Government Response to the Independent Review of Radio Spectrum Management Executive Summary 1 The radio spectrum is a key resource for communications in the private and public sectors. Its effective management is essential if we are to make the UK the most dynamic and competitive communications market in the world while at the same time making spectrum available for defence purposes, essential public services and scientific applications. 2 We agree with the underlying analysis of the review that market-based spectrum management tools have an important role to play in making the best possible use of the finite spectrum resource. As described below, we broadly accept the review’s recommendations for extending and developing our policies on auctions, incentive pricing and spectrum trading within a regulatory framework that ensures that sufficient spectrum is available for essential public services, safeguards competition, minimises harmful interference and ensures compliance with international obligations. The review has mapped out a substantial programme of work. The Radiocommunications Agency will pursue this purposefully and progressively. There will be full consultation with spectrum users, manufacturers and other interested parties throughout the process and changes will be phased in to give time to adapt. International Regulatory Framework 3 International harmonisation brings many benefits. However, it can also restrict national administrations’ ability to make spectrum available for new services in response to convergence and other developments. We will work towards ensuring that international harmonisation proceeds in a way that best meets the interests of equipment manufacturers, service providers and consumers while striking the right balance between stability to encourage investment and flexibility to adapt to change. Interference Management 4 We will look carefully at the scope to transfer more responsibility to those users able to do more to resolve interference while ensuring that all users have access to a credible and impartial service. There will be greater openness about assignment information but legitimate concerns about security and confidentiality will be met. Legislative Framework 5 Ofcom will have a separate spectrum management duty. The draft Communications Bill contains provisions to enable the Secretary of State to direct Ofcom in the specifics of spectrum management in order to ensure the wider public interest is taken into account but only if Parliament expressly agrees. Licensing will be made as flexible and technology-neutral as possible and will be complemented by a new system of Recognised Spectrum Access. Market Mechanisms for Managing the Spectrum 6 With limited exceptions, all spectrum users will face incentives to use spectrum more efficiently. Auctions remain our preferred method of assigning new 1 spectrum but are not appropriate in all circumstances. We will apply administrative incentive pricing where spectrum has not been auctioned. Fees will continue to be no higher than justified by spectrum management considerations. We will comprehensively review the current pricing methodology, re-examine licence conditions to remove any unnecessary restrictions and introduce spectrum trading. There will be full consultation throughout. Commercial Spectrum Use 7 The above general principles will be applied in particular to public telecommunications, licence-exempt spectrum, private mobile radio, fixed terrestrial services and satellite systems. There will be full consultation on the details. Defence 8 Our armed forces use spectrum for various purposes, including communication and radar. The Ministry of Defence has already made considerable efforts to release spectrum for non-military use and these efforts will continue. We will take various further steps to ensure that decision-makers have the information they need to use spectrum as efficiently as possible and face effective incentives to do so. These will include an audit of defence spectrum, the continued application of pricing in parallel with non-military users on a comparable basis and the introduction of trading to provide incentives. Nothing will be done that would compromise national security or the armed forces’ operational effectiveness. Broadcasting 9 Broadcasting is a major user of spectrum that is increasingly overlapping and competing with telecommunications services. We agree that broadcasters should pay for spectrum but that the introduction of spectrum pricing for television and its timing should be linked to digital switchover as the main spectrum efficiency gain will come from the move to digital-only broadcasting of television programmes. Incentive pricing for analogue television spectrum will be implemented after full consultation, but not before 2006, in a way that demonstrably provides an additional incentive for the broadcasters to do what they can to achieve the switchover conditions. We also envisage applying incentive pricing to digital television but not before 2010. For sound radio, we recognise that further work needs to be carried out on the scope for spectrum pricing to apply given the constraints that the regulatory framework imposes on broadcasters' use of spectrum. Aeronautical and Maritime 10 Aviation and shipping rely on spectrum for essential safety purposes. In many cases, international agreements limit the scope to improve spectrum efficiency. However, for other applications, administrative incentive pricing would provide incentives to improve efficiency. Nothing will be done to compromise safety; and incentive pricing will be phased in over a period of years after full consultation. Public Safety 11 Effective and efficient communication between public safety services is one of the most important and recognisable benefits society derives from the use of the radio spectrum. We will do nothing to compromise this. However, in some cases, more extensive application of spectrum management tools, such as pricing, will provide 2 incentives for this resource to be used more efficiently, delivering better public safety services while freeing up spectrum for other users. Space Science 12 We will continue to support space science in the UK. Some radio astronomy bands are protected internationally but others could be used commercially and there is scope to apply incentive pricing and leasing. However, we do not intend to reduce the overall resource currently devoted to radio astronomy. 3 1 Introduction 1.1 The independent review of radio spectrum management was commissioned by the Chancellor of the Exchequer and the Secretary of State for Trade and Industry to advise on the principles that should govern spectrum management and what more needs to be done to ensure that commercial and non-commercial users are focused on using spectrum as efficiently as possible. Professor Martin Cave published his report on 6 March 2002. 1.2 The review consulted extensively in producing its report and further comments were invited by 10 May. The report itself, the responses to the review’s consultation and the additional comments received after the report was published are all available electronically through the website of the Radiocommunications Agency www.radio.gov.uk, except where confidentiality was requested. 1.3 The Government would like to express its appreciation to Professor Cave and the review team for the comprehensive nature of its report, which makes a total of 47 wide-ranging recommendations, and for its cogent and rigorous analysis. 1.4 The review underscores the importance of spectrum management to the Government’s goal of making the UK the most dynamic and competitive communications market in the world. The main themes of its conclusions may be summarised as follows. The radio spectrum is a finite resource of considerable importance for national security, public services, the economy and future UK competitiveness. Effective management of this resource is crucial if we are to maximise the economic and social benefits of its use. Rapid and unpredictable change is both increasing the importance of spectrum and making its management more challenging. Centrally planned regulation alone cannot meet this challenge. Market-based mechanisms, such as incentive pricing, auctions and trading, can deliver clear benefits by putting spectrum into the hands of those who can use it best. In particular, they allow continuous dynamic adjustment as markets and technology change. Where, for reasons of public policy or welfare, spectrum is reserved for noncommercial purposes, there should be effective incentives on policy-makers and spectrum managers to use it as efficiently as possible. In the interests of maximising the economic and social value of the spectrum, internationally agreed frequency allocations and national frequency assignments1 should make spectrum available for commercial use subject to a minimum of restrictions on technology and services. 1 Allocation refers to the division of the spectrum into bands for particular services, such as fixed links, mobile communications and broadcasting. Assignment is the authorisation given to an individual users to use a specific frequency or frequencies under specified conditions. 4 1.5 The Government agrees with this analysis, which underpins reforms in spectrum management policy over the last 5 years. Under the Wireless Telegraphy Act 1998, the Radiocommunications Agency has progressively rolled out administrative incentive pricing and auctioned spectrum for Third Generation (3G) mobile telecommunications and broadband fixed wireless access. The Government is committed to introduce spectrum trading and, following changes to European Community law, has included the necessary provisions in the draft Communications Bill. 1.6 The Government welcomes the review’s endorsement of these reforms. As described in this document, it accepts the report’s recommendations for taking them further. Accordingly, the Government will continue purposefully and progressively to pursue the development of market-based spectrum management tools to complement regulation. 1.7 In addition, the Government will pursue opportunities to enhance flexibility in both allocation and assignment. This will involve removing any unnecessary restrictions on the services that may be offered or the technology that may be used. In doing so, it will recognise the benefits harmonisation can bring consumers and industry while ensuring that it does not become a straitjacket for innovation and competition. 1.8 The review recognises that the programme it recommends will take some time to complete. Some of the key recommendations require further technical and economic studies to determine details of how they should be implemented. However, it is essential that the momentum of reform is maintained to create a spectrum management regime for the 21st century to make the UK the most dynamic and competitive communications industry in the world. The Government has already taken steps to implement a number of the review’s recommendations. The Radiocommunications Agency has published consultative documents on spectrum trading and Recognised Spectrum Access, opened exempt bands to public services and commenced a comprehensive audit of defence frequency assignments. Membership of the Public Safety Spectrum Management Group (PSSMG) has been broadened, guidance has been published on a more rational basis for public safety spectrum assignments and a process agreed to transfer management of Home Office spectrum to the PSSMG. In addition, the draft Communications Bill reflects the review’s recommendations in several areas. The following Action Plan covering the next few years details key milestones in further progressing the review’s recommendations. Note that some of the dates are approximate as they depend on progress of the Communications Bill and decisions that will fall to be taken by Ofcom. 1.9 It is envisaged that incentive pricing will be progressively extended to radionavigation, radiolocation and broadcasting in line with detailed proposals presented later in this document. There will be full consultation on detailed implementation with users and others affected throughout the process. 5 Milestones in Implementing Recommendations of the Review 2002 Late 2002 Expressions of interest invited for economic and technical studies on international harmonisation and review of administrative incentive pricing methodology Report on study of civil radar deployment End of initial consultation period on spectrum trading and RSA Consultation on 2003 fees Publication of UK Peacetime Frequency Allocation Table Completion of first phase of audit of defence spectrum assignments Finalise proposals to charge emergency service spectrum users not migrating to Airwave for spectrum Exemption of 5 GHz spectrum for public services Consultation on removing licence restrictions for Broadband Fixed Wireless Access at 28 GHz Consultation on restrictions on PMR 2003 Early 2003 Mid-2003 Late 2003 Commission review of administrative incentive pricing methodology Consultation on removing unnecessary licence conditions as part of implementing the electronics communications Directives for implementation by 25 July Further consultations on trading and RSA implementation Review of constitution and resourcing of the UK Spectrum Strategy Committee Possible further audits of defence spectrum Development of appraisal methods for factoring spectrum efficiency into defence procurement decisions 2004 Completion of review of administrative incentive pricing and consultation on application to 2004 fees round Depending on progress of the Communications Bill and subject to further consultation, commencement of phased introduction of spectrum trading and RSA Completion of studies of licence conditions and international harmonisation Subject to outcome of consultation, commencement of phased implementation of conclusions of incentive pricing review and consequential changes to public sector spectrum charges Subject to further consultation, possible application of incentive pricing to on-board navigation and communications systems 2005 onwards Continuation of implementation of conclusions of incentive pricing review and consequential changes to public sector spectrum charges Continuing phased introduction of spectrum trading and RSA Subject to outcome of further consultation, introduction of incentive pricing for broadcasting Publication of value of NATO spectrum Subject to further consultation, application of incentive pricing to radionavigation and radiolocation equipment 6 1.10 The following sections of this document give the Government’s detailed response to each of the review’s recommendations. 