This essay is a survey of the socialist system that presided in the Soviet Union during the reign of Joseph Stalin prior to the Second World War (1928 – 1939). To provide context, a brief introduction to socialism in general, its roots, Joseph Stalin, and the state of the Soviet Socialist system at his tenure will be included to enable further understanding of the efforts of Stalin and the particular Socialist System he built. The main topics will be categorized in separate discussions, which will follow the mould of the three fundamental economic questions: What goods to produce? How to produce these goods? How are these goods to be distributed? Another important factor in understanding the Soviet Socialist system is the effect of the Soviet political economy on the socio-psychology of its population. Through this analysis the effectiveness of the Stalinist Socialist System in Russia will become apparent and will be criticized accordingly. With the rise of social and economic inequality came the dream of a perfect society that would return mankind to the state of equality that had been lost. We call this movement utopianism, which can be defined as a literary movement concerning the building of perfect societies, or actual attempts to form such societies. (2002, Busky, Pg. 2) Utopianism can be divided into two halves a socialist half and a non-socialist half. The father of modern socialism is Karl Marx and his most important piece of literary work was The Communist Manifesto. This is the ‘bible’ for all Marxian’s, and puts forward the limitations of capitalism, and materialism, but focuses largely on class struggles throughout history, as well as prediction of the eventual fall of capitalism. Stalin’s Socialist system in particular was a meld of old Bolshevik ideals and Marxian principles. Many of the Marxian principles would later be abandoned in the late 1930’s as many unegalitarian policies were implemented: “Actually as far is the Soviet Union is concerned, socialism in the original Marxian sense has long been dead. Joseph Stalin killed it.” (Daniels, 1991, Pg. 121) In 1924 the Soviet Union was under a New Economic Program [NEP], a policy of Soviet Dictator Vladimir Lenin. Following the death of Lenin in 1924 Stalin rose to power and in 1928 implemented mass industrialization programs, shifting from a heavily agricultural based economy, in the first of three five year plans. Stalin as well reversed the many liberal social policies of Lenin. The central themes and features of the Stalinist model of socialism are often said to have been a reanimated version of the civil war policies, representing a radical “break” with the policies of the NEP, as coercion, terror and the overwhelming application of state power over society and the economic sector replaced the relative calm and pluralism of the NEP. (Sandle, 1999, Pg. 199) The Stalinist system was a watershed in Soviet history implementing changes that would go on to become the very basis of Soviet Socialism: “The particular features of the Stalinist model emerged out of a complex and shifting socio-political atmosphere. The factional struggles within the party saw Stalin adopt a stance that combined rapid industrialization, collectivization, and class war.” (Sandle, 1999, Pg. 226) To answer the three fundamental economic questions it is first necessary to look at the political and economic nature of the Stalinist model. The Soviet Socialist system under Stalin was a dictatorship strongly focused on a central planning authority and the redistributive process. Redistribution economies characterized by a political centre that controls the movement of goods and services, as well as the production and the distribution of these goods. The ideal behind a central planning authority is to instil a 2 logical and methodical framework where economic decisions can be made objectively, thus circumventing any spontaneity and irrationality of markets. However Stalin’s Socialist Russia was planned: “on an ad hoc basis, using commands and instructions sent down from the centre, having the status of law. This administrative system produced its own brand of irrationality.” (Sandle, 1999, Pg. 227) Further Karl Polanyi says: “The redistributive pattern in the economy of the state sphere had many ramifications, as we have seen. In its day-to-day aspect, however, livelihood was embedded in state-free institutions of neighbourhood kinship, and worship, all of which were local.” (Polanyi, 1966, Pg. 60) This is not true in the case of Socialist Russia under Stalin, whose dictatorship was the hub of all institutions, thus deviating from the conventional redistributive pattern described by Polanyi and Rotstein in Reciprocity Mutual Aid and Co-Operation. Stalin “was guided by no higher vision than his personal glory and his vindictiveness toward past rivals and suspected enemies.” (Daniels, 1991, Pg. 224) It was Stalin’s intent to create a stable authoritarian apparatus for which he could author in his own image an industrious national power that could be rivalled by none; not even the industrial might of the western capitalists. Right from its very inception, the Soviet planning process was shaped by the need for speed, and for massive progress in a few key areas. This politicized context brushed aside questions of balance, equilibrium, rational calculations and precise information flows. (Sandle, 1999, Pg. 228) The decision making process addressing the fundamental question of “what will be produced?” was left up to a central planning authority. Socialism under Stalin was based on ambitious technological and industrial progress. Stalin longed to abandon a strongly 3 agriculturally based economy and what he called “Russian Backwardness.” His efforts however did not begin with an: “entirely undeveloped society, but rather from a midpoint at which industrial progress under tsarism had been stopped by world war and revolution.” (Daniels, 1991, Pg. 128) The first of Stalin’s five year plans (1928-32) focused exclusively on the rapid growth of the industrial sector; the second of the five year plans (1932-37) focused intently on the use and