The Potential Effects of Clean Elections Laws on Legislative Behavior: A Sketch of a Research Design Thad Kousser UC San Diego If clean elections laws can fundamentally alter political systems, then evidence of the changes that they bring must be present in the behavior of legislators. When electoral competitiveness rises, this should spur an increase in the responsiveness of elected officials to the demands of their constituents, observable in their voting patterns. In order for the direction of policy to shift, legislators must introduce different types of bills or decide on them differently. If public finance laws affect the role or potency of political parties, this too will alter the behavior of legislators. Yet even though changes in legislative behavior should be among the key effects of the clean elections laws now being implemented in several US states and cities, little research has been done so far in this area.1 Most likely, this is because the reforms are so recent that only now have legislatures established a record of operation in sessions held after elections in which clean money grants played a widespread role. Both the Maine and the Arizona programs did not go into effect until 2000. Another complicating factor is that the impact of campaign finance laws on legislative voting is notoriously difficult to isolate. The link between contributions and roll call votes presents a well-known chicken and egg problem. Campaign finance researchers are interested in isolating the “treatment” of money, in measuring how a grant or contribution causes a member to vote differently than she would have if she had not received it. Yet we cannot simply compare the behavior of those who get the money with those who do not, because the process of getting it is nonrandom. Indeed, there is little research on the legislative effects of any form of campaign finance activity or regulation in the states, according to Ramsden’s (2002) review of the literature. 1 This “endogeneity” is well known in the literature on the influence of interest group contributions, though the challenge to inference that it presents is not always taken seriously. Donors contribute to legislators who are sympathetic to their cause. We observe that legislators receive the money, and then see them voting in line with the interests of the donor. The question is whether they voted with the donor because they got the money, or whether they got the money because their past behavior and statements indicated that they would vote with the donor. Ansolabehere, de Figueiredo, and Snyder (2003) review the Congressional literature on this question, showing that many that claimed to find effects of contributions had not investigated this ambiguity. Using statistical techniques tailored to resolving this dilemma, they find that evidence that contribution influence roll call voting disappears when the endogeneity is taken seriously. Scholars who wish to study the legislative impact of clean money laws face a challenge that presents a variant on the traditional problem. Instead of asking whether or not legislators who get money from a particular interest group vote to further the group’s narrow objectives, we need to investigate whether or not those who accept clean money grants behave according to the broader demands of their constituents. But note that who gets the money, who falls into our treatment group, is still not chosen randomly. In 2002 in Maine, for instance, 41% of legislators took the grants and 59% did not (General Accountability Office, 2003). There could be systematic differences between these legislators. Those who did not take the grants may be those who expected to raise much more money from campaign contributors, possibly because they already had positions on policies that they knew would be attractive to a large group of donors such as labor unions, business organizations, environmentalists, or a resource extraction industry. If they eventually voted with one of these groups, it may be because they took the contributions rather than the public grant. But it is also plausible that their intention to vote in that manner gave them the opportunity to turn down the grant in favor of larger campaign contributions. This means that attempting to gauge the impact of clean elections laws by making the most obvious behavioral comparison – contrasting legislators who took public money with those who accepted private contributions – will be problematic. This inferential obstacle may not loom as large as it does in similar studies of interest group influence, for reasons that I will discuss below, but it is still present. To draw careful conclusions about the effects of clean elections laws on state legislatures, we will need to follow the lessons and techniques of the wider literature on campaign finance. I will begin this essay by exploring some of these techniques in a section that looks at participation in a clean elections program as an independent variable. I will also address two additional complexities that come to mind when thinking about the causal impact of these public grants. The first is that they may exert their effects through two pathways; by changing the behavior of legislators already in office and by attracting new types of public servants. In order to determine how clean