318 Legal Developments Unfairness Developments in FTC Advertising Cases Ivan L. Preston T he most interesting issue I found in the Federal Trade Commission's (FTC) (1994a) new "Enforcement Policy Statement on Food Advertising" was that it does not mention unfairness. The absence appears as an early section that states the "Legal Framework for Commission Action" as an introduction to procedures for harmonizing the FTC's food advertising decisions with the recent food labeling regulations of the Food and Drug Administration (FDA) (1993). The legal framework opens with the comment that the Commission "regulates food advertising under its statutory authority to prohibit deceptive acts or practices under Section 5 of the FTC Act" (FTC 1994a, p. 28389) In contrast, the Commission's statutory jurisdiction actually entails both "unfair or deceptive acts or practices" (FTC Act 1938, Section 5). The omission appears to represent the most recent reflection of the lessened use of unfairness in advertising cases. However, Congress amended the FTC Act (1994) to create (among other things) a statutory definition of unfairness and new rules for its use. I analyze the possibility that this treatment could retum unfairness to a greater degree of importance in regulating advertising. Background—The Trend in Use Over Time Although the FTC's original jurisdiction was solely to prohibit unfair competition (FTC Act 1914), it creatively stretched that authority in the early years to cover consumer protection actions even when injury to competitors was absent. Eventually, however, the Supreme Court told the FTC not to consider consumers except in cases in which injury to competitors was a factor {FTC v. Raladam 1931). Congress then gave the FTC an explicit role in consumer protection in the Wheeler-Lea Amendments (FTC Act 1938), which produced today's familiar prohibition against "unfair or deceptive acts or practices." After applying the unfairness concept on a case-by-case basis over many years, the Commission integrated the results in a summary, the Unfairness Statement (FTC 1980), using criteria first specified in its Cigarette Statement (FTC 1964). There were three cigarette criteria, which are also known as the S&H criteria after being recognized by the Supreme Court in FTC v. Sperry & Hutchinson (1972) (for an extensive historical discussion, see Rice 1983, 1984). They held that commercial acts could be found unfair by (1) causing consumer injury, (2) violating established public policy, or (3) being unethical or unscrupulous (in the numerical re-ordering of the FTC (1980) statement). The 1980 statement used the reordering to reflect changed specifications of importance. Thus, it assigned the greatest importance to consumer injury, which existed for the rule's purpose if the injury was substantial and was neither out- weighed by countervailing benefits nor reasonably avoidable by consumers. Substantial means that the injury could not be trivial or speculative. In most cases it is monetary; it might also involve health or safety, but not emotional impact or other subjective harms. Countervailing benefits means, where they are present, that a practice might not be injurious in its net effects, determined by assessing both benefits and costs, and so would not be unfair. The costs of a remedy are also used to assess such net effects. Nor reasonably avoidable means that consumers must not have simply failed to avoid the injury, but must also have been prevented from doing so by high costs or other effects of unreasonable seller behavior: "Most of the Commission's unfairness matters are brought... to halt some form of seller behavior that unreasonably creates or takes advantage of an obstacle to the free exercise of consumer decisionmaking" (FTC 1980, p. 1074). The second cigarette criterion was downgraded; it could now be used to provide additional evidence of the first and could also be an independent basis for finding unfairness, but only when the pertinent policy was formally stated in laws or judicial decisions covering jurisdictions broader than isolated states or courts. The Commission later added, however, that it did not believe such conditions allowing public policy to be an independent basis were ever likely to be met (Miller 1982). The third cigarette criterion was dismissed. It was recognized as having existed earlier, but was duplicative of the first two, and therefore was declared not independently usable. In this way the FTC's (1980) Unfairness Statement reduces the earlier criteria to (1) showings of consumer injury and (2) use of public policy considerations as additional evidence of such injury. These and other events indicate that the FTC has treated unfairness as an active concept over the years. There was an extensive early application, from which the original cigarette criteria were