9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 309 Tijdschrift voor Economie en Management Vol. LI, 3, 2006 Exchange Market Pressure in the Formerly Planned Central and Eastern European Countries: the Role of Institutions by A. VAN POECK, J. VANNESTE and M. VEINER André Van Poeck Universiteit Antwerpen, Departement Algemene Economie, Antwerpen Maret Veiner Universiteit Antwerpen, Departement Algemene Economie, Antwerpen Jacques Vanneste Universiteit Antwerpen, Departement Algemene Economie, Antwerpen ABSTRACT In this paper we find evidence that institutional improvements such as economic liberalization, improved corporate governance, banking sector reform, improvements of rule of law and pushing back corruption have significantly reduced tensions on the exchange market in the formerly planned Central and Eastern European transition economies. We also show that countries with extreme exchange rate arrangements (such as a currency board or a freely floating exchange rate) have – ceteris paribus – been less vulnerable to turbulence on the exchange market than countries with intermediate exchange rate arrangements, such as an adjustable fixed peg. This confirms the so-called bi-polar view on exchange rate regimes for this group of countries. Testing for the interaction between economic fundamentals (current account, domestic credit growth and the inflation differential) and institutions our results are in general quite supporting to the hypothesis that a higher quality of institutions lessens the adverse effect of weak economic fundamentals. Low corruption, efficient banking regulatory and supervisory systems and profound economic liberalization significantly reduce the impact on exchange market pressure of domestic credit growth and inflation. 309 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 310 I. INTRODUCTION The role of institutions in economic performance has been one of the research topics covered by Professor W. Moesen during his fruitful academic career. In this paper we want to contribute to his field of interest by focusing on the institutional developments which have taken place in the formerly planned Central and Eastern European countries (CEECs) and the impact on their exchange markets. The research question is whether institutional reforms such as economic liberalization, improved corporate governance, banking sector reform, improvements of rule of law and pushing back corruption have affected tensions on the currencies of these countries. The formerly planned economies of Central and Eastern Europe have experienced drastic changes since the beginning of the 1990s. Together with the introduction of a market economy institutional reform has been high on their economic and political agenda. In some countries the institutional reforms were speeded up by the eagerness to become member of the European Union. As a matter of fact, eight CEECs successfully joined the EU in the spring of 2004 and others are likely to follow. Yet, these transition processes have not always been very smooth. On the contrary, several transition countries have experienced highly turmoil periods on the currency markets, like e.g. Hungary (1994), the Czech Republic, Romania and Bulgaria (1997) and Russia (1998). This being said, the general impression is one of decreasing financial turbulence and increasing institutional quality. The reason why institutional improvements are expected to lead to lower tensions on the exchange markets is straightforward. Financial and corporate governance, the quality of the legislative institutions and the advancements of the liberalization process all contribute to relieving the information asymmetries in the economy and consequently improve the quality of the investment decisions, thereby raising overall productivity and economic performance. Moreover, sound institutions increase transparency and credibility of government and central bank policies. All this is expected to contribute to a smoother working of the financial markets. But there’s a snake in the grass. We should also take into account a possible adverse effect of institutional improvements on financial vulnerability as they induce increased capital imports and capital dependency. This makes the economies concerned more vulnerable to 310 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 311 sudden changes in international investors’ sentiments. This raises the difficult question of how to phase institutional reform and capital mobility liberalization. In this respect it should be noted that since the mid of the 1990s a number of transition countries have increasingly benefited from capital imports, which make them more vulnerable to sudden capital withdrawals. This concern has been voiced by a number of economists (see e.g. Buiter and Grafe (2002)). As a matter of fact, in the examples cited above, the countries experienced rapid capital outflows (see Vanneste, Van Poeck and Veiner (2003)). In this paper we therefore want to investigate whether formerly planned economies with weaker institutional settings have been more vulnerable to currency weakness than those with stronger institutions. The susceptibility to currency turmoil is proxied by an indicator of exchange market pressure (emp). The advantage of this measure is that it enables comparison of countries with different exchange rate regimes. One specific institution that has received attention in the economic profession is the exchange rate regime under which an economy operates. A distinction can be made between intermediate exchange rate arrangements, such as e.g. conventional fixed pegs and extreme exchange rate systems, such as credible fixed exchange rate systems (monetary union or currency board) and freely floating exchange rates. It has been argued that intermediate exchange rate systems are more vulnerable to exchange rate crises because they can never be made fully credible (as long as the central bank cares about domestic objectives) and because the incentive of the central bank to devalue the currency increases once economic agents expect it to happen (see De Grauwe and Grimaldi (2002))1. Although an extensive empirical literature on explaining or predicting the occurrence of foreign exchange crises exists (see e.g. Flood and Marion (1998)) few studies have tested the role of the exchange rate system and of institutions. Notable exceptions are Effenberger (2004), Mulder, Perelli and Rocha (2002) and Ghosh and Ghosh (2002)2. Effenberger (2004) tests a logit model with a binomial crisis variable on 11 CEECs. Using institutional indicators in addition to macroeconomic fundamentals he shows that the exchange rate regime, the quality of the regulatory and supervisory setting and the degree of liberalisation of the economy significantly influence the probability of a currency crisis. Mulder, Perelli and Rocha (2002) explain the probability and depth of external crises by macroeconomic, corporate, and institutional indicators on a wider set of developed countries. Their 311 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 312 results suggest that corporate balance sheet variables such as leveraged financing and a the ratio of short term debt to working capital play an important role in the occurrence of crises and the depth of crises. The same holds for macroeconomic variables such as the ratio of bank and corporate debt to exports and institutional indicators like the legal regime of a country and shareholders’ rights. Ghosh and Ghosh (2002) analyse 42 mainly emerging market countries. They find that overall governance and rule of law, corporate sector governance and corporate financing structure significantly affect the vulnerability to crises. Their findings also suggest that there exist interactions between structural vulnerabilities and macroeconomic imbalances. Weak governance increases the sensitivity to the effects of macroeconomic and corporate sector weaknesses. All in all these studies confirm the impact of institutions on financial crises and stress the interactions between structural vulnerabilities and macroeconomic imbalances. In our research we specifically focus on transition economies and use data for 24 formerly planned economies in Central- and EasternEurope. This allows us to concentrate on transition-specific aspects, such as e. g. banking sector reform. As our aim is to explain tensions in the exchange market rather that currency crises we use a measure of exchange market pressure instead of a binary crisis dummy as our dependent variable. We explicitly test for interaction between macroeconomic and institutional variables. The different countries in the sample have a lot in common. They all went through a difficult liberalisation process resulting in deep recession and high inflation. Further, they were subject to common external shocks, such as the Russian crisis. All this increases the probability that the differences in crisis experience were related to the quality of their institutional setting and the adopted exchange rate regime. The remainder of this paper is as follows. In section II the literature on currency crises and institutions is briefly reviewed. Section III recalls the bi-polar view on exchange rate regimes which is empirically tested in section VI. Section IV sketches the institutional developments in the transition countries covered in the analysis. In section V a quarterly measure of exchange market pressure is defined, computed and documented for three subgroups of our dataset, i. e. EU members; EU candidates and potential candidates; and other countries of the Commonwealth of Independent States. The regression analysis is presented in section VI. Policy conclusions and prospects for further research are discussed in the final section. 