government outlays C government strategies that increase AD D cost-cutting, productivity-promoting measures that increase Australia’s competitiveness. school assessment tasks and learning activities STRUCTURED SHORT-ANSWER test questions Instructions: You may like to try a selection of the following structured short-answer questions. These questions may enable students to practise in readiness for the end-of-year examination. Question 1 A What is meant by microeconomic reform or policy? (2 marks) B Distinguish between the following types of efficiency: (a) Allocative efficiency and technical (productive) efficiency. (2 marks) (b) Intertemporal efficiency and dynamic efficiency. (2 marks) C What do you consider to be the three most important objectives of microeconomic policy? (3 marks) D In general terms, explain how microeconomic policy might affect any three of the following: (a) economic growth (b) inflation (c) unemployment (d) the CAD (e) efficiency in resource allocation (f) the distribution of income. (2 + 2 + 2 = 6 marks) 276 Economics Down Under Book 2 Question 2 A Concerning the policy of trade liberalisation: (a) Explain what is meant by the policy of free trade, outlining the extent to which it has currently been adopted by the Australian Government. (6 marks) (b) Identify and explain one strength and one weakness of pursuing this policy. (2 + 2 = 4 marks) B Concerning deregulation and other reforms of the labour market: (a) Define what is meant by labour market deregulation, giving specific examples of reforms. (4 marks) (b) In what ways are enterprise or workplace agreements different from the traditional minimum wage system? (6 marks) (c) List and outline two important strengths and two weaknesses of labour market deregulation in Australia during the 1990s and 2000s. (4 marks) C Concerning reforms to promote national savings: (a) Explain what national savings means. (2 marks) (b) Outline two reasons why is it important to lift the level of saving in Australia. (4 marks) (c) Suggest three specific ways this has been encouraged by government microeconomic reform. (3 marks) (d) the abolition of tariffs. (4 + 4 = 8 marks) F Outline one weakness of microeconomic reforms aimed at increasing the sustainable rate of economic growth. (4 marks) G In general terms, how might the creation of a more efficient and competitive economy using microeconomic reform, eventually help to lower unemployment? H Explain how any two of the following microeconomic reforms might affect the rate of unemployment: (a) the exemption of small firms employing fewer than 100 staff from unfair dismissal laws (b) trade liberalisation including the signing of FTAs with China and Japan (c) the future privatisation of Medibank Private, the ABC and the Snowy Mountains Hydro Scheme (d) a reduction in the rate of company tax from 30 to 20 per cent (e) the abolition of the minimum wage system (f) a reduction in welfare assistance paid to the unemployed (g) a rise in the minimum age for receiving the pension to 70 years (h) welfare and other reforms to increase the participation rate. (4 + 4 = 8 marks) I Apart from microeconomic reform, suggest one other category of government policy used to help lower Australia’s unemployment rate. (4 marks) Examine figure 7.11 showing trends in Australia’s unemployment rate between 1992–93 and 2005–06. In April 2007, the unemployment rate reached a 32 year low of only 4.4 per cent. Suggest and explain two important microeconomic reforms that could help to lower this rate even more. (4 marks) J Examine figure 7.12 (p. 278) showing trends in Australia’s employment by industry. (a) Identify and explain two important government microeconomic policies that could account for the trend in ‘manufacturing’ employment between 1997 and 2006. (4 marks) (b) How would you expect these employment trends to alter Australia’s distribution of income? (2 marks) Question 3 A In general terms, how does microeconomic reform help to lower inflation? (4 marks) B Explain how any three of the following microeconomic reforms introduced during the 1990s and 2000s, may help to lower Australia’s inflation and promote price stability: (a) the move towards free trade with lower subsidies and tariffs (b) labour market reform including the encouragement of enterprise or workplace bargaining (c) reform of the public sector (d) tightening of the TPA and broadening of prices surveillance by the ACCC (e) tax reform (f) the promotion of national savings (g) deregulation of the financial sector and transport reform. (2 + 2 + 2 = 6 marks) C Giving an example, identify one important constraint on the effectiveness of microeconomic policy, when it is used to slow inflation. (4 marks) D ‘Between 1992 and 2006, Australia enjoyed more rapid economic growth than during the 1970s and 1980s. There were also much lower rates of inflation and unemployment.’ In general terms, explain how microeconomic reform can help to achieve all three aspects of domestic stability simultaneously. Illustrate this on a fully labelled AD–AS diagram, showing the ‘before’ and ‘after’ effects of microeconomic reforms. (6 marks) E Selecting two reforms from the list below, explain how each microeconomic policy can be used to help increase Australia’s sustainable rate of economic growth? (a) tax reform (b) workplace agreements (c) competition reforms 12 % unemployed 10 8 6 4 2008–09 2007–08 2006–07 2005–06 2003–04 2004–05 2002–03 2001–02 2000–01 1999–2000 1998–99 1997–98 1996–97 1995–96 1994–95 1993–94 0 1992–93 2 Figure 7.11 Australia’s unemployment rate (percentage of labour force) Source: Data derived from ABS 1350.0. CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 277 school assessment tasks and learning activities D Concerning reforms to the public sector: (a) What is the difference between privatisation and corporatisation? (2 marks) (b) Why can privatisation lead to greater efficiency in the operation of a business? (3 marks) (b) reduced industry subsidies (c) tax reform involving further reductions in personal, capital gains and company tax rates (d) further privatisation and corporatisation of government business enterprises (e) banking deregulation (f) the extension of enterprise or workplace agreements and other labour market reforms (g) further reforms to increase national savings C Giving an Australian example, outline one constraint or weakness of using microeconomic reforms to improve external stability. (2 marks) Property and business services Construction Retail trade Health and community services Education Government administration and defence Transport and storage Accommodation and cafes etc. Finance and insurance Personal and other Mining Cultural and recreation Communication services Electricity, gas and water Manufacturing Wholesale trade Agriculture, forestry and fishing –100 0 100 200 300 400 Figure 7.12 Change in Australia’s employment numbers by industry — 1997–2006 school assessment tasks and learning activities Source: Data derived from ABS 1350.0. Question 4 A Outline how two structural problems currently help to cause Australia’s large CAD:GDP ratio and NFD. (4 marks) B By 2005–06, Australia’s CAD equalled $54.4 billion, while the NFD had grown to $494 billion. Faced with this sort of external problem, select any three of the following government microeconomic reforms and outline how each might improve Australia’s external stability. (2 + 2 = 4 marks) (a) tariff cuts and the signing of additional FTAs with China and Japan Table 7.12 Question 5 A Define clearly what is meant by an efficient allocation of resources. (2 marks) B Identify the two types of statistical evidence that you would use to confirm whether or not there has been an improvement in Australia’s efficiency in resource allocation in recent times. (2 marks) C From the following list, select and explain one important microeconomic reform that has helped to improve allocative efficiency and one reform that has helped to improve intertemporal efficiency: (a) relaxation of unfair dismissal laws (b) tariff cuts and trade liberalisation (c) welfare reforms (d) deregulation of the financial market (e) deregulation of domestic and international aviation carriers (f) savings reforms (g) tax reforms. (4 + 4 = 8 marks) D Explain how the Workplace Relations Act (1996) and or the more recent Work Choices Act (2005) might help to increase labour efficiency. (3 marks) E Explain two constraints of microeconomic policy that is designed to increase efficiency in resource allocation. (4 marks) F Examine table 7.12 showing annual average changes in productivity across selected Australian industries, 1998–2004. (a) How is productivity generally measured? (2 marks) (b) Suggest two likely reasons why productivity grew strongly, especially in areas like manufacturing, and agriculture, forestry and fishing. (4 marks) Annual rates of productivity change in selected Australian industries INDUSTRY PRODUCTIVITY, 1998–99 TO 2003–04 INDUSTRY PRODUCTIVITY, 1998–99 TO 2003–04 Agriculture, forestry and fishing 4.8 Health and community services 1.7 Manufacturing 4.1 Cultural and recreational services 1.6 Wholesale 3.9 Accommodation, cafes and restaurants 1.3 Transport and storage 3.4 Construction Finance and insurance 3.0 Mining –0.6 Total change overall 2.0 Electricity, gas and water –2.4 Source: Data estimated from ABS, 5204.0. 278 Economics Down Under Book 2 0.6 (f) the further encouragement of enterprise or workplace bargaining (g) further tightening of welfare eligibility (h) an extension of superannuation by a rise in the levy on employers, from 9 to 15 per cent of a worker’s wage. (2 + 2 + 2 = 6 marks) C ‘Microeconomic reform may increase economic efficiency, but this is at the expense of equity.’ Discuss this statement. (4 marks) D Explain how budgetary policy can compliment or support microeconomic reform in increasing equity in the distribution of goods, services and incomes. (6 marks) E Quoting specific policy examples, explain how microeconomic reforms may help to achieve better material living standards for Australian citizens. (4 marks) A PROBLEM-SOLVING exercise A possible task for Unit 4, SAC 2 is a problem-solving exercise. The following may provide you with practice for this type of question. Imagine that you have been appointed to the position of Head of the Economic Task Force set up to advise the government of Atlantis about microeconomic reform. This action was prompted by the fact that economic conditions had deteriorated seriously over the ten years to 2009. Table 7.13 summarises the dire economic problems faced by Atlantis. A Using the following headings, briefly outline the economic conditions that had developed in Atlantis between 2000 and 2009. (a) Domestic conditions (b) External conditions (c) Efficiency levels in resource allocation (d) Equity conditions Table 7.13 B In general terms, how could microeconomic policy help to correct the economic problems experienced by Atlantis, 2000–2009? C Select any three of the following microeconomic reforms. For each policy, outline the changes that should be made to help correct Atlantis’s economic problems. (a) Labour market reform (b) Promotion of national saving (c) Promoting stiffer competition (d) Shift away from industry protection towards freer trade (e) Reform of the public sector (f) Reforms implemented by firms in the private sector following the government’s move towards freer trade (g) Tax reform D Outline two constraints or weaknesses of applying the policies you selected for your answer to part C above. Economic indicators for Atlantis — 1990–99 to 2000–2009 ECONOMIC INDICATOR FOR ATLANTIS 1990–1999 2000–2009 (1) Annual average growth in GDP per capita (%) 3.1 0.2 (2) International ranking for GDP per capita ($ per year) 3rd 15th (3) Unemployment rate (% labour force) 5.8 7.1 (4) Productivity growth (% GDP per hour worked) 2.4 −0.5 (5) Inflation (%) 2.2 5.7 (6) RULCs (% per year) 0.2 4.8 (7) CAD:GDP ratio (%) 2.9 5.5 (8) Domestic interest rates (% on business overdrafts) 4.5 8.4 20 55 0.3 0.4 3 9 (9) NFD:GDP ratio (%) (10) Gini coefficient for final income distribution (11) General tariff rate (%) (12) Company tax rate (% profits) 30 40 (13) Number of working days lost per year per 100 employees through strikes 10 190 (14) Household savings (% of income) (15) Level of business concentration in ownership by industry (16) Size of government sector (percentage of GDP) 10 1 low high 20 30 CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 279 school assessment tasks and learning activities Question 6 A In general terms, outline three important ways whereby microeconomic reform can promote a more equitable distribution of income. (6 marks) B Explain how any three of the following microeconomic policies may affect the degree of equity in the distribution of income: (a) the move towards a user-pays principle in the provision of government services and social infrastructure (b) complete privatisation of Telstra (2006) (c) toughening of the Trade Practices Act (d) further tariff cuts in the TCF and car industries (e) reducing rates of personal, company and capital gains taxes OTHER learning activities Have you tried the following learning activities in your class recently? 1. Web Quest Visit the website for this book and click on the Weblinks for this chapter (see Weblinks, page 310). Use the Internet for researching some of the following: – projects of the Productivity Commission – the AFPC decisions about rises in award wages – the ACTU’s campaigns over pay and conditions – the ACCC’s investigations into companies – the Office of Employment Advocate, and Workplace Relations and Small Business – government tax reform – current debates in federal parliament or statements by the Prime Minister – wider aspects of microeconomic reform in Australia reported in Australian newspapers (e.g. magazines using various search engines. As always, teachers are strongly advised to check all website addresses listed in this text for suitability, appropriateness of content, operation and accuracy, before asking students to conduct research. school assessment tasks and learning activities 2. Class debate Select one of the following topics or create your own: ■ ‘That in the 1990s and 2000s, Australia’s microeconomic policy has brought more pain than gain.’ ■ ‘That microeconomic reform faces so many constraints as to make it ineffective.’ ■ ‘That labour market reforms are exactly what the doctor ordered for improving our economic performance.’ 