derived. That early history involved, among other things, using unfairness as the original foundation for the reasonable basis rule (Pfizer 1972), though deceptiveness became the prevailing foundation with National Dynamics (1973). The writing of the Unfairness Statement and its application in a prominent litigated case {International Harvester 1984) have extended the use of unfairness in more recent times. Yet, there have been signs of a reduction of such activity. The principal reason was the FTC's ill-fated consideration of an industrywide rule that would have banned advertisements addressed primarily to children; the result was Congress broadly decreeing that the FTC no longer could issue rules regulating advertising based on unfairness (FTC Act 1980). It could still use the concept in individual cases—as in International Harvester (1984), Orkin (1986), and C&D Electronics {192,1). Whether or not the overall record shows a waning of the concept, the use of unfairness has been minor in advertising cases in the 1990s. Is it possible, though, that the recent codifying of the definition into the FTC Act may significantly increase the usage? Journal of Public Policy & Marketing The 1994 Amendments and Their Implications Section 5 of the FTC Act (1994), which authorizes the prohibition of unfairness and deceptiveness, was amended to state: The Commission shall have no authority ... to declare unlawful an act or practice on the grounds that [it] is unfair unless [it] causes or is likely to cause substantial injury to consumers which is not reasonably avoidable by consumers themselves and not outweighed by countervailing benefits to consumers or to competition. In determining whether an act or practice is unfair, the Commission may consider established public policies as evidence to be considered with all other evidence. Such public policy considerations may not serve as a primary basis for such determination. The statement obviously reflects the 1980 formulation, but emphasizes the primacy of consumer injury. The original third criterion is not mentioned at all, and the second is not mentioned as an independent basis. The potential significance of the latter change is reflected by a complaint, quickly issued by a consumer activist, that the weakening of the ability to treat unfairness by public policy is hurtful to a petition of the Center for Science in the Public Interest. The petition, which asks for restrictions on alcohol advertising, is based largely on public policy considerations and must now be restated to rely on consumer injury issues (Silverglade 1994). Altematively, however, the reduction in scope may not be great, because the 1980 statement had already made the third criterion no longer independently applicable and the second applicable primarily in the way the new wording still permits. Meanwhile, a result that seems more clearly significant is that the definition is now "set in stone" and, thus, is no longer subject to further change by unilateral action of the Commission. The 1994 amendments also restore unfairness as a basis for industrywide rulemaking, which points the concept toward its former breadth of scope. However, the change is subject to the following provision: The Commission shall issue a notice of proposed rulemaking only where it has reason to believe that the unfair or deceptive acts or practices which are the subject of the proposed rulemaking are prevalent [if] (A) it has issued cease and desist orders regarding such acts or practices, or (B) any other information available ... indicates a widespread pattem of unfair or deceptive acts or practices (FTC Act 1994, Section 5). The privilege is not greatly narrowed by the requirement to show prevalence, because the FTC has traditionally needed to justify its actions as being in the public interest. The requirement for a "reason to believe," however, could be confining if challenges are raised, because, in the past, the FTC occasionally appeared to have established its justification primarily by self-assertion. More provocative among the 1994 changes could be the wording that unfairness may occur if the action not only causes, but merely is "likely to cause," consumer injury. Sufficiency of a finding of likeliness was not acknowledged specifically in the 1980 statement, and the difference could be significant, because likeliness to injure precedes actual injury and is easier to establish as a factual finding. Thus, 319 the change conceivably could lead to a greater use of unfairness. I make this suggestion cautiously, however, because prior statutes and interpretations have never blocked the FTC from basing a finding of unfairness on mere likeliness. The possibility of such use, along with the low incidence of doing so, are both indicated in a prominent case comment: "Unlike deception, which focuses on 