312 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 313 II. THE LITERATURE ON THE THEORY OF CURRENCY CRISES AND INSTITUTIONS Since the collapse of the Bretton Woods system in the 1970s the world has witnessed a huge number of currency crises (see Feldstein (2002)) and they have been a widely studied subject. In this section we briefly summarize three currently existing classes of crises models and the role that institutions play in these models. Weak macroeconomic fundamentals are the main cause of currency crises according to the first generation models pioneered by Krugman (1979). Krugman’s model considers the situation where the government pursues an overly expansionary monetary policy in a fixed exchange rate regime. The excessive expansion of domestic credit results from monetization of fiscal deficits or from supporting a weak banking system. It leads to a fall in the domestic interest rate, capital outflow and a loss of international reserves. Rational speculators regard this situation as unsustainable and believe the maintenance of a fixed peg is impossible in the long run. They anticipate the devaluation and launch an attack long before the international reserves are completely exhausted. According to the first generation models a currency crisis stems from monetary or fiscal policies that are inconsistent with the fixed exchange rate regime. Institutions have no specific contribution in this view. Since such crises result from macroeconomic imbalances they are in principle predictable. However, the crisis of the EMS at the beginning of the 1990s has demonstrated that countries with relatively sound macroeconomic fundamentals can be victims of speculative attacks too (see e.g. Eichengreen, Rose and Wyplosz (1994)). The EMS crisis gave support to second generation models which incorporate the phenomenon of selffulfilling expectations and multiple equilibria. Castrén and Takalo (2000) add the institutional setting to the model of self-fulfilling currency crises. They argue that institutions fostering corporate governance increase the credibility of the exchange rate peg. They also show that the impact of institutional reforms depends crucially on the extent of the reforms, partial reforms increasing instead of reducing the vulnerability of a fixed exchange rate. Increasing attention to institutions is characteristic for the so-called third generation models which were developed after the outburst of the South-East Asian crisis of 1997. Besides macroeconomic fundamentals (the inconsistency of economic policy with the fixed 313 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 314 exchange rate regime) and the role of expectations, these models stress problems in the banking sector and weak institutions in general as the main driving forces behind banking crises which spill over into currency crises. Weak supervision of the banking sector and implicit government guarantees, leading to moral hazard problems and over-indebtedness abroad are crucial elements in these models. Pitt (2001) e.g. develops a model where the costs and benefits of a fixed exchange rate are based on the country’s ability to meet its external obligations while maximising economic growth. He concludes that liberalisation and institutional improvement increase the return on investment as the economy grows and thereby lower the cost of maintaining the peg. Stressing the difference between financial institutions in Taiwan and Korea during the recent Asian crisis Huang and Xu (2000) particularly explain the financial crisis in Korea with the high government participation in financing and lending decisions. III. THE BI-POLAR VIEW ON EXCHANGE RATE REGIMES It is clear from the above overview that including the institutional setting in crisis models is a relatively new phenomenon, mostly related to the third generation crises models. Most of the models indicate that the sources of turbulence can be linked to one or more of the following institutional aspects: the exchange rate regime; the degree of economic liberalization, the level of corporate governance, the quality of the financial institutions, the development of the legal regime and the degree of corruption. With respect to the exchange rate regime, the so-called bipolar view argues that conventional fixed pegged exchange rate systems are considered intrinsically more vulnerable to currency crises (see Fischer (2001)). Hence in this view countries should prefer extreme exchange rate arrangements (such as a currency board or a freely floating exchange rate) to intermediate exchange rate arrangements, such as an adjustable fixed peg. Moreover flexible exchange rate regime advocates stress that this system offers greater financial stability and allows transition countries to reform their economies more smoothly. Masson (1999) adds that structural differences between the CEECs and the EU-countries make adjustable pegs in the CEECs especially vulnerable to speculative attacks. 314 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 315 In an adjustable pegged exchange rate regime, a central bank always has a temptation to renege on its promise not to devalue and hence to abandon the peg. This temptation increases with the importance that the central bank attaches to other objectives than defending the peg. This can be any economic objective that is conceivably part of the central bank’s (or the government’s) social welfare function and whose attainment involves a trade-off with the fixed peg (e.g. output stabilisation or employment growth). It can be shown that the temptation to renege increases with the size of the shock to the economy (e.g. the deepness of the recession) and the cost of defending the peg (e.g. the output loss as a result of the interest rate increase to defend the peg). The temptation to abandon the peg decreases with the cost of the devaluation, such as the loss of credibility of the monetary authorities after the devaluation (De Grauwe and Grimaldi (2002)). IV. INSTITUTIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN THE TRANSITION COUNTRIES In this section we discuss several institutional indicators for the transition economies we consider in this paper. For analytical purposes the countries are divided into three groups based on their progress towards the membership of the EU, viz. the new EU members, the EU candidates and potential candidates3 and the other CIS countries. The first group consists of the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, the Slovak Republic and Slovenia. The countries Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Bulgaria, Croatia, Macedonia and Romania constitute the second group and the third group is formed by Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Georgia, Kazakhstan, the Kyrgyz Republic, Moldova, Russia, Tajikistan, and Ukraine. Economic liberalisation and institutional reform have been important issues in transition countries for the last 15 years. As a proxy to reflect these processes several institutional indexes are available, viz.: o o o o the exchange rate regime the index of economic freedom the index of rule of law the index of corruption 315 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 316 o the governance and enterprise restructuring index o the index of banking sector reform o the index of non-banking sector reform. Although the theoretical models limit themselves mostly to either fixed (pegged) or flexible systems, central banks in practice pursue a variety of exchange rate policies. The IMF