Duration Analysis of Regime Changes in the Exchange Rate Mechanism February 2002 Preliminary version Please do not quote without the authors’ permission Simón Sosvilla-Rivero (FEDEA and Universidad Complutense de Madrid) Reyes Maroto-Illera (FEDEA and Universidad Carlos III) Francisco Pérez-Bermejo (FEDEA) ABSTRACT This paper examines the regime changes in the Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM), applying the duration model approach to quarterly data of eight currencies participating in the ERM, covering the complete EMS history. The time spells between two consecutive changes in the ERM is studied, estimating the survival and hazard functions of such variable. We first make use of the nonparametric (univariate) analysis, finding that the probability of maintaining the current regime decreases very rapidly for the short durations to register then smoother variations as time increases. Therefore, for those regimes with high durations, the ERM would have been relatively stable, while for the (more common) regimes associated with short durations would have been more unstable. Then we apply a parametric (multivariate) analysis to investigate the role of other variables in the probability of a regime change. In this case, three alternative theoretical frameworks are used to select potential explanatory variables: exchange-rate determination models, first generation models of currency crisis and second generation models of currency crisis. Our results suggest that the money supply differential with Germany would have negatively affected the probability of change of a given regime, while credibility, price differential with Germany, the reserves/GDP ratio, changes in reserves and the evolution of the Share index would have positively influenced such probability. Finally, when distinguishing between groups of currencies, we observe that those in the core are more stable than those in the periphery. A formal test for equality of survival functions among currencies confirms that there is evidence of heterogeneity in our sample of currencies. As well, after including a dummy variable to control for the heterogeneity by groups of currencies, previous findings remained unaltered. JEL Codes: C41, F31, F33 Keywords: Duration analysis, exchange rates, European Monetary System. 1. Introduction The European Monetary System (EMS) was initially planned as an agreement to reduce exchange rate volatility for a Europe in transition to a closer economic integration. Following its inception in March 1979, a group of European countries linked their exchange rates through formal participation in the Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM). The ERM was an adjustable peg system in which each currency had a central rate expressed in the European Currency Unit (ECU), predecessor of the Euro. These central rates determined a grid of bilateral central rates vis-à-vis all other participating currencies, and defined a band around these central rates within which the exchange rates could fluctuate freely. Intervention to support bilateral rates where obligatory at the margins, with unlimited amounts of credit available between central banks for this purpose through the very short term financing facility. Following the Base-Nyborg agreement of September 1987, central banks were also empowered to intervene within margins before limits were reached. If the participating countries decided by mutual agreement that a particular parity could not be defended, realignments of the central rates were permitted. The ERM is the most prominent example of a target-zone exchange rate system. There exist an extensive literature that builds on the seminal paper by Krugman (1991) studies the behavior of exchange rates in target-zones. The main result of the target-zone model is that, with perfect credibility, the zone exerts a stabilizing effect (the so called “honey-moon” effect), reducing the exchange rate sensitivity to a given change in fundamentals. Nevertheless, in a target-zone with credibility problems, expectations of future interventions tend to destabilize the exchange rate, making it less stable than the underlying fundamentals (Bertola and Caballero, 1992). Therefore credibility (i.e., the degree of confidence that the economic agents assign to the announcements made by the policy makers) becomes a key variable. In a context of an exchange rate target-zone, like the EMS, credibility refers to the perception of economic agents with respect to the commitment to maintain the exchange rate around a central parity. Therefore, the possibility for the financial authorities to change the central parity could be anticipated by the economic agents, triggering expectations of future changes in the