Environmental networks contra agricultural networks – A comparative analysis of the political decisionmaking processes regarding land reclamation and restoration of wetlands Anders Branth Pedersen National Environmental Research Institute Department of Policy Analysis Grenaavej 12 DK-8410 Roende Denmark Tel: +45 89 20 17 08 E-mail: apd@dmu.dk www.dmu.dk Paper for the XIth World Congress of Rural Sociology, July 25-30 2004, Trondheim, Norway, Globalisation, Risks, and Resistance. Working Group 29: Changing frameworks of agricultural and rural policy. 1 Abstract Over two centuries (1750-1970) a huge number of land reclamation projects were implemented in Denmark. Often supported by state grants, rivers were straigthened and lakes and fjords drained, with the aim of gaining fertile agricultural soil. But, from the mid-1980’s and forward, Denmark experienced a U-turn. In these two decades the state financed several restoration projects as part of Danish environmental and nature policies. Using the British policy network theory as a theoretical framework, an empirical comparative analysis of the decision to regulate the Skjern River in the 1960’s and the decision to restore the river in the 1990’s – northern Europe’s largest nature restoration project – reveals that the networks involved (the institutional framework) have undergone major changes. The once strong policy community consisting of land reclamation interests has disintegrated into a much weaker type of network, whereas the once weak issue network of environmental interests has integrated into a stronger type of network. These network changes are making new rural policy regarding land-use in the wider countryside possible. The network changes can be explained by major changes in the contextual variables: Socioeconomic context, ideological context, scientific context, institutional context, public opinion and presence of other networks. Finally, by comparing the Skjern River decisions with the decision to drain Lake Soeborg and the subsequent scrapping of plans to restore the lake, it is evident that at the micro-level the timing of the policy entrepreneurs is important. 1. Introduction Denmark ranks among the world’s most cultivated countries. Today, 63 pct. of Denmark is registered as cultivated and only 9 pct. as nature1 (Hansen 2003: 36, 313). The comprehensive cultivation is partly due to numerous land reclamation projects implemented in the period 1750-1970. Rivers were straigthened out, and lakes and fjords drained, with the aim of claming fertile farmland. In the name of progress, many natural or semi-natural areas were transformed into waving fields of corn. In the beginning of the 1970’s, however, the Danish land reclamation policy entered a standstill-phase. No new projects were being implemented; on the other hand, no farmland was being ‘returned’ to nature. This phase lasts until the mid-1980’s where a complete policy turnaround is evident. The state here started to finance nature restoration projects, giving reclaimed land back to nature, thereby changing the policy framework. What has led to Denmark experiencing this U-turn in the rural policy regarding land-use in the wider countryside? By focusing on the decisions in the middle of the 20th century to regulate the Skjern River and Lake Soeborg, the 1987 decision to restore Skjern River, and the decisions in the 1990’s not to restore Lake Soeborg, it is possible to analyse the development of Danish reclamation and restoration policy. A characteristic of the policy process is that interest groups have exercised a striking influence on the decisions, making it relevant to analyse the policy process within a policy network framework. 2. Policy network analysis In explaining the historical radical policy change, the British policy network approach is useful since the concept is essentially a comparative concept. The approach addresses the policy consequences of different organisational arrangements and argues that different sectoral policy network types can be linked with differences in sectoral policies. Policy networks influence policy choices (Marsh & Rhodes 1992; Daugbjerg 1998). The metaphor of a network seeks to direct focus onto the pattern of formal and informal contacts between government and interest groups, where the involved actors (politicians, public servants, ministries, municipalities, interest organisations, etc.) exert influence on the policy agenda and decision making processes (Parsons 1995: 185). Following Bensons (1982) oft-cited definition, a policy network is: 2 .....a cluster or complex of organizations connected to each other by resource dependencies and distinguished from other clusters or complexes by breaks in the structure of resource dependencies. (Benson 1982:148) Later, Rhodes (1988) argued, that network types can be differentiated according to degree of integration. Rhodes & Marsh (1992) demonstrated this idea by setting up a continuum based on the degree of integration exhibited by the individual network. Daugbjerg (1998) has described the continuum in a table depicting three dimensions (table 1). TABLE 1 HERE At one end of the continuum the loose issue networks are situated. Access to this type of network is relatively open, the degree of integration and institutionalisation is low, power is unevenly distributed and the members are often in conflict over policy principles. Therefore, this type of sectoral policy network is basically unstable, making the policy output quite unpredictable. At the other end of the continuum, the tight policy community is situated. The policy community concept describes a strong, tight, closed, highly integrated and highly institutionalised network. All actors in this policy community are in possession of resources, though are still dependent on the cooperation and resources of the other actors in the network. There is widespread consensus on policy principles and procedures with which to approach policy problems. Furthermore, opposing interests/actors are excluded from participation. This type of sectoral policy network makes policy stability more likely. By virtue of the nature of the policy community, it is easier for the actors to influence the policy in question, as a powerful coalition can be formed, thereby exercising influence on the decisions in a way as to make them privilege those interests aligned with their own. This is normally not an option for members of an issue network because the actors, here, fundamentally disagree on policy principles (Blom Hansen & Daugbjerg 1999:15-16). Why do networks change? The policy network approach is generally recognised for its descriptive qualities in periods with policy stability (Marsh 1998:185), but the approach’s ability to explain the dynamic elements of network’s origin, change, and outcome has been questioned (e.g. Blom-Hansen 1997; Dowding 2001; Peters 1998:26). Marsh & Rhodes were aware of the problem (1992:260-61) and recommended coupling the policy network concept with micro and macro theory (Daugbjerg & Marsh 1998:67). Marsh & Rhodes (1992:257-59), themselves, identified four (very) broad categories of network environment changes (exogenous changes): Socioeconomic changes, changes in ideology of the government, knowledge changes, change in institutions (e.g. EC institutions). Marsh (1998:187-88) later acknowledged that ‘presence of other networks’ and ‘public opinion’ constitute additional important aspects in the exogenous context. These six exogenous factors can be used in a dynamic analysis of network changes. At the macro-level, changes in the network’s exogenous context can result in network changes by altering the actor’s perception of reality such that it diverges markedly from the appreciative system of the network (Smith 2000:98), or by elevating some resources and rendering others obsolete (ibid). Changes in the context 3 have to be transformed to policy changes by the actors. Actors in a privileged network will