classifies exchange rate arrangements into eight categories depending on the level of flexibility. The classification is based on de jure declarations of the central banks and does not necessarily reflect the actual policy followed by those central banks. Recently, however, the IMF has started to correct its classification towards the real situation and policy of the central banks. Our comparison with one alternative classification, viz. the one by Reinhart-Rogoff (2004) shows a high correlation between the de facto and the de jure classification for the transition countries. Therefore we use the IMF classification as it provides a more complete set of data over the entire sample period. Table 1 shows the exchange rate regimes in the transition countries over the period 1992-2005 (end of the year observations) according to the official IMF classification. During the last 15 years the transition countries have followed a variety of regimes and many countries have changed their regime several times. In the CIS countries more flexible regimes have dominated over the entire period, the reason being that the extremely low credibility that these countries enjoy often precludes the use of fixed exchange rates. In the two other groups we observe a mixture of fixed and flexible exchange rate regimes. Estonia and Lithuania have operated constantly under a currency board regime and Albania and Bulgaria have also introduced this regime. But there is also a tendency for moving to a more flexible exchange rate regime, actually in the Czech Republic, Poland, the Slovak Republic, Bosnia & Herzegovina and Croatia. The number of countries that operate under an intermediate system i.e. neither permanently, fixed or flexible, is low, viz. Hungary, Latvia, Slovenia, Macedonia and Ukraine. The insight on the role of economic liberalization for a country’s vulnerability to crises is not clear-cut. Economic liberalization in transition countries has created the necessary market forces which enabled these economies to react to changing economic conditions in an effective way. However, as Feldstein (2002) argues, capital account liberalization has produced much more volatile capital flows 316 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 317 which can destabilize domestic financial markets and the exchange rate. The negative side effects of economic liberalization can however be counterbalanced by a good corporate governance environment. Corporate governance consists of various rules and organizations that govern good behavior of corporate owners, directors and managers of companies. Currency crises were also often preceded by banking crises which were closely related to financial liberalization (Kaminsky and Reinhart (1996)). Therefore sound financial institutions are expected to play a crucial role in preventing currency crises in the transition countries. The index of economic freedom published by the Heritage Foundation (2005) measures how countries score on a list of 50 single variables divided into 10 broad factors: trade policy, fiscal burden of government, government intervention in the economy, monetary policy, capital flows and foreign investment, banking and finance, wages and prices, property rights, regulation, and informal market activity. The scale runs from 1 to 5. The higher a country’s score on a factor, the greater the level of government intervention in the economy and the less economic freedom there is. A considerable increase in liberalization is noted over the last decade in the transition countries, as shown by Figure 1 (and Appendix I). Nevertheless, there still remain significant differences between the new EU members and other two groups considered. The highest degree of economic freedom is found in the EU members’ group, whereas the EU candidates and potential candidates and the CIS countries are generally characterized by a low degree of economic freedom. Estonia exhibits the overall highest degree of economic freedom. By 2007 two quite different countries will join the EU. The degree of economic liberalization in Bulgaria is the highest within the EU candidates and potential candidates and close Slovenia’s score. Romania’s economic freedom is much lower and only at the CIS countries’ average level. Within the group of CIS countries, Armenia has a relatively high degree of economic freedom, whereas in Belarus and Tajikistan economic freedom is still very low. To reflect the general quality of the legal system and the spread of corruption we use two World Bank (2004) indicators, viz. the index of rule of law and the index of control of corruption. Since 1996 the World Bank assesses once every two years six dimensions of 317 318 3 2 3 (8) (8) 5 3 7 8 3 8 3 8 8 Czech Republic Estonia Hungary Latvia Lithuania Poland Slovak Republic Slovenia Albania Bosnia & Herzegovina Bulgaria Croatia Macedonia Romania 1992 4 2 6 3 2 6 4 7 1997 7 2 6 3 2 6 4 7 7 2 6 3 2 6 7 7 1998 EU members 1996 7 2 6 3 2 6 7 7 1999 8 3 8 4 3 8 8 3 8 4 3 8 8 3 2 4 3 8 8 2 2 4 3 7 8 2 2 7 3 7 EU candidates and potential candidates 3 2 6 3 2 6 3 7 1995 8 2 2 7 3 7 7 2 6 3 2 7 7 7 2000 8 2 2 7 3 6 7 2 6 3 2 7 7 7 2001 8 2 2 7 3 6 7 2 4 3 2 7 7 7 2002 8 2 2 7 3 6 7 2 4 3 2 8 7 6 2003 2 8 2 7 3 7 7 2 4 3 2 8 7 4 2004 2 8 2 7 3 7 7 2 4 3 2 8 7 4 2005 10:36 8 3 8 4 3 8 3 2 3 3 2 5 3 7 1994 04-10-2006 8 3 8 8 8 8 3 2 3 (8) (8) 5 3 7 1993 TABLE 1 Exchange rate regimes in the transition countries, 1992-2005 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck Pagina 318 (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) (3) na (3) (8) (3) (3) (8) (8) (8) (8) (8) (3) (8) 8 8 (7) 7 8 8 8 8 (3) 8 8 8 7 7 8 7 8 4 8 7 8 8 4 7 8 7 8 6 8 7 8 8 7 3 7 7 8 6 8 4 8 7 7 8 7 7 8 7 7 4 8 7 7 8 8 7 8 8 7 4 8 7 7 8 8 7 8 8 7 7 8 7 7 8 7 7 8 7 8 7 8 7 6 8 7 7 8 7 7 3 8 7 6 7 7 7 8 7 7 3 8 7 6 7 7 7 8 7 7 3 8 7 6 7 7 7 8 7 7 3 04-10-2006 Note: End-year observations. Codes in parentheses refer to the periods when the newly-introduced national currencies have not yet assumed the status as the sole legal tender. The meanings of the codes are: Na = not available, 1 = currency union (no separate legal tender), 2 = currency board arrangements, 3 = conventionally fixed pegs (adjustable pegs, de facto pegs), 4 = horizontal bands, 5 = crawling pegs, 6 = crawling bands, 7 = managed floating without preannounced path for the exchange rate, 8 = independent floating. Source: von Hagen and Zhou (2002), IMF Annual Report on Exchange Rate Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions. Armenia Azerbaijan Belarus Georgia Kazakhstan Kyrgyz Republic Moldova Russia Tajikistan Ukraine Commonwealth of Independent States 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 10:36 Pagina 319 319 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 320 FIGURE 1 Economic liberalization in transition countries, 1995-2005 Note: The four categories of economic freedom: o Free—countries with an average overall score of 1.99 or less; o Mostly free—countries with an average overall score of 2.00 to 2.99; o Mostly unfree—countries with an average overall score of 3.00 to 3.99; and o Repressed—countries with an average overall score of 4.00 or higher. Source: Heritage Foundation. governance which cover the degree of democracy, formation and implementation of policies and the respect of citizens. The index of rule of law includes indicators such as perceptions of the incidence of crime, the effectiveness and predictability of the judiciary, and the enforceability of contracts. This indicator measures the success of a society in developing an environment in which fair and predictable rules form the basis for economic and social interactions and the extent to which property rights are protected. Control of corruption measures perceptions of corruption, conventionally defined as the exercise of public power for private gain. The measures vary between –2.5 and 2.5 where the higher score is considered as the better result. The development in governance has been quite different in transition economies (see Figure 2 and Appendix II). Legal environment and corruption control improved in the group of new EU members during the period covered. For the EU candidates and potential candidates only Bulgaria, Croatia and Romania show a 320 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 321 FIGURE 2 Rule of law and control of corruption in transition countries, 1996-2004 Source: World Bank - http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/govdata2002/index.html. clear improvement. But only Croatia has positive, although small, values for both the rule of law and index of corruption. In contrast all CIS countries stayed under “ground 0” and we observe a continuous deterioration for this group. The development of reform in the enterprise sector, the banking sector and the non-banking sector is taken from EBRD publications ((1996), (2005)). Corporate governance is evaluated through the governance and enterprise restructuring index which measures such aspects as the corporate control mechanism and bankruptcy legislation. The index of banking sector reform assesses the compliance of supervision and competition in the transition countries’ banking sector towards international standards. The EBRD index of non-banking sector reform reflects the level of the development of securities market rules and assesses the regulatory framework regarding non-banking financial institutions (e.g. insurance companies). The indexes of EBRD are given on a 1 to 4+ scale4 where 1 means the least developed sector and 4+ denotes the level of advanced industrial economies. 