Transaction costs and information systems: does IT add up? Antonio Cordella Abstract Transaction cost theory has often been used to support to support the idea that information and communication technology (ICT) can reduce imperfection in the economic system. Electronic markets and hierarchies have repeatedly been described as solutions to inefficiencies in the organisation of transactions in complex and uncertain settings. Far from criticising this assumption, this paper highlights the limits associated with this application of transaction cost theory that has been prevalent in IS research. Building on the concepts first proposed by Ciborra, the paper argues that information-related problems represent only some of the elements contributing to transaction costs. These costs also emerge due to the interdependencies among the various factors contributing to their growth. The study of the consequences associated with ICT design and implementation, grounded in transaction cost theory, should therefore consider the overall implication ICT has on these interdependences and not only the direct effect it has on on information flow, distribution, and management. Introduction: The diffusion of information and communication technology (ICT) in society is always associated with an increased amount of information becoming available. Moreover, ‘information society’ is not only defined by the greater amount of information required in an ever increasing range of human activities, but also by the expanded number of sources from which information emanates. A significant volume of unwanted unsolicited information is received via traditional physical channels of communication such as post, but increasingly, more is being sent via ICT such as e-mail and the Internet. In an era of ever shortening product life cycles and lead times, it has become essential for companies to improve their internal and external information flows. More information is necessary to deal with emergent complexity, dictating a requirement for faster information processing. A key resource for survival in this new environment is the ability to obtain access to more information and to be able to manage this information flow. As Lewis (1996) states: ‘professional and personal survival in modern society clearly depends on our ability to take on board vast amounts of new information. Yet that information is growing at an exponential rate.’ ICT has become the major enabler of the efficient exchange and retrieval of information in organisations. However, conflicting approaches indicate that ICT is either a powerful tool to support the economic system managing information or, conversely, one that creates a more complex environment that is difficult to manage. A clear indication of the first perspective is found in ICT studies based on the transaction cost approach (Malone et al., 1987; Ciborra, 1993; Wigand et al., 1997). Such studies argue that ICT supports the economic system, providing a more efficient information flow that facilitates the interaction among economic agents under complex and uncertain circumstances, and reducing transaction costs. On the other hand, the literature addressing the problem of ‘information overload’ underlines the negative effects of ICT due to a greater level of complexity being faced as a consequence of the increased quantity of information made available by the technology (Palme, 1984; Schultze and Vandenbosch, 1998). While being cognisant of these different approaches to the effects of ICT on organisational settings, this paper will focus only on the transaction costs approach, depicting that it is possible to identify situations where rather than reducing transaction costs, ICT will increase them. Building on Ciborra’s (1993) work on transaction costs theory (TCT) and ICT, the paper will present the main elements of the theory to discuss the effects of ICT on the different dimensions of the transaction cost model. The paper highlights the importance of considering the interdependency among the factors contributing to transaction costs when ICT is designed and implemented to reduce the effects of these factors on transaction costs. The paper is organised in a number of sections: Section two reviews transaction costs theory; section three presents a summary of Ciborra’s contribution to information system research and TCT; section four summarises the debate on TCT and ICT; section five reviews how this literature has often underestimated the importance the interdependencies between the various factors contributing to transaction costs to explain the overall effect of ICT on transaction costs; section six reflects on any possible strategic implications from the ideas proposed in the paper. Transaction costs The need for a better understanding of the impact of ICT on organisational structures, such as markets and hierarchies, has increased the attention received by transaction costs theory in the study of information systems. Transaction costs theory represents one of the first attempts to develop a comprehensive theory that considers the structure of the firm as a source of explanation for outcomes, in contrast to viewing the firm as a ‘black box’ that has little influence in explaining such outcomes. Presenting a minimalist version of the theory, Williamson (1975, 1985) and Coase (1937) considered the cost of organising and managing the firm as analogous to the cost of constructing and working in an ideal organisational structure. In contrast, transaction costs were depicted as analogous to the costs associated with the management of the imperfections of this structure. In economic terms, the ideal structure (i.e. the one without imperfections), would be a perfectly informed and efficient market where prices were sufficient to communicate to dispersed buyers all the knowledge required to make a purchase decision (Hayek, 1945). Through the price mechanism, the market efficiently collects and transfers a large amount of information