7 2 International Regulatory Framework Recommendation 4.1 The Government should, wherever technically and operationally feasible, facilitate greater flexibility in the use of a given frequency band. This can be achieved by a broader interpretation of the internationally agreed radio communications service definitions, or by adding additional services to a given frequency band through negotiations at ITU and CEPT level. 2.1 The Government agrees with the review’s analysis that increasing convergence of broadcasting, telecommunications and computing makes it desirable to draw international service definitions as flexibly as possible. As digital technology facilitates convergence, rigid demarcations, such as between broadcasting and telecommunications, become less meaningful and relevant. The result is an erosion of boundaries between services such as broadcasting, voice communications and data transmission. The new EC Directives, for example, refer generically to electronic communications. At the same time, point-to-multipoint fixed services are taking on many of the characteristics of mobile communications. 2.2 To reflect this convergence, spectrum allocations should, as far as possible, be based on spectrum management considerations, not content. Otherwise, there is a risk, already identified in work by the Radiocommunications Agency on future scenarios for convergence2, that a new service could be denied access to spectrum because it does not come within a particular service definition even though it could share with existing services without causing interference. 2.3 As recognised in paragraph 4.9 of the report, there is already considerable flexibility within the general international allocative framework. So far, no cases have been identified where service definitions in the ITU’s Radio Regulations or ITU procedures have been a constraint in practice but the Radiocommunications Agency will continue to be alert to the possibility. 2.4 The Government agrees with the review about the importance of technical and operational considerations. The overriding treaty constraint in the International Radio Regulations is to ensure that there is sufficient protection from interference between services operating in different countries. Greater allocative flexibility is likely to result in more complex sharing situations between different services sharing the same spectrum in different countries. This implies a need to develop mutually acceptable technical coordination procedures and sharing criteria. 2.5 A technical study carried out by Aegis Systems and Indepen Consulting for the review3 suggests that there is already considerable national flexibility within the existing international allocative framework. However, national allocations that are outside the ITU framework are on a ‘non-interference – no protection’ basis in 2 Mapping the Future of Convergence and Spectrum Management, May 2000 with a 2001 update, available through the Agency’s website www.radio.gov.uk. 3 Implications of International Regulation and Technical Considerations on Market mechanisms in Spectrum Management, Aegis Systems and Indepen Consulting, November 2001, available through the Agency’s website www.radio.gov.uk. 8 relation to services in other countries, which constrains the use of spectrum near national boundaries. This effect will tend to be greater at lower frequencies. 2.6 There is therefore a trade-off between national flexibility and the intensity with which the spectrum can be used and the benefits that are derived from it. Further studies are necessary to define the technical limits of this flexibility, which will differ from service to service and with frequency, and also of the economic trade-off between the benefits of harmonisation and the advantages that might accrue from greater national flexibility. 2.7 The Radiocommunications Agency is commissioning substantive technical and economic studies to assess how to strike the optimal balance. These are expected to be completed by early 2004. Meanwhile, the Agency plans further discussion at the forthcoming World Radio Conference next year about making the uhf broadcasting allocation more flexible. It will also take a pragmatic approach to applications for spectrum for new services that balances the benefits of mandatory harmonisation and the advantages of the national flexibility allowed within the present international framework (see recommendation 4.2 below) and review its regime for Test and Development licences for testing new technology. In so doing, it will comply in full with all international, including EC, obligations and continue to take a positive and constructive approach to discussions in the ITU, CEPT and EU. Recommendation 4.2 Where proposals are made for harmonisation at the European Community level, the UK should encourage the Commission and Member States to assess carefully the economic costs and benefits of this approach. Proposals should be tested against the European Commission’s technical and single market criteria for harmonisation. 2.8 International harmonisation can deliver substantial benefits. Harmonisation allows international roaming by consumers, facilitates the roll-out of innovative services as operators have greater certainty about spectrum availability and provides scope for economies of scale in equipment manufacture. Manufacturers have argued that, for major commercial services, the guarantee of a harmonised European and preferably global market place for their products is a necessary prerequisite to justify investment on the scale required. 2.9 EC spectrum decisions and directives mandating harmonisation have had some notable successes, for example, in case of GSM. Nonetheless, mandated harmonisation can also impose costs and hold back spectrum efficiency as spectrum that has been allocated internationally to a particular service cannot normally be used for other services and will, in effect, be sterilised if the harmonised application fails to become commercially viable. This has been the case, for example, with ERMES, the European paging system, and also the Terrestrial Flight Telecommunications System (TFTS), for which 10MHz of spectrum was reserved in 1992 by the CEPT. Neither has ever been developed as a commercial service. 2.10 In certain cases, a purely national allocation might deliver greater benefits, although industry has consistently argued that, for major services, an individual 9 national market does not offer efficient economies of scale. Inappropriate harmonisation can hold back European progress on desirable developments. Each case needs to be considered on its merits and the principle of subsidiarity rigorously applied. The Government agrees that an analysis of the costs and benefits should be a key part of the decision-making process. 2.11 The European Commission is generally required to publish an assessment of the regulatory impact of its proposals and the Government will continue to press strongly, as it did during the EU communications review, that proposals for spectrum harmonisation should demonstrate clear economic benefits. It also agrees that EC proposals should be tested against technical and single market criteria. New arrangements for spectrum management within the EU have been established by the Radio Spectrum Decision (676/2002/EC), which was formally adopted in March 2002. Under the Decision, the Commission may submit to a Radio Spectrum Committee of Member States proposals for technical implementing measures for spectrum harmonisation. In addition, the Commission adopted on 26 July 2002 Commission Decision 2002/622/EC establishing a high level Radio Spectrum Policy Group, which will provide strategic advice to the Commission on spectrum management priorities. The UK will seek to use its influence within these new structures to argue strongly that future binding harmonisation measures adopted at the EU level should be based on a thorough analysis of the costs and benefits involved. Recommendation 4.3 Where the UK agrees with a collective European decision to harmonise spectrum to a particular service and/or technology standard, it should seek to ensure that harmonisation constrains the minimum number of parameters necessary to achieve the policy goals of economic and technical efficiency. In the medium term, this implies moving towards harmonisation of broad service categories (e.g. mobile, fixed, etc) within defined bands, rather than specific technology descriptions (such as DECT, UMTS etc). This should provide the future spectrum certainty necessary for large-scale research and development investments, while allowing scope for technology competition and innovation. 2.12 The pace and unpredictability of convergence developments make it desirable to maximise flexibility by keeping restrictions on spectrum use to the minimum necessary. In general, it is now already normal within Europe for harmonisation measures to be broadly defined, permitting the use of a suite of compatible technologies rather than one specific technology standard. The economic and technical studies mentioned in the response to recommendation 4.1 will throw light on the considerations to be taken into account in determining which restrictions are necessary to maximise the overall benefits derived from radio spectrum. Recommendation 4.4 Harmonisation should be time limited and subject to periodic review. Once it has achieved its goal of enabling manufacturers and operators to deliver a costeffective service to the European market, other developing services and technologies should be able to contest for access to the spectrum. If, on the other hand, harmonisation fails to stimulate the development of a commercially viable market, or the market has plateaued without requiring the full anticipated spectrum allocation, then the regulatory constraint on use of the spectrum 10 should be freed. 2.13 The Government agrees with the review that it is important to keep harmonisation under review. The pace of change makes it desirable to review harmonisation measures periodically and the UK has taken the lead in arguing for this in the CEPT. 2.14 It is virtually impossible to predict in advance which applications will succeed in the market place. Where spectrum has been reserved on a harmonised basis for a purpose that has been overtaken by market developments or that has proved a commercial failure, it should speedily be made available for other applications. Otherwise, restrictions on the use of the harmonised spectrum will block re-farming for new technology with resulting loss of consumer benefits and European competitiveness in world markets. The in-flight communications system TFTS and the pan-European paging system ERMES illustrate this risk. 2.15 A process of dynamic review will help maintain and enhance European competitiveness. This process will need to balance manufacturers’ and operators’ desire for a measure of stability and certainty against the loss of consumer benefits if innovation is held back. The Detailed Spectrum Investigation (DSI) by the European Radiocommunications Office provides one mechanism for reviewing harmonised frequency allocations. Since 1993, the DSI process has reviewed the spectrum from 29 MHz to 105 GHz and, in a number of cases, has recommended a specific timetable for the CEPT to decide on the future use of harmonised frequency bands where the relevant service appears not to be materialising. The UK fully supports this aspect of the DSI. 2.16 Where harmonisation measures are subject to periodic review, the Government believes that the timeframes should be clearly and publicly defined from the outset. These should take into account that industry preparedness to invest in new technology could be undermined without some certainty that harmonised spectrum would be available during the period in which they would hope to recoup their costs. Recommendation 4.5 Where harmonisation is proposed, the technology standards developed for specified bands should be open and led by industry bodies. This should support innovation and competition in technology throughout the harmonisation process, and enhance competition in production of equipment. 