321 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 322 FIGURE 3 Development of enterprise reform in transition countries, 1993-2005 Source: EBRD Transition Reports Figures 3 and 4 show the evolution of corporate governance, banking and non-banking sector reforms in the three groups of transition countries. Enterprise and banking sector reforms started in all transition countries from a situation of an (under)developed and/or nonexistent institutional framework (see Appendix III and IV). The group of the EU members has followed the quickest reform path of all transition economies. Today the Czech Republic, Hungary and Estonia have banking sector standards close to the advanced economies. The same holds for Croatia. The corporate governance indexes in the EU (potential) candidates and CIS countries still remain on average at a moderate level. The hard road towards a market economy can be illustrated for example by the decreased score of the enterprise sector index of Albania in 2003. Also striking is the low level of corporate governance in EU-candidate Romania. The data in Appendix III and IV clearly illustrate the negative impact of 1998 Russian crisis on the institutional setting of the Russian 322 FIGURE 4 04-10-2006 10:36 Source: EBRD Transition Reports Development of banking and non-banking sector reforms in transition countries, 1992-2005 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck Pagina 323 323 324 Index of economic freedom Rule of law Index of corruption Index of banking sector reform Index of non-banking sector reform Index of enterprise reform 1 Index of economic freedom –∞∞0.78 1 Rule of law –∞∞0.69 0.94 1 Index of corruption –∞∞0.79 0.82 0.78 1 –∞∞0.75 0.77 0.75 0.76 1 Index of Index of banking sector non-banking reform sector reform TABLE 2 Correlation matrix of institutional variable –∞∞0.80 0.86 0.79 0.89 0.77 1 Index of enterprise reform 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 324 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 325 enterprise sector and financial markets. The crisis caused a set-back of the Russian transition process of almost seven years in banking sector reform. It goes without saying that the above mentioned indexes are often highly correlated, as countries tend to perform strongly or weakly in many institutional standards at the same time. Table 2 shows the simple correlation coefficients between institutional variables which range from (in absolute value) 0.69 to 0.94. As a result, in the regressions reported in section VI not all institutional variables can be included at the same time, since this would result in multicollinearity. Therefore one should not be too much convinced about the contribution of one specific institutional characteristic and regard each of them more as an aspect of overall institutional quality. V. EXCHANGE MARKET PRESSURE IN THE TRANSITION COUNTRIES In section VI we investigate in a more formal way the extent to which foreign exchange markets in transition countries have been subject to tensions between 1990 and 2005. To this purpose we compute a quarterly based measure of exchange market pressure (emp) for each of the transition countries. We also define a currency crisis and compute the proportion of crises quarters to which the transition countries have been subject. The notion of exchange market pressure was introduced by Girton and Roper (1977). They started from the insight that excess demand or supply on the foreign exchange market can result in a change in the price of foreign exchange as well as in a change in the level of foreign reserves. The interesting feature of the concept is its equal applicability to countries with different institutional frameworks and exchange rate regimes. We also tried an extended measure of exchange market pressure which includes the change in the interest rate differential, in addition to reserve and nominal exchange rate changes (see Eichengreen et al. (1995)). The correlation with the simple measure proved to be very high viz. from 0.71 for Poland to 0.94 for Bulgaria. Therefore, and for reasons of data availability we stick to the narrower concept of Girton and Roper5. We take into account the different volatility of the components by using variance smoothing weights. The weight on the 325 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 326 intervention term is the ratio of the standard error of the percentage change of the exchange rate over the standard error of the percentage change of reserves. Exchange market pressure is thus defined as: emp = e˙ − se˙ ⋅ r˙ sr˙ (1) where: e: rate of depreciation of domestic currency; r: increase in domestic international reserves; se˙ , sr˙ : standard error of the variables respectively. The data are derived from IMF International Financial Statistics (see Appendix V). Changes in the domestic exchange rate are computed relative to the German mark using the fixed euro conversion rate after 1999. We drop the possibility of intervention by foreign authorities, which is quite a realistic assumption for the transition countries. So only the unilateral intervention measure is used. The general trend of emp-measure over time is shown in Figure 5. The impact of Russian crisis in 1998 can be easily detected. We can also see the diminishing volatility and declining tensions form the beginning of the 21st century. FIGURE 5 Exchange market pressure in the CEECs, 1994-2005 326 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 327 Table 3 shows the statistics of the emp-measure and crisis quarters by country and country group. A crisis quarter is defined as one in which the emp-measure exceeds the mean value by 1.5 standard deviation. However the general picture and conclusions are not TABLE 3 Emp-measure in transition countries: 1990-2005 Country Observations Average emp Standard deviation Number of “crisis” quarters1 Proportion of “crisis” quarters1 (%) 51 55 64 49 51 64 51 56 441 44 –∞∞1.89 –∞∞0.28 1.28 –∞∞1.54 –∞∞4.49 –∞∞1.44 –∞∞1.15 –∞∞1.22 –∞∞1.30 –∞∞4.97 4.55 0.88 6.42 5.24 7.71 8.29 5.27 6.75 6.37 11.84 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 20 56 52 36 58 –∞∞0.06 4.89 –∞∞9.10 0.10 10.54 1.00 50.37 24.22 4.31 52.73 0 6 1 0 3 0.00 0.11 0.02 0.00 0.05 266 –∞∞0.61 35.93 10 3.76 Armenia Azerbaijan Belarus Georgia Kazakhstan Kyrgyz Republic Moldova Russia Tajikistan Ukraine 52 28 40 36 44 47 47 48 13 48 20.78 –∞∞2.16 20.06 5.72 –∞∞1.77 4.76 11.52 16.46 2.79 25.94 150.11 7.92 37.16 12.60 13.64 13.26 20.71 53.10 8.11 73.66 5 0 3 0 0 0 1 6 0 6 0.10 0.00 0.08 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.02 0.13 0.00 0.13 Commonwealth of Independent States 403 7.99 64.12 21 5.21 1110 2.24 42.83 31 2.79 Czech Republic Estonia Hungary Latvia Lithuania Poland Slovak Republic Slovenia EU members Albania Bosnia & Herzegovina Bulgaria Croatia Macedonia Romania EU candidates and potential candidates All countries 1 A “crisis” quarter occurs when the time series exceeds the sample mean by 1.5 standard deviation 327 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 328 significantly altered by using weaker (1 standard deviation) or stronger (2 standard deviations) definitions of currency crises. The emp-measure in the eight EU member countries has been low and not much fluctuating. The average emp-measure amounts to –1.30 and standard deviation to 6.37. The EU-candidates and potential candidates have higher average exchange market pressure (–∞∞0.61) and the emp-measure varies considerably over time. The countries belonging to the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS) form the most volatile region, the average emp-measure equals 7.99 and shows a high standard deviation of 64.12. The incidence