exchange rate that can act as a destabilizing element of the system. In the literature, there has been several tests of credibility based on financial instruments that reflects these market expectations [see Svenson (1992) for a survey of literature]. Svenson (1991), e.g., proposed an arbitrage-based test of exchange rate credibility. This test uses the interest rate differential between the domestic and foreign currency to show that whenever the forward exchange rate lies outside the band, one can reject the null hypothesis that the existing exchange rate is credible. On the other hand, Campa and Chang (1996) use option prices to derive two more arbitrage test of credibility of an exchange rate. Furthermore, Fernández-Rodríguez, Sosvilla-Rivero and MartínGonzález (2002) develop a test for target-zone credibility that make use of nonlinear forecastable dependencies in time series. Finally, Ledesma-González et al. (2001) study the degree of credibility of the EMS using a battery of credibility measures. On the other hand, another important line of research has aimed to estimate the probability of realignment using econometric techniques. To that end, some explanatory variables of that probability are considered, usually the interest rate differential, the inflation differential, the current account balance, and the unemployment rate [see, e.g., Edin and Vredin, (1993)]. We depart from the previous papers by using duration analysis to examine the survival of the central parities in the EMR. We have applied this approach to eight currencies participating in the ERM, using quarterly data of exchange rates vis-á-vis the Deustchemark for the first quarter 1979 to the fourth quarter 1998 period, covering in practically the complete EMS history. The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we present the data. Section 3 briefly describes the methodology of duration model approach, while Section 4 presents the empirical results. Section 5 assesses the possibility of heterogeneity in the sample. Finally, some concluding remarks are provided in Section 6. 2. Data It is common to distinguish four different subperiods in the experience of the ERM (see, e. g. De Grauwe, 2000). The first subperiod extended from the ERM inception, in March 1979, to January 1987 During this subperiod, the relatively large fluctuations bands in the EMS (compared to those in the Bretton Woods system), together with relatively small and frequent realignments, helped to reduce the size of speculative capital movements and stabilised the system. The second subperiod, the so-called “New ERM”, lasted from 1987 to the end of 1991, coinciding with increasing confidence in the ERM, the removal of capital controls, and a greater convergence in the economic fundamentals. The third subperiod covered successive crises of September 1992 an August 1993, where the evolution of the EMS into a truly fixed exchange rate system with almost perfect capital mobility led to credibility losses in a context of policy conflict among EMS countries about how to face the severe recession experienced in 1992-93. Finally, a fourth subperiod iniciated after the crisis of 1993, when the EMS changed its nature in drastic ways: the EMS gained credibility with the enlargement of the fluctuation bands to ±15% (reducing the scope for large speculative gains) and with the fixed exchange rate commitment among potential European Monetary Union (EMU) member countries. As a result, speculation became a stabilising factor and the market rates converged closer and closer to the fixed conversion rates, although the world was hit by a major crisis during the second half of 1998 (De Grauwe et al., 1999). Table 1 shows the main realignments and changes in the EMS during the 1979-1999 period. As can be seen, although the fluctuation band was originally set at 2.25%, Italy and the newcomers (Spain, the UK and Portugal) used a wider band of fluctuation ( 6%) . After almost a year of unprecedented turmoil in the history of the EMS, the fluctuation bands of the ERM were broadened in August 1993 to 15% except for Dutch guilder and Deutschemark, which remained with the narrow bands of 2.25%. On 1 January 1999 the EMS ceased to exist. On the other hand, as shown in Table 1, there were nineteen realignments in the EMS history, being twelve of them prior to the currency turmoil of the subperiod 1992-1993. Table 1: Main realignments and changes in the ERM (1979-1998) 13.03.1979 ERM starts to operate with the BFR, DKR, DM, FF, IRL, LIT and HFL. They are in the narrow band ( 2.25% fluctuation), except the LIT in the wide band ( 6% fluctuation). 