2.17 The Government agrees that, where harmonisation is proposed, technical standards should be industry-led and also that they should, wherever possible, be open. This is the basis on which ETSI operates, with UK support. However, it should be noted that the development of standards to avoid harmful interference requires input from regulators in order to balance all interests fairly. Recommendation 4.6 Any proposals for harmonisation within Europe of licensing procedures should be subject to a clear demonstration of the benefits this would bring to the single European market. Otherwise, the UK should retain autonomy over the manner in which it assigns spectrum to particular users, which will need to take account of the balance of supply and demand for particular frequencies and the state of competition in the relevant markets. 11 2.18 The Government agrees that the use of the various spectrum management tools available to NRAs needs to be judged according to national conditions and policy priorities. For example, patterns of spectrum demand and congestion can be expected to differ between countries according to the state of the national market for communications services, consumer preferences and other characteristics. There are also likely to be differences in the balance between social and economic considerations and in public policy priorities and objectives. On the principle of subsidiarity, the UK believes that national authorities should have flexibility to select the combination of regulation, incentive pricing, auctions and trading that best suits their national circumstances and requirements. A ‘one size fits all’ policy on the details of spectrum management is unlikely to be optimal for all countries and risks causing inefficient use of spectrum in many. 2.19 Nonetheless, the Government agrees that there needs to be a harmonised framework to ensure that national policies are implemented in accordance with basic principles of fairness, transparency and proportionality and have as their core purpose the optimal use of the spectrum resource. The new suite of Directives on electronic communications strikes the right balance between high-level principles, which are appropriately set at the Community level, and detailed implementation, for example on assignment and licensing, which remain a matter for national authorities. The UK would oppose further harmonisation of assignment methods unless there was clear demonstration that the benefits would outweigh the loss of national flexibility. 12 3 Interference Management Recommendation 5.1 The RA should explore fully the scope for, and means of, transferring more responsibility to operators for interference management, in support of wider moves towards using market mechanisms for spectrum management. 3.1 The Government agrees that a move to more market-based spectrum management may provide scope for licensees to assume greater responsibility for interference management. For example, the introduction of spectrum trading will provide more scope for licensees to resolve interference problems by negotiating mutually acceptable solutions to interference problems. Where mutual resolution is not possible, the move to greater flexibility could increase the demand for Ofcom to arbitrate and there will continue to be a need to maintain a credible and impartial service responsible for monitoring and enforcement. It follows that the Radiocommunications Agency and Ofcom should continue to meet this demand. 3.2 As the report explains, the Radiocommunications Agency currently adopts a variety of approaches to interference management depending on the circumstances of the service in question. In line with the general trend to more market-based and decentralised approaches, the Government is in favour of devolving interference management where practicable and where users are willing to take this on and will continue to explore the scope to do so. In so doing, it will seek to ensure that all spectrum users have confidence in the effectiveness, impartiality and competence of whatever arrangements are in place and that those arrangements meet their needs. For example, where users are able themselves to resolve in-band disputes, the Government would encourage them to do so. However, the Government recognises that smaller users may be unwilling or unable to undertake this role to the same extent. Moreover, dealing with out-of-band interference between different services, interference from unauthorised transmitters and interference from another country through the international procedures of the ITU will continue to require the involvement of the Radiocommunications Agency or Ofcom. 3.3 The details of interference management will be considered further in the course of consulting on the introduction of spectrum trading and in implementing the Government’s response to the recommendations in chapter 7 of the report. Recommendation 5.2 The RA should seek to implement an on-line frequency register covering all the civil radiocommunications bands and the radio systems utilising them. The frequency register should contain a core set of technical and location-based information which would form the basis for operators to carry out the necessary interference co-ordinations associated with any proposed change of use and/or trade within a given band. The RA should also, in conjunction with industry, agree a common understanding of the technical criteria for calculating interference levels. 3.4 The Government agrees it would be desirable to publish more information about frequency assignments, provided this can be done in a way that meets legitimate 13 concerns about national security, law enforcement and commercial confidentiality. The Radiocommunications Agency consulted earlier this year on plans to publish such information. The response to the consultation indicated considerable support while also expressing concerns about security and confidentiality. 3.5 As the review points out, greater openness will be an important pre-condition for spectrum trading and will also help meet the transparency requirement set out in the EC Authorisation Directive and the Radio Spectrum Decision. Accordingly, the Radiocommunications Agency will proceed to consult on detailed plans to publish more assignment information, including on-line, while taking full account of the need for appropriate and effective safeguards. 3.6 The Government also agrees on the importance of consulting with industry on the interference levels that should be specified in licences and will take this forward in the course of the work mentioned in connection with recommendation 7.2 on removing unnecessary restrictions from licences. 14 4 Legislative Framework Recommendation 6.1 Ofcom should operate under a distinct spectrum management duty, which should provide an ongoing requirement on the regulator to maximise the value of benefits derived by UK society from spectrum use. One potential formulation for such a duty would be: ‘to maximise, by ensuring the efficient allocation and use of the spectrum, the overall public benefit derived from using the radio frequency spectrum’. 4.1 The Government notes the recommendation that Ofcom should have a distinct spectrum management duty. The draft Communications Bill includes in the list of Ofcom’s primary duties, which are all of equal status, the duty, “to encourage, in the interests of all persons, the optimal use for wireless telegraphy of the electro-magnetic spectrum”. The Joint Committee on the draft Communications Bill4 recommended some changes to the wording of Ofcom’s duty but not to the principle that there should be a separate duty on spectrum. The precise wording of this duty will be considered further in the Government’s response to the Joint Committee. Recommendation 6.2 With the transfer of spectrum management functions from the RA to Ofcom, the constitution and resourcing of the Cabinet Office UK Spectrum Strategy Committee should be reviewed to ensure that it can continue to balance the competing requirements of civil and military, public and private sector spectrum users. 4.2 The transfer of spectrum management to Ofcom will not change the need for a high-level inter-departmental body to bring together managers of civil, military and public service spectrum with authority to coordinate and agree national and international spectrum policy. The UK Spectrum Strategy Committee currently plays this role and the Government intends that it should continue to do so. However, the Government agrees with the review that, with the prospective transfer of the Radiocommunications Agency’s functions to Ofcom, it would be sensible to review the Committee’s constitution and resourcing and will make arrangements to do so before Ofcom assumes responsibility for spectrum management. Recommendation 6.3 The Government should limit its powers to intervene in the details of spectrum licensing. Ministers should retain powers to intervene with Ofcom over the distribution of radio spectrum, in order to make essentially political judgements about: the allocation of spectrum between different classes of use; and the reservation of spectrum for specified uses (such as defence) or for specified users (such as the BBC to enable it to meet its current universal terrestrial coverage requirement). Ministers should also retain a power to specify other 4 Report published by The Stationery Office Ltd by authority of the House of Lords and House of Commons, 31 July 2002, HL Paper 169-I and HC 876-I, available electronically from http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/jt200102/jtselect/jtcom/169/169.pdf. See paragraphs 25-27 and 175-176 and recommendations 4 and 67 on Ofcom’s duty on spectrum. 15 public policy objectives and criteria which Ofcom should take into account in regulating spectrum access. Such powers should be clearly defined, transparent and limited in scope in order not to compromise Ofcom’s responsibilities for efficient spectrum management. Ministers should refrain from taking powers to direct Ofcom in the specifics of spectrum management tools, such as assignment methods, auction design, administrative incentive pricing, and exemptions from licensing. 4.3 The review rightly recognises the significant public interest concerns surrounding the management of the radio spectrum. The spectrum is a finite resource, and the Government is best placed to be the final judge of whether its overall allocation between different classes of use is in line with its economic and social objectives. Not only is the radio spectrum an indispensable resource necessary for the provision of essential public services, but there is a need to protect wider public policy where decisions about spectrum management made independently from government might affect this. In particular there is a clear need for the Government to retain powers that allow it to make decisions about the use of the radio spectrum that affect national security, public safety or health and international obligations or relations. 4.4 The Government agrees with the review that where Ministers intervene in spectrum management decisions, this intervention should be clearly defined, transparent and limited in scope. The draft Communications Bill, therefore, contains provisions that would empower Ministers to give directions on spectrum management, subject to affirmative confirmation by Parliament. The requirement for express Parliamentary approval would safeguard Ofcom's independence while striking an appropriate balance with Ministers' ability to intervene in the public interest. 4.5 The Joint Committee on the draft Communications Bill too has considered the scope of powers of direction on spectrum. The Committee recognised that there is a wider public interest in the allocation, assignment and management of spectrum that Ofcom may not be best placed to judge. It went on to recommend that the Government should consider amending the draft Bill to require directions to concentrate on the ends to be achieved rather than on details of the means; and that directions should be approved in draft by both Houses instead of retrospectively5. The Government will set out its views on these recommendations in its response to the Committee. Recommendation 6.4 The Government should introduce, in the Communications Bill, a power for Ofcom to regulate spectrum use via a complementary form of spectrum access licensing, which could be applied as an alternative to a traditional apparatus licence for certain frequency bands. This new form of licence should grant the licensee some exclusivity and protection from interference for transmission and/or reception of radio signals within specified frequencies and geographical See footnote 4 above for report reference. Paragraph 179 of the Committee’s report and recommendation 68 relate to powers of direction. 5 16 areas. Spectrum access licences should be capable of being cast in neutral terms with respect to the type and coverage of the service deployed in the band and the technology used. 4.6 The draft Communications Bill includes provisions on Recognised Spectrum Access to complement licensing and with many of the characteristics of the complementary spectrum management tool recommended by the review. In addition, the draft Bill includes minor amendments to enhance ability to develop licences that are technology- and service-neutral and facilitate a more flexible approach to licensing. Defining exclusivity and acceptable levels of interference that may be expected will form an important part of this exercise, as suggested by the review. 