fight to prevent any policy changes, while disprivileged actors will use endogenous transformation mechanisms to strengthen the network and win political and institutional control. Grant Jordan (1998) has demonstrated, that Baumgartner & Jones’ (1993) punctuated equilibrium model of policy change can be linked with the policy network approach. Interaction between policy image and policy venue can result in policy change. Policy image can be described as ‘how a policy is understood and discussed’ (ibid: 26). Policy venues are ‘institutions or groups in society [that] have the authority to make decisions concerning the issue’ (ibid:31). Privileged interests will therefore try to keep the existing policy image and policy venue, while disprivileged interests, as an endogenous transformation mechanism, will try attempt to shift them and make them interact to produce a policy change. At the micro-level it will, in the following, be assumed that there is bounded conflict over political and institutional control (Nørgaard 1997:24). The political actors’ behaviour is goal-oriented, though not motivated only by narrow self-interest, but by an ambition for political control. This political control can be used to further a number of other political goals - ideology, prestige, fortune, etc. The political control is bounded, because in most societies there are limits to what policy-makers can ‘get away with’. The process will be characterised by conflict, because there will always be competing interests and ideas (ibid). The analysis which follows will test whether the changes in Danish rural policy regarding land-use in the wider countryside can be explained by disprivileged actors successfully taking advantage of radical changes in the exogenous context, by connecting a new policy image to a new policy venue. Danish rural policy regarding rivers, fjords and lakes in the wider countryside can be separated into three distinct periods through which the policy has undergone radical change. Two networks from different sectors interact: In the agricultural sector, a land reclamation network, originally constituting a policy community, can be observed and in the environmental sector a nature network, who originally constituted an issue network. Through a complex interplay between changing exogenous factors and internal actor dynamics, the networks change over the years; the land reclamation network disintegrates and the nature network integrates, resulting in a radically different policy output. 3. Land reclamation phase The agricultural country, Denmark, has a long tradition of straigthening rivers, and draining lakes and fjords, for the purpose of increasing available farmland. In particular, after the Danish defeat in the second Schleswig War (1864), where Southern Jutland was lost to Prussia and Austria, land reclamation was systematised as a way of winning back lost territory. The establishment of Hedeselskabet (the Danish Heath Society) by a group of influential men in 1866 created an ‘entrepreneur’ committed to land reclamation on heathland areas. Later, when the engineers of Hedeselskabet had cultivated most of the heaths, the company moved on to new tasks in dewatering meadowland, draining lakes, straigthening rivers, etc. (Geckler 1982). The economic crisis of the 1930’s led to the Council of Unemployment requesting Hedeselskabet for measures to promote employment, to which Hedeselskabet responded by suggesting projects to improve waterlogged farmland 4 areas (Geckler 1982:99). In a 1933 political horse-trade, the Liberal Party (Venstre), originally formed to represent farmers’ and rural interests, secured farmers (and Hedeselskabet) a new act on state subsidies to land improvement operations in return for not voting against the Social Democratic led governments social reform (Hansen 2003:23). According to the new act, farmers were entitled to a 50-pct. grant when e.g. dewatering meadows2, thereby causing draining activities to accelerate. In 1940, following the German occupation of Denmark, the Council of Unemployment once again asked Hedeselskabet for measures to promote employment. This time, the result was an act on the reclamation of land (Lov om Landvinding af 1940). According to the act, landowners were entitled to a state grant of two thirds of the costs of establishment, when implementing new land reclamation projects. The purpose of the act was to promote the production of grain and feed, and to promote employment. The two acts started a ‘golden period’ 1940-70 for the ‘land reclamation network’. The network members were: Hedeselskabet. The entrepreneur implementing the majority of the land reclamation projects. The company was a private foundation, financed by the state, with an idealistic and (formally) non-profit purpose of improving heathlands for agriculture, and a factor of power, e.g. due to its very close connections to the political system3 (Geckler 1982:128, 145). The board (of thirteen) consisted of three members appointed by the Minister of Agriculture (the head of department was normally among the appointed), two members appointed by agricultural organisations and two members appointed by the employees of the company. The board selected the remaining members itself – over the years several members of the Danish parliament have been represented among the board members (Pedersen 2004:75). Furthermore, Hedeselskabet has been represented in a row of other organisations, e.g. in the Society for the Conservation of Nature, where the manager of Hedeselskabet was a member of the central board for several years. The landowner representatives. The majority of the landowners were usually in favour of the projects, most of the costs being covered by the state, the farmers reaping the advantages. The agricultural organisations. They were in favour of the projects and had two representatives on the board of Hedeselskabet. Furthermore, local agricultural organisations were often involved in the preparatory phase of reclamation projects. The Ministry of Agriculture. There is, in general, a strong tendency for the development of a close relationship between a bureaucracy and its client interests (e.g. Jordan 1998:603). The ministry had three representatives on the board of Hedeselskabet. The Land Reclamation Board. The act on land reclamation institutionalised the land reclamation process even further by establishing the Land Reclamation Board (Statens Landvindingsudvalg), the purpose of which was to recommend projects to the Ministry of Agriculture upon request from the landowners. The frequent meetings in the committee represented the pivotal point for the very powerful policy community. The committee’s members were: The head of department of the Ministry of Agriculture, one representative from Hedeselskabet, one from the union of engineers, two farmers and one representative from each of the ministries of public works, finance, and labour (from 1953 a representative from the Ministry of Fishery was added4). No actors representing environmental interests were members of the committee. At the same time, a number of the representatives met in the Central Land Board (Statens Jordlovsudvalg), this board also engaging in land reclamation (Hansen 2003:47-48). 