24.09.1979 Realignment (DKR –3%, DM +2%) 30.11.1979 23.03.1981 5.10.1981 22.02.1982 14.06.1982 Realignment (DKR –5%) Realignment (LIT –6%) Realignment (DM +5.5%, FF –3%, HFL +5.5%, LIT –3%) Realignment (BFR –8.5%, DKR -3%) Realignment (DM +4.25%, FF –5.75%, HFL +4.25%, LIT –2.75%) Realignment (BFR +1.5%, DKR +2.5%, DM +5.5%, FF –2.5%, IRL –3.5%, HFL +3.5%, LIT –2.5%) 22.03.1983 22.07.1985 Realignment (BFR +2%, DKR +2%, DM +2%, FF +2%, IRL +2%, HFL +2%, LIT –6%) 17.09.1992 23.11.1992 1.02.1993 14.05.1993 2.08.1993 9.01.1995 6.03.1995 14.10.1996 25.11.1996 Realignment (BFR +1%, DKR +1%, DM +3%, FF –3%, HFL +3%) Realignment (IRL –8%) Realignment (BFR +2%, DM +3%, HFL +3%) The PTA joins the ERM with the wide band ( 6%) The LIT joins the narrow band ( 2.25%). Realignment (LIT –3.6774%) The UKL joins the ERM with the wide band ( 6%) The ESC joins the ERM with the wide band ( 6%) Realignment (BFR +3.5%, DKR +3.5%, DM +3.5%, ESC +3.5%, FF +3.5%, IRL +3.5%, HFL +3.5%, LIT –3.5%, PTA +3.5%, UKL +3.5%) The UKL and the LIT suspend their participation in the ERM. Realignment (PTA –5%) Realignment (ESC -6%, PTA –6%) Realignment (IRL -10%) Realignment (ESC –6.5%, PTA –8%) The ERM fluctuation bands are widened to 15%, except for the DM and the HFL The ATS joins the ERM with the new wide band ( 15%) Realignment (ESC –3.5%, PTA –7%) The FIM joins the ERM with the new wide band ( 15%) The LIT re-joins the ERM with the new wide band ( 15%) 16.03.1998 Realignment (IRL +3%). The DR joins the ERM with the new wide band ( 15%) 7.04.1986 4.08.1986 12.01.1987 19.06.1989 8.01.1990 8.10.1990 6.04.1992 14.09.1992 Note: ATS, BFR, DKR, DM, DR, ESC, FF, FIM, HFL, IRL, LIT, PTA and UKL denote, respectively, the Austrian schilling, the Belgian franc, the Danish krone, the Deustchemark, the Greek drachma, the Portuguese escudo, the French franc, the Finnish markka, the Dutch guilder, the Irish pound, the Italian lira, the Spanish peseta and the Pound sterling. In our study we use quarterly data of eight currencies participating in the ERM of the EMS, these are: the French Belgian franc (FF), the Irish pound (IRL), the Belgian franc (BFR), the Italian lira (LIT), the Dutch guilder (HFL), the Danish crown (DKR), the Spanish peseta (PTA) and the Portuguese escudo (ESC). Given the central role of Germany in the European Union [see Bajo-Rubio et al. (2001)], our exchange rates are expressed vis- á-vis the Deustchemark. The sample period runs from the first quarter of 1979 to the fourth quarter of 1998, covering in the complete history of the EMS. Starting from this data set, we construct a dummy variable called change, taking value one if a regime change takes place and zero otherwise. To that end, we shall consider as a regime change each realignment, modification of fluctuations bands or entrance/exit in the ERM. Based on the variable change, we generate the variable duration, representing the time spell between two consecutive regime changes. These variables, duration and change, define the survival-time data associated with each regime. Table 2. Descriptive statistics ALL CURRENCIES Change Duration Mean 0.468 6.617 Dev. Std. 0.501 5.976 Variance 0.251 35.715 Skewness 0.130 1.004 Kurtosis 1.017 2.932 Min 0 1 Max 1 21 N. of change Observations 72 154 The summary statistics for change and duration are presented in Table 2. As can be seen, for all the currencies considered, we have 154 observations. The average duration of regime changes is 6.6 quarters, being the minimum duration of 1 quarter and the maximum of 21 quarters. The average probability of change is 47%. Figure 1 shows the duration of the ERM regimes along the whole sample period 1979-1998. There is a high percentage of short durations (less than 5 quarters), representing the 52% of the total sample, while long durations (greater than 15 quarters) only account for 9%. This result shows that the regime changes are frequent in the sample, in particular the number of changes with duration less than 5 quarters is 49. Figure 1: Duration of regimes in the EMS, 1979-1998. ALL CURRENCIES .4 Fraction .3 .2 .1 0 1 5 10 analysis time 15 20 3. Econometric methodology In this section, we offer a brief description of the main concepts and functions used in the duration analysis. This analysis has been mainly used in Labor Economics 1, to study the duration of periods of employment and unemployment and the determinants of entry and exit rates [see Kiefer (1988) for a literature review]2. 3.1. Non-parametric analysis In the non-parametric, or empirical analysis, we use the information contained in the duration variable. In our case, this variable measures the time that passes between two consecutive regime changes in the ERM. Those econometric models developed to analyze this type of information are called duration models. If we define T as the discrete random variable that measures the time spell between two consecutive ERM regime changes, the observations at our disposal consist of 1 Duration models have been also used in the field of Industrial Organization, to analyze for example the life duration of multinational subsidiaries in the UK manufacturing industry (McCloughan and Stone, 1998), or to analize investment decisions (Licandro O., Goicolea A. And Maroto R , 1999). 