between economic agents; information that would be prohibitively costly to capture and distribute by other means. Defining the elementary unit of analysis as the economic exchange between at least two individuals, the transaction costs model depicts the exchange process with reference to the resources that required to execute this exchange. While in the optimal case these costs approach zero, when imperfections occur, these costs increase. Inefficiencies and imperfections in the organisation of the transactions, called ‘market failures’, are the result of information and behavioural-related problems, with these imperfections defining the complexity of the transaction (Ciborra, 1993). Economic agents invest in resources to mitigate the effects of these imperfections in the execution of the exchange. These investments are the costs associated with the transactions, and defined as transactions costs. Transactions costs are the consequence of the asymmetrical and incomplete distribution of information among the economic agents involved in the transaction. More specifically, every transaction life cycle is characterised by different cost phases, with each incurring specific information-related costs: - Search costs: the costs of locating information on the opportunities for exchange - Negotiation costs: the costs of negotiating the terms of the exchange - Enforcement costs: the costs of enforcing the contract Transactions will conclude successfully only when all the participating agents possess the necessary information to rationally assess the equity of the exchange. When costs reach a particular level, it can be more convenient to ‘re-organise’ the exchange processes within a structure that more adequately addresses uncertainty and information asymmetry. This shift in the organisation of transactions occurs in order for the effects of transaction costs not to jeopardise the opportunity to conclude an exchange that is advantageous to all the involved parties. The model proposes a theoretical apparatus that assists in explaining why alternative forms in the organisation of transactions exist. Markets and hierarchies are proposed as alternative forms in the governance of transactions. Adhering to the underlying assumptions of the theoretical model, transactions that take place once, such as those on the ‘spot markets’, will incur relatively little transaction costs because they are associated with a low level of uncertainty (both environmental and strategic). In these cases it is straightforward to collect all the required information and to manage this information using the price mechanism. On the other hand, transactions that involve a commitment over time have a certain level of endogenous uncertainty related to the future behaviour of agents and of resource dependencies established within the transactional process (Barney and Ouchi, 1986). To manage these contingences, investment in resources and strategies designed to address emerging challenges is required. These solutions are maintained by the development and enforcement of rules and regulations that produce a new coordination mechanism to replace the price mechanism. TCT argues that the alternative to the market found in organisational forms and hierarchies, are responses to the need to minimise the transaction costs associated with the management of transactions (Coase, 1937; Alchian and Demsetz, 1972; Williamson, 1975). This both explains and justifies the decision to reorganise the transaction process. The hierarchy organises exchanges on the basis of rules and procedures within a regulatory framework that is a substitute for prices. Long-term commitment and contractual arrangements are developed to reduce the uncertainty facing agents, while enforcing alternative ways to organise the exchange process (Varian, 1992). The cost associated with the transaction will be lower than the one that, ceteris paribus, would be supported if the exchange was managed through a market mechanism. The same uncertainty is managed by a more efficient mechanism, the hierarchy, based on adherence to predefined norms and rules. Transaction costs theory explains the existence of alternative forms of organisation on the basis of their relative efficiencies in response to the combined effects of environmental factors (uncertainty and small numbers) and human factors (opportunism and bounded rationality) (Williamson, 1975; Moe, 1984). Transaction costs for a specific exchange can be captured by the function: Tc = f(U;C;Br;Ia;As;Ob;Cc) where Tc is transaction costs, U is uncertainty, C is complexity, Br is bounded rationality, Ia is information asymmetry, As is asset specificity, Ob is opportunistic behaviour, and Cc is coordination costs. Information technologies have also been discussed within the transaction costs model, with their impact on the factors in this equation often questioned. A number of authors have criticised the assumptions underpinning TCT. Opponents to the Theory have previously criticised its failure to consider the power of stakeholders within organisations (Francis, 1983; Perrow, 1986; Braddach and Eccles, 1989; Collin and Larsson, 1993). Others have criticised what they deem to be unrealistic assumptions, including that market based resources are always available (Bauer and Cohen, 1983; Dugger, 1983; Etzioni, 1988; Dietrich, 1994). Finally, several researchers claim that TCT is an inadequate unit of analysis because it ignores broader contextual issues that influence sourcing decisions, such as organisational learning (Collin, 1993; Elg and Johansson, 1993; Dietrich, 1994). Some criticism of TCT (Lacity and Willcocks, 1995) focuses on the ambiguity of the definition of the factors contributing to transaction costs. These include asset specificity and uncertainty, which are posited as making the operationalisation of the theory extremely difficult. Similarly, some authors question the possibility of clearly defining the micro level unit of analysis of