5 The land reclamation network was a classic example of a strong policy community. Members were few and strong. They had a common view on rational farming and a common purpose (the benefit of farmers). There was very frequent interaction among the members, through many meetings in different fora. E.g. the head of department of the Ministry of Agriculture held a seat in the ministry, Hedeselskabet and the Land Reclamation Board. Furthermore, the network was exclusive, critical actors normally being excluded from meetings (Pedersen 2004), illustrated by the fact that fishing interests were not represented in the board until 1953. The nature network, in contrast, was very loosely integrated. Nature interests had, following a trend in Europe and US, been organised in the Danish Society for the Conservation of Nature since 1911 (Madsen 1978:22-25). The organisation was allowed to offer statements on land reclamation projects, but in practice had very limited power (Pedersen 2004). The Council on Nature Conservation was established when the act on nature conservancy was implemented in 1917. The five members of the council were natural scientists and were consulted in business relating to nature conservancy projects of scientific interest (Madsen 1978:41-43). However, the chairman of the council in the period 1925-44 came from a leading position in Hedeselskabet (Madsen 1978:80-81). For many years the scientists in the council often publicly disagreed with the Society for the Conservation of Nature (Madsen 1978). In addition, the Danish Ornithological Organisation, professional fishermen’s organisations, angling organisations, the Danish Outdoor Council and the Ministry of Fishery, all had some interest in putting an end to the land reclamation projects, however, they were not in possession of any significant resources (although the Ministry of Fishery did have a seat in the Land Reclamation Board from 1953). Moreover, they had a very unstable pattern of contact (if any) and they were not in agreement as regards the ultimate purpose of fighting land reclamation projects; some wanted recreational areas with beautiful sceneries, some wanted more fish, etc. Also, it was not until 1971 that a Ministry of the Environment was established. The nature network was an issue network. The decisions to straighten Skjern River and to drain Lake Soeborg illustrate the fight between the two networks, and the superiority of the land reclamation network. 3.1 The decision to straighten Skjern River Skjern River is situated in Western Jutland and constitutes Denmark’s largest watercourse by volume. The idea of straigthening the river and draining the river valley to improve conditions for cornfields over those for the cutting of hay, can be traced back to an engineer of Hedeselskabet in 1880. It was not until the act on land reclamation was passed in 1940, however, that the idea really gained ground. Local agricultural organisations appointed a committee to win Skjern River landowners for the project. Initially, there were some problems convincing landowners, but after Hedeselskabet was asked to develop a project in the 1950’s, in 1955, landowners were called to a meeting. Hedeselskabet presented the project and out of 834 landowners, 360 voted for a Skjern River project and 111 against (315 did not show up at the meeting), resulting in the project being agreed upon (Pedersen 2004). For the next six years, a concrete project plan was developed in cooperation between Hedeselskabet, the (local) Landowner’s Committee, and the Land Reclamation Board. In practice, the 6 project came to be considered and recommended by the Land Reclamation Board’s sub-committee for Jutland. In the deciding phase in 1958, the sub-committee consisted of three members, who all of whom having a connection with Hedeselskabet (ibid): 1) The manager of Hedeselskabet. 2) A member of the Danish Parliament (Liberal Party), a farmer himself, representing the farmers in the committee and, furthermore, a former member of the board of representatives in Hedeselskabet. 3) A former employee of Hedeselskabet. It was not surprising, therefore, that the committee recommended the project proposal from Hedeselskabet with no objections. The proposal of straigthening a meandering river, transforming 4000 hectares of meadows and marsh into arable farmland, was controversial. But when the Society for the Conservation of Nature in 1955 was asked for a statement, the answer given was ambivalent. The organisation’s experts responded that from a freshwater biological viewpoint there were no sufficiently strong arguments for opposing the project, although the project’s predicted negative impacts on the bird-life were regretted. From internal communications in the organisation it is evident that e.g. the executive committee regretted the resultant loss of scenic beauty, but that in view of the expected economic benefits for the country in a period of recession and high unemployment, the organisation found it difficult project (Pedersen 2004; Archivefiles of the Society for the Conservation of Nature). The professional fishermen’s local organisation feared that a project would cause ochre pollution in the local fjord connected to the river and complained in 1958 to the Minister of Agriculture, a member of the Liberal Party (traditionally the farmers’ party) and a farmer himself. The ministerial response was that the Land Reclamation Board had assessed, that the velocity of the river would solve the problem. As mentioned above, the Ministry of Fishery had a representative in the board. He pointed out at several meetings that the project had the potential to threaten fish stocks (e.g. due to ochre pollution), and that more investigations were required. Finally, a group of 53 landowners protested against the project, fearing the personal economic consequences (Pedersen 2004). Towards the end of the 1950’s the Danish economy recovered and the employment situation improved rapidly. Consequentially, the opposition against the Skjern River project increased in the public arena. However, after the accept in 1958 from the Land Reclamation Board, the Minister of Agriculture, in 1960, won a blueprint of the project through with a 17-1 vote in the parliament’s Finance Committee (Pedersen 2004). The Ministry of Labour placed the expensive project on hold, but the chairman of the Landowner’s Committee managed to make a local MP (Liberal Party) persuade the Minister of Labour (Labour Party) to release the money for the project (Archive-files of Hedeselskabet). More and more scientists, national newspapers, TV journalists, nature organisations, fishing organisations, and some MP’s questioned the project in the start of the 1960’s, claiming that the project would spoil the fishery and the beautiful scenery (Pedersen 2004). The Society for the Conservation of Nature, a new and more active president being appointed in 1960, demanded the project be reconsidered, while, at the time, the motivation to promote employment had retreated. The move did not meet with success. The Minister of Agriculture referred to the fact that normal parliamentary procedures had been followed. In March 1962 the excavators started digging in the steep banks of Skjern River. Meanwhile, the manager of Hedeselskabet was the initiator behind an initiative forcing the new proactive president of the Society for the Conservation of Nature to retire. A new president with more of a softly 7 approach, remained in charge of the organisation for the next two decades (Geckler 1982:16; Svold 1989:47). In 1965, Denmark’s largest land reclamation project was inaugurated. The price was about 33 million euro (today’s prices) (Pedersen 2004). 