2 See also Sosvilla-Rivero and Maroto (2001) for a detailed study of the duration of exchange rates regimes in the European Monetary System (EMS). This section borrows heavily from the section they dedicate to duration analysis in that article. a series of data (t1, t2,… tn) which correspond to each of the observed durations of each regime change in our sample. The probability distribution of the duration variable can be specified by the cumulative distribution function: F(t)=Pr(T<t) (1) which indicates the probability of the random variable T being smaller than a certain value t. The corresponding probability function is then: P(t)=Pr (T=t) (2) But in duration models, two main functions are used to characterize the probability distribution of the duration variable: (a) The survivor function is defined as: S(t)=Pr(T≥t)=1-F(t) (3) and it gives the probability of the duration being greater than or equal to t. (b) The hazard function is defined as: h(t)=Pr(T=t/ T≥t) (4) and it gives, for each duration, the probability of a regime change, given a survival up to t. There exists a relation between both functions given by the following expression: S (t ) s 1|t (1 h( s )) (5) One of the advantages of the hazard function is that it allows us to characterize the dependence path of duration. Formally, there exists a positive duration dependence in t* if dh(t)/dt>0, in the moment t=t*. This positive relation implies that the probability that a regime ends in t, given that it has reached t, depends positively on the length of the period. Thus, the longer the period, the higher the conditional probability of entering into a new regime. Similarly, there exists negative duration dependence if dh(t)/dt<0 in t=t*. In this case, the longer the period, the lower the conditional probability of regime change. The non-parametric analysis is used to estimate the unconditional hazard function which registers all the observations for which there is a change, that is, the relative frequency of observations with T=t. For this analysis, the Kaplan-Meier estimate is widely used (Kaplan and Meier, 1958). The hazard function is calculated as follows: d hˆ(t ) t nt (6) where dt represents the number of changes registered in moment t, and nt is the surviving population in moment t, before the change takes place. From the hazard function, it is possible to obtain the cumulative hazard function with a estimation procedure proposed by Nelson (1972) and Aalen (1978). It is given by the following expression: t Hˆ ( s ) hˆ( s ) (7) s 1 The Kaplan-Meier survivor function for duration t is calculated as the product of one minus the existing risk until period t: nj d j Sˆ (t ) j|t t ( ) j nj (8) 3.2. Parametric analysis The non-parametric analysis is very limited because it does not take into account other variables, apart from duration, that can influence the probability of a regime change. In order to address the issue of other variables determining this probability, we also include in this paper a section dedicated to parametric analysis. In the literature, two frequently used models for adjusting survival functions for the effects of covariates are the accelerated failure-time (AFT) model and the multiplicative or proportional hazard rate (PH) model. In the Proportional Hazard (PH) rate model, the covariates have a multiplicative effect on the hazard function: h(t , X ) h0 (t )* g ( X ) (9) where ho(t) is the baseline hazard function that captures the dependency of data to duration, and g(X) is a nonnegative function of individual variables. A popular choice, and the one adopted here, is to let g(X) equal the relative risk: g(X)=exp(X´β). The function ho(t) may either be left unspecified, yielding the Cox proportional hazard model [see Cox (1972)], or take a specific parametric form. Two models are currently implemented as proportional hazard (PH) models: the Exponential and Weibull models. In the second one, h0(t)=θt θ-1 , where θ is a parameter that has to be estimated. When θ=1, the Weibull Model is equal to the Exponential Model, where there exists no dependency on duration. On the other hand, when the parameter θ>1, there exists a positive dependency on duration, and a negative dependency when θ<1. Therefore, by estimating θ, it is possible to test the hypothesis of duration dependency of the regime changes. Note that in this