transactions, particularly where ICT outsourcing occurs (ibid). Ciborra, ICT and TCT Ciborra (1981) was the first author to propose TCT as an approach to explain the design of computer based information systems. He argues that TCT brings together many of the concepts that had been traditionally used to analyse the effects of ICT on organisations, and that TCT illuminates the transactional dimension of economic exchanges. This includes the problem of the rational action of the organisational agents; the economic view of organisational forms such as teams and hierarchies; the notion of mediating technologies, and the use of ICT to support markets, hierarchies and teams. In depicting the transactional dimension of economic exchanges, TCT discusses varying organisational forms as alternative responses that are enacted to overcome problems in the efficient allocation of economic resources. As a result, ICT is proposed as a solution that can reduce transaction costs. Following these ideas, Ciborra views the problem of designing information systems as something connected to the problem of designing an efficient economic system. He states that ‘the key feature of …. (ICT) is in the framework proposed here, the possibility of lowering the costs of transacting. Accordingly, data processing can be identified with other devices that lower such costs as mediators and money,’ (Ciborra, 1993). ICT designed to lower transaction costs must take into consideration that the introduction of this technology ‘reduces the costs of exchange and increases gains for both parties, if the resources it consumes are less that the transaction costs incurred,’1 (Ciborra, 1993). It follows that the evaluation of the effects of ICT on the economic system must be considered in the context within which transactions occur. Markets, hierarchies, and teams are alternative solutions enforced to mitigate the effects of the complex set of factors that contribute to the emergence of transaction costs. Alternative frameworks need to be considered when studying the design of ICT in order to 1 This is a significant point that will be iterated later in this paper when a discussion occurs of the development of the ideas first produced by Ciborra, in relation to the introduction of ICT as possible instruments in lowering transaction costs. reduce transaction costs. Ciborra’s (1993) book Teams, Market and Systems is a significant contribution to this debate. Following TCT, this work discusses how it is possible to formulate alternative ICT solutions to enforce the different transactional mechanisms of teams, markets, and hierarchies. What characterises the originality of this contribution is its depth and extensive analysis of alternative transactional mechanisms, in addition to depicting the proposed solutions in terms of ICT development driven by TCT. Additionally, a framework is proposed that guides the decisions steps to be followed when assessing the cost-benefits associated with these alternative choices. Building upon the ideas proposed by socio-technical studies, Ciborra (1993) suggests that ICT solutions designed to lower transaction costs should follow the efficiency criterion when designed: cost-benefit analysis is proposed as the optimal approach to aid such design. Following this paradigm, Ciborra (1993) discusses alternative architectures ‘by adapting the analytical model proposed by Williamson (1985) to appreciate how technology and organisational forms jointly can make more efficient certain ways of coordinating the task of producing goods’. A model is proposed that compares alternative organisational forms and the subsequent impact of ICT on these forms. This comparison considers the possible combination of factors contributing to transaction costs and the effect of ICT on these factors. Utilising empirical data, Ciborra (1993) suggests that the impact of ICT on transaction costs should be appraised not only in quantitative terms but also by taking into account qualitative changes that can be induced by ICT when it fosters a shift in the paradigm of the organisation that hosts it: from ‘hierarchies to the market’, or from ‘clans to hierarchies’. If this occurs, Ciborra (1993) suggests that the costs or benefits associated with such a shift must be taken into consideration when assessing the effects of ICT on the economic system. Drawing upon the ideas underpinning socio-technical analysis, Ciborra (1993) concludes that, ‘appraising the costs and benefits of information technology is more than accounting or auditing tangible and intangible consequences of computer applications. Apart from the easiest cases, each time we carry out an economic analysis of the actual or expected impacts of information technology, we need a point of view and a conceptual framework on which to ground our evaluation. The point of view has been spelled out by adopting a dichotomy: work tool vs organisational technology. The first perspective allows us to look for the automating effects of information technology; the second for the more subtle, but not less relevant, information effect.’ Ciborra suggests that care should be exercised in evaluating the costs and benefits ICT can have on transaction costs, because this assessment is not always as clear as it first appears. The problem of assessing the information effects associated with the adoption of ICT, has not been neglected by the author in his latest research. The information effect of ICT, produced by what Zuboff (1988) defines as informating technologies, coupled with Ciborra’s depiction of mediating technologies, were starting points for the development of his more recent research on phenomenology and IS. Ciborra (forthcoming in 2008) posits that as ‘informating’ technology, ICT embodies the notion that all types of data models and representations embedded in information systems provide a powerful set of representation of the processes of the firm that is an important means of conveying, sharing and harnessing knowledge