3.2 The decision to drain Lake Soeborg The power of the land reclamation network also becomes visible when viewing the decision to drain Lake Soeborg. Lake Soeborg was a 1200 hectare lake situated in the northern part of Sealand and was the first Danish large aquatic area at which attempts to drain were made, in the late 18th century (Petersen & Meyhoff 1986:21). The first drainage attempt was ineffective and when Count Frijs acquired ‘the lake’ a century later in 1872, 400 hectares were still covered by water, therefore Frijs improved the drains (ibid:62). However, drainage was still not optimal and around 1940 the soil was severely waterlogged. At this point, the Act on Land Reclamation (1940) was heaven-sent, it offering the possibility of state grants for land reclamation. The act gave rise to a number of the local landowners asking Hedeselskabet for practical advice, and, as a result, a comprehensive project was presented at a meeting in 1942 (Archive-files of the Land Reclamation Board). At the meeting, the Land Reclamation Board’s sub-committee for the islands, around 150 landowners, Hedeselskabet, the municipality and a couple of other individuals were present. Many of the landowners spoke out against a new drainage effort, as they feared the personal economic consequences, despite the potential of two thirds of the costs to be paid by the state. Two representatives of the Land Reclamation Board went to the platform. The first, the chairman of the board, explained that the board was willing to listen to the landowner’s concerns, but added that the board could go ahead and adopt the drainage proposals even if the majority of the landowners were against them. This could be the case, as long as the benefits of the project were at least one third of the costs. The other member of the board, a former smallholder himself, and at this time an MP for ‘the smallholder’s party’, the Radical Liberal Party, entreated the landowners to accept the proposal and mentioned that the current state of affairs in Denmark dictated this action, adding that if he, himself, had been a landowner, he would have done it for the common good of the country. After this ‘motive speech’ a vote was performed. Forty landowners voted for the proposed project, twenty voted against, and there were a large number of blank votes (Archive-files of the Land Reclamation Board). A year later Hedeselskabet presented a proposal for the project, which was much more comprehensive than expected. Some of the landowners complained, their expected just a bit of digging in the ditches, but instead Hedeselskabet had designed a huge project with expensive pumping stations. In defiance of the protests, the project was accepted in 1944 by the Ministry of Agriculture at a price of around 2 million euro (todays prices) and the last remaining area of lake was drained (Archive-files of the Land Reclamation Board). The nature network was almost not present in the decision to drain Lake Soeborg. When the two first decisions to drain the lake in the 18th and 19th centuries were decided upon, no environmental interests were organised – no nature network existed. When the last section of lake was drained in the 1940’s, it appears that actors from the nature network did not oppose this project either. Here, it can be argued that the lake was already damaged before environmental interests were organised, therefore, it was not worth investing resources in securing the remaining section. The strong agricultural policy community succeeded in advancing the proposal without competition from other networks. 8 In general, the land reclamation network’s policy community had an easy time advancing land reclamation projects until the end of the 1960’s. In the period 1940-64 alone, land reclamation projects gave 180000 hectares of new farmland to the farmers (Landbokommissionen 1966:23). Environmental interests began to organise in the 20th century, but were part of a much looser and weaker issue network. The situation, however, started to change around 1970. 4. Standstill phase (1970-1986) The straigthening of Skjern River became the last land reclamation project of significant size. From 1966 the comprehensive state grants diminished rapidly. This process was started when two commissions were appointed. From the end of the 1950’s Danish farmers experienced problems in sale of their produce due to domestic overproduction, and protectionism on the international market. Therefore, a Land Commission was appointed in 1960 to analyse the agricultural industry’s structural problems (Porsmose & Bjørn 1997:105-106). One working group consisting of MPs, representatives from agricultural organisations, and public servants analysed the economic aspects (Landbokommissionen 1962a: 5-7). In July 1962, the commission appointed a special committee to investigate and evaluate drainage activities. Hedeselskabet and the Ministry of Agriculture were represented (three of the representatives sat on the Land Reclamation Board at the same time), but also the Ministry of Fishery and the Council on Nature Conservation (Landbokommissionen 1964:8). The representative from the Council on Nature Conservation was also a member of the board of the Danish Outdoor Council, this council having adopted a very critical stance in relation to the Skjern River project (Pedersen 2004:77). In 1964, the committee recommended a continuation of state grants for land improvements (Landbokommissionen 1964: 19). A majority of the committee further concluded that there was no longer an employment related motive for awarding grants for land reclamation, that state grants should still be granted, but that the funding should be reduced to 25 pct. of the costs with a possibility of 50 pct. funding for larger projects and even higher funding if there was an employment motivation. A committee minority, on the other hand, recommended a halt to the state grants (Landbokommissionen 1966:5-6). Furthermore, the representative from the Ministry of Fishery asked for a formal protection of fishery interests, but was denied by the majority who referred to the agricultural interests being superior to fishery interests (ibid:115). The representative from the Council on Nature Conservation proposed, moreover, that the council be represented in the Land Reclamation Board, however a committee majority refused the proposal (ibid:114). Along with the Land Commission, a Nature Conservation Commission was appointed in the autumn of 1961 when a new Ministry of Culture got the task of reforming the Act on Nature Conservation (Madsen 1978:141-142). This commission contained representatives from a range of different government ministries, agricultural interests and environmental interests. Environmental interests outnumbered agricultural interests in the commission this being evident in the working group for fresh water (Naturfredningskommissionen 1967:11). The commission described the scenic beauties and amenities of the sea and the fresh waters, and was in general negative towards land reclamation projects. The work carried out by the Land Commission resulted, in 1966, in passage through parliament of a new act on land reclamation and a new act on land improvements. This brought land reclamation projects in coastal areas to a stop. With 9 regard to state grants, the recommendation of the Land Commission was followed, resulting in a comprehensive lowering of grants for (fresh water) land reclamation. Furthermore, it was decided to revise the act after 5 years (Folketingstidende 1965/66 Tillæg A: sp.2209; Folketingstidende 1965/66 Folketingets Forhandlinger sp.624554). When the two acts were revised in 1970, they became one (an act on land improvement and stream regulation) appearing that the parliamentarians having been inspired by both of the commissions. The purpose of the act was two-sided: It aimed both to ensure necessary drainage of existing farmland, and to safeguard recreational areas to meet the public’s growing demand in this area. According to the act, it was not longer possible to favour projects, which had employment generation considerations, the state grant being fixed at a maximum of 25 pct. There were to be no grants for the regulation of lakes, and the grants were to be directed only at areas, which had already been agriculturally exploited. The act was passed by a significant majority in the parliament and formally brought the land reclamation era to a halt. A new era was started. An era (1970-86) characterised by a relatively low degree of switching status of land. 5. Restoration of wetlands phase Soon after the comprehensive Skjern River project was implemented towards the end of the 1960’s, severe ochre pollution problems appeared at the mouth of the river as anticipated by fisher organisations and the Ministry of Fishery (Geckler 1982). In 1974, a chartered surveyor proposed restoring the meanders in the river, but both the proposal and the problems were shelved in an ‘ochre committee’ during the 1970’s (Pedersen 2004:78). However, through the 1970’s acts on protection of rivers, lakes, and wetlands were implemented, and Denmark signed the Ramsar Convention (Knuth-Winterfeldt 1990:10-11, 14). Denmark had become a member of the EC in 1973. During the early 1980’s the EC experienced serious problems concerning the common agricultural policy, when huge surplus stocks were building up and marginal farmland was required to be taken out of production (Pedersen 2004:81). In June 1985, a committee in the Danish Ministry of the Environment presented a discussion paper analysing how this negative trend in the agricultural sector could be transformed into an environmental success by e.g. recreating lakes and establishing wetlands on marginal farmlands (Fredningsstyrelsen 1985:29). Since then, a number of restorations of drained lakes and wetlands have been implemented. The decision to restore the Skjern River, Northern Europe’s largest river restoration project, was the first milestone. 