adaptation of technological processes; the third of the five year plans (1938-41) was to focus again on massive industrial transformations, however it was interrupted by the Second World War, shifting concern to national defence. The major policies outlined by Stalin were as follows: An economy resting on administrative approaches; A centrally organized, state directed economy; A preference for large-scale projects; Prioritization of heavy industry; Removal of the last residue of workers’ control and imposition of one man management; Orientation to quantity of quality; Emphasis upon haste; Strict labour discipline and subordination of the trade union to the state; Central location of all materials and capital goods; State control of retail trade Centrally fixed prices for all consumer good, and for produce acquired from the rural sector; Quasi-market elements remained, in the collective farm sector and in the labour sphere; (Sandle, 1999, Pg. 233) The planning of the Stalinist model evolved from conflict between the two main central planning agencies: The Gosplan and The Vesenkha. The ideals of the Gosplan were moderate, whereas The Vesenkha’s maximalist views were more consistent with the radical reforms of the times. The Central Committee and the council of People’s Commissars governed the soviet planning process. They would draw up general guidelines and targets to be achieved for the entire economy. The role of the Gosplan 4 was to resolve the differences of the general guidelines and the realities of what the lower levels of the bureaucratic hierarchy reported to be possible. Gosplan would draw up a balance sheet in quantitative terms: a general 5YP and a more specific annual plan. The commissariats for each branch of industry then drew up a plan for each enterprise, broken down into annual and monthly targets. The factory director received a quota to be fulfilled. This was an obligatory directive. Within the political atmosphere of intensified class war and suspicion of moderation, fulfilling the quota became an incantation for factory managers. (Sandle, 1999, Pg 228) The Vesenkha on the other hand functioned as the supreme economic council and vied to wrestle away the power from trade syndicates and industrial trusts which they had accumulated up until 1928. In the late 1930’s industrial functionalism was restored by the soviet central planning elites by stripping trade syndicates of the ability to affect production, and the splitting up of industrial trusts. In what was an attempt to create a new leaner efficient bureaucratic power ended up with the new central power being overwhelmingly bombarded with requests and orders. The centralized power swelled enormously with bureaucratization and all hopes of a systematic planning were lost. This movement of sub-ordination of trade syndicates and industrial trusts produced many time lags which eventually led to the recreation of the virtually the same system of syndicates and trusts. The process of deciding “how the goods will be produced?” was also affected by the central planning authority. In fact the production process would be the very limbs or tentacles of the central planning authority. In the first, of the five year plans, the Stalinist regime embarked on a vast program of industrialization and farm collectivization. Goods were produced as economically and rapidly as possible. 5 To Stalin, quantity was paramount not quality. Stalin implemented ‘full employment’ and instituted labour discipline policies in order to achieve this goal. The Soviet concept of full employment is not based on the traditional wage-price ratio or any notions of market equilibrium or any concept of natural unemployment all part of neo-classical economic models. “The Soviet concept of full employment starts with a citizen’s right and duty to work.” (Lane, 1986, Pg. 69) This entailed all citizens, woman, men, and criminals. Kolkhozy [farm collectivization] and Sovkhozy [state farming] were introduced in 1929 changing the land tenure system, and ending an era of “Russian backwardness” where the peasants freely worked a small piece of land which they themselves owned. “The state declared war on the peasantry.” (Sandle, 1999, Pg. 234) These new collective and state run farms embraced the use of tractors and other forms of technology in order to increase output in accordance to Stalin’s mandate, and teams of people flooded to the countryside in search of work. Resistors of Stalinist doctrine were either killed to be displayed for all to see as the ultimate penalty paid for resistance, or sent to labour camps. “The Kulaks or middle peasants, who resisted the taking of their property when a system of state farms was established in 1929, were deported wholesale to labour camps.” (Busky, 2002, Pg. 186) This policy had two effects. First it displaced ownership of land and peasants wealth to the state. Secondly it packed labour camps with any would be resistors; labour was a fundamental necessity for rapid industrialization. “The main forms of forced labour, however, were the corrective labour colonies.” (Lane, 1986, Pg. 58) The NKVD supplied entire labour forces for the work done in these institutions. Labour specialization was extremely tight under Stalin in fact it was so specialized that many entire states in the USSR would have only one production function. 6 The distribution of goods and wealth under Lenin had been consistent and egalitarian, across the board; even the political elite were subject to the same salary as unskilled workers. However, with Stalin in power new policies differentiating wages for skilled and unskilled labourers came into effect; as well salary caps for the political elite became obsolete. Clearly ‘some men were more equal than others.’ Political elites, managers, and military officials were favoured by many other benefits. The importance of theses benefits is clear: “They represented an attempt on the part of the authorities to ensure the survival of elite-lifestyles in a consumer deficit economy.” (Matthews, 1978, Pg.36) Political elites under Stalin were beneficiaries of the ‘party packet’ system. Party packets delivered monthly were sealed envelopes containing money up too one hundred percent of the receiving elites formal salary. In such a deficit system it was necessary to appease, to particular individuals of merit with accessibility to the goods and the services; which were otherwise scarce. Kremlin and academic rations were devised as well as other restricted forms of distribution allowing prominent figures the ability to receive sufficient supply of goods and or services. In the case of non-elites it was not uncommon for household savings to increase far beyond the desired levels, as there were no consumer outlets where they could spend disposable incomes on improving the quality of life. Prices being fixed by the central power did not allow for any sort of market mechanism to make adjustments; thus soviet paper [rubble] was worthless to those without special privilege. Workers in non-preferential positions essentially received only what was allotted to them. 7 The social effects of Stalin’s economic goals were many as his policy reforms geared toward mass industrialization infringed on many of the social liberties of the workers. Stalinism put an end to the social and cultural liberty that had followed the revolution. Experimental free schools were replaced by a hierarchical, competitive-based educational system. Modern art was denounced, and only “socialist realism” glorifying the worker and state was permitted. In music, Western jazz was deemed decadent. Abortion was again made illegal, and divorce while not banned, was made difficult again. (2002, Busky, Pg. 187) The outlawing of abortion and other family reforms acted as guarantor, insuring a strong working population, which in turn would help facilitate the mass industrialization process. Restrictions on art and music [Socialist realism] would strengthen the ideals put forward by Stalin creating an ideologically mono-centric [Socialist] system for which all would live under. Deviation from Stalinist doctrine was futile. While these policies blatantly infringed on the Soviet workers: “Stalinist construction made the Soviets less important then the organization of the state.” (Busky, 2002) Social status and career positioning was dependant on youth involvement and a personality fit. The three main social organizations Komsomol, the Profsoyuz and the Party attracted dedicated youth who were ready to take charge and get ahead in a highly competitive society. Future members of the elite apparatchik [member of government organization] found themselves networking at an early age in childhood with extensive involvement in youth activism. Upward occupational mobility was dependant on one thing the social skills of the individual. One could not get ahead with out learning their role through exposure to their elders in the field, later on these same contacts and friends would become the key to promotion, children learned the right words “the proper words … yes to all requests. They need not actually do what they have promised to do.” (Klugman, 1989, Pg. 24) 8 With out this polishing which started with youth involvement and networking as early as kindergarten success would not be possible. Later on involvement with the Komsomol [young communist league for students] would spell certain success and recognition often leading to an entry-level position. The Profsoyuz [Russian trade union] “tended to attract army personnel, athletes, and in general a rough and ready group. The path leading to the party however required much more self control, faith in the system at least in the sense that one can not negotiate a quid pro quo in the party.” (Klugman, 1989, Pg. 25) Diligence in youth was not always the only possibility for success. Problematic youth sometimes had a competitive advantage as they developed in depth relationships with the authorities and in particular the KGB and their informers. If a troubled youth showed respect and co-operation for the right individuals they: “would get more leeway about the rules.” (Klugman, 1989, Pg. 25) These troubled individuals would develop a life long network of contacts, and eventually becoming bound to them if behaviour would not improve. It was not uncommon for these individuals to end up in law enforcement, or being recruited directly to the KGB. In conclusion the Stalinist Socialist system presiding in Russia from 1928 - 1939 had many inherent faults based on the systems implementation, and was largely ineffective as a whole. In terms of “what goods will be produced?” it is discovered that the soviet Production and Operations Management system, the political centeredness of the Stalinist Socialist System, and the decision making process were ineffective at meeting the demands of such a vast economy. The Russian System was too bulky, inadaptable, and laden with time lags, (recognition, processing, and implementation) to govern resources 9 of such a large populace efficiently. In regards to “how were these goods produced?” it is apparent that the soviet production technique put far too great an importance on haste and quantity over quality. Collectivization and industrialization under Stalin led to the use of brute force and terrorization of the people in order to keep on schedule, and still ran a deficit economy. The ‘redistribution of goods and wealth’ reveals a class based system un-Marxian in all its endeavours that favoured the elite and left the workers without means to enjoy a reasonable quality of life. Such a system failed to make goods available so that consumers could fully enjoy their disposable incomes, and due to fixed prices the soviet economy was not able to capture any consumer surplus that nonpreferred consumers would have been willing to pay for scarce goods. The social effects of Stalinism are reverberating throughout the world today. Stalin created a country where the people were secondary to the state, creating competitive and experimental social policies and institutions scaring his own people for all of time. Conformity led to one brand of soviet man focused only on necessity, stripped away of other fundamental rights such as protection and sustenance. 10