proportional specification regressors intervene re-escalating the conditional probability to leave the current regime, not its own duration. In the accelerated failure-time model, the natural logarithm of the survival time ln(t) is expressed as a linear function of the covariates, yielding the linear model: ln(t ) X ´ (10) where is the error with density f(.). The distributional form of the error term determines the regression model. If we let f(.) be the normal density, the lognormal regression model is obtained and the associated hazard function is then given by the following expression: 1 1 exp 2 (ln(t ) X ) 2 2 h(t ) t 2 ln(t ) X 1 ( ) (11) where (.) is the standard normal cumulative distribution and is an ancillary parameter to be estimated from the data. On the other hand, when f(.) follows a three-parameter gamma density, the generalized gamma regression is obtained. The hazard function associated with this model depends on the ancillary parameters and , being extremely flexible allowing for a large number of possible shapes. In particular, if =0, we have the lognormal model, and if =1 we obtain the Weibull model. Finally, if =1 and =1, we have the exponential model. Therefore, the generalized gamma model is commonly used for evaluating and selecting an appropriate parametric model from the data. Table 3 shows the parametrization and ancillary parameters for the survival distributions defined for both the PH and AFT models. Each of those alternative models implies a given temporal structure in the data. For example, the Weibull distribution is suitable for modeling data with monotone hazard rates that either increase or decrease exponentially with time, while the exponential distribution is suitable for modeling data with constant hazard. In contrast, the lognormal distribution is indicated for data exhibiting nonmonotonic hazard rates, initially increasing and then decreasing. Finally, the hazard function of the generalized gamma distribution is extremely flexible, allowing for a large number of shapes, including an U-shape. Table 3: Parametric survival distributions Ancillary parameters Distribution Metric Survival function Parametrization Exponential PH exp t exp( X ) Exponential AFT exp t exp( X ) Weibull PH exp ( t ) exp( X ) exp( X ) X X , Weibull AFT Lognormal AFT Generalized gamma AFT exp ( t ) ln(t ) 1 ln(t ) 1 I , exp Note: PH and AFT denote proportional hazard and accelerated failure time respectively. ( z ) is the standard normal cumulative distribution and I , a is the incomplete gamma function. 4. Empirical Results In this section we present the results obtained in the duration analysis of the different regimes in the history of the ERM. We first report the results from the nonparametric analysis using the Kaplan-Meier survival and hazard estimates. We then include the covariates making use of the different parametric models introduced in the previous section. 4.1 Nonparametric estimation The estimate for Kaplan-Meier survival function is shown in Table 4 and Figure 2. This function gives, for each duration spelt, the probability of maintaining the current regime. As can be seen, these probability decreases very rapidly for the short durations (less than 4 quarters), to register then smoother variations as time increases. This behavior suggests that for those regimes with high duration, the ERM would be relatively stable, while for the (more common) regimes associated with short durations the ERM would be more unstable. For the whole sample, the probability of maintaining a certain regime is estimated to be 0.56. Table 4. Kaplan-Meier survivor and hazard function Beg. Net Survivor Hazard Time Total Failure Lost Function Function 1 154 11 22 0.93 0.07 2 121 15 4 0.81 0.12 3 102 19 6 0.66 0.19 4 77 4 0 0.63 0.05 5 73 0 2 0.63 0.00 6 71 1 12 0.62 0.01 7 58 0 2 0.62 0.00 8 56 2 0 0.60 0.04 9 54 4 7 0.55 0.07 10 43 7 0 0.46 0.16 12 36 1 8 0.45 0.03 13 27 1 5 0.43 0.04 15 21 2 5 0.39 0.10 18 14 1 4 0.36 0.07 21 9 4 5 0.20 0.44 Failure Change Analysis Time Duration Figure 2. Kaplan-Meier estimate. All currencies. Kaplan-Meier survival estimate 1.00 0.75 0.50 0.25 0.00 0 5 10 analysis time 15 20 Figure 3 shows the log-log plot for the Kaplan-Meier survival function. As can be seen, this plot reveals convexity rather than linearity, suggesting that a non-monotonic hazard function could be appropriate for our data. The convexity of that function implies that the probability of regime change is an increasing function in t, conditional on duration. This means that the longer the period of regime accumulated until t, the higher the probability that the regime will end in moment t. The estimated hazard function, plotted in Figure 4, enhance this intuition, since its shape