5.1 The Skjern River Restoration In September 1985, three months after the Ministry of the Environment’s presentation of a discussion paper, the Society for the Conservation of Nature invited the parliamentary Radical Liberal Party on an excursion into the Danish countryside. Inspired by prime minister Poul Schlüter’s simultaneous launch of a plan of ‘economic restoration’ of Danish society, the organisation launched a new word in the Danish vocabulary, ‘nature restoration’. After the excursion, the leader of the party asked the organisation to develop a motion for a proposal, and a process was started (Refn 2001:7). Meanwhile, Ringkoebing Fjord, severely polluted by ochre, nitrogen, and phosphorus from the Skjern River, was protected by the Ministry of the Environment in June 1985, and a Ringkoebing Fjord Committee was appointed to monitor the 10 consequences (Pedersen 2004). On 15 September 1986, the committee convened a seminar on the pollution of the fjord. The Minister of the Environment (Christian People’s Party) was giving a speech and was surprisingly explicit, when stating: ‘The bottom is dead, the fishery and the birds are in a wretched state, the water is dirty and muddy’ (Ringkjøbing Amts Dagblad 16.09.86). A couple of days later a marginal land conference, inspired by the discussion paper from the ministry, was convened in Skjern and a biologist from the ministry told how a restoration of the Skjern River’s meanders could save the fjord by improving the stream’s oxidation, and by creating ‘wet meadows’, which could reduce the pollution. The mayor (Conservative Party) of the Municipality of Skjern was attending both the seminar and the conference, and it would seem that he combined the information from the two events when stating on national television in November 1986, to the indignation of most farmers, ‘that the regulation of the Skjern River was a crime against the nature in the river valley’, and that the meandering course of the river should potentially be restored (Pedersen 2004:79). The mayor (Liberal Party) of the other involved municipality, the Municipality of Egvad, supported a restoration as well (Ringkjøbing Amts Dagblad 31.12.86). In January 1987, the Social Democratic Party, which was part of what was termed the “alternative green majority” in the parliament opposing the LiberalConservative minority government, proposed restoration of the meanders in the river, with the purpose of reducing pollution and improve the amenity. The proposal was passed with a sizeable majority in parliament in May 1987, and a committee was appointed to draw up a project. In 1999, the excavators were back in the Skjern River Valley. However, this time they were not straigthening the river, but instead restoring its meanders. The farmland was acquired by the state by purchase from or exchange with the farmers5. A few farmers were expropriated. When the project was finished, an area corresponding to 4000 football fields was restored. Ironically, cost was the same as that for straigthening the river in the first place: 33 million euro (Pedersen 2004). But, what had happened to the strong land reclamation network? The local farmers/landowners were fiercely opposed to handling over farmland to a restoration project, e.g. claiming either that the project would ruin them, that the project was an insult towards the hard work carried out by their ancestors in straigthening the river, or that the project was developed by Copenhageners who knew nothing about conditions in Western Jutland. Furthermore, they were very reluctant to take seat in a local committee set up to investigate the pollution problem, while the unpopular (among farmers) mayor was a member. The farmer’s local organisation attempted to activate the former strong policy community by asking for the help of the national agricultural organisation, but did not succeed (Pedersen 2004). In the working group behind preparation of a particular Skjern River Project, the local farmers possessed two seats and fought against a comprehensive project. However, they constituted a minority in the group, which was dominated by pro-restoration interests. Furthermore, the farmers overestimated their own strength, it not being until very late in the decision-making process that they organised themselves into a new landowners committee as previously (ibid).6 The main problem for the land reclamation network was that it was severely weakened compared with the 1960’s. The restoration decision was prepared, taken, and implemented in a new policy venue: The Ministry of the Environment. The former ally, the Ministry of Agriculture, was not involved. The national agricultural organisations were not particularly helpful either: They were aware, that there was a problem regarding pollution with nutritive salts; they were aware, that Denmark, as a member of EC, needed to take marginal farm land out of production, and the farm 11 land of Skjern River Valley was marginal7; environmental problems were high on the political agenda; and meanwhile they were fighting against the so called Plan for the Aquatic Environment. Therefore, it appears that the national agricultural organisations were not willing to invest resources in supporting the local agricultural organisations, but keeping, rather, a low profile in the matter (Pedersen 2004:80-81). Furthermore, the powerful Land Reclamation Board was abolished in 1983 (ibid), and Hedeselskabet was deprived of its state grants (Hansen 2003:50) leading the engineers in the company to turn their attention to restoration projects instead of land reclamation projects as source of income (Pedersen 2004:81). Finally, towards the end of the 1980’s a greater number of politicians supported environmental considerations. On the other hand, the nature network had strengthened over the years. The Ministry of the Environment has definitely brought new venues into play. Furthermore, the ‘nice’ Society for the Conservation of Nature got a new president in 1984, taking on a more aggressive and media-oriented policy style. Soon too, the public were rating environmental problems very highly on the agenda, and at the time of introducing the term ‘nature restoration’, the organisation had an impressive number of members: 245000 (Svold 1989:28,44), with one out of twenty Danes a member of the organisation. Meanwhile, the organisation was represented on all important committees regarding the Skjern River restoration. Here, the organisation joined the civil servants from the Ministry of the Environment and various other environmental interests. In the most important forum, the Skjern River working group, which developed the project, five of the members were part of the nature network, while only two members were part of the land reclamation network. Four representatives from the municipalities could be considered neutral, but two of them, the two mayor’s in the involved municipalities, had supported