well beyond the information stored in systems. ICTs not only represent tools that support information flows, but they possess an enframing force that converts everything they encounter ‘into a reserve stock of resources to be harnessed and deployed for further development,’ (Ciborra and Hanseth, 1998). ICTs are not tools but are a Gestell (ibid). The phenomenological argument underpinning the vision of ICTs as enframing forces (Gestell) does not allow for claims in favour of the managerial approaches to the study of ICT. These tend to examine the implementation of ICT as a process that can be completely designed and controlled ex ante (Ciborra, 2000), and hence easily measured ex post. This conclusion had already been reached when Ciborra made his claim that the effect of ICT on transaction costs cannot be assessed ex ante by only examining the results of technologies as automation tools. This paper explores these ideas, including a discussion on the effects of ICT on transaction costs. Transaction costs and ICT Following Ciborra’s (1981) initial proposal that transaction cost theory is a potential framework for undertaking research in the design and impact of ICT, this model has been used extensively in the field. Typically, studies in information systems based on the transaction costs approach depict ICT as a tool that sustains information needs, providing additional information and information management power. ICT is perceived as a powerful tool to foster the efficiency of the transactional process within which economic exchanges take place. There is little disagreement that the effects of ICT on the economic organisation of exchanges continue to be positive. Malone et al. (1987) discussed the impact of ICT on the market and hierarchies, arguing that ICT facilitates the transactional process, supporting information flow and management during the various phases of transactions. It was theorised that the use of ICT supports market structures where without the presence of ICT, a hierarchical solution would be required. Similarly, Ciborra (1993) argued that the use of ICT reduces information asymmetry and resultantly increases the conditions under which the market mechanism is an efficient allocative structure. Analogous conclusions are also supported by Brynjolfsson et al. (1994) and Wigand et al. (1997). Other authors discuss ICT as a factor behind the increased interest on network and virtual organisations. Ciborra (1993), Malone et al. (1987), and Bakos and Brynjolfsson (1997) highlight that ICT can reduce the effect of opportunistic conduct increasing the possibility of monitoring agents’ behaviour in partnerships. None of these works, however, discussed the impact of ICT on transaction costs in light of the interdependency existing among the various factors, both human and environmental, that ultimately generate transaction costs. In their research, Malone et al. (1987) argue that ICT lowers transaction costs because technology allows information to be communicated in real-time and at much lower costs, thereby reducing the costs that are required in order to find a particular good that is focus of the transaction. These authors also suggest that ICT enables an easier matching between buyers and sellers once goods have been located, and lowers the cost of brokerage. Wigand (1997) posits technology and ICT as enabling the design and deliberate strategic deployment of linkages and networks among cooperating firms intending to achieve joint strategic goals to gain competitive advantage. Benjamin and Wigand (1995a) discuss how ICT can reduce transaction costs by decreasing coordination costs within the value chain, resulting in benefits for consumers through lower prices. Additionally, producers/retailers can reduce their intermediation and coordination costs. Bakos (1991, 1998) depicts the effect of ICT on electronic markets through its impact on search costs in particular, with a resulting reduction in transaction costs occurring when subsequent exchanges take place in electronic markets. These various approaches addressing the impact of ICT on transaction costs underestimate the effects of the interdependence among contributory factors. By considering these interdependencies and their combined effects on transaction costs, an assessment can occur of the real effects of ICT on the reduction of these costs. TCT is grounded in the assumption that the relationship between human and environmental factors is the reason transaction costs increase in the economic system. This is, however, not the only reason why these costs exist. The interdependence of factors contributing to transaction costs can contribute to their increase. Attempts to reduce transaction costs should not aim to reduce the effect of a single factor, but the effects of the interdependencies between factors. Transactions costs are not only the sum of the costs generated by the different factors, but are influenced by the imbricate, interdependent relationship between them. The effect of ICT on transaction costs must be studied by assessing this imbrication. Research in information systems has mainly focused on the first approach. Illustrations of the second can be found in principal agent theory (Grossman and Hart, 1983; Laffont and Martimort, 2002). The following section extends Ciborra’s (1993) notions on TCT and ICT, discussing the effects of ICT on transaction costs by not only considering the factors contributing to transaction costs, but also their interdependencies. This will provide a richer theory in order to understand if ICT is, ceteris paribus, always lowering transaction costs. Re-thinking ICT’s effects on transaction costs When scholars state that ICT reduces transaction costs by affecting constitutive elements of a transaction such as search, negotiation, and enforcement, they usually assess the effect of ICT on one specific transactional problem. For example, ICT can reduce search costs by increasing the amount of information