election laws change politics rather than merely if they do, it is important to set up a research design which will differentiate between these two potential effects. The second complexity created by the political realities of implementing public finance laws is that independent expenditures may allow interest groups or parties to exert just as much influence on legislators who accept clean elections grants as have on other members. Recognizing and testing for this influence is necessary in order to create a clean test of clean election reforms. The second half of the essay focuses on the effects of these laws, proposing a number of dependent variables. It begins with some of the more obvious measures, such as party support in roll call voting patterns and adherence to the agendas of well-funded interest groups. I also discuss ways of gauging less direct effects, which may or may not be worth gathering data to explore. These including committee voting behavior, changes in committee assignment patterns, competition for leadership slots, patterns in bill authorship, levels of access granted to interest groups, and legislative oversight of the executive branch. I conclude by suggesting one additional path for future research on the legislative impact of clean election laws. I. Clean Elections Laws as a Causal Variable They key causal inference that we are trying to draw is to whether or not the act of accepting clean election funding causes legislators to behave differently than they would have if they relied on private contributions. The most obvious empirical comparison, between the behavior of accepters and non-accepters, may not allow us to make this comparison. As research on the influence of interest groups on Congress has noted, money may cause votes, or expected votes may direct the flow of money (Herndon 1982, Grier and Munger 1986). In my view, we have three options for dealing with this obstacle. The first is to think hard about what makes accepting clean elections grants different from receiving interest group contributions and to question whether or not the acceptance of these grants is actually endogenous to systematic differences between legislators. We may conclude that it is not, or that we can measure all of these differences. After all, since qualifying candidates from across the ideological spectrum can take clean money, the link plaguing traditional studies – between the specific policy positions of lobbyists and the legislators to whom they donate – is severed. There are legislators from all points of the spectrum both accepting and rejecting the grants. Controlling for district preferences and other member characteristics, there may not be any significant differences between accepters and rejecters. If this is the case, we can compare their behaviors, ceteris paribus, and draw a straightforward inference about the impact of grants. Arizona’s multimember lower house districts can make such a comparison especially clear, when paired legislators who represent the same constituents make different decisions about accepting clean elections funds. Yet if some unmeasured characteristic such as “potential to raise large sums in private contributions” distinguishes accepters from rejecters, ignoring this endogeneity will bias our estimates of the effect of clean money. If we agree that this is a problem, a second approach that we can take is to conduct a time series analysis that tracks individual legislators before and after the implementation of clean elections laws. This will hold constant their potential to raise private money, as well as their district preferences and other characteristics. If nothing else changes from before to after the implementation of the laws, this will be our strongest research design. Unfortunately, time brings other changes to legislatures. From one session to another, the legislative agenda can shift, along with levels of party competition, policy demands, and the legislative-executive dynamic. These problems will be present everywhere, but our cases pose particular challenges to conducting clean time series analyses. In the same year that Arizona’s clean elections law first went into effect (2000), the state’s term limit law was also implemented, and a new redistricting commission was created (Mayer, Werner, and Williams, 2004). In both Arizona and Maine, 2002 brought new legislative districts. With the exception of the post-2000 session in Maine and the session that is currently being held, all is else is clearly not held constant in a time series analysis of individual legislators. A third option for addressing endogeneity in the link between money and votes is to follow Chappell (1981) and Ansolabehere, de Figueiredo, and Snyder (2003) by taking an instrumental variables approach. This technique identifies a set of instruments which can predict (in our application) whether or not a legislator will choose to accept clean money grants, but which should have no independent effect on that legislator’s voting behavior. These instruments are then used to predict the legislator’s financing choice, and the predictions are used in a two-stage model to explain a legislator’s voting behavior. Ansolabehere, de Figueiredo, and Snyder (2003) use the political competition that a member faces2 and her power3 within the