of crisis quarters is also much higher in the CIS countries as compared to the other two sets of countries. VI. REGRESSION ANALYSIS In this section we test the bi-polar view on exchange rate regimes and the role of institutions in explaining exchange market pressure in transition economies while controlling for economic fundamentals. The exchange rate regime dummy takes the value of 1 for the extreme and 0 for the intermediate regimes6. Hence the expected coefficient of this dummy is negative. We have to keep in mind that evaluating the role of institutions in currency crises involves several problems. Firstly, the quality of institutions is hard to measure and therefore offers ground for debate. Secondly, the available institutional indexes do not always coincide completely with the theoretical concepts that we want to measure, e.g. the index of economic freedom measures a wider set of factors than only economic liberalisation. Lastly, the frequency of these data is lower than for the financial and macro-economic data. As for the choice of the fundamentals we based ourselves on the findings of the theoretical and empirical literature (see Flood and Marion (1998), for an overview). The following explanatory variables were used in our regressions: current account balance (as % of GDP), domestic credit growth rate, inflation differential (with Germany) and the growth rate of government borrowing (see data definitions and sources in Appendix V). We did not include international reserves or the money supply-reserves ratio since reserves also enter in the computation of the emp-measure. The panel for the 24 transition economies has quarterly data over the period 1990 (Q1) – 2005(Q4). 328 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 329 Our regressions are presented in Table 4 and Table 5. These results confirm to a large extent the importance of the economic fundamentals: the current account, domestic credit growth and inflation differential significantly contribute and with expected sign in explaining exchange market pressure. The coefficient on the growth rate of government borrowing has the expected sign, but is statistically not significantly different from zero. We also included a dummy for the Russian crisis representing a contagion effect. This dummy takes the value 1 for 1998 Q3 and Q4 for all countries in the sample except for Russia. As expected the Russian crisis affected the other transition countries considerably, the coefficient being positive and significant in all regressions. The exchange rate regime dummy enters with the expected sign and is statistically significant at 10%-level. The bi-polar view of exchange rate regimes is thus confirmed in this sample of 24 transition countries. As for the legal system variables we find that lower corruption decreases the vulnerability to currency crises. The coefficient on the index of corruption has the expected sign but is insignificant. This conclusion is in line with Effenberger (2004) who also does not find a relation between the occurrence of currency crises and the legal system. Efficient banking regulatory and supervisory systems reduce exchange market pressure in the transition countries, as shown by the significance of the index of banking sector reform. Surprisingly the index of enterprise reform turns out to be insignificant, whereas Ghosh and Ghosh (2002) and Mulder, Perrelli and Rocha (2002) find banking regulation, supervision and corporate governance to be significant in predicting financial crises. On this point our result is in line with Effenberger’s (2004) finding and can be explained by the fact that in our sample of countries capital market financing in most cases plays only a marginal role. The second column of Table 4 reports our estimation results for a more refined version of the bi-polar view. The hypothesis tested is that extreme exchange rate arrangements lead to lower exchange market pressure, where a currency board even outperforms a freely floating exchange rate regime. This is tested by including an additional dummy for a currency board. As the currency board dummy turns out to be insignificant we cannot discriminate between irrevocably fixed and floating exchange rate regimes as to their predicted impact on emp. 329 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 330 TABLE 4 Econometric estimation of the bi-polar view on exchange market pressure in transition countries Regression No. 1 2 Explanatory variables Constant Current account Domestic credit growth Inflation differential Government borrowing Dummy for Russian crisis contagion GDP per capita CIS countries dummy Extreme exchange rate arrangement dummy Currency board dummy Average index of corruption Index of banking sector reform Index of non-banking sector reform Index of enterprise reform 6.4271 (0.6577) –∞∞0.3745** (–∞∞2.8436) 0.2932*** (9.4232) 0.3767*** (5.5247) 0.0012 (0.9480) 17.2841*** (3.5508) –∞∞0.0324 (–∞∞0.0112) 2.6667 (0.7191) –∞∞3.9943* (–∞∞1.7484) –∞∞4.2170 (–∞∞1.0462) –∞∞8.8515*** (–∞∞2.7098) 3.4527 (1.2412) 5.5784 (1.5198) 10.7206 (1.0353) –∞∞0.3815*** (–∞∞2.8950) 0.2943*** (9.4585) 0.3820*** (5.5936) 0.0011 (0.9206) 17.0073*** (3.4914) 1.4708 (0.4703) 2.9591 (0.7966) –∞∞5.2751** (–∞∞2.1074) 4.6425 (1.2500) –∞∞5.5798 (–∞∞1.3367) –∞∞9.6359*** (–∞∞2.8978) 3.4539 (1.2420) 5.5778 (1.5201) Statistics R2 R2ad F 0.241 0.231 23.28 0.243 0.232 21.63 Notes: 1. Dataset consists of 937 quarterly observations for 24 countries over the 1st quarter of 1990 to the 4th quarter of 2005. 2. t-statistics are given in parentheses. *, ** and *** statistically significant at 10%, 5% and 1% level respectively. 3. Institutional indexes – higher value implies to better institutions 4. Exchange rate arrangement dummy takes the value 1 for regimes 2, 7 and 8; the value equals 0 for all other exchange rate regimes. 330 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 331 As an alternative to the specification in Table 4 we also tested for interactions between the institutional variables – including the exchange rate system – and the economic fundamentals. This specification takes the following general form: ( ) emp = a0 + ∑ a j1 + a j 2 Insti F j with Insti: dummy of exchange rate regime or institutional variable i, Fj: economic fundamental variable j. The interpretation of the exchange rate dummy is same as in the regressions reported in Table 4. For the other institutional variables we define the overall sample average as the threshold value. If the index of an institutional variable exceeds the mean value the corresponding dummy variable equals one, otherwise zero. The results are shown in Table 5 and are in general quite supporting to the hypothesis that a higher quality of institutions lessens the adverse effect of economic fundamentals. Low corruption, efficient banking regulatory and supervisory systems and profound economic liberalization significantly reduce the impact on emp of domestic credit growth and inflation differential. The coefficient on the variable (aj2) has a sign that is opposite to the coefficient aj1 but is smaller – roughly half – in absolute value. The exchange rate dummy has only a significant interaction with government borrowing growth. Extreme exchange rate regimes entirely dampen the impact of increasing government borrowing on emp. Interactions of extreme exchange rate regimes with other economic fundamentals are insignificant. It is further shown that better legal environment significantly largely mitigates the effect of the Russian crisis contagion dummy on exchange market pressure. VII. CONCLUSIONS This research focussed on exchange market pressure in 24 Central and East European transition economies between 1990 and 2005. Although an extensive literature exists on explaining the occurrence of foreign 331 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 332 TABLE 5 Interaction of institutions and economic fundamentals on exchange Exchange rate arrangement dummy Regression No. Constant 1 –∞∞4.1944** Average index of corruption 2 3 4 (–∞∞4.1566) (–∞∞2.8864) –∞∞7.6139*** (–∞∞4.1633) Current account –∞∞0.2862 (–∞∞1.0039) –∞∞0.2182 (–∞∞1.4740) –∞∞0.1637 (–∞∞1.0805) –∞∞0.2436 (–∞∞1.6592) –∞∞0.1855 (–∞∞1.2369) Insti 0.0008 (0.0027) –∞∞0.0950 (–∞∞0.4040) –∞∞0.2839 (–∞∞1.2360) –∞∞0.0490 (–∞∞0.1912) –∞∞0.1735 (–∞∞0.7391) Domestic credit growth 0.2717*** (4.1850) 0.4442*** (9.2607) 0.4191*** (10.3684) 0.3616*** (10.4094) 0.3861*** (10.5515) Insti 0.0101 (0.1407) –∞∞0.2284*** (–∞∞3.8623) –∞∞0.2566*** (–∞∞4.4412) –∞∞0.2628*** (–∞∞3.6822) –∞∞0.2529*** (–∞∞4.2290) Inflation differential 0.2300 (1.1079) 0.6714*** (6.5986) 0.6837*** (6.9457) 0.3008*** (4.3233) 0.6455*** (6.7124) Insti 0.1481 (0.6825) –∞∞0.4673*** (–∞∞3.6838) –∞∞0.4328*** (–∞∞3.3425) 0.1583 (0.2698) –∞∞0.3421*** (–∞∞2.6101) Government borrowing 0.2049** (2.0897) 0.0012 (0.6280) 0.0012 (0.6204) 0.0010 (0.8224) 0.0013 (0.6825) –∞∞0.2040** (–∞∞2.0810) –∞∞0.0008 (–∞∞0.3303) –∞∞0.0008 (–∞∞0.3258) –∞∞0.0037 (–∞∞0.0349) –∞∞0.0010 (–∞∞0.4007) 22.6275*** (2.8535) 28.2374*** (4.2076) 27.4833*** (3.5412) –∞∞5.3661*** 5 (–∞∞4.1639) Dummy for Russian crisis contagion –∞∞7.4973*** Index of enterprise reform (–∞∞2.3101) Insti –∞∞7.5206*** Index of Index of banking non-banking sector reform sector reform 28.3382*** (4.3391) 30.0754*** (4.4552) Insti –∞∞7.3156 (–∞∞0.7310) –∞∞22.3539** (–∞∞2.3739) –∞∞16.9007* (–∞∞1.7304) –∞∞23.4573** (–∞∞2.4164) –∞∞24.0213** (–∞∞2.5348) GDP per capita –∞∞4.4352*** (–∞∞2.6802) –∞∞1.1575 (–∞∞0.6752) –∞∞1.0239 (–∞∞0.5973) –∞∞1.4107 (–∞∞0.7593) –∞∞0.4689 (–∞∞0.2649) 0.277 0.270 31.1 0.281 0.272 31.1 0.246 0.236 26.0 0.273 0.264 30.0 R2 R2ad F Notes: 0.228 0.218 23.9 1. Dataset consists of 937 quarterly observations for 24 countries over the 1st quarter of 1990 to the 4th quarter of 2005. 