available and the speed at which it is collected and processed (Bakos, 1991, 1998; Ciborra, 1993). However, IS studies that consider the interdependencies among the factors contributing to transaction costs and the effect of ICT on these interdependencies are rare. Ciborra (1993) highlights this problem when pointing out that positive and negative externalities are associated with the use and adoption of ICT in organisations. He does not discuss this issue in detail, however. This paper discusses the implication this concept can have for the further development of research on TCT and ICT. To accomplish this, externalities are explored that are generated by the interdependence of the factors contributing to transaction costs and the effects ICT can have on these externalities are discussed. This approach embodies the notion that transaction costs are not the sum of the costs generated by the single factors, but rather, are the result of the interlinked relationships between them: they do not sum each other and are functionally interdependent. A simple example is presented that reflects how ICT can reduce uncertainty and increase the amount of information available while augmenting complexity. Transactions take place in settings where human and environmental uncertainties are not isolated but intertwined. Ciborra (1993) posited that ICT reduces transaction costs if the resources it consumes are less that the transaction costs it generates. The reduction of transaction costs occurs only if certain conditions are met, with these unlikely to occur through chance. When assessing the impact of ICT, an understanding of the interdependencies and imbrication of the factors contributing to transaction costs produces a clearer picture of the problems inherent in the evaluation of the economic consequences of ICT adoption. When the aim is, for example, to understand the effects of ICT on transaction costs, the impact of environmental complexity on transactions needs to occur, due to bounded rationality. If economic agents have infinite computational capabilities, then complexity and coordination costs should not affect the transaction costs. At the same time, environmental uncertainty, information asymmetry and asset specificity affect the transaction because of the risk derived through opportunistic behaviour. The factors are deeply interdependent and when one increases or decreases, this variation requires analysis in relation to the effects reflected in the interdependencies among all of the various factors. Adopting an analytical perspective congruent with the one proposed by Ciborra (1993), namely that TCT is applicable in depicting the process of designing information technologies, an exploration can occur on what conditions are required to successfully design ICT that reduce transaction costs. The effect of ICT in reducing the impact of any of the factors contributing to transaction cost has to occur in light of the overall consequences that a solution has on the set of interdependencies that generate transaction costs. The impact of the adoption of ICT can be negative as a result of unplanned consequences produced by these interdependencies. The nature and direction of these effects cannot always be considered positive and unidirectional. As already outlined (Cordella, 2001), ICT does not always positively impact transaction costs. The interdependencies between human and environmental factors have to be made explicit in order to assess if the impact of ICT will produce an overall positive or negative effect. Following the depiction of the three major phases of transactions and the associated costs proposed by Ciborra (1993), a more relevant description of the possible cross-effects of ICT can occur. This facilitates better positioning while designing ICT that aims to reduce these costs. The following presents an overview of the three phases of search costs, negotiation costs and enforcement costs: Search costs ICT can lower search costs only if the increased amount of information and/or speed in its exchange is balanced by an equal increase in its ability to manage, process, and evaluate that information2 (Malone et al, 1987). Greater information results in lower uncertainty but greater complexity. The effect of ICT on this phase of the transaction is positive only if the increased information flow is equally balanced by an improvement in the ability to manage it. When this does not occur the costs required to manage the increased information flow provided by ICT will be greater than the advantage supplied by this new information. This will result in a negative effect of ICT, leading to higher transaction costs. The positive effects of ICT on search costs have often discussed in terms of disintermediation of the exchange processes. Traditionally, intermediaries are considered a necessary transaction costs that has to be incurred in order to reduce the search costs for sourcing and retrieving information. To complete an exchange, the collection of information regarding available options is required, in addition to the location of the goods and their characteristics. Malone et al. (1987) highlight that ICT can lower these costs by making the retrieval process easier and cheaper while providing additional information on the characteristics of the goods. Once acquired, ICT does for free what intermediaries do for a fee. One of the most visible consequences of the diffusion of ICT in electronic markets is the disintermediation of these markets (Malone et al., 1987; Benjamin and Wigand, 1995b; Chircu and Kauffman, 1999). 