indicates a positive-to-negative duration dependence and possibly log-normality. Figure 3. Log Negative Log survivor function Figure 4. Kaplan-Meier hazard estimate Kaplan-Meier hazard estimate 1 .4 -1 h(t) Negative Log SDF 0 .2 -2 0 -3 0 1 2 3 1 5 Log of quarter 10 analysis time 15 20 4.2 Parametric estimation Before proceeding to present the results from the parametric estimation, it is necessary to identify and measure those variables that can influence the probability of a regime change. To that end, we make use of three alternative theoretical frameworks: exchange-rate determination models, first generation models of currency crisis and second generation models of currency crisis. Each of these approaches suggests alternative explanatory variables to be included in the parametric analysis. Regarding the models of exchange rate determination, the flexible-price monetary model [see Frankel (1976), Mussa (1976) and Bilson (1978a, 1978b)] suggests that the (log) of the exchange rate is a function of the relative (logs of) money supply, relative (logs of) real income and relative interest rates: s=s1 + s2(m-m*) - s3( y-y*) +s4( i-i*) (12) where s is the (log of) exchange rate (expressed as the home currency price of a unit of foreign exchange), m is the (log of) money supply, y is the (log of) real income, i is nominal interest rate, and an asterisk denotes a foreign variable. On the other hand, Dornbusch (1976)´s sticky-price model leads to the following relationship between the exchange rate and its fundamental variables: s=s1 + s2(m-m*) - s3( p-p*) -s4( y-y*) (13) where p is the (log of) price level. Given that these models were developed for floating exchange rates, in our empirical investigation for the ERM we will also considered the role of a credibility indicator based on the results in Ledesma-Rodríguez et al. (2001). In particular we use their measure of marginal credibility, since it renders the best indicator to proxy the perception of economic agents with respect to the commitment to maintain the exchange rate around a central parity. Therefore, we will explore the following relationships: h=h1 + h2(m-m*) - h3( y-y*) - h4( i-i*) - h5 credibility (14) and h=h1 + h2(m-m*) - h3( p-p*) - h4( y-y*) - h5 credibility (15) where h denotes, for each duration, the probability that a regime change occurs. As for the first generation models of currency crisis (also called “exogenous policy” models), they are based on the inconsistency, under fixed exchange rates, between domestic expansionary policies (financed by expanding domestic credit) and the exchange rate. This causes a steady loss of international reserves. The inevitable exhaustion of reserves are foreseen by speculators so the final stage of the collapse of the fixed rate is characterised by a speculative attack [see Krugman (1979) and Flood and Garber (1984)]. These models focus on the financial aspects of the problem, paying special attention to nominal variables as determinant of the currency crisis, and therefore the abandon of the fixed exchange rate. In our empirical analysis we will considered the following macroeconomic indicators to evaluate the first generation models of currency crisis: changes in international reserves (ΔR), money supply differential (M-M*), the ratio money supply to reserves (M/R), and an index of equity prices (E). Therefore, we will explore the following relationship3: h= h1 - h2 (ΔR) + h3 (M-M*) + h4 (M/R) – h5 (E) (16) Finally, the second generation models of currency crisis (also called “endogenous policy” models or “escape-clause” models) introduce non-linearities and the reaction of government policies to changes in private behaviour (see Obstfield, 1986, 1996). The commitment to the fixed exchange rate is state dependent, so the government can always exercise an escape clause. Non-linearity is a source of multiple equilibrium, some of which can be stable, others being unstable. Finally, second generation models can explain speculative attacks even when fundamentals are not involved, introducing the idea of “selffulfilling” speculative attacks which can arise even when there is no inconsistency in policy. In contrast with first generation models of currency crisis, second generation models emphasise the role of real variables as potential causes of such crises. We will examine the role of the following variables in explaining the ERM changes: industrial production (IPI), current account balance over GDP (CA/GDP) and the unemployment rate (UR). Therefore, we will explore the following relationship4: h= h1 - h2 (IPI) + h3 (CA/GDP) + h4 (UR) (17) We have assembled quarterly data for these macroeconomic variables from the first quarter of 1979 to the fourth quarter of 1998. The exact definition of the variables as well as the data sources are detailed in the Appendix. Regarding the exchange-rate determination models, since it is not clear which money supply measure is appropriate, we use several candidate data sets. On the other hand, since we do not have quarterly data on We have also considered the changes in money supply (ΔM) and the inflation differential (ΔP- ΔP*), but they never were significant. 