2. t-statistics are given in parentheses. *, ** and *** statistically significant at 10%, 5% and 1% level respectively. 332 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 333 exchange crises few studies have tested the role of the institutional setting. Using transition specific indicators such as the indexes of enterprise, banking sector and non-banking sector reforms we investigate whether transition countries with intermediate exchange rate regimes and weaker institutional settings have been more vulnerable to exchange market tensions. Economic liberalisation and institutional reform have considerably increased in the period covered. Nevertheless there still remain significant differences between the three groups of countries considered, viz. the new EU members, the EU candidates and potential candidates and the CIS countries. In the regression analyses we used the Girton and Roper definition of exchange market pressure (emp). The emp-measure in the group of EU members and EU (potential) candidates has been low and not much fluctuating. The CIS countries proved to be the most volatile region with high average emp-measures. The regression results confirm the bi-polar view on exchange market regimes. The incidence of economic fundamentals (current account, domestic credit growth and the inflation differential) for exchange market pressure is as expected. The contribution of sound institutions for reducing exchange market turbulence is clearly demonstrated. Low corruption, efficient banking regulatory and supervisory systems and profound economic liberalization significantly reduce exchange market pressure in the transition countries. And, as expected, the Russian crisis heavily affected the other transition countries. The results of the interaction-specification are in general quite supporting to the hypothesis that a higher quality of institutions lessens the effect of economic fundamentals on exchange market pressure. This is for example the case for transition countries having reformed their financial sector towards international standards. Their institutional improvement is rewarded through a milder effect of domestic credit growth and inflation differential on exchange market pressure. Another example is the attenuating effect of a better legal environment offsetting the Russian crisis contagion. Clearly institutional development in transition economies is the issue at stake when exchange market pressure is studied. 333 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 334 NOTES 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. In developing countries financial instability seem to go hand in hand with flexible exchange rates, though. The reason may be that the extremely low credibility precludes the use of fixed exchange rates. The effect of political institutions like government turnover and democracy is not considered in our study. Lebland and Satyanath (2004) use a logit estimator to determine the factors behind developing countries’ currency crises. They conclude that turnover in government and devided democratic government are robustly associated with crises in addition to economic fundamentals. Shortland (2004) tests the probability to devaluation with a panel logit analysis in 98 least developed countries. She concludes that economic imbalances have little explanatory power in maintaining the exchange rate, while the low turnover of the governer of the central bank and the strength of the government lessen the probability to devalue. Also Serbia and Montenegro is considered to be a potential candidate for the EU but due to the data deficiencies we exclude the country from our analysis. The “+” is expressed numerically as 0.3. In the spirit of the emp-measure one might also include changes in capital controls. The empirical research testing the effectiveness of capital controls often relies on data from the IMF’s Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions. However, this source does not measure the intensity of controls and only reports on capital outflows. In the case of transition countries it is especially hard to connect increased capital controls with increased speculative pressure on their currencies. The eight EU joiners have achieved almost full alignment with the aquis’ requirements on free capital movement. The fall of iron curtain has attracted foreign capital also in the other transition economies. Hence during the last decade there has been almost a constant trend of liberalisation of capital flows. For these various reasons we do not include capital controls in our emp-measure calculations. Dummy takes the value of 1 for the exchange rate arrangements 1, 2, 6, 7 and 8 and the value of 0 for the exchange rate arrangement 3, 4, and 5 (see Table 1). REFERENCES Buiter, Willem H. and Clemens Grafe, 2002, Anchor, Float or Abandon Ship: Exchange Rate Regimes for the Accession Countries, CEPR Discussion Paper No. 3184. Castrén, Olli and Tuomas Takalo, 2000, Capital Market Development, Corporate Governance and the Credibility of Exchange Rate Pegs, ECB Working Paper No. 34. De Grauwe, Paul and Marianna Grimaldi, 2002, Exchange Rate Regimes and Financial Vulnerability, European Investment Bank Papers 7, 2, 33-48. EBRD, 1996, Transition Report 1996, (The European Bank of Reconstruction and Development, London). EBRD, 2005, Transition Report 2005, (The European Bank of Reconstruction and Development, London). Effenberger, Dirk, 2004, Institutional Vulnerability Indicators for Currency Crisis in Central and Eastern European Countries, in Morten Balling, Frank Lierman and Andy Mullineux, eds., Financial Markets in Central and Eastern Europe Stability and Efficiency, Routledge Studies in the European Economy, 312-338. Eichengreen, Barry, Andrew K. Rose, Charles Wyplosz, 1994, Speculative Attacks on Pegged Exchange Rates: an Empirical Exploration with Special Reference to the European Monetary System, NBER Working Paper No. 4898. Eichengreen, Barry, Andrew K. Rose, Charles Wyplosz, 1995, Exchange Market Mayhem: the Antecedents and Aftermath of Speculative Attacks, Economic Policy 21, October, 249–312. 334 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 335 Feldstein, Martin, 2002, Economic and Financial Crises in Emerging Market Economies: Overview of Prevention and Management, NBER Working Paper No. 8837. Fischer, Stanley, 2001, Exchange Rate Regimes: is the Bipolar View Correct?, Journal of Economic Perspectives 15, 2, 3-24. Flood, Robert and Nancy Marion, 1998, Perspectives on the Recent Currency Crisis Literature, NBER Working Paper No. 6380. Girton, Lance and Don Roper, 1977, A Monetary Model of Exchange Market Pressure Applied to the Postwar Canadian Experience, American Economic Review 67, 4, 537548 Ghosh, Swati and Atish Ghosh, 2002, Structural Vulnerability and Currency Crises, IMF Working Paper, No 02/09 Huang, Haizhou and Chenggang Xu, 2000, Financial Institutions, Financial Contagion, and Financial Crises, IMF Working Paper, No 00/92. Heritage Foundation, 2005, Index of Economic Freedom, The Heritage Foundation and Wall Street Journal, http://www.heritage.org/research/features/index/. Kaminsky, Graciela L. and Carmen M. Reinhart, 1996, The Twin Crises: the Causes of Banking and Balance-of-Payments Problems, (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (U.S.)), International Finance Discussion Papers, No 544. Krugman, Paul, 1979, A Model of Balance-of-Payments Crises, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 11, 311-25. Leblang, David and Shanker Satyanath, 2004, Institutions, Expectations and Currency Crises, mimeo, http://www.polisci.wisc.edu/~pevehous/Leblang&SatyanathAug2004.pdf. Masson, Paul, 1999, Monetary and Exchange Rate Policy of Transition Economies of Central and Eastern Europe after the Launch of EMU, IMF Policy Discussion Paper, No 99/5. Mulder, Christian, Roberto Perrelli and Manuel Rocha, 2002, The Role of Corporate, Legal and Macroeconomic Balance Sheet Indicators in Crisis Detection and Prevention, IMF Working Paper, No 02/59 Pitt, Alexander, 2001, Sustaining Fixed Exchange Rates—A Model with Debt and Institutions, IMF Working Paper, No 01/27. Reinhart, Carmen M., and Kenneth Rogoff, 2004, The Modern History of Exchange Rate Arrangements: a Reinterpretation, Quarterly Journal of Economics, (forthcoming), available via the Internet: http://www.puaf.umd.edu/faculty/papers/reinhart/papers.htm Shortland, Anja, 2004, The Role of Politics and Institutions in LCD Currency Devaluations, (University of Leicaster, Department of Economics), Working Paper, No 04/03. Vanneste, Jacques, André Van Poeck and Maret Veiner, 2003, Capital Reversals and the CEEC’s Transition to the EMU, Bank- en Financiewezen. 