a restoration project prior to the working group being appointed(Pedersen 2004:82-83). In other fora where the Skjern River featured, the situation was the same, with environmental interests outnumbering agricultural interests. In addition, the network was tighter than in the 1960’s. The actors met in different fora and a number of the actors apparently even had close personal relationships. Furthermore, they agreed on the demands; they wanted the meanders back (Pedersen 2004). But - what changes at each of the six levels in the exogenous context of the networks made the policy U-turn possible? Socioeconomic changes. In the years between the two Skjern River decisions, the relative importance of the agricultural sector, for both employment and economy, fell significantly (Jensen 1998). Furthermore, the Danes were much more prosperous on average, than in the middle of the century, affording them more post material values. Changes in public opinion. Through the 1980’s environmental problems won a more and more central position in the Danish public debate and, in 1987, a majority of the voters ranked environmental considerations higher on the agenda, than industrial and agricultural considerations (Tonsgaard 1989: 271, 277). Changes in ideology. Possibly due to the perceived changes in the public opinion, the politicians co-opted the environmental issue. For a couple of years in the middle of the 1980’s, the Conservative-Liberal minority government faced a so-called ‘alternative green majority coalition’ in the parliament, which consisted of the leftwing parties, the Social Democrats and the Radical Liberals. On several occasions, this majority forced the Conservative-Liberal minority governments to adopt certain environmental policies which they disliked (e.g. Daugbjerg and Pedersen 2004). The formal proposal to restore Skjern River came from the Social Democratic Party, which was a member of the ‘alternative green majority’. However, when the deciding 12 vote was performed in the Parliament, there was almost consensus, even the farmers’ party, Venstre, voted for the proposal and only the right-wing Progress Party voted against. In addition, at the local level the two mayors’, a Conservative and a Liberal, a bit surprisingly, supported a restoration project. Knowledge changes. In the 1950’s and 1960’s scientists were aware, that straigthening the river could cause pollution problems, but they did not know to what extent. In the 1980’s the problems were very visible. Furthermore, new knowledge regarding agricultural emissions of nitrogen and phosphorous came forth, as well as more information on the positive effect meanders have on pollution levels (Pedersen 2004). Change in institutions. Comprehensive changes occurred at the institutional level. A new Ministry of the Environment was born in 1971 resulting in a new venue. On the other hand, the Land Reclamation Board was erased as a venue. Furthermore, Denmark joined the EC in 1973, resulting, once again, in new venues, as well as new demands on Danish decision-makers (e.g. regarding marginal farmland). Presence of other networks. As described, two networks conflict regarding the use of the wider countryside. If no competing network had attempted to privilege their position, the possibility of policy stability, i.e. continued land reclamation, would have been greater. Disprivileged actors in the nature network used the change in context behind a turnaround regarding the relative positions of two involved networks, and in turn, in rural policy. Civil servants in the Ministry of the Environment proposed turning marginal farmlands into lakes and wetlands again. The ‘new’ aggressive Society for the Conservation of Nature invented the very positive word ‘nature restoration’ and sold the idea to the Radical Liberal Party, a very important party at the centre of the left-right cleavage line in Danish politics, but more ‘green’ than the Social Democrats (e.g. Daugbjerg and Svendsen 2001:59-60). The party, at that time, were part of the alternative green majority in the Danish parliament. A couple of months later, another member of the green majority, the Social Democratic Party, proposed a restoration of Skjern River. For the politicians, it was significant, at the time, that voters rated environmental considerations exceptionally high on the agenda, and that there was a new policy image regarding the use of the wider countryside. A new policy image was coupled to a new policy venue (the Ministry of the Environment) resulting in policy change. Furthermore, the old land reclamation network had disintegrated. The crucial venue, the Land Reclamation Board was lost, and the entrepreneur, Hedeselskabet, had changed perceptions with regard to the wider countryside, in assesment that there was more income to be generated in restoration projects. The result was a U-turn in the policy. 5.2 Lake Soeborg – no restoration The new strong nature network is not, in itself, always successful and did not succeed in initiating a restoration of Lake Soeborg, despite, since 1987, several proposals having been brought to the table. In the beginning of 1987, the forest supervisor in the area where Lake Soeborg was formerly situated, inspired by the debate on marginal farmland in February 1986, proposed that the Ministry of the Environment restore 430 hectares of the former lake, at a cost of approximately 3 million euro. A project was designed by Hedeselskabet (Politiken 27.02.1987; Archive-files of Danish Forest and Nature Agency). The proposal was not adopted. 13 In December 1988, Hedeselskabet designed a smaller project (126 hectares). The price of implementation was less than 1 million euro (Archive-files of Danish Forest and Nature Agency). The proposal was not adopted either. In August 1993, the Social Democrats in the Municipality of GraestedGilleleje, where Lake Soeborg is situated, proposed a 600 hectares restoration of the lake (Berlingske Tidende 26.10.93). The proposal, once again, was not adopted. In 2001, the private foundation, Aage V. Jensens Foundation, tried to buy a 75 hectares farm in the area with the purpose of implementing a small restoration project on the land (Politiken 23.02.01). The foundation was not allowed to buy the farmland and no restoration project was implemented. Why was it possible to implement a Skjern River, but not a Lake Soeborg, project? The forest supervisor introducing the first proposal was a member of a marginal farmland working group, under the Ministry of the Environment, involved in analysing drained lakes and fjords (Archive-files of Danish Forest and Nature Agency; Politiken 27.02.87). The project had been designed by Hedeselskabet, the “deserter” from the land reclamation network, and involved a 430 hectare restoration of the lake, to the enthusiasm of nature interests. The cost was estimated at approximately 3 million euro (Politiken 27.02.1987), however, as mentioned above, the proposal was not adopted. It is apparent that the project entered a vacuum. The project was proposed directly after the Skjern River project, but before a new act on nature management, adopted in 1989, which allotted approximately 75 million euro to nature restoration projects in the period 1989-998 (Madsen 1999). However, the government did create a 4 million euro pool for restoration projects in the summer of 1987, (Archive-files of Danish Forest and Nature Agency) although the project was assessed as too expensive (3 million euro) compared with total available funds in the pool. The project enters a regulatory ‘black hole’, leading to Hedeselskabet developing a new and smaller project, for which proposals were presented in December 1988. This new proposal coincided with the new act on nature management and was supported by many landowners, the municipality and the county (Archive-files of Danish Forest and Nature Agency). However, the proposal was refused by the Forest and Nature Agency, under the Ministry of the Environment. The formal argument put forward was that it was too expensive compared with the recreational benefits predicted. There are four possible reasons why the project was denied: 1. The project, in essence, involved ‘too little nature for too much money’. 