'likely' injury, unfairness cases usually involve actual and completed harms.... [They] may also be brought on the basis of likely rather than actual injury, although this is not the usual practice" {International Harvester 1984, p. 1061). Thus, the suggestion here is not that likeliness to injure will arise as a brand new concept, but that its use could move toward becoming a usual practice. Should that happen, the concept of likeliness to injure could regularly function similarly to the way such likelihood is used in deceptiveness cases. The ease of finding deceptiveness, rather than actual deception, has played an essential role in the interpretation of the statutory term deceptive, by giving the FTC a far greater chance of finding violations. It also accurately reflects the FTC's mandate to prevent deceptive acts before they occur, which in tum reflects the FTC Act's status as civil law, intended to set matters right— in contrast to criminal law, which is intended to punish. An absolute requirement to prove actual deception would greatly reduce the FTC's findings of deceptive acts and less adequately reflect its goal of prevention. In parallel, the tendency in unfaimess actions toward needing to prove actual injury could help explain why unfaimess has been less used than deceptiveness, whereas the new encouragement to find likeliness to injure could increase its usage in the future. In terms of the Commission's ability to produce the needed factual findings, there is no guarantee that the use of likeliness to injure is as feasible as the use of likeliness to deceive. It appears, for example, that the causal connection of the challenged act to consumer injury will still need to be proved, and will be difficult to prove. Furthennore, there are constraints that apply to the likeliness to injure, though not to the likeliness to deceive; they are the provisions that the threat of injury must not be outweighed by countervailing benefits or cost considerations and that consumers are not reasonably able to avoid the injury. The role of such factors can be only speculated on at present, because Commission cases to date reveal no comprehensive identifications and assessments of required evidence of the sort that have long since been available for deceptiveness (Preston 1990). The prospects are mixed; the greater use that seems possible in theory may be restrained in application. To illustrate such chances, consider that prior to the 1994 amendments, the FTC investigated but did not act on the possible relationship of the Joe Camel cartoon figure to children's smoking (FTC 1994b). Had that investigation followed, rather than preceded, the new statutory definition, the FTC might have felt more confident of proving likeliness to injure even if it could not prove actual injury. On the other hand, as the majority said in deciding against issuing a complaint, the agency would still have had to show "a link between the Joe Camel advertising and increased smoking among children" (FTC 1994b, p. 2). It would also 320 Legal Developments have had to overcome any countervailing benefits and costs of the regulation that might be found, as well as the possibility that consumers might reasonably be able to reject the persuasive impact of the Joe Camel messages. Given the challenges of these various tests, the new definition might or might not have made a difference. On the whole, however, the addition of a strengthened unfaimess violation to the existing deceptiveness violation is more than trivial in its regulatory impact, because unfaimess can reach activity that may cause consumer injury, though it is not deceptive. Deceptive acts are unfair, but are treated by the FTC as a subset of unfaimess, with unfaimess being a more general principle {International Harvester 1984, p. 1060). Thus, any increase in the use of unfaimess would likely lead to an increase in regulation overall. A valuable device, for example, that might be strengthened by a rebirth of unfaimess is the remedy of affirmative disclosure. Although the usual result of finding a claim deceptive is to prohibit it, the FTC also recognizes that some claims can convey useful information without the accompanying deceptiveness. Rather than imposing an outright prohibition in such conditions, the FTC may let a claim continue if it is accompanied by a disclosure that eliminates its deceptiveness. Thus, the harmful part is removed without also removing the useful provision of information. To such purpose, affirmative disclosure has been widely used, and yet it is subject to the limitation of being applied only when it cures deceptiveness. As the FTC's Policy Statement on Deception explains, "A misleading omission occurs when qualifying information necessary to prevent a practice, claim, representation, or reasonable expectation of belief from being