7, October, 390-401. Vanneste, Jacques, André Van Poeck and Maret Veiner, 2006, Exchange Rate Regimes and Exchange Market Pressure in the New EU Member Countries, Journal of Common Market Studies, (forthcoming). Von Hagen, Jürgen and Jizhong Zhou, 2002, The Choice of Exchange Rate Regimes: an Empirical Analysis for Transition Economies, (Centre for European Integration Studies), ZEI Working Paper, No. B02-03. World Bank, 2004, Worldwide Governance Research Indicators Dataset, available via the Internet: http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/govdata/ . 335 336 2.29 2.46 1.54 2.91 3.05 3.09 3.18 3.45 2.75 1999 2.43 2.43 1.40 2.84 2.98 2.91 3.31 3.15 2.68 2.14 2.29 1.51 2.74 2.90 2.83 3.38 3.05 2.60 EU members 1998 2.20 2.19 1.40 2.69 2.84 2.84 3.18 3.20 2.57 2000 3.58 3.50 3.53 3.40 3.50 3.48 3.56 3.60 3.55 3.30 3.49 3.53 3.56 3.59 3.21 3.72 3.53 4.61 3.60 3.63 3.20 3.67 3.51 4.61 3.49 3.55 3.20 3.64 3.78 4.40 3.35 3.49 EU candidates and potential candidates 2.33 2.44 1.50 3.24 3.50 3.24 3.18 3.74 2.89 1997 3.59 3.55 3.48 4.04 3.28 3.39 2.10 1.89 1.29 2.49 2.53 2.64 2.85 3.01 2.35 2001 3.24 3.89 3.28 3.29 3.35 3.78 3.47 2.29 1.73 1.39 2.49 2.35 2.60 2.76 3.25 2.36 2002 3.28 3.49 3.26 3.06 3.23 3.71 3.34 2.35 1.68 1.44 2.30 2.21 2.83 2.71 2.86 2.30 2003 3.10 3.30 2.98 3.11 3.04 3.66 3.20 2.39 1.76 1.34 2.36 2.19 2.81 2.44 2.75 2.26 2004 2.93 3.16 2.74 2.95 3.00 3.58 3.06 2.31 1.65 2.40 2.31 2.18 2.59 2.43 2.64 2.31 2005 10:36 2.53 3.46 2.88 2.38 2.40 1.51 1996 04-10-2006 Albania Bosnia & Herzegovina Bulgaria Croatia Macedonia Romania Average Czech Republic Estonia Hungary Latvia Lithuania Poland Slovak Republic Slovenia Average 1995 The index of economic freedom, 1995-2005. APPENDIX I Economic liberalization 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck Pagina 336 3.50 3.65 3.75 3.82 4.10 3.55 4.05 3.85 3.70 3.69 4.78 3.45 3.94 3.83 3.89 3.65 3.83 3.50 4.58 3.95 3.88 3.50 4.35 4.20 3.78 2.99 4.00 3.48 3.54 4.30 3.83 3.80 3.50 4.29 4.19 3.85 4.14 2.40 3.49 3.60 4.15 3.75 3.74 3.21 4.33 4.18 3.80 3.90 3.78 3.35 3.75 4.21 3.75 3.83 3.03 3.93 4.10 3.68 2.85 3.80 3.75 3.79 4.11 3.88 3.69 2.78 3.58 4.16 3.48 3.70 3.65 3.30 3.74 4.09 3.84 3.63 2.59 3.50 4.19 3.40 3.55 3.41 3.13 3.54 4.10 3.59 3.50 2.63 3.39 4.04 3.19 3.70 2.70 3.09 3.46 4.15 3.49 3.38 2.58 3.43 4.04 3.29 3.61 3.34 3.11 3.61 4.05 3.16 3.42 04-10-2006 Note: The index takes scores from 1.00 to 5.00 where lower score means freer economy. Source: Heritage Foundation. Armenia Azerbaijan Belarus Georgia Kazakhstan Kyrgyz Republic Moldova Russia Tajikistan Ukraine Average Commonwealth of Independent States 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 10:36 Pagina 337 337 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 338 APPENDIX II Rule of Law and Corruption Index of Rule of Law, 1996-2004 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 EU members and candidates Czech Republic Estonia Hungary Latvia Lithuania Poland Slovak Republic Slovenia Average 0.61 0.33 0.62 0.18 –∞∞0.14 0.44 0.11 0.49 0.33 0.62 0.54 0.78 0.08 0.19 0.57 0.13 0.91 0.48 0.6 0.73 0.85 0.25 0.27 0.64 0.32 0.89 0.57 0.74 0.8 0.9 0.46 0.48 0.65 0.4 1.09 0.69 0.69 0.91 0.85 0.48 0.6 0.51 0.49 0.93 0.68 –∞∞0.92 –∞∞0.88 0.05 0.11 –∞∞0.41 –∞∞0.12 –∞∞0.36 –∞∞0.8 –∞∞0.76 0.05 0.07 –∞∞0.44 –∞∞0.18 –∞∞0.34 –∞∞0.44 –∞∞0.79 –∞∞1.12 –∞∞1.17 –∞∞0.9 –∞∞0.83 –∞∞0.49 –∞∞0.78 –∞∞1.27 –∞∞0.79 –∞∞0.86 –∞∞0.58 –∞∞0.85 –∞∞1.31 –∞∞0.87 –∞∞0.98 –∞∞1.04 –∞∞0.65 –∞∞0.7 –∞∞1.18 –∞∞0.83 –∞∞0.90 EU candidates and potential candidates Albania Bosnia & Herzegovina Bulgaria Croatia Macedonia Romania Average –∞∞0.3 –∞∞0.18 –∞∞0.09 –∞∞0.5 –∞∞0.53 –∞∞0.27 –∞∞0.31 –∞∞0.93 –∞∞1.04 –∞∞0.22 –∞∞0.04 –∞∞0.33 –∞∞0.25 –∞∞0.47 –∞∞0.75 –∞∞0.83 –∞∞0.11 0.15 –∞∞0.3 –∞∞0.21 –∞∞0.34 Commonwealth of Independent States Armenia Azerbaijan Belarus Georgia Kazakhstan Kyrgyz Republic Moldova Russia Tajikistan Ukraine Average Note: –∞∞0.44 –∞∞0.81 –∞∞0.96 –∞∞0.8 –∞∞0.69 –∞∞0.65 –∞∞0.19 –∞∞0.8 –∞∞1.34 –∞∞0.64 –∞∞0.73 –∞∞0.35 –∞∞0.81 –∞∞1.08 –∞∞0.73 –∞∞0.8 –∞∞0.67 –∞∞0.13 –∞∞0.78 –∞∞1.42 –∞∞0.76 –∞∞0.75 –∞∞0.51 –∞∞0.98 –∞∞0.99 –∞∞0.56 –∞∞0.76 –∞∞0.9 –∞∞0.54 –∞∞0.86 –∞∞1.25 –∞∞0.71 –∞∞0.81 The scores lie between -2.5 and 2.5, with higher scores corresponding to better outcomes. Source: World Bank, http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/govdata2002/ index.html. 338 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 339 Index of Corruption, 1996-2004 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 0.55 0.05 0.59 –∞∞0.52 –∞∞0.12 0.38 0.39 0.98 0.29 0.35 0.49 0.69 –∞∞0.1 0.07 0.49 –∞∞0.08 0.83 0.34 0.38 0.76 0.76 0.01 0.27 0.47 0.25 1.08 0.50 0.38 0.66 0.6 0.09 0.25 0.39 0.28 0.89 0.44 0.3 0.82 0.65 0.23 0.36 0.16 0.39 0.97 0.49 –∞∞0.92 –∞∞0.35 –∞∞0.5 –∞∞0.33 –∞∞0.3 –∞∞0.38 –∞∞0.46 –∞∞0.63 –∞∞0.5 –∞∞0.15 0.02 –∞∞0.48 –∞∞0.48 –∞∞0.37 –∞∞0.85 –∞∞0.6 –∞∞0.17 0.23 –∞∞0.73 –∞∞0.34 –∞∞0.41 –∞∞0.72 –∞∞0.54 –∞∞0.04 0.08 –∞∞0.52 –∞∞0.25 –∞∞0.33 –∞∞0.71 –∞∞1.01 –∞∞0.6 –∞∞0.64 –∞∞0.86 –∞∞0.69 –∞∞0.51 –∞∞0.69 –∞∞1.12 –∞∞0.89 –∞∞0.77 –∞∞0.76 –∞∞1.13 –∞∞0.07 –∞∞0.73 –∞∞0.87 –∞∞0.86 –∞∞0.87 –∞∞1.05 –∞∞1.15 –∞∞0.98 –∞∞0.85 –∞∞0.72 –∞∞1.07 –∞∞0.78 –∞∞1.03 –∞∞1.05 –∞∞0.84 –∞∞0.89 –∞∞0.9 –∞∞1.07 –∞∞0.96 –∞∞0.93 –∞∞0.53 –∞∞1.04 –∞∞0.91 –∞∞0.91 –∞∞1.1 –∞∞0.92 –∞∞0.86 –∞∞0.72 –∞∞1.11 –∞∞0.89 –∞∞0.90 EU members and candidates Czech Republic Estonia Hungary Latvia Lithuania Poland Slovak Republic Slovenia Average EU candidates and potential candidates Albania Bosnia & Herzegovina Bulgaria Croatia Macedonia Romania Average 0.05 na –∞∞0.62 –∞∞0.45 –∞∞0.93 –∞∞0.17 –∞∞0.42 Commonwealth of Independent States Armenia Azerbaijan Belarus Georgia Kazakhstan Kyrgyz Republic Moldova Russia Tajikistan Ukraine Average –∞∞0.6 –∞∞0.9 –∞∞0.86 –∞∞0.98 –∞∞0.79 –∞∞0.73 –∞∞0.19 –∞∞0.69 –∞∞1.53 –∞∞0.69 –∞∞0.80 Note: The scores lie between -2.5 and 2.5, with higher scores corresponding to better outcomes. Source: World Bank, http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/govdata2002/ index.html. 339 340 3 3 3 2 2 3 3 2 2.63 1 1 1 1 1 2 1.17 Czech Republic Estonia Hungary Latvia Lithuania Poland Slovak Republic Slovenia Average Albania Bosnia & Herzegovina Bulgaria Croatia Macedonia Romania Average 1993 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 2.7 2.96 1996 1998 3 3 3 2.7 2.7 3 2.7 2.7 2.85 3 3 3.3 2.7 2.7 3 2.7 2.7 2.89 EU members 1997 3 3 3.3 2.7 2.7 3 3 2.7 2.93 1999 3.3 3 3.3 2.7 2.7 3 3 2.7 2.96 2000 2 1 2 2 2 2 1.83 2 1 2 2.7 2 2 1.95 2 1 2.3 2.7 2 2 2.00 2 1.7 2.3 2.7 2 2 2.12 2 1.7 2.3 2.7 2 2 2.12 2 1.7 2.3 2.7 2.3 2 2.17 2.3 1.7 2.3 2.7 2.3 2 2.22 3.3 3.3 3.3 2.7 2.7 3.3 3 2.7 3.04 2001 3 1.7 2.3 2.7 2.3 2 2.33 3.3 3.3 3.3 2.7 3 3.3 3.3 3 3.15 2002 2 2 2.7 2.7 2.3 2 2.28 3.3 3.3 3.3 3 3 3.3 3.3 3 3.19 2003 2 2 2.7 3 2.3 2 2.33 3.3 3.3 3.3 3 3 3.3 3.3 3 3.19 2004 2 2 2.7 3 2.3 2.3 2.38 3.3 3.7 3.7 3 3 3.7 3.7 3 3.39 2005 10:36 EU candidates and potential candidates 3 3 3 2 2 3 3 2.7 2.71 1995 04-10-2006 2 1 2 2 2 2 1.83 3 3 3 2 2 3 3 2.7 2.71 1994 Enterprise reform index, 1991-2005 APPENDIX III Corporate Governance 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck Pagina 340 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1.00 1 1 1 1 1 2 2 1.7 1 1 1.27 2 1.7 1.7 2 1 2 2 2 1 2 1.74 2 1.7 1.7 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1.84 2 1.7 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1.77 2 1.7 1 2 2 2 2 2 1.7 2 1.84 2 1.7 1 2 2 2 2 1.7 1.7 2 1.81 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 1.7 2 1.87 