4.7 The Radiocommunications Agency has a general policy of minimising the extent to which licences restrict the services to be provided and technologies to be used. Each licence sector needs to be considered on a case-by-case basis to decide how far restrictions should be removed in the interests of achieving optimal use of the spectrum and this issue will be considered further in the context of the work mentioned in the response to recommendation 7.2. 17 5 Market Mechanisms for Managing the Spectrum Recommendation 7.1 All classes of users should face incentives to economise on the spectrum they occupy. For the majority of frequency bands, where demand exceeds supply, this will entail paying a positive price to obtain access to spectrum, provided there are potential alternative users or uses of a block of spectrum (i.e. the opportunity cost is greater than zero). 5.1 The Government strongly agrees with this general principle, which lay behind its reform of spectrum pricing in 1998 and its intention to introduce spectrum trading. The Government has a strong record of applying market-based tools that provide incentives for more efficient use of the finite spectrum resource. 5.2 The Government intends to continue this policy where use of market incentives furthers spectrum efficiency. In so doing, it will continue to maintain and apply the basic principle that, as required by EC and UK law and in line with assurances given during passage of the Wireless Telegraphy Act 1998, licence fees will be set on the basis of spectrum management considerations, not revenue-raising. 5.3 The Government believes that market-based tools should, in general, be applied so that users face the opportunity cost of the spectrum they occupy and that this principle applies equally to public and private sectors. In some cases, incentive pricing may not be appropriate. For example where users effectively have no choice as to the technology they use, they cannot respond to price signals by using different equipment; and where users are not given individual assignments, there is no limit on the number that can be accommodated in the band in question. Radio amateurs and some aeronautical and maritime applications are cases in point. Recommendation 7.2 The RA should aim to minimise the licence conditions necessary for efficient spectrum use. Existing licences should be amended to remove restrictions which are not needed for reasons of international coordination or interference management, and new licences should be issued with the minimum number of restrictions possible. 5.4 The Government agrees that unnecessary licence conditions should be removed. This mirrors a requirement of the new EC Directives on electronic communications services. The Radiocommunications Agency is planning a comprehensive re-examination of licence conditions to amend them to be compliant with the Directives and will publish proposals on this in spring 2003 for implementation by 25 July 2003, the due date under the Directives. It will then consider which, if any, further restrictions could be removed. Meanwhile, the Government is minded, subject to consultation with interested parties, to relax restrictions in existing licences for Broadband Fixed Wireless Access at 28 GHz concerning purpose of use and coverage obligations and to do likewise in relation to the further award of licences in this band. The Radiocommunications Agency is issuing a consultative document with detailed proposals. 18 5.5 In carrying out this programme of work, it will be necessary to bear in mind that licence conditions serve a number of purposes. For example, some are imposed for technical reasons to avoid risk of harmful interference. Others are intended to ensure compliance with international obligations or to promote public policy objectives. However, the Government recognises that overly restrictive conditions can act as a barrier to efficient spectrum use. 5.6 On the technical side, it will be necessary to examine licences carefully to judge which conditions may safely be dispensed with without causing unacceptable risk of harmful interference. This will require additional research to build on the technical study carried out for the review by Aegis. It is also necessary to take account of economic trade-offs. A minimum of regulation may be required in order to define clearly the rights and obligations that licences bestow and so to avoid a lack of certainty that could result in less intensive use of spectrum. Recommendation 7.3 Spectrum trading should be implemented in the UK as soon as possible. The trading regime should be designed to minimise the transactions costs of trading, and it should allow operators to change the use of traded spectrum within international allocations and the national interference management framework. 5.7 The Government agrees with this recommendation, which supports its commitment, reaffirmed in the White Paper A New Future for Communications, to introduce spectrum trading. Trading is an efficient and effective mechanism that will allow spectrum to be transferred to the users who will make most productive use of it and value it the most. Effectively deployed, trading should improve speed and flexibility of access to spectrum and facilitate innovation. 5.8 Following changes to EC law to allow trading to be developed, clauses have been included in the draft Communications Bill to give Ofcom flexible powers to introduce and regulate spectrum trading. The Government is aware that, while there is broad support for spectrum trading, there are also concerns about some aspects of its implementation. These are addressed in a consultative document that the Radiocommunications Agency issued in July 20026. Recommendation 7.4 The general competition regime, relying on an ex post analysis of the impact of spectrum trading in defined markets, should be the primary safeguard against any anti-competitive behaviour. Where spectrum is an input into a market which is subject to sector-specific regulation, then the objectives of this regulatory regime may be furthered by a more interventionist approach towards spectrum trading, such as ex ante 6 Implementing Spectrum Trading, published July 2002 by the Radiocommunications Agency and available electronically at www.radio.gov.uk. 19 approval of specific trades. In all cases, Ofcom will need to monitor and register trades. 5.9 It is expected that, with wider application of market-based spectrum management tools, ex-post competition regulation will play an increasing role in the management and regulation of spectrum use. The Government agrees with this recommendation, which is reflected in the consultative document on trading. More detailed analysis, including an assessment of the appropriate balance between ex-post (after the event) and ex-ante (before the event) regulation, will depend on the outcome of that consultation. Recommendation 7.5 There should be greater legal clarity than at present about the tenure of incumbent licensees. Ofcom should consider, band by band, how best to provide some certainty for licensees to engage in trading, together with some ability for Ofcom to retrieve spectrum where necessary for any future strategic re-planning of frequency bands. Options include converting the terms of licences to a rolling five to ten year period, or to perpetual licences with a compulsory purchase provision for Ofcom. 5.10 The Government agrees with this recommendation. The consultative document on spectrum trading emphasises the importance of certainty and security to the successful establishment of spectrum trading and seeks views on how to achieve this. The Government will decide how to proceed in the light of responses to that consultation. Recommendation 7.6 Trading rights should be extended to extant commercial licences regardless of the method of original assignment (auction, comparative selection, or ‘first come, first served’). These rights should be granted for free. The Government should assess the case for levying a duty on net gains from spectrum trades and/or continuing with spectrum pricing for tradable licences, against its objectives of encouraging efficient use of spectrum and achieving full economic value for consumers, industry and the taxpayer. 5.11 The consultative document discusses how trading might be introduced, including the extension of trading rights to current licences, and also seeks views on the complex issue of how to treat gains from trading. The Government will consider these issues further in the light of the responses. Recommendation 7.7 Auctions should become the default means of assigning spectrum licences between competing users, to achieve an efficient market-driven outcome. 20 5.12 The Government believes auctions are the fairest, most transparent and most efficient way of assigning spectrum to those who value it most and can generate greatest value from it. The Government’s existing policy is to favour auctions when considering mechanisms for assigning spectrum. 5.13 However, the Government also recognises that auctions are not always feasible or appropriate. They are best suited to new national or regional services and the Government has undertaken not to require existing users to undergo an auction to continue to provide their existing services in the same frequency assignment. Nor will broadcasters who have competed for their franchises in a competition under the Broadcasting Acts be expected to bid separately for the spectrum to exploit those franchises. Furthermore, auctions are not generally suitable for auctioning large numbers of low value assignments as transaction costs would be prohibitive. 5.14 The Radiocommunications Agency will continue to consider each case on its merits with a general preference for auctions while exploring the possibility of developing innovative auction processes. Recommendation 7.8 Where licensees are currently granted tailored access to shared spectrum which is managed by the RA, such as in fixed links and certain private mobile radio bands, the RA should move progressively to converting the spectrum to auctionable geographic licence blocks. Competing commercial licensees would then manage access for their own and/or third party use of this spectrum. 5.15 The Government agrees with the analysis underlying this recommendation although it will be necessary to proceed carefully taking views of users into account and the practicalities of having competing spectrum managers. 5.16 The Radiocommunications Agency already contracts out the issue of over 70% of licences and has a general policy in favour of extending such arrangements to other bands and services where they deliver benefits for users. In doing so, it aims to ensure that the contractor delivers a high standard of service and is technically competent, trusted by users to act impartially and does not suffer from any conflict of interest. 5.17 Similar principles would apply to auctioning blocks of spectrum to be administered by third parties. The Government agrees that the concept has attractions and, in order to explore its feasibility and potential, the Radiocommunications Agency intends to conduct a pilot scheme when a suitable opportunity arises, possibly in currently unassigned spectrum in the fixed link bands at 32 GHz and 52 GHz. So far, one-third of each of these new bands is in the process of being released for assignment with the remaining two-thirds being held back to give scope for novel allocation or assignment methods to be tried. 21 Recommendation 7.9 Spectrum pricing should be applied at more realistic levels and more comprehensively across spectrum uses. Where spectrum pricing has already been implemented, and where there is evidence of continuing shortage of spectrum, then incentive prices should be set at the full opportunity cost level, rather than at the current 50 per cent of the levels derived from pricing models. 5.18 The Government agrees that, now the initial rolling out of administrative incentive pricing is advanced, it would be timely to review the effects of incentive pricing and the model and methodology for valuing spectrum and setting fees. 5.19 This will be a substantial study that the Radiocommunications Agency expects to complete early in 2004 . Further details and an invitation to tender for an external study will be published shortly. This study will encompass how incentive pricing can support spectrum management objectives, how spectrum in specified frequency bands should be valued for purposes of incentive pricing and the factors that should be taken into account in setting licence fees for individual users. Before this work is completed, it would be premature to reach firm conclusions on the relationship between full opportunity cost and current fees. 5.20 Meanwhile, for any frequency bands and parts of the country where hot-spots of spectrum congestion are making it difficult to meet demand, incentive pricing fees will be reviewed as part of the 2003 fees round and may be increased if necessary for spectrum management purposes to reflect more accurately the opportunity cost of spectrum use. Equally, if congestion has abated, fees may be reduced. There will continue to be full consultation in due course about any changes to fee levels. 