4 We also used gross domestic product (GDP) instead of IPI, but the results were qualitatively similar. 3 real income, we use the industrial production indices and the gross domestic product as the indicator of current economic activity. We have estimated the functional forms discussed in Section 2 by maximum likelihood, using 154 observations and 72 changes of regime. In all the estimations we have included as an additional explanatory variable the number of previous changes, but this variable was never statistically significant. Following a “general-to-specific” modelling methodology [see, e. g., Hendry (1995)], equations (14) to (17) were continuously simplified and re-parameterised until a parsimonious representation of the data generation process was arrived at. Table 5 to 7 contain the parameter estimates for the alternative hazard function models for the ERM under the three theoretical approaches. It should be notice that the estimate from an AFT model have the opposite algebraic sign from those obtained from a PH model or from the semiparametric Cox estimation. Therefore, in order to compare directly the parameter estimates and to show the impact on the hazard of each covariates, we report the corrected coefficients for the parametric models. As can be seen in Table 5, in the case of the fundamental variables (i. e., those explanatory variables suggested by the exchange-rate determination models) the covariates are significant and have the expected sign (positive for the money supply differential and negative for the price differential, the credibility indicator and the reserves/GDP ratio) for all the alternative specifications. It seems that the sticky price monetary model augmented with credibility and reserves is a good approximation of the determinants of duration of ERM regimes. Regarding the nominal variables (i. e., those explanatory variables suggested by the first generation models of currency crisis), Table 6 shows that changes in international reserves and the share index are significant in four of the five cases considered, while the money supply differential is only significant in two of the five cases. Note that all the coefficients have the expected sign. Finally, Table 7 reports the results for the case of real variables (i. e., those explanatory variables suggested by the first generation models of currency crisis). As can be seen, both the industrial production index and the CA/GDP ratio are significant and have the expected sign. Tables 5 to 7 also report estimates of the ancillary parameters for the last three distributions. As shown, we find a significant positive duration dependence in the Weibull model, since θ is greater than one (1.409 for the fundamental variables, 1.225 for the monetary variables and 1.205 for the real variables), indicating that as time passes the probability of a realignment increases, in contrast with the empirical hazard function obtained using the Kaplan-Meier method (see Figure 4). Regarding the log-normal model, changes in σ compress or stretch the hazard function and when this parameter is large, the hazard peaks so rapidly that the function is almost indistinguishable from those like the Weibull. In our case, we obtain an estimated value of 0.961 for the fundamental variables, 1.051 for the nominal variables and 1.145 for the real variables. Finally, the shape estimate (κ =0.297 for the fundamental variables, -0.648 for the nominal variables and 0.757 for the real variables) allows us to test the null hypotheses κ =0 and κ =1, to evaluate the validity of the log-normal and Weibull models, respectively. Tables 5 to 7 offer the Wald test and the likelihood ratio (LR) test for each of these hypotheses. The results of the Wald test clearly suggest that for the fundamental variables and for the real variables we can reject neither the null hypothesis κ =0 nor the hypothesis κ=1. In the case of the nominal variables, we reject the hypothesis κ =1 but we cannot reject κ =0, what suggests that the log-normal specification is the most appropriate one in this case5. Also, we can use the likelihood-ratio test (LR) to test the hypothesis that κ=0 or κ=1. All the tests have one degree of freedom, except that for the exponential model versus the generalized gamma model, that has two degrees of freedom. The results