misleading is not disclosed. Not all omissions are deceptive...." (Miller 1984, note 4). The statement then shows how to distinguish the difference: The test is simple and pragmatic: Is it likely that, unless such disclosure is made, a substantial body of consumers will be misled to their detriment...? [D]eception occurs only if consumers could actually be misled by a seller's inaction. In other words, the Commission must fmd that consumers have erroneous expectations that are contrary to an undisclosed material fact (Miller 1984, note 37). Although the Policy Statement on Deception was advisory, these points were more solidly established and given additional analysis in a subsequently litigated case {International Harvester 1984, pp. 1057-60). Despite the consequent attention and importance of such application, however, there might also be instances in which the absence or inadequacy of infonnation hurts consumers' ability to cope, though the situation involves no deceptiveness. In such instances, a remedy that assures retention of the useful information would seem equally valuable, but is not readily available, despite the legislative intent that the FTC Act prevent harm to consumers. Although the use of unfaimess to undergird affirmative disclosures in advertising technically has always been possible, it has happened infrequently in recent times. In International Harvester {\9M), failure to disclose was found to be unfair, but no order was issued, because changes in the company's provision of information and the nature of its products were found to render further disclosure unnecessary. In C&D Electronics (1987), a requirement for disclosure by the seller directly to the buyer at the point of sale was supported by unfaimess, and in Consumer Direct (1990), a requirement for disclosure in advertising was similarly supported. Consumer Direct illustrates the role unfaimess plays and could play more often in the absence of deceptiveness. The complaint referred to a risk of injury from the snapping or breaking of the spring in an exercise device and charged that failure to disclose such fact in advertising and selling "has caused substantial and ongoing injury to consumers" and, thus, was unfair. The complaint also made several charges of deceptiveness, but its drafters, though possibly they could have done so, did not include the failure to disclose among them. Although this case shows how unfaimess can be an alternative violation, the low level of its use means this has not often happened. It seems, therefore, that a significant increase of such activity, in affirmative disclosure matters, and elsewhere in advertising cases, could occur should it be encouraged by recent developments. Conclusion If the new statutory definition of unfaimess encourages greater use of the concept, the scope of FTC regulation could become broader than it currently has been. Accordingly, interested parties should keep an eye on the impact of the 1994 amendments. References Alberty {194S), 44 ETC. 475. Alberty v. FTC (1950), 182 F.2d 36 (D.C. Cir). C&D Electronics {im), 109 F.T.C. 72. Consumer Direct {1990), 113 FT.C. 923. FDA (1993), "Food Labeling Regulations," 21 C.F.R. §101, implementing the Nutrition Labeling and Education Act of 1990, 104 Stat. 2353, 21 U.S.C. §343. FTC (1964), "Statement of Basis and Purpose, Unfair or Deceptive Advertising and Labeling of Cigarettes in Relation to the Health Hazards of Smoking" (Cigarette Statement), 29 Fed. Reg. 8355. (1980), "Commission Statement of Policy on the Scope of the Consumer Unfairness Jurisdiction" (Unfairness Statement), letter to Senators Ford and Danforth, December 17; reprinted in 104 ETC. 1072(1984). (1994a), "Enforcement Policy Statement on Eood Advertising," 59 Fed. Reg. 28388 (June 1). (1994b), "Joint Statement of Commissioners" in R. J. Reynolds (Camel Cigarettes), File 932 3162, June 7. FTC Act (1914), 15 U.S.C §41 et seq. (1938), amended, 15 U.S.C. §41 et seq. (1980), amended, 15 U.S.C. §41 et seq. (1994), amended, 15 U.S.C. §41 et seq. FTC V. Raladam (1931), 283 U.S. 643. FTC V. Sperry & Hutchinson Co. (1972), 405 U.S. 223. International Harvester {\9M), 104 ETC. 949. Journal of Public Policy & Marketing Miller, James C. (1982), letter from FTC Chairman to Senators Packwood and Kasten, March 5. (1984), "Policy Statement on Deception," appendix to Cliffdale Associates, 103 F.T.C. 174 (originally an enclosure in letter to Congressman John D. Dingell, October 14, 1983). National Dynamics {\913), 82 F.T.C. 488. Orkin (1986), 108 F.T.C. 263, affirmed, 849 F.2d 1354 (llth Cir. 1988). Pfizer (1972), 81 F.T.C. 23. Preston, Ivan L. (1990), "The Definition of Deceptiveness in Advertising and Other Commercial Speech," Catholic University Law Review, Vol. 39, 1035-79. Rice, David A. (1983), "Consumer Unfaimess at the FTC: Misadventures in Law and Economics," George Washington Law Review, 52, 1-66. (1984), "Toward a Theory and Legal Standard of Consumer Unfaimess," Joumal of Law and Commerce, 5, 111-54. Silvergiade, Bruce (1994), "Comment," FTC:Watch, 421 (October 24), 8. 