22 6 Commercial Spectrum Use Recommendation 8.1 Public telecoms: Auctions should be used to assign spectrum available for public telecoms use. Where spectrum pricing is currently used, prices should be raised to the full opportunity cost levels. Once spectrum trading is introduced, public telecoms operators should be able to trade spectrum subject to international constraints. 6.1 In line with the response to recommendation 7.7, the Government’s policy is to favour auctions as the preferred method for assigning spectrum for new national or regional public telecommunications services. The Government also agrees that administrative incentive pricing levels for public telecommunications services should be reviewed and will do so in the context of the study mentioned in the response to recommendation 7.9. 6.2 The introduction of spectrum trading for public telecommunications is being addressed in the consultation on the introduction of spectrum trading. Recommendation 8.2 Licence-exempt spectrum use: The current constraint on the use of licenceexempt bands for the provision of public access communications services should be removed as soon as possible. 6.3 The Government supports this recommendation and, as announced on 10 June 2002, restrictions on the use of licence-exempt spectrum at 2.4 GHz have been relaxed to allow the band to be used for public telecommunications services. Parts of the licence-exempt spectrum at 5 GHz will also be liberalised for public services in November 2002. Recommendation 8.3 Private mobile radio: Current restrictions on the use of PMR bands should be removed, and PMR licences should be made tradable. Area licences should be auctioned in a number of different bands. This approach could, if successful, be extended across the majority of PMR spectrum. 6.4 The Government accepts this recommendation in principle. The Radiocommunications Agency plans to carry out a detailed consultation, commencing by the end of this year, that may cover amongst other things the merits of a phased approach to lifting restrictions with evaluation at each stage. This will cover the extent to which current restrictions should be lifted and the economic and technical benefits. Removing the current restriction that limits PMR to business use would be a significant change. 6.5 Introduction of trading of PMR licences will take into account responses to the consultation on introducing spectrum trading. There will be separate consultation on the potential for auctioning area licences and this is expected to seek views on the 23 bands that would be suitable for auctions and the circumstances in which auctions would be appropriate. Full account will be taken of the views and concerns of users. Recommendation 8.4 Fixed terrestrial services: Current restrictions on the use of fixed wireless access bands should be removed so as to allow the deployment of any fixed service. Licences should also be converted to allow spectrum trading. The RA should begin to auction area licences in fixed bands which would allow the licensees to deploy any fixed service, or trade the rights to do so. 6.6 The Government accepts that new licences should not generally include restrictions on use. Existing licences will need to be reviewed on a case-by-case basis, in particular to avoid compromising spectrum auctions that have taken place or are running at the time of implementation. It will also be necessary to take account of EC requirements that apply when licences are varied. Conversion of licences to allow spectrum trading will be considered in the context of the consultation on introducing spectrum trading. As stated in the response to recommendation 7.8, the Radiocommunications Agency is actively considering new approaches to fixed links assignments in the new fixed links bands, which could involve auctioning blocks of spectrum. Recommendation 8.5 Satellite systems: Opportunity cost pricing should be applied to satellite systems' use of spectrum where such use shares with, and constrains, the deployment of UK-based terrestrial services. Spectrum pricing should continue to apply to permanent earth stations but at full opportunity cost levels. Transmissions from user/interactive terminals should also be licensed with an appropriate spectrum charge. Spectrum access licensing could be used to clarify the rights and responsibilities of satellite transmissions into the UK and where appropriate to apply opportunity cost pricing to such spectrum use. 6.7 The Government accepts this recommendation and has included clauses in the draft Communications Bill to provide for a new system of Recognised Spectrum Access (RSA). This would enable opportunity cost pricing to be applied where necessary for spectrum management purposes, for example where use of spectrum by satellites contributes to spectrum congestion. 6.8 RSA is a potentially useful spectrum management tool that would fill a gap in the present spectrum management regime. This could be of particular advantage where satellite and terrestrial services share spectrum and help provide a level playing field where they compete in the market. As recommended by the review, RSA would provide a mechanism for Ofcom to provide spectrum efficiency incentives in certain of the frequency bands used by satellites. 6.9 In reaching this view, the Government has taken full account of the opinions expressed on recommendation 8.5. The Government understands the concerns that have been expressed but believes that these can be met by the way in which RSA is 24 applied and charged for. In particular, it is envisaged that RSA will be introduced selectively; and fees will be subject to the same safeguards that apply in respect of licences to ensure that they are no higher than justified by spectrum management considerations. 6.10 As pointed out by the Joint Committee on the draft Communications Bill, the draft clauses on RSA provide a framework only: the value and operation of RSA will depend on regulations to be made by Ofcom. There will be full consultation before decisions are taken on the services to which RSA should apply, how RSA should be defined, the level of charges and the arrangements to phase them in. The Radiocommunications Agency has issued an initial consultative document on introducing RSA7. Full account will be taken of the views expressed in the responses and there will be further consultation before RSA is introduced for specific services. 6.11 As recommended by the review, the administrative incentive pricing fees currently charged for permanent earth stations in the UK will continue to be phased in, as already announced, pending the wider review mentioned in connection with recommendation 7.9. 7 Introducing Recognised Spectrum Access, published July 2002 by the Radiocommunications Agency and available electronically at www.radio.gov.uk. 25 7 Defence Recommendation 10.1 The RA should publish the (unclassified) UK Peacetime Frequency Allocation Table, identifying which bands are under MOD management. 7.1 The information in the UK Peacetime Frequency Allocation Table is to a large extent already incorporated in the Frequency Order table, which forms part of the UK Spectrum Strategy published by the Radiocommunications Agency and in fact gives far more detailed information about current spectrum use and proposed changes. However, the Table itself is the definitive source document and its publication will help enhance transparency and accountability for the management of the spectrum for which the Ministry of Defence is responsible. It is anticipated that the table will be published at the earliest possible opportunity by the end of the year. Recommendation 10.2 MOD should invest in a comprehensive audit of all frequency assignments, including patterns of usage by time and location, in order to inform its own tactical and strategic management of the military spectrum asset. This data should be periodically updated, and should be disclosed to RA to improve RA’s own visibility and understanding of military spectrum use. MOD should combine this data capture with investment in new frequency management tools, to enable more sophisticated sharing of military frequencies by time and location. 7.2 The Ministry of Defence has a significant spectrum management function, managing nearly 30 % of the spectrum below 60 GHz. It has an obligation to make the best possible use of the spectrum for which it is responsible, both for operational purposes and through making it available for civil users where this can be done without compromising operational effectiveness. 7.3 Efficient use requires full and up to date information on how spectrum is assigned and used. The Ministry of Defence has usage information and management tools to manage its spectrum in accordance with its operational needs and has a strong record of using these to make spectrum available for non-military applications. However, marginal improvements in spectrum efficiency can deliver valuable wider economic benefits. Identifying such opportunities is likely to require more detailed data collection and management. 7.4 A more comprehensive audit of defence spectrum will provide valuable information necessary for the Ministry of Defence to manage its spectrum efficiently into the future. A prioritised plan starting immediately for auditing the current and future use of those parts of Ministry of Defence managed spectrum that are most in demand by civil users has been agreed with the Radiocommunications Agency with the objective of increasing the scope for spectrum sharing, leasing or release for civil use. The initial phase is planned to be completed by the end of the year. The audit will subsequently be extended to other parts of the spectrum where civil demand is lower but which could nonetheless prove worthwhile in terms of efficient spectrum utilisation. 26 7.5 The Ministry of Defence is reviewing the resource it devotes to managing the efficient utilisation of military spectrum, including the development and application of tools. There could be greater scope for some aspects of military spectrum management to be contracted out or carried out on behalf of the Ministry by the Radiocommunications Agency or, in future, Ofcom. Recommendation 10.3 MOD should, without prejudice to security, disclose to industry those bands where spectrum sharing may be feasible as a result of the patterns of military usage. MOD should identify the pre-emption terms and interference management requirements for military systems, to enable commercial operators to judge the viability of sharing such spectrum on a subordinate basis. 7.6 It is already the Government’s practice to identify and publicise defence spectrum available for use by industry through the UK Spectrum Strategy. As described in the UK Spectrum Strategy, the Radiocommunications Agency and the Ministry of Defence have an ongoing dialogue that has done much to identify opportunities for making military spectrum available for civil use. 7.7 Consideration will be given to publicising the availability to civil users of military spectrum by other means, possibly through the UK Plan for Frequency Authorisation that is proposed in the draft Communications Bill. The agreed audit programme will enable this information to be made more comprehensive. 7.8 Where sharing opportunities are identified, it will be necessary to specify the terms of the sharing arrangements, particularly concerning interference management. This is currently done through the Radiocommunications Agency, which acts as the interface between the Ministry of Defence and commercial users. If appropriate, further investment in spectrum management tools might allow the Ministry of Defence to contribute more to this work. Recommendation 10.4 The value of spectrum effectively given over to NATO for management should be more clearly and publicly identified, through disclosure of an annual ‘shadow’ charge which would apply if the bands were MODmanaged. 7.9 The valuation of spectrum internationally reserved for defence purposes will provide greater clarity when making policy decisions about reserving spectrum internationally, and ensure consistency with the anticipated treatment of non-military ‘reserved’ spectrum. The valuation methodology will be consistent with that applied to other areas of civil and military spectrum. The shadow charge level will be made publicly available, possibly in the next Spectrum Strategy. 27 Recommendation 10.5 MOD should bear the full ‘opportunity cost’ of spectrum which is currently subject to incentive pricing (fixed and mobile bands subject to MOD management), with comparable tariffs applying to comparable civil and military uses. MOD should also be subject to a spectrum charge for all of its radar bands, with the tariff unit equal to that applied to civil aeronautical and maritime radar usage. New spectrum charges should be introduced for MOD as soon as practically possible after the preparatory technical studies to determine the standard tariff units. 7.10 The Government agrees with the review’s argument that policy makers and spectrum managers need to be aware of the economic costs of decisions affecting spectrum use. Spectrum charges are consistent with the regime of resource account budgeting, which ensures departments take full account of their assets. Pricing is an effective mechanism for making the value of spectrum more transparent, facilitating clearer understanding of the costs and benefits of decisions about allocating scarce resources – spectral, financial and otherwise. 