legislature as instruments for the amount candidates receive in business and labor contributions. They then estimate a two-stage least squares model that ultimately explains variation in the ratings that legislators receive from the US Chamber of Commerce. We could follow a similar strategy. The level of competition that a legislator faces and her power within the body should affect her decision about whether or not to take the grants. Then we could use these predicted probabilities to explain variation in ideal point estimates, interest group ratings, and other roll call measures. Regardless of which of the three strategies we pursue, we will explore whether or not accepting clean money grants changes the behavior of legislators. But we should also pay particular attention to another causal pathway through which clean money laws might work. They may bring a new type of legislator to state capitols, either by making running for office more attractive to those who had been discouraged by the cost of campaigning, or by giving poorly-funded candidates the opportunity to get out their message and win. To test for these effects, we will likely need to compare new legislators elected after the implementation of clean elections laws (and participating in them) with those who represented the same districts in the prior era. This will face the aforementioned obstacles to time series analysis They measure competition by the total campaign spending of the legislator’s opponent, her general election vote share minus 50%, and whether or not she faced a general election opponent. 3 They measure power by recording whether or not a legislator was a party leader, a committee chair, or a member of a fiscal committee. 2 in these states, but, since it examines one of the key claims made by clean elections advocates, seems to be worth pursuing. A final consideration for treating participation in a clean elections program as a causal factor is how to treat candidates whose campaigns are supported by large independent expenditures. In Maine, the prominent role that these interest group-led shadow campaigns have had in competitive districts has been well documented. According to La Raja (2004), 44% of House contests and 60% of Senate races featured independent expenditures in Maine. Even if a candidate forgoes private financing in exchange for a clean elections grant, she may still be influenced by an interest group that makes a considerable independent expenditure on her behalf. We should put such candidates in a category that is separate from the category for those who take clean money grants and receive no outside support. A reasonable dividing line defining a “significant” independent expenditure could be when it totals 25% of the value of the clean money grant. Legislators who accepted public grants but were supported by this much money from an interest group may be just as likely as privately-funded candidates to behave as if they are under the group’s influence. II. Where to Look for Legislative Effects The literature on campaign contributions and Congressional behavior suggests many places to look for the influence of interest groups, though it generally finds little clear evidence that they hold sway. This section proposes a series of hypotheses that we could test in states with clean elections programs. Most are applications of Congressional studies to the states, though a few present new tests that are specific to state legislative dynamics or to the predictions of clean elections advocates. • Legislators who accept clean elections grants will be less likely to vote as if they are influenced by particular interest groups, compared with legislators who take contributions from these groups. Testing this hypothesis could proceed in the manner that is common in many Congressional studies: Regress legislators’ support scores from an interest group that is active in the state upon their party membership, their district’s partisanship, and their fundraising activity. This model could be a simple linear regression, a two-stage model, or a panel analysis with legislator fixed effects, depending on our approach to concerns about endogeneity. If we found that legislators who accepted contributions from a group scored significantly higher than those who did not, holding other factors constant, we would conclude that clean elections grants served as a bulwark against moneyed influence. Since the category of legislators who did not receive money from the group would include both clean money grantees and privately-financed members who did not attract funds for that specific group, we would need to repeat this exercise using scores and contributions from interest groups with varying ideological positions. Once an initial dataset is constructed, though, this will be trivial. Gathering scores from interest groups in prior sessions is possible, but will take some effort. In the past, I have had trouble getting groups in Maine to dig these up, even when I visited them in Augusta, but I located a legislative almanac which printed a variety of scores as of 1997 (Maine People’s Resource Center, 1997). If it has been published consistently since then, this data collection will be trivial. • Legislators who take donations for a particular interest group will be more likely to cast committee