2. The Liberal-Conservative government forced the agency to reject the proposal, there no longer being an alternative green majority in parliament (dissolved summer of 1988). 3. The Forest and Nature Agency was planning implementation of a more comprehensive project under the new act on nature management. 4. The Agency knew that one of the largest landowners was against the project9 and therefore wanted to avoid conflict. Speaking against no. 2. is that most of the farmers apparently supported the proposal, this making it unlikely that a Liberal-Conservative government would have rejected the proposal. Furthermore, the Minister of the Environment represented the Radical Liberal Party, a former participant in the “alternative green majority” 10. Unfortunately, though, it has yet to be proven which of the three other possibilities proved decisive. 14 The comprehensive third proposal in August 1993 came from the Social Democrats in the Municipality of Graested-Gilleleje. The political context, however, had changed in the municipality and it was now a representative of the farmers’ party, Venstre, who was the mayor. Where the landowners were fiercely against the proposal (Frederiksborg Amts Avis 05.10.94), evidently, so were the majority of the municipality (Archive-files of Danish Forest and Nature Agency). The Society for the Conservation of Nature actively supported the proposal (Frederiksborg Amts Avis 29.10.93) along with other interests from the nature network, but they did not succeed in advancing any restoration. In January 1993, a Social Democratic-led majority government had come to power, giving rise to a possibility of implementing the project in defiance of the municipality’s and the landowners’ resistance, however the possibility was not realised. The final attempt, to date, to initiate restoration of the lake was when a private foundation attempted to buy a 75 hectare farm in the area, with the purpose of implementing a small restoration project on the land. The foundation’s general aim was to conserve nature and protect the wildlife. The foundation did not succeed as the purchase, according to law, was to be approved by an agricultural commission. The agricultural commission consisted of two representatives appointed by the local agricultural organisations and one representative appointed by the local county. Two of the members voted for the deal, one, a local pig farmer, voted against. Since a single member in the commission could veto a particular deal, the foundation’s plan to purchase the land was denied (Politiken 23.02.2001). The nature network did not succeed in bringing about a Lake Soeborg restoration, illustrating that despite the privileged position enjoyed by the nature network, today, the fight against the old land reclamation network cannot always be won. The case, in hand, demonstrates that timing in relation to the actions of the policy entrepreneurs is important. Today, both of the networks can be characterised as being at a point on the continuum between a policy community and an issue network. Policy instability is more prevalent than back in the middle of the 20th century, where the land reclamation interests strong policy community reigned. The Soeborg-case reveals that the timing of the entrepreneur’s pro-restoration of Lake Soeborg was not optimal. The restoration proposal in 1987 came during a regulatory ‘black hole’ the project being seen to be too expensive compared with the means – there was an institutional context difference when compared with the Skjern River project. This, potentially, was the reason why the second proposal was turned down as well. When a third attempt was made in 1993, an ideological change had taken place in the municipality, it now being led by a mayor from the Liberal Party, opposing a restoration, differentiating this case from the Skjern River projects, where the mayors of the two involved municipalities supported restoration efforts. The final attempt failed (again), this time due to the prevailing institutional framework, the agricultural commission having to approve the purchase of the land for restoration, this not being a factor entering the case of the Skjern River restoration. However, as a result of the veto in the agricultural commission, described above, the Minister of Food, Agriculture and Fisheries (Liberal Party) changed the law on agricultural holdings (Lov om landbrugsejendomme 09.06.2004) which, to an extent, facilitated the purchase of farms with the purpose of returning the farmland to nature. The composition of the agricultural commission was also changed, it now comprising five representatives: One appointed by the county, two appointed by the agricultural organisations and two appointed by nature organisations. It is, moreover, no longer possible for a single 15 member to veto a decision. The above removes one potential obstruction to a potential Lake Soeborg restoration. In summing up, when the entrepreneurs proposing the Lake Soeborg restoration introduced the projects, conditions in the exogenous context were not as favourable as when the Skjern River restoration was proposed, making it more difficult to push a Lake Soeborg restoration project through. 6. Conclusion Denmark has experienced a U-turn in rural policy regarding land-use in the wider countryside. Until 1970, rivers were straigthened, and lakes and fjords drained, with the aim of gaining fertile agricultural soil. A strong policy community of land reclamation interests privileged itself at the expense of nature interests organised in an issue network. Since the mid-1980’s, numerous nature restoration projects have been implemented, the Skjern River restoration being one significant example. At the macro-level the development can be explained by radical changes in the two networks’ exogenous context, causing the land reclamation network to disintegrate and the nature network to integrate, forming intermediate-type networks at mid-points along the continuum. At the micro-level, the disprivileged nature network took advantage of the changes and was able to capitalise on a new policy image and a new policy venue to bring about a new policy output. However, the successive failures to win through projects aimed at restoration of Lake Soeborg illustrates that, today, rural land-use policy, in the context of this paper, is characterised by instability due to the character of the two networks involved. In the case of Lake Soeborg, the nature network did not succeed in initiating a restoration project as projects were proposed when conditions in the exogenous context were not as favourable as when the Skjern River Project was adopted. The timing of the policy entrepreneurs was not optimal. References Archive-files of Danish Forest and Nature Agency. Archive-files of Hedeselskabet. Archive-files of the Land Reclamation Board. Archive-files of the Society for the Conservation of Nature. Baumgartner, Frank R. & Bryan D. Jones, 1993, Agendas and instability in American Politics, Chicago & London: The University of Chicago Press. Benson, J. Kenneth, 1982, ‘A Framework for Policy Analysis’ pp.137-76 in David L. Rogers & David A. Whetten (eds.), Interorganizational Coordination: Theory, Research, and Implementation, Ames: Iowa State University Press. Berlingske Tidende (Danish daily newspaper). Blom-Hansen, Jens, 1997, ‘A ‘New Institutional’ Perspective on Policy Networks’, Public Administration vol.75 pp.669-93. Blom-Hansen, Jens & Carsten Daugbjerg, 1999, ’Staten og de organiserede interesser: En teoretisk introduktion’ pp.6-20 in Blom-Hansen & Daugbjerg (eds.), Magtens organisering: Stat og interesseorganisationer i Danmark, Århus: Systime. Daugbjerg, Carsten, 1998, Policy Networks under Pressure: Pollution Control, Policy Reforms, and the Power of Farmers, Aldershot: Ashgate Publishing. 