7.11 The Government’s policy is to charge public sector spectrum users on a comparable basis to private sector users. The Ministry of Defence is currently charged for bands where equivalent civil users are charged. This consistency of treatment between civil and military users will be maintained, the level of charges for defence spectrum being adjusted to reflect the coverage and level of administrative incentive pricing applied to comparable civil bands. Following recommendations elsewhere in the review, this will include applying to defence spectrum, at a comparable level and on the same timetable, any alterations in the level of civil charges to reflect opportunity cost more accurately and also the application of pricing to a wider range of bands. Recommendation 10.6 Decisions on MOD’s departmental budget should made consistent with the maintenance of credible and enduring incentives on MOD from spectrum pricing and leasing, to provide positive financial benefit to MOD from efficient spectrum use over time. 7.12 In determining departmental budgets, a number of considerations are taken into account, including the objectives and targets in Public Service Agreements and, in respect to obligations to pay spectrum charges, the scale and timing of their introduction. The Government agrees that incentives, such as incentive pricing and leasing, which can produce financial benefits, are effective tools for more efficient spectrum use. Recommendation 10.7 The MOD should consider making specific proposals to Treasury for bringing forward budgeted equipment spending which would enable reequipment and thus an earlier opening of identified military spectrum for release to, or sharing with, the civil sector. Where MOD has agreed to vacate spectrum for commercial licensing, RA should enable rapid re- 28 farming through assigning overlay licences which provide for new licensees to compensate MOD for early departure from the bands. 7.13 Efficient spectrum use is a desirable characteristic of military equipment that should be given due weight in the defence procurement process. This is for a number of reasons. Spectrum, like other resources, has a cost attached to it. Military demand for bandwidth is likely to grow over time as a result of the deployment of new technologies. More efficient spectrum use resulting from defence procurement decisions can generate wider economic benefits. 7.14 The cost of spectrum use and the expected wider economic benefits should therefore be taken into account in procurement decisions and balanced against operational considerations in the same way as the use of other resources. The extension of spectrum management mechanisms such as pricing and leasing will provide further incentives for the Ministry of Defence to take such issues into account when planning expenditure. The outcome will be more efficient use of overall resources. 7.15 For those cases where the Ministry of Defence makes equipment procurement decisions within its delegated authority for expenditure, the Ministry will, in consultation with the Treasury and the Radiocommunications Agency, develop in the course of the coming year robust appraisal methods for factoring spectrum efficiency into those procurement decisions. Equipment proposals above the Ministry’s delegated authority, including any acceleration of scheduled re-equipment, will be considered by the Treasury on a case-by-case basis taking into account spectrum efficiency gains. The Treasury will also consider, on a similar basis, proposals from the Radiocommunications Agency for expenditure analogous to spectrum efficiency grants or the use of ‘overlay’ licences to the rationalisation of the Ministry of Defence spectrum where these are considered to be the most effective method of reallocation. Recommendation 10.8 MOD should have the ability to retain income generated from arrangements to lease access to spectrum which remains under active MOD management. Such spectrum should continue to bear the full spectrum charge, to be paid by MOD to RA/Ofcom. 7.16 The Recognised Spectrum Access provisions in the draft Communications Bill will provide a mechanism to introduce leasing. The Government agrees that the ability to retain income generated by leasing spectrum should usefully reinforce the incentives generated by spectrum charging. 7.17 Further work will be required to determine the most effective process for managing the leasing process. In particular the Government is examining whether spectrum leasing by the Ministry of Defence, and the resulting receipts, is eligible to fall under the Wider Markets Initiative. But the Government intends to allow retention of proceeds from leasing on a comparable basis as soon as possible. 29 8 Broadcasting Recommendation 11.1 Market-based spectrum management tools should be applied to the broadcasting sector so that usage of spectrum by all broadcasters is exposed to the full opportunity cost of spectrum use. 8.1 The Government agrees that, as for other sectors, market-based spectrum management tools, such as spectrum leasing and administrative pricing, can and should play a role in the management of spectrum for both television and radio broadcasting. As the pressure on the use of the broadcasting spectrum for more broadcasting and other uses increases and convergence erodes the traditional boundaries between broadcasters and telecommunications operators, the Government believes that market-based spectrum management tools have an increasing role to incentivise more efficient use of the spectrum 8.2 The Government acknowledges that, in return for certain privileges, some broadcasters are subject to public broadcasting and other obligations, relating, for example, to coverage and signal quality, which effectively constrain their ability to economise on spectrum use. The Government also recognises that broadcasting is undergoing a fundamental change from analogue to digital transmission. The introduction of market based spectrum management tools will take account of these constraints and will be consistent with the Government’s general approach to encouraging the move to digital broadcasting. It will also take into account any fees already paid by broadcasters which include an implicit sum for spectrum. 8.3 The Government believes that there is a balance to be struck between ensuring efficient and effective use of spectrum as a scarce and valuable resource and the promotion of plurality, diversity and universal accessibility of broadcasting services. These objectives are not necessarily mutually exclusive. The Government believes that like other spectrum users, broadcasters should be encouraged to be as efficient as possible in their use of spectrum, within the constraints set out above. A measured and reasoned use of incentive pricing and spectrum leasing can help do this, at least in the longer term. 8.4 Before market-based spectrum management tools are applied, the Government will consult fully with broadcasters and other interested parties. Recommendation 11.2 Broadcasters should be given the ability to lease spectrum to other uses and/or users, once they have met their public service broadcasting commitments and other obligations. Broadcasters leasing spectrum would be able to keep the resulting revenues. 8.5 The Government agrees in principle that broadcasters should have the flexibility to lease spectrum to other users and use the spectrum for non-broadcasting purposes (as certain broadcasters currently do). The Government further agrees that to reinforce incentives towards spectrum efficiency, through leasing capacity, 30 broadcasters should be able to keep the proceeds of any spectrum-related commercial activities. 8.6 Broadcasters will, of course, have to comply with the other obligations they face. In particular, public service broadcasters (as such term is defined in the draft Communications Bill) will have to be able to demonstrate to Ofcom (or, in the case of the BBC and S4C, the Secretary of State) that any arrangement would not diminish the scope of their service coverage and that viewers and listeners could access their content, regardless of the communications platform they choose. 8.7 The Government equally recognises that the terms on which broadcasters and their lessees will be permitted to lease spectrum must be flexible enough to accommodate commercial objectives. Further exploration with broadcasters and other interested parties on the appropriate leasing mechanism and the timing of spectrum leasing will therefore be essential, following the outcome of the valuation exercise discussed in our response to Recommendation 11.3 below. The terms of any spectrum leasing arrangements undertaken by the BBC would also need to be agreed between the Government and the BBC and set out in the BBC Charter. Recommendation 11.3 The spectrum used for broadcasting should be valued and the valuations released into the public domain. From the overall valuation, a value for each national analogue channel and digital multiplex should be derived, based upon relevant factors such as geographical coverage and bandwidth used. 8.8 The Government agrees that all of the spectrum used for broadcasting should be valued and that the valuations should be released into the public domain. It believes that spectrum valuation is the first step in determining when and which market-based spectrum management tools should be applied to television and radio broadcasters. It is important for the Government, broadcasters and taxpayers to fully understand the true value of the spectrum used for broadcasting purposes, so that these costs can be factored into public debates about spectrum management and broadcasting policy. 8.9 Determining the value of spectrum in the absence of market data is a difficult exercise, and the Government will need to identify the appropriate proxy for market values in the broadcasting sector. Since spectrum pricing was introduced in 1998 for other spectrum users, the Radiocommunications Agency has valued spectrum on the basis of the cost of the next best alternative cost of (radio or non-radio) technology, alternative service or alternative frequency bands. The appropriate means of valuing broadcasting spectrum will depend on underlying spectrum management objectives, which include ensuring effective use of the available spectrum. Broadcasting policy objectives, such as the effective availability of television and radio services for all, are also relevant. 8.10 Given the complex issues surrounding valuation, the Government will therefore need to undertake a detailed spectrum valuation exercise. As explained in our response to Chapter 7, the Radiocommunications Agency will be undertaking this exercise across all areas of the spectrum. The Department of Culture, Media and 31 Sport and the Radiocommunications Agency together will consider how spectrum in the frequency bands reserved for broadcasting should be valued, how incentive pricing can support spectrum management objectives and the factors that should be taken into account in setting licence fees for individual users. However, previous economic work considering the costs of providing national coverage for television using digital television multiplexes suggests that a full annual charge for one nationwide analogue service (such as BBC1, BBC2 or ITV1) would be of the order of £10-15 million. Channel 4, Channel 5 and S4C all have less than nationwide coverage and the charge would be proportionately lower. 8.11 The Government anticipates the valuation exercise will be completed by early 2004. As part of this process the Government will consult fully with industry and other interested parties. Recommendation 11.4 Spectrum pricing should be applied to all broadcasters. The timing of the introduction of spectrum pricing should take account of extant regulatory agreements between broadcasters and the Government (including commercial broadcasters’ current franchise fees, which encompass access to spectrum). It should also take into account the Government’s commitment to promote and support the take-up of digital TV. 8.12 The Government agrees that spectrum pricing is a tool which should be applied to all broadcasters to promote the most efficient use of the spectrum. This should be done within a framework that allows the Government and Parliament to ensure that wider public policy is taken into account, including in respect to how spectrum is allocated to broadcasting and assigned between broadcasters. 8.13 However, the way in which spectrum pricing is introduced and the timetable for its introduction will depend on a number of factors, including practical constraints - for example, extant regulatory agreements between broadcasters - and policy considerations, including the take-up of digital TV, competition concerns and the legitimate expectations of commercial licensees, and other objectives, including universal availability, of broadcasting policy. Given these factors and the need for public consultation, the Government anticipates that spectrum pricing for broadcasters (as for other sectors) will need to be phased in over time. Where necessary and appropriate, transitional arrangements will also be explored. Television Broadcasting Spectrum 8.14 Spectrum pricing is a way of encouraging efficient use of the radio spectrum. For television broadcasters there may be some scope for efficiency at the margins in analogue frequency channels (eg some limited opportunities to use spectrum for data casting as well as programme broadcasting) and probably greater scope in relation to digital multiplexes. The main spectrum efficiency gain, however, will come from the move to digital-only broadcasting of television programmes. 