Portfolio Construction Capital Allocation Capital Allocation and Security Selection Capital allocation decision is concerned with how you allocate your funds in broad asset classes: e.g., the risk free asset and the risky assets. Security selection decision is concerned with how you allocate your money among individual securities, e.g., IBM stock, Microsoft stock. Capital Allocation In making the capital allocation decision, I assume that you have already selected the (optimal) risky portfolio. For ease of exposition, I sometimes just call the risky portfolio as the risky asset. In constructing their portfolios, Individual investors or portfolio managers seek to achieve the best possible trade-off between risk and return. To do this, the individual investors or portfolio managers have to make two decisions: ______________ and _____________ Top-down or bottom-up? top-down approach bottom-up approach As you will see, the capital allocation decision and the security selection decision are largely independent according to the modern portfolio theory. Portfolio of A Risk-free Asset and A Risky Asset Assume the expected return of the risky asset is E(r) and the standard deviation of the return of the risky asset is σ. Then the expected return of the portfolio is E(rp) = (1-y) rf + y E(r) = rf + y (E(r)-rf ) y = proportion of funds in the risky asset 1 Portfolio of A Risk-free Asset and A Risky Asset By definition, the expected return of the riskfree asset is the ___________ and the standard deviation of the return of the riskfree asset is _____. The correlation between the risk free rate and the return on any risky asset is also _____. N Var ( X ) = σ X2 = ∑ pi [ X i − E ( X )] Portfolio of A Risk-free Asset and A Risky Asset 2 i =1 Cov( X , Y ) = E [( X − E ( X ))(Y − E (Y ))] = N N ∑∑ p ( X ij i =1 j =1 i − E ( X ))(Y j − E (Y )) Sharpe Ratio Example Reward to risk ratio Sharpe Ratio = E (RP ) − R f σP σP = y (E ( R ) − R f ) yσ = σ Suppose r f = 7%, E (r ) = 15%, σ = 22% and A = 4 E ( R) − R f Example Suppose r f = 7%, E (r ) = 15%, σ = 22% and A = 4 E ( RP ) − R f The portfolio of a risk-free asset and a risky asset has the same Sharpe Ratio as the risky asset Sharpe Ratio = What about the variance of the portfolio? σ p2 = w12 σ 12 + w22 σ 22 + 2w1w2 Cov(r1, r2) In this case, σp2 = (1-y)2 02 + y2 σ 2 + 2y(1-y ) 0 =y2σ2 And the standard deviation of the return of the portfolio is simply: σp = y σ If you put 20% of your money in the risky asset and the rest in the risk free asset, E(R)= ________________________ Stdev(R)= _____________________ Sharpe Ratio= __________________ If you put 80% of your money in the risky asset and the rest in the risk free asset, E(R)= ________________________ Stdev(R)= _____________________ Sharpe Ratio= __________________ Capital Allocation Line E(rp) = rf + y (E(r)-rf ) σp = y σ Î E(rp) = rf + (σp/σ) (E(r)-rf ) ÎE(rp) = rf + σp (E(r)-rf )/ σ Expected return is linear in the standard deviation of the portfolio. Graphically, it is a straight line. 2 Capital Allocation Line Capital Allocation Line We can represent combinations of a risky asset and the risk-free asset on a graph (this is also the investment opportunity set): Expected Return E(Ri) Capital Allocation Line (CAL) E(Rp)=15% S= E ( RP ) − R f σP = 0.15 − 0.7 = .36 0.22 • Risky Asset Rf=7% The slope of the CAL measures the excess return being earned per unit of volatility. In our present example, the slope is • Risk-free Asset This “reward-to-risk ratio” is commonly referred to as the Sharpe ratio. σ σ = 22% Indifference Curve Optimal Capital Allocation Expected Return Increasing Utility Standard Deviation Utility and Risk Aversion CAL with Risk Preferences E(r) Borrower Rf Risky Asset Lender σ 3 Risk Aversion and Allocation Greater levels of risk aversion lead to larger proportions of the risk free asset Lower levels of risk aversion lead to larger proportions of the portfolio of risky assets Willingness to accept high levels of risk for high levels of returns may result in leveraged combinations Optimal Allocation Optimal Allocation Optimal Allocation Consider a portfolio with y risky asset and 1-y risk-free asset. The expected return of this portfolio is: E (rp ) = y E (r ) + (1 − y )rf [ = rf + y E (r ) − rf We have shown that different investors will choose different positions in the risky asset. In particular, the more risk averse investors will choose to hold less of the risky asset and more of the risk-free asset. How do we quantify this? We start from the utility function of the investor: U = E (r ) − 0.5 Aσ 2 The investor attempts to maximize her utility level, by choosing the best allocation to the risky asset, y. U = E (r ) − 0.5 Aσ 2 ] [ ] = rf + y E (r ) − rf − 0.5 Ay 2σ 2 The variance of the return of the portfolio is: σ p2 = y 2σ 2 Optimal Allocation Optimal Allocation Taking the first order derivatives of U with respect to y and set it to zero. E (r ) −r f − Aσ 2 y = 0 ⇒ y* = E (r ) − rf Aσ 2 y* = E (r ) − rf ( ) Aσ 2 If r f = 7%, E r = 15%, σ = 22% and A = 4 y* = E (r ) − rf Aσ 2 = 4 Optimal Allocation Other things being equal, the higher the expected return of the risky asset, the higher the optimal allocation in the risky asset. y* = y* = E (r ) − rf Aσ 2 E (r ) − rf ♦ Other things being equal, the more risk averse the investor is, the lower the optimal allocation in the risky asset. y* = Aσ 2 E (r ) − rf Aσ 2 of the return of the risky asset, the lower the optimal allocation in the risky asset. y* = y* = = Aσ 2 E (r ) − rf ♦ Other things being equal, the higher the variance = Optimal Allocation y* = Optimal Allocation E (r ) − rf Aσ 2 E (r ) − rf Aσ 2 = = Market Price of Risk = E (r ) − rf σ2 is called the market price of risk. Note that the market price of risk is different from the Sharpe Ratio, which is defined as: E (r ) − rf σ = Both the market price of risk and Sharpe Ratio captures reward to risk ratio. 5