16 Daugbjerg, Carsten & David Marsh, 1998, ‘Explaining policy outcomes: integrating the policy network approach with macro-level and micro-level analysis’ pp.5371 in David Mrash (ed.), Comparing Policy Networks, Buckingham & Philadelphia: Open University Press. Daugbjerg, Carsten & Anders Branth Pedersen, 2004, ‘New Policy Ideas and Old Policy Networks: Implementing Green Taxation in Scandinavia’ in Journal of Public Policy (forthcoming). Daugbjerg, Carsten & Gert Tinggaard Svendsen, 2001, Green Taxation in Question. Politics and Economic Efficiency in Environmental Regulation, Basingstoke & New York: Palgrave. Dowding, Keith, 2001, ‘There Must Be End to Confusion: Policy Networks, Intellectual Fatigue, and the Need for Political Science Methods Courses in British Universities’ pp.89-105 in Political Studies vol.49. Folketingstidende. Frederiksborg Amts Avis, (local Danish daily newspaper). Fredningsstyrelsen, 1985, Miljøinteresser og marginaljorder. Et debatoplæg, Copenhagen: Fredningsstyrelsen. Geckler, Rolf, 1982, Hvad indad tabes. Hedeselskabets virksomhed, magt og position, København: Gyldendal. Hansen, Kjeld, 2003, Der er et yndigt land. En fattig natur i et rigt samfund – status over Danmarks natur, Copenhagen: Gads Forlag. Jensen, Jørgen Dejgård, 1998, Landdistrikternes økonomi og udvikling – en oversigt, Copenhagen: AKF Forlaget. Jordan, Grant, 1998, ‘Indirect Causes and Effects in Policy Change: The Brent Spar Case’ pp.713-40 in Public Administration vol.76. Kaarsted, Tage, 1992, De danske ministerier 1953-72, København: PFA Pension. Knuth-Winterfeldt, Henrik, 1990, ‘En epoke i naturbeskyttelsens historie’ pp.9-20 in Bo Brix et al., Landet og loven, Copenhagen: Ministry of the Environment. Kongelig dansk hof- og statskalender. Landbokommissionen, 1962, Betænkning afgivet af Landbokommissionen af 1960. Første del, om brugsstørrelser, nedlægning og sammenlægning af landbrugsejendomme, hovedparcellers mindstestørrelse og jordboniteringen m.v. (Betænkning nr. 306), Copenhagen: Statens Trykningskontor. Landbokommissionen, 1964, Betænkning afgivet af Landbokommissionen af 1960. Andel del, om grundforbedring (Betænkning nr. 354), Copenhagen: Statens Trykningskontor. Landbokommissionen, 1966, Betænkning afgivet af Landbokommissionen af 1960. Fjerde del, om landvinding m.m. (Betænkning nr. 410), Copenhagen: Statens Trykningskontor. Lov om landbrugsejendomme, lov nr. 435 af 09.06.2004. Lov om landvinding (26.10.1940). Maas, Arthur, 1951, Muddy Waters – The Army Engineers and the Nation’s Rivers, Cambridge (MA): Harvard University Press. Madsen, Bent Lauge, 1999, ’Ti år med naturforvaltningsloven’ pp.9-11 in Proceedings fra seminar om restaurering og vedligeholdelse af vandløb 12.-13. oktober 1999, Copenhagen: Ministry of the Environment and Energy & National Environmental Research Institute. Madsen, Flemming Kiilsgaard, 1979, Naturfredningssagens historie i Danmark, Odense: Odense Universitetsforlag. 17 Marsh, David, 1998, ‘The utility and future of policy network analysis’ pp.185-197 in David Marsh (ed.), Comparing Policy Networks, Buckingham & Philadelphia: Open University Press. Marsh, David & R.A.W. Rhodes (eds.), 1992, Policy Networks in British Government, Oxford: Clarendon Press. Naturfredningskommissionen, 1967a, Betænkning on naturfredning I. Afgivet af den af Ministeriet for kulturelle anliggender under 23. november 1961 nedsatte Naturfredningskommission (Betænkning nr. 461), Copenhagen: Statens Trykningskontor. Naturfredningskommissionen, 1967b, Betænkning om naturfredning II. Afgivet af den af Ministeriet for kulturelle anliggender under 23. november 1961 nedsatte Naturfredningskommission (Betænkning nr. 467), Copenhagen: Statens Trykningskontor. Nørgaard, Asbjørn Sonne, 1997, The Politics of Institutional Control – Corporatism in Danish Occupational Safety and Health Regulation & Unemployment Insurance, 1870-1995 (PhD-dissertation), Aarhus: Department of Political Science, University of Aarhus. Parsons, Wayne, 1995, Public Policy – An Introduction to the Theory and Practice of Policy Analysis, Aldershot, UK & Brookfield, US: Edward Elgar. Pedersen, Anders Branth, 2004, ’Først den ene vej og så den anden vej: de politiske beslutningsprocesser vedrørende udretning og genslyngning af Skjern Å’ pp.7187 in Politica vol.36 no.1. Peters, B. Guy, 1998, ‘Policy networks: myth, metaphor, and reality’ pp.21-32 in David Marsh (ed.), Comparing Policy Networks, Buckingham & Philadelphia: Open University Press. Petersen, Flemming Rune & Gerda Meyhoff, 1986, Søborg Sø – gennem sump til agerland, Søborg: Bogudvalget. Politiken (Danish daily newspaper). Porsmose, Erland & Claus Bjørn, 1997, Landbrugets historie – kort fortalt. Fra bondestenalder til GATT-aftale, Aarhus: Landbrugsforlaget. Refn, Jesper, 2001, ‘90 år i naturens tjeneste’ pp.4-9 in Natur og Miljø no.2. Rhodes, R.A.W., 1988, Beyond Westminster and Whitehall: The Sub-Central Governments of Britain, London: Unwin Hayman. Rhodes, R.A.W., 1990, ‘Policy Networks – A British Perspective’ pp.293-327 in Journal of Theoretical Politics vol.2 no.3. Rhodes, R.A.W. & David Marsh, 1992, ‘New Directions in the Study of Policy Networks’ pp.181-205 in European Journal of Political Research, 21. Ringkjøbing Amts Dagblad (local daily Danish newspaper). Smith, Adrian, 2000, ‘Policy Networks and advocacy coalitions: explaining policy change and stability in UK industrial pollution policy?’ pp.95-114 in Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy vol.18. Svold, Claus, 1989, Danmarks Naturfredningsforening – Fra pæn til aggressiv miljøorganisation, Aarhus: PLS Consult. Tonsgaard, Ole, 1989, ’Miljøpolitisk enighed?’, pp.271-90 in Jørgen Elklit & Ole Tonsgaard (eds.), To folketingsvalg – Vælgerholdninger og vælgeradfærd i 1987 og 1988, Aarhus: Politica. 18 Table 1: Extremes on the Policy Network Continuum Dimensions Policy community Issue network Membership Very limited number of members. Large number of members. Narrow range of interests represented Wide range of interests represented. Bargaining and negotiation. Consultation. Frequent interaction Unstable pattern of interaction Integration Institutionalisation Consensus on policy principles and procedures to approach policy problems Conflict over policy principles and procedures to approach policy problems (adopted from Daugbjerg 1998) 1 In EU-25, only UK is a bit more cultivated (64 pct. cultivated) Several other European countries have a long tradition of giving state grants to land reclamation projects. E.g. Finland, Switzerland, West Germany, Austria, and the Netherlands (Landbokommissionen 1966:52-55) 3 A parallel can be drawn to Maas’ (1951) description of the power of the US Corps of Army Engineers 4 The fishery organisations in 1940 plead for a seat to a representative for fishery interests, but were denied (Landbokommissionen 1966:89). 5 Since 1972 it was by law, due to EC regulation, possible for the state to acquire areas with the purpose of leisure activity (Knuth-Winterfeldt 1990:10). 6 When the project finally was implemented, most farmers were actually satisfied with the payment for their land (Pedersen 2004) 7 Farm land in drained river valleys or lakes often becomes marginal as years are passing by, because the land “sinks”. 8 The money is e.g. spent for buying areas, where nature restoration can be implemented. Later, in 1998, according to the socalled Plan for the Aquatic Environment II, it was decided to take out 16.000 hectares of marginal farmland and make it wetlands (Hansen 2003:253). 9 A very large landowner spoke against the project three weeks after the rejection of the agency (Archive-files of Danish Forest and Nature Agency) 10 Unconfirmed information, however, points to the fact that one of the largest landowners and most devoted protesters was a member of the Radical Liberal Party, as was the Minister of Environment. 2 19