2 What Malone et al. (1987) call ‘electronic communication effect’ The above conclusion is predicated on the assumption that ICT reduces the transaction costs of electronic markets by making more information available at a lower cost while making the task of processing the information easier and cheaper. The literature does not in general consider cross-effects in cost benefit analyses, with different conclusions reached that discuss the case of re-intermediation as it occurs in electronic markets (Bakos, 1991; Sarkar et al., 1995). Bailey and Bakos (1997), studying thirteen different firms participating in electronic markets, find evidence for the emerging roles of new intermediaries. This implies that disintermediation does not occur and new transaction costs emerge as consequence of the digitalisation of the marketplace. The most direct effect of this digitalisation on search costs is the problem of matching buyers and sellers. Electronic marketplaces are bigger and more disperse, making it more difficult to retrieve information about the available goods and their characteristics. As a result of ICT, customers have access to a greater number of goods and considerable information about these goods. Empirical work by Bailey and Bakos (1997) reveals that this can lead to ambiguous results: ‘on one hand lower search costs will reduce the importance of intermediaries by allowing buyers to search directly for appropriate suppliers, while on the other hand the overwhelming abundance of information offered by internet-based market infrastructure my increase the need for intermediaries that can help to match customers and suppliers by filtering information,’ (Bailey and Bakos, 1997). This scenario leads to greater transaction costs. What Bailey and Bakos (1997) discover through empirical evidence is presented theoretically in this paper. Namely, once ICT is implemented in order to lower transaction costs, the externalities of the cross-effects of the interdependencies among the factors contributing to transaction costs may be negative, resulting in the overall effect of the adoption of ICT being negative: under this scenario, transaction costs increase rather than decrease. Negotiation costs These are the costs of executing the transaction and may include commission costs, the costs of physically negotiating the terms of an exchange, the costs of formally drawing up contracts, and others. Within this stage, better control over the transaction can occur through the use of ad hoc ICT applications, in term of quality evaluation and service provisioning3 (Malone et al, 1987). A more sophisticated inventory system can reduce the costs associated with the management of transactions when goods require delivery according to specific contractual requirements. Ad hoc systems can be designed to facilitate the evaluation of the services purchased. However, the evaluation of this effect of ICT on the transaction cannot be fully assessed without considering the costs associated with new coordination requirements that emerge as a consequence of the adoption of the ICT application. Moreover, in changing the distribution of information among economic actors, ICT can alter the information symmetry between them, increasing or decreasing it, and offering new opportunities for opportunistic behaviour; what Williamson (1975) defines as conditions of information impactedness. The effects of ICT on this phase of the transaction have to be considered within the associated effects on the interdependent factors. A positive balance is reached if all of the factors are counterbalanced and aligned. It cannot be taken for granted that this always occur. Bakos (1998) argues that electronic marketplaces, as physical markets, need to fix prices in order to process transactions, manage inventories, guarantee quality, and to monitor the process of transacting. These needs provide a fertile platform for the proliferation of new intermediaries that 3 What Malone et al. describe as brokerage effect (op cit). facilitate these activities in global, bounded-less electronic marketplaces. Sarkar et al. (1995) presents extensive analysis of the process that redesigns the organisation of intermediaries in electronic marketplaces. Criticising the conclusion reached by Benjamin and Wigand (1995a) on the effect of disintermediation in digital markets, they show that the number of intermediaries and their role can increase, potentially leading to higher negotiation costs for the agents that exchange in those markets. The assessment of the effects of the introduction of ICT on transaction costs is once again complex and not unidirectional. Any analysis of this impact must consider the cross-effects and externalities associated with attempts to overcome the limits of the analyses that assume that a change in the exchange channel structure does not have effects on the redistribution of the welfare among the agents that use this structure (Sen and King, 2003). Enforcement costs The costs in this phase encompasses those incurred by the buyers and sellers in order to ensure that the virtual goods and services they transact, and the terms under which the transaction is made, are translated into physical goods and services. This encompasses any negotiations that address inadequate delivery, payment disputes, and any investment undertaken to ensure unsatisfied buyers and sellers have their issues remedied through the enforcement of their initial contract. As was evident in the previous two phases, ICT can provide a more efficient environment for the enforcement of the exchange process by facilitating a match between contractual agreements. ICTs can also assist in the process and subsequent monitoring of quality certification. In this scenario, radio tags facilitate the monitoring of production and distribution, making it easier to control the quality of goods. Moreover, ICT can make the information exchange between the parties more expedient, efficient and extensive, increasing the links between them and the resulting quality of the information flaw underpinning the exchange process4 (Malone et al., 1987). In this scenario, a positive result occurs only if solutions exist to manage the enriched information setting provided by ICT. The enhanced communication flow with additional information increases the requirement for coordination. This scenario can alter the information