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2.3 1.7 2 1.90 2.3 2 1 2 2 2 2 2.3 1.7 2 1.93 2.3 2.3 1 2 2 2 1.7 2.3 1.7 2 1.93 2.3 2.3 1 2 2 2 1.7 2.3 1.7 2 1.93 2.3 2.3 1 2.3 2 2 2 2.3 1.7 2 1.99 04-10-2006 Note: 1 – soft budget constraints (lax credit and subsidy policies weakening financial discipline at the enterprise level), few other reforms to promote corporate governance; 2 – moderately tight credit and subsidy policy but weak enforcement of bankruptcy legislation and little action taken to strengthen competition and corporate governance; 3 – significant and sustained actions to harden budget constraints to promote corporate governance effectively (eg privatisation combined with tight credit and subsidy policies and/or enforcement of bankruptcy legislation); 4 – substantial improvement in corporate governance, for example, an account of an active corporate control market, significant new investment at the enterprise level; 4+ – standards and performance typical to advanced industrial economies, effective corporate control exercised through domestic financial institutions and markets, fostering market-driven restructuring. Source: EBRD Transition Reports. Armenia Azerbaijan Belarus Georgia Kazakhstan Kyrgyz Republic Moldova Russia Tajikistan Ukraine Average Commonwealth of Independent States 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 10:36 Pagina 341 341 342 3 3 3 2 2 3 2.7 3 2.71 1.3 1 2 2 1.3 1 1.43 Czech Republic Estonia Hungary Latvia Lithuania Poland Slovak Republic Slovenia Average Albania Bosnia & Herzegovina Bulgaria Croatia Macedonia Romania Average 1993 3 3 3 3 3 3 2.7 3 2.96 1996 1998 3 3.3 4 3 3 3 2.7 3 3.13 3 3.3 4 2.7 3 3.3 2.7 3 3.13 EU members 1997 3.3 3.7 4 3 3 3.3 2.7 3.3 3.29 1999 3.3 3.7 4 3 3 3.3 3 3.3 3.33 2000 2 1 2 2.7 3 3 2.28 2 1 2 2.7 3 3 2.28 2 1 2.7 2.7 3 2.7 2.35 2 2.3 2.7 2.7 2.7 2.7 2.52 2 2.3 2.7 3 2.7 2.7 2.57 2.3 2.3 3 3.3 2.7 2.7 2.72 2.3 2.3 3 3.3 2.7 2.7 2.72 3.7 3.7 4 3.3 3 3.3 3.3 3.3 3.45 2001 2.3 2.3 3.3 3.7 2.7 2.7 2.83 3.7 3.7 4 3.7 3 3.3 3.3 3.3 3.50 2002 2.3 2.3 3.3 3.7 2.7 2.7 2.83 3.7 3.7 4 3.7 3.3 3.3 3.3 3.3 3.54 2003 2.7 2.7 3.7 4 2.7 3 3.13 3.7 4 4 3.7 3.3 3.3 3.7 3.3 3.63 2004 2.7 2.7 3.7 4 2.7 3 3.13 4 4 4 3.7 3.7 3.7 3.7 3.3 3.76 2005 10:36 EU candidates and potential candidates 3 3 3 3 3 3 2.7 3 2.96 1995 04-10-2006 2 1 2 2.7 2 2 1.95 3 3 3 3 2 3 2.7 3 2.84 1994 Index of banking sector reform, 1991-2005 APPENDIX IV Financial Institutions 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck Pagina 342 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 1 1 1.1 1 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 1 1 1.3 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1.9 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1.8 2.3 2 1 2.3 2.3 2.7 2 2.3 1 2 1.99 2.3 2 1 2.3 2.3 2.7 2.3 2 1 2 1.99 2.3 2 1 2.3 2.3 2.3 2.3 1.7 1 2 1.92 2.3 2 1 2.3 2.3 2 2.3 1.7 1 2 1.89 2.3 2.3 1 2.3 2.7 2 2.3 1.7 1 2 1.96 2.3 2.3 1.7 2.3 2.7 2 2.3 2 1.7 2.3 2.16 2.3 2.3 1.7 2.3 3 2.3 2.3 2 1.7 2.3 2.22 2.3 2.3 1.7 2.7 3 2.3 2.7 2 2 2.3 2.33 2.7 2.3 1.7 2.7 3 2.3 2.7 2.3 2 2.7 2.44 04-10-2006 Note: 1 – little progress beyond establishment of a two-tier system; 2 – significant liberalisation of interest rates and credit allocation, limited use of direct credit and interest rate ceilings; 3 – substantial progress in establishment of bank solvency and a framework for prudential supervision and regulation, full interest rate liberalisation with little preferential access to cheap refinancing, significant lending to private enterprises and significant presence of private banks; 4 – significant movement of banking laws and regulations towards BIS standards, well functioning banking competition and effective prudential supervision, significant term lending to private enterprises, substantial financial deepening; 4+ – standards and performance norms of advanced industrial economies, full convergence of banking laws and regulations with BIS standards, provision of full set of competitive banking services. Source: EBRD Transition Report. Armenia Azerbaijan Belarus Georgia Kazakhstan Kyrgyz Republic Moldova Russia Tajikistan Ukraine Average Commonwealth of Independent States 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 10:36 Pagina 343 343 344 2 1.7 2 1 1.7 2 2 2 1.80 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 Czech Republic Estonia Hungary Latvia Lithuania Poland Slovak Republic Slovenia Average Albania Bosnia & Herzegovina Bulgaria Croatia Macedonia Romania Average 1993 1997 1998 1999 2.7 1.7 3 2 2 3 2.7 2.7 2.48 2.7 2 3.3 2.3 2.3 3.3 2.3 2.7 2.61 2.7 2 3.3 2.3 2.3 3.3 2.3 2.7 2.61 3 3 3.3 2.3 2.7 3.3 2.3 2.7 2.83 EU members and candidates 1996 3 3 3.7 2.3 3 3.7 2.3 2.7 2.96 2000 1 1 2 2 1 2 1.4 1.7 1 2 2 1 2 1.54 1.7 1 2 2.3 1 2 1.6 1.7 1 2 2.3 1.7 2 1.74 1.7 1 2 2.3 1.7 2 1.74 1.7 1 2 2.3 1.7 2 1.74 1.7 1 2 2.3 1.7 2 1.74 3 3 3.7 2.3 3 3.7 2.3 2.7 2.96 2001 1.7 1.7 2.3 2.7 1.7 2 2.02 3 3.3 3.7 3 3 3.7 2.3 2.7 3.09 2002 1.7 1.7 2.3 2.7 1.7 2 2.02 3 3.3 3.7 3 3 3.7 2.7 2.7 3.14 2003 1.7 1.7 2.3 2.7 2 2 2.08 3.3 3.3 3.7 3 3 3.7 2.7 2.7 3.18 2004 1.7 1.7 2.3 2.7 2 2 2.08 3.7 3.3 4 3 3 3.7 2.7 2.7 3.26 2005 10:36 EU candidates and potential candidates 2.7 1.7 3 2 2 3 2.7 2.7 2.48 1995 04-10-2006 1 1 1 2 1 2 1.2 2.7 1.7 2 2 2 2 2.7 2.7 2.23 1994 Index of non-banking sector reform, 1990-2005 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck Pagina 344 1 1 2 1 1 1 1 1.7 1 1.7 1.24 1 1 2 1 1.7 1 2 1.7 1 1.7 1.41 1 1 2 1 1.7 1.7 2 2 1 2 1.54 1 1 2 1 1.7 2 2 3 1 2 1.67 1 1 2 1 1.7 2 2 3 1 2 1.67 2 1.7 2 1 2 2 2 1.7 1 2 1.74 2 1.7 2 1 2 2 2 1.7 1 2 1.74 2 1.7 2 1.7 2.3 2 2 1.7 1 2 1.84 2 1.7 2 1.7 2.3 2 2 1.7 1 2 1.84 2 1.7 2 1.7 2.3 2 2 2.3 1 2 1.90 2 1.7 2 1.7 2.3 2 2 2.7 1 2 1.94 2 1.7 2 1.7 2.3 2 2 2.7 1 2.3 1.97 2 1.7 2 1.7 2.3 2 2 2.7 1 2.3 1.97 04-10-2006 Note: 1 – little progress; 2 – formation of securities exchanges, market-makers and brokers, some trading in government paper and/or securities, rudimentary legal and regulatory framework for the issuance and trading of securities; 3 – substantial issuance of securities by private enterprises, establishment of independent share registries, secure clearance and settlement procedures, and some protection of minority shareholders, emergence of non-bank financial institutions (eg investment funds, private insurance and pension funds, leasing companies) and associated regulatory framework; 4 – securities laws and regulations approaching IOSCO standards, substantial market liquidity and capitalisation, well-functioning non-bank financial institutions and effective regulation; 4+ – standards and performance norms of advanced industrial economies: full convergence of securities laws and regulations with IOSCO standards, fully developed non-bank intermediation. Source: EBRD Transition Report. Armenia Azerbaijan Belarus Georgia Kazakhstan Kyrgyz Republic Moldova Russia Tajikistan Ukraine Average Commonwealth of Independent States 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 10:36 Pagina 345 345 9213-06_TEM_06/3_07_VanPoeck 04-10-2006 10:36 Pagina 346 APPENDIX V Data sources e – Rate of depreciation of domestic currency. Defined as the percentage change of exchange rate vis-à-vis Deutsche mark. Calculated on the basis of IMF International Financial Statistics line ae. r – Proportional change in domestic international reserves. Defined as the change in the level of reserves divided by money base of previous period – IMF International Statistics financing of the balance of payments (line 79dad), for Poland the change in net foreign assets (line 11-line16c) was used; the whole was deflated by inherited money base (IFS line 14). CA – Current account (as % of GDP) – IMF International Financial statistics line 78ALD and line 99b. DC – Domestic credit growth rate – percentage change compared to previous period. Calculations based IMF International Financial statistics line 32 (domestic credit). Real depreciation rate – defined as q = e – p + p*, where p and p* are domestic and German inflation rates respectively. The time series are lagged for 1 period. IMF International Financial statistics line 64 ‘consumer price index’ and line ae ‘bilateral dollar rate’. Inflation differential (with Germany) – IMF International Financial statistics line 64 consumer price index. Growth rate of government borrowing – percentage change compared to previous period. IMF International Financial statistics lines 12a and 22a (claims on central government). D– 346 Exchange rate dummy – dummy variable takes the value of 1 for the exchange rate arrangements 1, 2, 6, 7 and 8 (see Table 1) and the value of 0 for the exchange rate arrangement 3, 4, and 5.