'Unfair'Advertising and the FTC: Structural Evolution of the Law and Implications for Marketing and Public Policy Alexander Simonson' The Federal Trade Commission's power over 'unfair'advertising (and other marketing practices) is of major importance to marketers, advertising agencies, and public policymakers. This power has undergone two major structural changes. First, the definition of unfairness is now codified. Second, the ban on industry-wide regulations is now lified. The author analyzes the structural evolution of the law, namely, the background, debate, and changes to the law, and concludes with implications for public policy and marketing. T he Federal Trade Commission Act Amendments of 1994 codified what may be the most significant changes in over a decade to the Federal Trade Commission's (FTC) power in policing "unfair" marketing. These amendments grew out of protracted debate involving numerous industry and advertising associations and consumer organizations. The legislation containing the amendments and reauthorizing the FTC was signed into law on August 26, 1994, toward the close of the Democratically controlled 103d Congress (Federal Trade Commission Act Amendments of 1994). The FTC's authority over unfair marketing stems from Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act (FTC Act), which states that "unfair or deceptive acts or practices in 321 commerce are declared unlawful" (codified in 1938, 15 U.S.C. §45). Advertising is a key act or practice subject to FTC policing. The FTC is responsible for enforcing the statute and has two distinct mandates: (1) to prevent deception and (2) to prevent unfaimess. The authority provided in Section 5 of the FTC Act enables the FTC to adjudicate cases one-by-one. Section 18 of the Act gives the FTC broad rulemaking power (i.e., the power to create federal regulations) to prevent unfair or deceptive acts or practices (codified in 1975, 15 U.S.C. §57a). Because advertisers can fmd themselves subject to the potentially unpredictable and politically motivated decisions of the FTC, there are questions conceming the FTC's adjudicatory and regulatory power over marketers' unfair acts and, in particular, whether the FTC's authority should be limited to protect the rights of advertisers. Ironically, the amendments received only limited media attention (Fisher 1994), but they were passionately debated, with hundreds of pages of testimony and input gamered from numerous entities, ranging from the Association of National Advertisers to the Consumers Union. I analyze the FTC's evolving authority over unfaimess and explain the major changes that have taken place in unfaimess jurisprudence. Finally, I conclude with implications for public policy and marketers. Prior Framework What is "Unfair"? What is unfair advertising? Is it unfair to advertise to vulnerable groups, such as children? Is it unfair to advertise products that are harmful, such as cigju"ettes? Numerous fundamental legal concepts, such as due process and equal protection, are left undefined by statute or constitution. Therefore, courts are left to interpret these terms in the common-law tradition. Because faimess is linked to highly charged domains of morality, personal values, cultural norms, and public policy, its conceptualization and operationalization might vary accordingly. In 1914, recognizing the highly subjective nature of the term unfair. Congress purposefully failed to provide a definition when it declared "unfair methods of competition" unlawful (15 U.S.C. §45). The House Conference report stated: [I]t is impossible to frame definitions which embrace all unfair practices. There is no limit to human inventiveness in this field. Even if all known unfair practices were specifically defined and prohibited, it would be at once necessary to begin all over again. If Congress were to adopt the method of definition, it would undertake an endless task (U.S. Congress. House 1914, pp. 18-19). Again, in 1938, Congress failed to define unfaimess when it added that "unfair or deceptive acts or practices" are unlawful. The legislative history to the 1938 amendments also provides no substantial guidance (Rice 1983). Three-Prong Test 'ALEXANDER SIMONSON is Assistant Professor of Business, School of Business Administration. Georgetown University. He received his J.D. from New York University. School of Law and his Ph.D. in marketing from Columbia University, Graduate School of Business. In 1964 (in cigarette labeling and advertising rulemaking proceedings), the FTC voluntarily presented a test to determine whether an act or practice is "unfair." The test is re-