8.15 The Government has set the criteria that have to be achieved before the analogue signal is fully switched to digital. These are: 32 all viewers who can receive free to air analogue television channels now must be able to receive the same channels free digitally after switchover; consumers must not face unacceptable switching costs when converting to digital services. Prices must be within reach of people on low or fixed incomes, particularly older people; 95% of consumers must have (access to) digital receiving equipment before switchover is completed. 8.16 The Government has said that full switchover could start to happen as early as 2006 and be completed by 2010. It has already introduced some measures to encourage analogue broadcasters to promote the take-up of digital TV by consumers – for example Channel 3 and Channel 5 receive a discount on their Broadcasting Act licence payments for the proportion of viewers watching via digital TV. Broadcasters also have their own incentives, such as the reduction in transmission costs that would be realised when simulcasting in analogue and digital ends. 8.17 The Government believes that spectrum management tools including incentive spectrum pricing should also be applied to spectrum used for broadcasting. The key issue for analogue television broadcasting is the digital switchover programme, which requires actions by a range of stakeholders including Government, broadcasters and manufacturers. The main spectrum efficiency gain will come from this move to digital-only broadcasting of television programmes. Incentive pricing for analogue spectrum should therefore be implemented in a way that demonstrably provides an additional incentive for the broadcasters to do what they can to achieve the switchover conditions. It is essential that the mechanism by which such incentives are introduced is practical and likely to achieve the desired outcome. As a first step, to provide a common understanding for discussions about the application of pricing in the future, the Government intends to proceed with the valuation of spectrum used for broadcasting, as announced in A New Future for Communications (Cm 5010). We will consult on the methodology to be used. Once the valuation has been made, we will publish our conclusions and the reasons for them. 8.18 Once we have the outcomes of the statutory review of digital take-up and of the cost benefit analysis undertaken as part of the Digital Television Action Plan, the Government will formulate proposals as to how and when incentive spectrum pricing should be applied to analogue TV spectrum. There will also be consultation on these proposals before implementation. 8.19 The proposals will take into account in particular: the effect of the proposals on the actions that broadcasters can take to make progress towards early achievement of the conditions for digital switchover; the ability of broadcasters to meet their public service obligations; and the need for the charging proposals to be based on incentives that work in practice and are likely to have a material effect on the broadcasters in enhancing spectrum efficiency. 33 The proposals will set out the date when charging will begin, what is expected of broadcasters, the transition arrangements between the current cost charging regime to one based on economic incentives, and the means by which the path towards the likely full switchover date is reflected in the charge. 8.20 The proposals will take account of the fact that while broadcasters can make a significant contribution to meeting the switchover conditions, the decision to switch off analogue transmissions is ultimately a matter for Government, not broadcasters. The proposals should therefore avoid penalising broadcasters if there is a gap between meeting the switchover conditions and switching off the analogue signal. 8.21 This process will take some time and so the Government has decided that charging for analogue TV spectrum will not start before 2006 at the earliest. The actual date will be part of the consultation, take account of progress made towards meeting the conditions for switchover and be kept under review. A firm picture of the level of charging will only be possible when we have first completed the valuation of the spectrum, and agreed the way in which market tools can best incentivise switchover. The charges can only be implemented after consultation as required by the Wireless Telegraphy Act 1998. 8.22 Today all the analogue television broadcasters make some payment for use of spectrum, but they do so indirectly. Because spectrum fees are applied through the Wireless Telegraphy Act licences, it is ntl and Crown Castle, the transmission network operators, who pay the cost recovery charges to the Radiocommunications Agency. These charges are passed on to the broadcasters through their contracts for transmission. When introduced, the administrative incentive prices will replace the cost recovery charges (currently around £2m per annum) applied to ntl and Crown Castle. In this way, all the broadcasters will face additional incentives to achieve full switchover. There will be no double charging for use of spectrum. The extent to which each broadcaster makes any other payments to Government which reflect directly use of spectrum will also be taken into account in setting the appropriate administrative incentive price. For example, Channel 3 licensees and Channel 5 were awarded their Broadcasting Act licences through a competitive process and those licences, and the payments made for them, implicitly provide for access to spectrum. 8.23 Digital broadcasts of ITV and Channel 4 are carried on a multiplex operated by Digital 3&4 Ltd (D3&4), while digital broadcasts of S4C and Channel 5 are carried on a multiplex operated by S4C Digital Networks Ltd (SDN). The first 12year term of these multiplex licences expires in 2010. The Government is committed to not charging under the Broadcasting Act 1996 until this point. The Government believes this is a strong incentive for the promotion of digital TV. It also considers that the waiving of spectrum charges for the same period, whether for recovery of the costs incurred by the Radiocommunications Agency or in future Ofcom, or administrative incentive pricing, will recognise the benefits of digital TV and kickstart its take up and availability. By 2010 digital terrestrial TV will have been running for 12 years, and the multiplex operators (and through them the broadcasters) should be ready to face incentives to use the spectrum efficiently. We should then be able to apply the appropriate means of charging to encourage the efficient use of the spectrum for digital television. 34 8.24 The BBC was awarded its multiplex under its Charter at around the same time. The Government believes that it is appropriate to introduce spectrum pricing for the BBC multiplex on the same basis as the other multiplexes awarded at the same time from 2010, 12 years after the award of that multiplex. 8.25 As with the analogue television spectrum, we envisage that spectrum pricing for these three digital multiplexes will be introduced only after wide consultation, with charging phased in. 8.26 The licences for three further digital television multiplexes were granted by the ITC to the BBC and Crown Castle on 16 August 2002. As announced on 22 May 2002, any operator awarded a digital television multiplex licence under the Broadcasting Act 1996 between 30 May 2002 and the date of this publication will not be subject to administrative pricing for the use of spectrum to support that multiplex before the date of renewal of that licence in 2014. Without prejudice to any decision on future payments under the Broadcasting Act, the Government believes that the licensees for these three multiplexes should, from 2014, pay for use of spectrum on a similar basis to the operators of the three other multiplexes. 8.27 The charges levied on broadcasters after switchover will balance the value of the spectrum used with the ability of broadcasters to meet their public service obligations and take account of the scope to make more efficient use of the spectrum. 8.28 When introduced, spectrum pricing will be applied to the relevant Wireless Telegraphy Act licensees. Where these entities are not themselves broadcasters, it is proposed that they should be able to determine how they pass the spectrum charges on to the relevant broadcaster, subject to compliance with competition law. 8.29 Valuation of digital spectrum and the methodology for setting incentive pricing fees will form part of the study mentioned in the response to Recommendations 7.9 and 11.3 though given the time period before spectrum pricing may be applied it may be necessary to revisit this data closer to the pricing date. Sound Broadcasting 8.30 The Government believes that users of spectrum for analogue and digital sound services should face economic incentives to use spectrum efficiently and that market-based spectrum management tools are the best way to create these incentives. As for all broadcasters, the Government will value the radio spectrum as part of the spectrum valuation exercise referred to in our response to Recommendation 11.3. 8.31 The Government recognises, however, that the regulatory framework for commercial radio seriously constrains the way in which sound broadcasters may use spectrum. Further work is needed to assess if there is scope for spectrum pricing to apply to sound broadcasters. If there is no scope for the application of spectrum pricing, sound broadcasters will be subject only to such charges as Ofcom is required to recover from licensees to cover its administrative costs and this will be applied to digital broadcasters as well as analogue broadcasters. If, however, spectrum pricing is appropriate, the Government intends that it should be phased in over time. Like other 35 spectrum users, sound broadcasters would be consulted on the details in advance of its introduction. Recommendation 11.5 The Government, its agencies and broadcasting regulators should explore options for using variable spectrum pricing and/or spectrum efficiency grants to contribute to the Government’s aim of promoting and supporting the take-up of digital TV. The Government should also consider using overlay licences as a mechanism for achieving digital switchover. 8.32 The Government acknowledges that achieving the full switchover to digital TV is the principal way that spectrum efficiency can be improved. As explained in our response to Recommendation 11.4, the Government is committed to finding practical ways to implement variable pricing for analogue spectrum to further encourage industry to enable full digital switchover to happen. 8.33 In collaboration with industry and consumer groups, the Government has already developed a detailed Digital Television Action Plan to map the way to meeting the criteria set for digital switchover, and the implementation of variable spectrum pricing is another measure the Government will take to meet its objectives for digital television. However, the fundamental tenet of the Action Plan - that digital switchover should be market-driven - remains in place. 8.34 Spectrum efficiency grants may have a role to play in achieving switchover. The occurrence of any persistent market failures may, for example, justify such grants; however, the Government would need clear evidence that the benefits of such grants would, in fact, encourage digital switchover or would otherwise promote efficient use and management of the broadcasting spectrum. The benefits of such grants would also need to outweigh the costs of any grant scheme. The overarching cost benefit analysis undertaken within the Digital Television Action Plan should provide any evidence of whether or not such grants may be appropriate. The Government is also mindful of its obligations concerning state aid under the EC Treaty and any grant (if awarded) would need to comply fully with those obligations. 8.35 Overlay auctions may also play an important role in maximising spectrum use and efficiency by accelerating digital switchover. Overlay auctions could allow the Government to release analogue spectrum that continues to be used for analogue television purposes to future users earlier than otherwise may be feasible if the Government waited for the spectrum to be cleared of all analogue television users. The expectations of analogue broadcasters and their viewers and listeners would need to be carefully considered before overlay auctions were used. It is premature to consider any means for reassigning the spectrum that will be freed up by switchover. Recommendation 11.6 Limits on the proportion of digital broadcasting multiplex capacity which can be used for non-programme related data services should be relaxed as soon as possible, and ultimately eliminated. Spectrum released in the future which can potentially be employed for broadcasting should not be confined to 36 broadcasting use alone, but should be made available for other uses through a competition auction. 