votes against bills which that interest group opposes, compared to legislators who accept clean elections grants. While the political science literature has found little evidence that interest groups can turn contributions into support for their bills on the floor, my intuition from my days as a legislative staffer is that money often translated into opposition in committee. The power to kill bills is vital, but evidence of the carnage never shows up in interest group scores based on floor votes. Yet it can be observed if committee votes are public and if a high contributing interest group either registers its opposition to bills with committee staff or publishes a member newsletter advertising its attempts to stop legislation. If so, we could create our own measure of interest group support scores in various committees, and estimate the impact of campaign finance activity on these scores in a way that parallels our analysis of interest group support on the floor. • Legislators who accept clean elections grants will be less likely to follow the party line on roll call votes, compared with legislators who receive substantial support from parties or party leaders. Clean money programs may free members from the influence of their party as well as from interest groups. In order to investigate this, we would need access to a dataset with the full set of contested roll call votes for a session. Using this dataset, we would conduct a number of tests for party effects. First, we could create party support scores for each legislator in the way that Congressional Quarterly compiles them for members of Congress, and analyze them in much the same way that we analyze interest group support scores. Second, we could estimate each legislator’s ideal point using some form of the Nominate procedure (Poole, 2005) and see whether those who accept clean money grants are more likely to stray from their party’s median, controlling for their district’s partisanship. Third, we could identify votes that brought “party rolls” – roll calls in which a majority of one party’s caucus was on the losing side of a vote (Cox and McCubbins, 2005) – and ask if clean money grantees were more likely to bolt from the party and allow it to be rolled. Much of the roll call data necessary to conduct these analyses has already been collected. Gerald Wright’s project at Indiana University has already released roll calls from all states in the 1999-2000 session, and will soon release the 2003-4 session. Nolan McCarty’s project at Princeton is gathering roll calls from all states for the 2001-2 and 2002-3 sessions. • Legislators who accept clean elections grants will be more likely to vote in line with their constituents than other legislators. This hypothesis lies at the heart of the claim the clean elections will make legislatures more representative of voter preferences, but will be difficult to test. One way would be to look at the match between a legislator’s district partisanship and her ideal point estimate. The problem is that because these two measures are not on the same scale, it is impossible to know what translation of partisanship into ideal point denotes a perfect level of representation. An option we have in direct democracy states that report initiative results by legislative district is to attempt to create a common ideal point estimate by looking at how a district votes on issues that also came up on the floor of legislatures. I have advised undergraduate projects that do this in a simple way for California, and I believe that Lillard Richardson and Anthony Knownes have made a more sophisticated attempt in Arizona. With ideal point estimates for both legislators and districts, we would see whether clean money grantees were more faithful representatives. (Of course, it is entirely possible that the opposite might be the case, because listening to and being influenced by contributors could be an efficient way of learning about what your district wants and needs.) • Lobbyists will have greater access to legislators who take private contributions than they will to legislators who accept clean elections grants. Although scholars have found little evidence that contributions buy influence, some have found that money leads to greater access. Langbein (1986) shows that members of Congress spend more time with lobbyists who contributed to their campaigns. To test for this sort of effect, we would have to get legislators to participate in a survey about how they spent their time and whose policy advice they took. I see many challenges in administering this sort of survey. Response rates for state legislator surveys are not very high, and would likely be lower for such a delicate matter. I would also worry about priming effects that push clean money grant recipients to declare their independence from lobbyists if they know this is a survey about clean elections. But if we did conduct it, this sort of survey would be useful for figuring out where clean money legislators turn for advice. Arizona and Maine are term limits states, and it is almost certain that all clean elections states will be term limits states since both reforms are usually made through the initiative process. Where do term limits rookies who have no institutional memory turn for information if clean money grants severs