symmetry and the prospects and risks associated with opportunistic behaviour. The effect of ICT can be positive if specific conditions are matched. The globalisation of the digital economy increases the complexity and the uncertainty in the enforcement of contractual agreements (Milosevic et al., 2003). From the transaction costs perspective this more complex and uncertain environment also makes the definition of contractual agreements more difficult and expensive. Angelov and Grefen (2003) depict that the increased complexity and uncertainty faced by companies in digital markets are the reasons for the increased number of contracts established by companies trading in these markets. In extreme cases, these authors argue that a situation of ‘contract overload’ has occurred. Daskalopulu and Sergot (1997) provide evidence highlighting the increased complexity of the content of these contracts, which supports the argument presented in this paper: higher costs will be incurred in order to stipulate the use of contracts under these conditions. A greater number of contracts coupled with increased complexity leads to higher transaction costs. An increased number of contracts create the need for a company to invest in contract management systems. The increased complexity of contractual agreements has therefore necessitated investment in technological solutions that facilitate the establishment and execution of electronic contracts (Allen and Widdison, 1996; Merz et al., 1998). Once again, the cross-effects of the adoption of ICT are difficult to assess. 4 What Malone et al. define as electronic integration effect (op cit). As argued by Ciborra (1993) the evaluation of the effects of ICT on the economic system must take into consideration the socio-technical context within which the transactions occur. Similarly, Lacity and Willcocks (1995) argue that transactions occur in dynamic environments that change over time, rendering it difficult to take decisions that minimise transaction costs without considering the context within which these transactions occurs. Conclusion and implications for ICT strategies The transaction costs approach is a powerful theory that describes the potential of information technology to improve information flow and to reduce transaction costs, thereby improving the efficiency of the economic system. This paper has, however, shown that in order to achieve this goal, a more informed approach to the study of the effects of ICT is required. Transaction costs in fact often increase as a consequence of the adoption of ICT. Lower transaction costs can be achieved when the costs associated with ICT adoption do not exceed the cost of the externalities that are affected by this adoption. When this occurs, the usefulness of the strategy producing such a result has expired. This paper has shown that the externalities linked to ICT can alter from being positive, to becoming negative. The adoption of ICT in this setting will result in significantly increased transaction costs because of the associated extra costs required to accommodate the more complex environment that emerges as a consequence of the effects of externalities. The use of information technology will subsequently be unable to establish the conditions for a more efficient economic system, but will contribute to the creation of electronic disorder and suboptimal economic results. Accordingly, the use of ICT may present diseconomies of scale when the externalities associated with its diffusion reach a particular level (Cordella, 2001). The traditional strategy of ICT adoption, based on transaction cost theory utilising ICT to increase information availability, is undoubtedly efficient when accelerating and increasing the amount of information available and its exchange. ICT makes economic exchanges easier and more efficient, reducing search, negotiation and enforcement costs. In order to account for the consequences of ICT, externalities, and the associated effects on the coordination of exchanges, an approach other than the traditional one has to be identified. This is required in order to avoid the failure of the economic system as a consequence of high search, negotiation and enforcement costs. By reducing the amount of information, filtering it appropriately, and reducing coordination needs, it is possible to decrease costs while maintaining an efficient economic system when these conditions are met. The ideas proposed in this paper offer a theoretical explanation for the proliferation of alternative, sometimes opposite strategies, in the design and adoption of ICT to reduce transaction costs. These strategies either conceive ICT as a powerful instrument that increases the amount of information managed in support of transacting on economic exchanges, or see ICT as a powerful tool to reduce the complexity and the amount of information to be considered while transacting. References Alchian, A. and Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organisation, American Economic Review 62: 777–792. Allen, T. and Widdison, R. (1996). Can Computers Make Contracts, Harvard Journal of Law and Technology 9: 25–52. Angelov, S. and Grefen, P. (2003). The 4W Framework for B2B E-Contracting, International Journal of Networking and Virtual Organisation 1: 78–97. Bailey, J. and Bakos, J.Y. (1997). An Exploratory Study of the Emerging Role of Electronic Intermediaries, International Journal of Electronic Commerce 1: 7–20. Bakos, J.Y. (1991). A Strategic Analysis of Electronic Marketplaces, MIS Quarterly 15: 295– 310. Bakos, J.Y. (1998). Towards Friction-Free Markets: The emerging role of electronic marketplaces on the internet, Communications of the ACM 41(8): 35–42. Bakos, J.Y. and Brynjolfsson, E. (1997). Organisational Partnerships and the Virtual Corporation, in C. Kramer (ed.) Information Technology and Industrial Competitiveness: How Information Technology Shapes Competition, Dordrecht, Boston MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Barney, J. and