8.36 The Government agrees in principle that the limits on the proportion of digital broadcasting multiplex capacity use for non-broadcasting purposes, currently set at 10 per cent of the spectrum assigned to each television multiplex licensee and 20 per cent for sound radio multiplexes, should be relaxed and ultimately eliminated. The draft Communications Bill provides for a new category of ‘general purpose’ multiplex that would not be subject to regulation under the Broadcasting Act 1996. These licences will give the flexibility to use spectrum allocated to them to provide a mix of programming and non-programming services. Broadcasters will, of course, have to continue to comply with their obligations under the Broadcasting Act, but the Bill provides for those obligations to be kept under review. 8.37 The reduction or ultimate elimination of the restrictions on the use of spectrum for non-programme related services would be predicated on the basis that spectrum used in excess of 10 percent (for television multiplexes) or 20 per cent (for sound multiplexes) of the multiplex capacity would be subject to spectrum pricing as appropriate for non-broadcasting use. The Government believes that application of spectrum pricing on this basis would be necessary to avoid market distortions. Recommendation 11.7 Once Ofcom is established, the Government should devolve detailed spectrum planning to the independent regulator, subject to Ministerial direction where necessary in particular circumstances, e.g. to reserve spectrum for BBC services. In order to ensure that the entire volume of spectrum is used in the most efficient way, Ofcom should be given responsibility to plan all the broadcasting spectrum, including that currently used by the BBC. 8.38 The Government agrees that detailed spectrum planning should be devolved to Ofcom, subject to Ministerial powers of direction to ensure that the mechanisms used to select terrestrial broadcasters may ultimately be decided by the Government and Parliament, in order to meet agreed broadcasting policy objectives. The Government also agrees that Ofcom should have overall responsibility for the planning of all broadcasting spectrum, including that currently used by the BBC. The draft Communications Bill published on 7 May incorporates the legislative changes that will empower Ofcom accordingly. Detailed arrangements for putting this into effect will be discussed with the broadcasters in due course, including their continuing role. Our response on the scope of Ministers’ powers of direction is set out at Recommendation 6.3. 37 9 Aeronautical and Maritime Recommendation 12.1 For spectrum reserved for on-board navigation and communications systems, the opportunity cost to individual users is, in most cases, effectively zero, since use of this spectrum is mandated internationally, and users are required to adopt specific technologies. But where UK-based users face some technology choice for their on-board systems, then the RA, working with the CAA and MCA, should apply differential licence fees to encourage moves to more spectrally efficient equipment, thus easing congestion over time. 9.1 The Government agrees with the review’s analysis. Where spectrum is mandated internationally and users effectively have no scope to economise on their use of spectrum, it is not appropriate to apply incentive pricing. However, where there is scope to adopt more efficient equipment, failure by users of UK-based systems to do so is a hindrance to making better use of the spectrum and pricing can help promote spectrum efficiency. 9.2 In these cases, the Government agrees that differential licence fees should be applied selectively where users face technology choices that can affect spectrum efficiency. This will provide a mechanism through which users can take account of the value of spectrum as an input cost. Differential fees could also deliver benefits in terms of airspace use if they encourage greater technical interoperability. 9.3 The Radiocommunications Agency will work with the CAA and MCA to identify where it would be sensible to apply administrative incentive pricing; and there will be full consultation with users of aeronautical and maritime equipment before differential fees are introduced, both on the level of the fees and the timing of their introduction. This work will be conducted in the context of the overall review of administrative incentive pricing that is mentioned in the response to recommendation 7.9. 9.4 Because of the need to complete this detailed work and in order to allow sufficient time to consult users, it is likely that implementation of this recommendation will take about two years. Recommendation 12.2 In light of the current study for RA of the UK’s civil radar deployment and the technical scope for reducing spectrum consumption, the RA should develop a pricing regime, in conjunction with CAA and MCA, for the spectrum used by UK-based radionavigation and radiolocation equipment. This should be phased in over the next five to seven years, consistent with outstanding economic regulation agreements in the aviation sector between companies and the CAA. 9.5 The study is due to report by the end of 2002. The Radiocommunications Agency will then consider, together with the CAA and MCA, how administrative incentive pricing should be implemented for civil radar and the timescale for its introduction, which may be extended in some cases. There will be full consultation with users and the need to ensure safety will be paramount. 38 10 Public Safety Services Recommendation 13.1 Public safety users should continue to benefit from guaranteed access to radio spectrum, subject to full spectrum pricing applicable to comparable private mobile radio uses. 10.1 The Government believes that provision of guaranteed access to sufficient bandwidth of interference-free spectrum necessary to secure essential emergency services is an important principle of policy. However, it is important to emphasise that this guaranteed access is limited to spectrum that is shown to be essential for emergency service operations. The continued and wider application of spectrum pricing, on a comparable basis to commercial users, will provide an important incentive for policy-makers to use this spectrum efficiently and economically, taking account of the costs of their decisions. 10.2 The Radiocommunications Agency and the Home Office are discussing plans to charge Home Office users for services not migrating to Airwave. It is hoped to finalise these plans this year. Recommendation 13.2 The RA should rationalise disparate assignments and widen the pool of spectrum reserved specifically for the delivery of public safety services, under the management of the Public Safety Spectrum Management Group. Wherever possible, a technology neutral approach should be taken to the systems adopted for use to allow for competition. 10.3 The Government agrees that rationalisation of assignments would be desirable and this is already in hand. The Radiocommunications Agency has agreed with the Home Office plans for amalgamating the Home Office bands with spectrum managed by the Agency and making other blocks available to users not going into Airwave, thus widening the available pool. 10.4 This rationalisation is not expected to result in any overall increase in spectrum in the short term although it is recognised that the need for emergency service spectrum is not static. The Public Safety Spectrum Policy Group, which is the successor to the PSSMG (see response to next recommendation), has published a guidance note detailing the available spectrum. 10.5 The Government agrees in principle that a technology-neutral approach would be preferable. It will be necessary to consider how far this principle is applied in practice, balancing the need for spectrum-efficient solutions with the advantages of open commercial competition. Recommendation 13.3 The remit of the Public Safety Spectrum Management Group should be broadened to encompass an expanded group of approved users, including: commercial and local government organisations with a public safety remit; and specialist users whose spectrum needs are currently met from within Home 39 Office managed bands. Bands currently managed by the Home Office which provide access for users not migrating to Airwave should be placed under the control of PSSMG. 10.6 The Government agrees with this recommendation. The PSSMG has been reconstituted as the Public Safety Spectrum Policy Group (PSSPG) with a broader membership to include a wider range of services and Government departments. A process has been agreed to transfer management of Home Office spectrum to the PSSPG. 40 11 Science Services Recommendation 14.1 UK-based radio astronomy sites should be subject to an administratively set spectrum charge for those bands it uses where the UK has scope, under ITU regulations, to deploy other actively transmitting radio services on a coprimary basis in the band. The charge should be directly related, as elsewhere, to the geographic area and bandwidth sterilised, and should be based on the spectrum pricing which would apply to the active use of the band in that region. Where radio astronomers allow other services to deploy within their defined spectrum access, they should be compensated, for example, by the RA passing on the spectrum fee levied on fixed links which it assigns within the protection zones around observatories. 11.1 The Government wishes to reaffirm its commitment to supporting world-class radio astronomy in the UK. Radio astronomers have little choice which frequencies to observe as these are determined by fundamental properties of matter. This is reflected in the fact that many frequencies used in radio astronomy are protected internationally under ITU Radio Regulations. 11.2 The Joint Committee on the draft Communications Bill states in its report that there is no effective scope for gains in spectrum efficiency or the application of incentives in radio astronomy bands8. While this is true in some bands, it is not the case in others. As stated by the review, there is scope under international rules to allow commercial services to share with radio astronomy in some bands as already happens, for example by reducing constraints placed on other potential users; and the Government believes that radio astronomers, like others, should face incentives to use spectrum efficiently. A combination of pricing and trading in those bands would do this and could also provide a mechanism for radio astronomers to acquire access to frequencies beyond the limits of the designated radio astronomy bands. 11.3 The review helpfully divides the radio astronomy bands into four categories ranging from primary exclusive allocation, which are fully protected under ITU Radio Regulations, through regional and local protection to completely unprotected. Where international obligations preclude alternative use or radio astronomy is unprotected, incentive pricing or leasing would serve little purpose. The Government therefore proposes to focus spectrum pricing on bands in which radio astronomy is protected but international rules allow alternative uses. 11.4 In determining departmental budgets, a number of considerations are taken into account, including the objectives and targets in Public Service Agreements and, in respect to obligations to pay spectrum charges, the scale and timing of their introduction. As elsewhere, the Government’s intention is that spectrum pricing should act as an incentive to efficient spectrum use. It is not the Government’s intention that spectrum pricing should reduce the resource currently devoted to radio astronomy. 8 See footnote 4 above for reference to the report. Paragraph 189 mentions radio astronomy. 41 11.5 The Government agrees with the review that any financial benefit that arises from arrangements that allow greater commercial use of radio astronomy bands should be retained for supporting astronomy or other areas of scientific research. It is recognised, however, that, at least in the short to medium term, radio astronomers will continue to make research using these bands their first priority. 11.6 In introducing spectrum pricing, account will be taken of the long-term nature of radio astronomy research and the need to ensure security of access to spectrum and financial certainty. The Radiocommunications Agency will discuss with PPARC how these requirements might be met. One option would be to grant Recognised Spectrum Access for an extended period of years in return for a single one-off payment. 42 Glossary 3G Third Generation mobile system BBC British Broadcasting Corporation CAA Civil Aviation Authority CEPT European Conference of Postal and Telecommunications Administrations DECT Digital Enhanced Cordless Telecommunications DSI Detailed Spectrum Investigation EC European Commission ERMES European Radio Messaging System ETSI European Telecommunications Standards Institute EU European Union GHz GigaHertz – A frequency of one thousand million Hertz (cycles per second) GSM Global system for mobile communications ITC Independent Television Commission ITU International Telecommunications Union ITV Independent Television MCA Maritime and Coastguard Agency MHz MegaHertz – A frequency of one million Hertz (cycles per second) MOD Ministry of Defence NATO North Atlantic Treaty Organisation NRA National Regulatory Authority OFCOM Office of Communications PMR Private Mobile radio PPARC Particle Physics and Astronomy Research Council PSSMG Public Safety Spectrum Management Group RA Radiocommunications Agency RSA Recognised Spectrum Access TFTS Terrestrial Flight Telecommunications System UMTS Universal Mobile Telecommunications System - 3G mobile standard 43