3. Data show or video Students could be asked to use either a video camera to make a 3–4 minute documentary OR a computer to create a PowerPoint presentation about one of the following aspects of recent microeconomic reform: 280 Economics Down Under Book 2 ■ ■ ■ ■ ■ ■ ■ ■ ■ the car industry the TCF industry the power industry social welfare reform tax reform tariff cuts reform of government banking deregulation labour market reform. 4. Newspaper reports Photocopy a newspaper report about a recent change in microeconomic policy or use the Internet for research. Students could then summarise the report, possibly identify bias, or expand on what has been said in the article. 5. Role play The government announced that it would again review tariffs applying to some areas of Australian manufacturing. Set up a mock meeting between the government and representatives from the ACTU, the Industry Commission, the Employer’s Federation and a consumer group lobby. Each group is given a chance to put their case about future tariff cuts for the TCF and automotive industries. 6. Crosswords Construct a crossword using terminology and knowledge about recent microeconomic policy. Use the Internet for access to software that makes this task easy. 7. Team quiz Divide the class into teams. When it is their turn to answer questions about microeconomic policy (that the teacher and or students have previously written), team members can act as a brains trust before the final answer is given. Perhaps the winning team could be awarded a prize. A variation of this is the Economics Wheel of Fortune using numbered questions and token prizes. summary Summary chapter 7 What is microeconomic policy? Microeconomic policy involves a range of supply-side efficiency reforms designed to improve the way particular firms, industries, markets and sectors of the Australian economy are structured and operate. Specific measures include tariff cuts and trade liberalisation, competition-promoting strategies, labour market reforms including the encouragement of workplace agreements, banking reform, transport reform, telecommunication reform, reform of government businesses and operations, welfare changes, tax reform and promoting national savings. The aims of microeconomic policy The key aims of microeconomic policy are probably domestic economic stability (i.e. especially stronger economic growth and price stability), external competitiveness and stability and increased efficiency in the allocation of resources. Unfortunately, equity in the distribution of income and wealth often suffers in the short term following the implementation of microeconomic policy. However, in the long term, rising production and real incomes resulting from reform, are beneficial, providing that these gains are redistributed equitably using budgetary policy (e.g. provision of welfare benefits and affordable community services, paid for out of progressive taxes). Using microeconomic policy to promote domestic economic stability Theoretically, microeconomic policy can promote improved domestic stability by means of efficiency measures designed to slow cost inflation and increase national output from the same inputs, improve competitiveness and, in the long term, increase employment. Measures here could include: – labour market reforms – promoting national savings – trade liberalisation – tax reforms – deregulation of financial and other markets – reform of the public sector. Unfortunately, in the short term, there may be an increase in structural unemployment following microeconomic reform. Between 1992 and 2007, recent policy has contributed to better price stability, economic growth and, perhaps nowadays, to falling unemployment. However, there are constraints including long implementation lags, conflict between the objectives of policy, political obstacles and institutional constraints. Using microeconomic policy to promote external stability Theoretically, microeconomic policy (e.g. the promotion of national savings, competition reforms, reform of the government sector, tax reform, labour market reforms, competition policy) can make an important contribution to external stability and a lower structural CAD. The main approach is by strengthening a nation’s international competitiveness in domestic and external markets for goods, services and money capital through costcutting and efficiency reforms. Recent policy has probably helped to do this, but the high CAD:GDP ratio is still a periodic or cyclical worry. Constraints have limited its effectiveness including time lags in implementation, unfavourable external events, the conflict that exists between some government objectives, the adverse short-term impact of trade liberalisation, political obstacles and institutional constraints. Using microeconomic policy to promote efficiency in resource allocation Theoretically, microeconomic policy (e.g. industry reforms, labour market deregulation, deregulation of the financial sector, and the