Ouchi, W.G. (eds.) (1986). Organisational Economics: Toward A New Paradigm for Understanding and Studying Organizations, San Francisco, California: Jossey-Bass. Bauer, M. and Cohen, D. (1983). The Invisibility of Power in Economics: Beyond market and hierarchies, in A. Francis, J. Turk and P. William (eds.) Power, Efficiency, and Institutions, London: Hienemann. Benjamin, R. and Wigand, R. (1995a). Electronic Markets and Virtual Value Chains on the Information Superhighway, Sloan Management Review 36: 62–72. Benjamin, R.I. and Wigand, R. (1995b). Electronic Market and Virtual Value Chains on the Information Superhighway, Sloan Management Review 36: 62–72. Braddach, J. and Eccles, R. (1989). Price, Authority and Trust: From ideal types to plural forms, Annual Review of Sociology 15: 97–118. Brynjolfsson, E., Malone, T., Gurbaxani, V. and Kambil, A. (1994). Does Information Technology Lead to Smaller Firms? Management Science 40(12): 1628–1645. Chircu, A. and Kauffman, R. (1999). Analyzing Firm-Level Strategy for Internet-Focused, 32nd Hawaii International Conference on System Science. Ciborra, C.U. (1981). Markets, Bureaucracies and Groups in the Information Society, Information and Policy 1: 145–160. Ciborra, C.U. (1993). Teams Markets and Systems, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Ciborra, C.U. (ed.) (2000). From Control to Drift, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Ciborra, C.U. (forthcoming in 2008). Imbrication of Representations: Risk and digital technologies, in C. Avgerou, O. Hanseth and L. Willcocks (eds.) Information Systems as Emergent Practice, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Ciborra, C.U. and Hanseth, O. (1998). From Tool to Gestell, Information Technology and People 11: 305–327. Coase, R.H. (1937). The Nature of the Firm, Economica 4: 386–405. Collin, S.V. (1993). The Brotherhood of the Swedish Sphere: A third institutional form for economic exchange, International Studies of Management and Organisation 23(1): 69–86. Collin, S.V. and Larsson, R. (1993). Beyond Markets and Hierarchies: A Swedish quest for a tripolar institutional framework, International Studies of Management and Organisation 23(1): 3–12. Cordella, A. (2001). Does Information Technology Always Lead to Lower Transaction Costs? European Conference in Information Systems, Bled. Daskalopulu, A. and Sergot, M.J. (1997). The Representation of Legal Contracts, AI and Society 11(1/2): 6–17. Dietrich, M. (1994). Transaction Costs Economies and Beyond, London: Routledge. Dugger, W. (1983). The Transaction Costs Analysis of Oliver E. Williamson: A new synthesis? Journal of Economic Issues 17: 95–114. Elg, U. and Johansson, U. (1993). The Institutions of Industrial Governance, International Studies of Management and Organisation 23: 29–46. Etzioni, A. (1988). The Moral Dimension: Towards a New Economies, New York: Free Press. Francis, A. (1983). Market and Hierarchies: Efficiency or domination?, in A. Francis, J. Turk and P. William (eds.) Power, Efficiency, an Institutions, London: Hienemann. Grossman, S. and Hart, O. (1983). An Analysis of the Principal-Agent Problem, Econometrica 51: 7–46. Hayek, F. (1945). The Use of Knowledge in Society, American Economic Review 35: 519–530. Lacity, M. and Willcocks, L. (1995). Interpreting Information Technology Sourcing Decisions from a Transaction Cost Perspective: Findings and critique, Accounting Management and Information Technology 5: 203–244. Laffont, J.-J. and Martimort, D. (2002). The Theory of Incentives: The Principal- Agent Model, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Lewis, D. (1996). Dying for Information, Reuters Business Information. Malone, T.W., Yates, J. and Benjamin, R.I. (1987). Electronic Markets and Electronic Hierarchies: Effects of information technology on market structure and corporate strategies, Communications of the ACM 30: 484–497. Merz, M., Griffel, F., Tu, T., Muller-Wilken, S., Weinreich, H., Boger, M. and Lamersdorf, W. (1998). Supporting Electronic Commerce Transactions with Contracting Services, International Journal on Cooperative Information Systems 7: 249–274. Milosevic, Z., Jøsang, A., Dimitrakos, T. and Patton, M. (2003). Discretionary Enforcement of Electronic Contracts, in Proceedings of the Sixth International Enterprise Distributed Object Computing Conference (Lausanne, Switzerland, 2002) 39–50. Moe, T.M. (1984). The New Economics of Organization, American Journal of Political Science 28(4): 739–777. Palme, J. (1984). You Have 134 Unread mail! Do You Want to Read Them Now? IFIP WG 6.5 Working conference on computer-based document services, Nottingham. Perrow, C. (1986). Complex Organisations, New Your: Random House. Sarkar, M.B., Butler, B. and Steinfield, C. (1995). Intermediaries and Cybermediaries: A continuing role for mediating players in the electronic marketplace, Journal of ComputerMediated Communication: http://www.ascusc.org/jcmc/vol1/issue3/vol1no3.html. Schultze, U. and Vandenbosch, B. (1998). Information Overload in a Groupware Environment: Now you see it, now you don’t, Journal of Organisational Computing and Electronic Commerce 8(2): 127–148. Sen, R. and King, R.C. (2003). Revisit the Debate on Intermediation, Disintermediation and Reintermediation due to E-commerce, Electronic Markets 13(2): 153–163. Varian, H.R. (1992). Microeconomic Analysis, Norton: London. Wigand, R. (1997). Electronic Commerce: Definitions, Theory, and Context, The Information Society 13: 1–16. Wigand, R.T., Picot, A. and Reichwald, R. (1997). Information, Organisation, and Management: Expanding Markets and Corporate Boundaries, New York: Wiley, Chichester. Williamson, O.E. (1975). Market and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications, New York: Free Press. Williamson, O.E. (1985). The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting,, Collier Macmillan, New York, London: Free Press. Zuboff, S. (1988). In the Age of the Smart Machine, New York: Basic Books, Inc.