their ties with lobbyists? If they become more reliant on the executive branch for information, this could be an undesirable side effect of clean money laws. • The subject matter addressed in bills authored by legislators who accept clean elections grants will be significantly different than the issues taken on by other legislators. It is possible that public financing changes the legislature’s agenda. Using online bill databases, we could code the subject matter of bills authored by different types of legislators to see whether they are more or less likely to address the fields in which major interest groups are active. • Legislators who accept clean elections grants will be less likely than other legislators to be elected to key floor leadership posts in the majority and minority parties. According to Bowser et al. (2003), leadership battles in post-term limits legislatures are fought primarily with money. Since those who accept clean elections grants do not have any money to spread around to members of their caucus, they may effectively remove themselves from consideration for leadership slots. If this is the case, we should rarely if ever see them capture top slots. • Party leaders will be less likely to assign legislators who accept clean elections grants to powerful committee slots. Here is another way in which legislative leaders may be adapting to clean elections laws and dampening their effects. Since members who accept the grants have little to give the caucus, they may have little chance of obtaining seats on key committees. By gathering the same legislative rosters that we would need to get to examine leadership patterns, we could look at committee assignments. • Legislators who accept clean elections grants will be less likely to engage in oversight of executive agencies. This could be a negative effect of clean money laws. If legislators who accept grants are less responsive to interest groups, they may be less energetic in pursuing the legitimate complaints that these groups have about policy implementation (or the lack thereof). Oversight is difficult to quantify, but we may be able to find records of legislator-initiated audits and legislative requests for information (both of which are available in California). III. Further Avenues of Research A final thought I have is that the Maine and Arizona clean elections laws appear to be quite similar. It may be that every clean election law follows the same mold, but it is also possible that there is significant variation in the provisions (the size of grants relative to the size of the electorate, the number of signatures required to qualify for grants, provisions to counter large opposition spending or independent expenditures). If so, much of this variation may come in city clean elections ordinances. It may be worth discussing how the measures that we devise for studying legislative behavior and other aspects of state politics can be applied to local government. This could give us the ability to discover not only whether or not clean elections laws have their intended effect but also which types of public financing work best. References Ansolabehere, Stephen, John M. de Figueiredo, and James M. Snyder, Jr., 2003. “Why is There So Little Money in U.S. Politics?” Journal of Economic Perspectives Vol. 17, No. 1, pp. 105-130. Bowser, Jennifer Drage, Rich Jones, Karl T. Kurtz, Nancy Rhyme, and Brian Weberg, 2003. “The Impact of Term Limits on Legislative Leadership.” In Rick Farmer, John David Rausch Jr., and John C. Green, editors, The Test of Time: Coping With Legislative Term Limits (Lanham, MD: Lexington Books). Chappell, Henry W. Jr, 1981. “Campaign Contributions and Voting on the Cargo Preference Bill: A Comparison of Simultaneous Models.” Public Choice Vol. 36, pp. 301-12. Cox, Gary W. and Mathew D. McCubbins. 2005. Setting the Agenda: Responsible Party Government in the US House of Representatives. New York: Cambridge University Press. General Accountability Office, 2003. Campaign Finance Reform: Early Experience of Two States That Offer Full Public Funding for Political Candidates. GAO-03-453. Grier, Kevin B. and Michael C. Munger, 1986. “The Impact of Legislator Attributes on Interest-Group Campaign Contributions.” Journal of Labor Research Vol. 7, pp. 349-61. Herndon, James, 1982. “Access, Record, and Competition as Influences on Interest Grop Contributions to Congressional Campaigns.” Journal of Politics Vol. 44, pp. 996-1019. La Raja, Ray, 2004. “Clean Elections: An Evaluation of Public Funding for Maine Legislative Contests.” Manuscript, University of Massachusetts, Amherst. Langbein, Laura I., 1986. “Money and Access: Some Empirical Evidence.” Journal of Politics, Vol. 48, pp. 1052-62. Maine People’s Resource Center, 1997. A Citizen’s Guide to the 118th Maine Legislature. Portland, ME: Maine People’s Resource Center. Mayer, Kenneth R., Timothy Werner, and Amanda Williams, 2004. “Do Public Funding Programs Enhance Electoral Competition?” Paper presented at the State Politics and Policy Conference, Kent State University, April 2004. Poole, Keith T. 2005. Spatial Models of Parliamentary Voting. New York: Cambridge University Press. Ramsden, Graham P., 2002. “State Legislative Campaign Finance Research: A Review Essay.” State Politics and Policy Quarterly Vol. 2, No. 2, pp. 176-198.