promotion of fiercer competition through lower tariffs and the ACCC) is extremely well suited to increasing allocative, dynamic, intertemporal and productive efficiency in resource allocation. Certainly, recent productivity has been at high levels (especially in the 1995–2004 cycle), well above those in the 1980s and early 1990s. However, there are factors limiting policy effectiveness including institutional constraints, time lags, overseas events and adverse political considerations. Using microeconomic policy to promote equity in income distribution Theoretically, microeconomic reform is likely to weaken equity in the distribution of income and wealth, in the short term, although there are considerable longer-term gains for equity arising from the impact of greater efficiency on real production and national income. This extra production and income then become available (through taxation) for redistribution and support of the needy (perhaps using various budgetary policies like progressive taxes, welfare and cheap services). In addition, equity is promoted through lower inflation, cheaper and more affordable goods and services and increased employment resulting from increased industry competitiveness. However, constraints operate to limit the effectiveness of microeconomic reform. These constraints include conflict between some government objectives, political constraints, long time lags in implementation and impact and financial considerations. CHAPTER 7 Economic management using microeconomic policy 281 using microeconomic policy Microeconomic policy Government reforms that increase structural efficiency and lower production costs so that more output can be gained from the same inputs of resources. These supply-side structural reforms increase AS and productive capacity. 1. Aims of microeconomic policy: Recent measures have emphasised the following objectives — Domestic stability by promoting greater output (GDP) from the same inputs and by cutting cost inflation — External stability (by promoting greater international competitiveness among local firms) — Efficiency in resource allocation by promoting greater technical, allocative, dynamic and inter-temporal efficiency — Better equity by reducing costs and prices, increasing GDP and incomes per head per year, government tax revenues and provision of welfare and services. 2. Instruments/aspects of microeconomic policy: Efficiency reforms include — Deregulation of the labour, capital and other markets by reducing government controls and increasing competition — Tax reforms that cut tax rates — Reform of the public sector (e.g. privatisation, corporatisation) — Promotion of stiffer competition — Encouragement of higher savings — Trade liberalisation. 3. Using microeconomic policy to promote internal/domestic economic stability: — Microeconomic reforms (e.g. deregulation of the labour market) are very effective in increasing economic growth by lifting the economy’s productive capacity (more output from the same inputs) and AS — Reforms (e.g. tax cuts, lower tariffs, promotion of competition) also help lower cost inflation by increases in efficiency and by strengthening the level of competition in the market. 4. Using microeconomic policy to promote external stability: — Microeconomic reforms (e.g. tariff cuts, tax reforms, government deregulation of various markets) are very effective in increasing the international competitiveness of local producers (in terms of price and quality) of goods and services relative to overseas firms. This helps increase exports relative to imports — Reforms that increase national savings (e.g. encouragement of superannuation by tax incentives, acceptance of fiscal balance) can help lower our reliance on foreign borrowing that adds to our CAD/NFD and weakens the exchange rate. 5. Using microeconomic policy to promote efficiency in resource allocation: — Microeconomic reform policies are most effective in lifting efficiency in resource allocation (i.e. they strengthen allocative, technical, inter-temporal and dynamic efficiency) — Here we think of the effects of tariff cuts, lowering of rates of personal, capital gains and company tax, tighter welfare access, stiffening of competition-promoting measures, reform of the public sector measures to promote savings and labour market reforms. 6. Using microeconomic policy to promote a more equitable distribution of personal income: — Microeconomic reforms are less effective and direct in the short-term in promoting greater equity in income distribution than, say, budgetary policy — Even so, microeconomic reforms are very effective in the long-term in lifting the volume of goods and services produced and general income levels. They also lower the cost or price of basic goods and make welfare and government services more affordable thus promoting equity. 282 Economics Down Under Book 2