are consistent with the ones obtained with the previous test, indicating that the exponential model is not 5 It is interesting to note that the log-normal model is consistent with the non-monotonic empirical hazard function depicted in Figure 4. adequate for our data in the cases of fundamental and nominal variables. As well, there is strong support against rejecting the Weibull model in the case of real variables. As a conclusion, neither the Wald test nor the LR test are helpful in order to choose one particular specification. This result can be due to the lack of power of such test in small samples. Then, to select the particular model which better fit our data, we will use the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC). Akaike (1974) proposes penalizing each log likelihood to reflect the number of parameters being estimated in a particular model and then comparing them. In our case, the AIC can be defined as: AIC 2 * log[ likelihood ] 2(c q 1) (18) where c is the number of model covariates and q the number of model-specific ancillary parameters. As shown in tables 5 to 7, for fundamental and nominal variables the lognormal specification is preferred by the AIC. In contrast, for the real variables we choose the Weibull model. Table 5: Parametric estimation for Fundamental variables. Ln M3 - Ln M3 G Cox Exponential Weibull Log-normal Gamma 0.102** (3.45) -3.811** (-2.92) -1.557** (-4.30) -0.967** (-5.06) - 0.071** (3.54) -3.553** (-2.93) -1.444** (-4.78) -0.946** (-5.29) -0.240 (-0.85) - 0.074** (3.52) -3.347** (-2.64) -1.419** (-4.65) -0.885** (-4.16) -0.323 (-1.04) 0.897** (6.94) 0.297 (0.80) 282.78 (κ =0) 0.65 (κ =1) 1.29 Theta - 0.088** (3.32) -3.215** (-2.34) -1.581** (-4.23) -0.853** (-4.46) -0.405 (-1.07) - Sigma - - 0.078** (3.83) -2.860** (-2.46) -1.330** (-4.43) -0.738** (-4.43) -0.562* (-1.76) 1.409** (13.95) - Kappa - - - 0.961** (14.10) - 581.56 - 293.08 14.30 283.11 2.33 281.16 0.38 P. Index – P. Index G Credibility Reserves/GDP Constant AIC LR[(df=1)] Wald test [(df=1)] No. of subject No. of failures Absolute z-statistics in parentheses. Robust variance-covariance matrix used significant at 10% ; ** significant at 5% G refers to Germany 154 72 Table 6: Parametric estimation for Monetary variables. Reserves Cox Exponential Weibull Log-normal Gamma -0.800 (-2.53) 0.148 (2.67) -0.549* (-1.78) - -0.884** (-3.15) 0.068 (1.29) -0.671** (-3.01) -1.072** (-6.08) - -0.890** (-3.05) -0.011 (-0.09) -0.770** (-2.56) -0.946** (-4.25) 1.108** (11.77) -0.648 (-0.74) 300.84 (κ =0) 0.54 (κ =1) 3.54 Theta - -0.814** (-2.47) 0.140** (2.41) -0.571* (-1.84) -1.328** (-5.84) - Sigma - - -0.700** (-2.51) 0.126** (2.45) -0.544* (-1.91) -1.347** (-4.9) 1.225** (15.21) - Kappa - - - 1.051** (13.99) - 601.03 - 311.59 14.75 306.05 10.21 300.11 1.27 M1-M1G Share Index Constant AIC LR[(df=1)] Wald test [(df=1)] No of subjects No of failures Absolute z-statistics in parentheses. Robust variance-covariance matrix used significant at 10% ; ** significant at 5% G refers to Germany 154 72 Table 7: Parametric estimation for Real variables. IPI Cox Exponential Weibull Log-normal Gamma -2.999** (-2.64) -0.009* (-1.89 - -1.783** (-2.14) -0.008* (-2.10) -0.382 (-0.64) - -2.719** (-2.00) -0.007* (-1.68) 0.197 (0.19) 0.915** (3.19) 0.757 (0.99) 313.20 (κ=0) 0.97 (κ =1) 0.1 Theta - -3.064** (-2.92) -0.008* (-1.69) 0.364 (0.39) - Sigma - - -2.846** (-3.26) -0.007* (-1.70) 0.229 (0.29) 1.205** (15.16) - Kappa - - - 1.145** (14.21) - 601.74 - 313.15 3.95 311.44 0.23 312.19 0.98 C A/GDP Constant AIC LR[(df=1)] Wald test No of subjects No of failures Absolute z-statistics in parentheses. Robust variance-covariance matrix used * significant at 10% ; ** significant at 5% 154 72 5. Heterogeneity In this section we repeat the parametric analysis of the previous section, but now we include a new variable that can control for group heterogeneity. To that end, we have identified two potential groups with different characteristics as shown in Figure 5 and Table 8: - A first group of currencies (that we shall denote as “core”, and that include: FF, BFR, HFL and DKR), with a total of 92 observations, being the average duration 7.17 quarters and 0.42 the average probability of change. - A second group (that we shall denote as “periphery”, formed by: IRL, LIT, PTA and ESC), representing the 40.3% of the observations, being 5.79 quarters the average duration and 0.53 the average probability of change. Table 8. Descriptive statistics by group CORE Change Duration Mean 0.424 7.174 Dev. Std. 0.497 6.475 Variance 0.247 41.925 Skewness 0.308 0.919 Kurtosis 1.095 2.579 Observations PERIPHERY Change Duration 0.532 5.790 0.503 5.087 0.253 25.873 -0.129 0.962 1.017 3.033 92 62 Figure 5: Duration of regimes in the EMS by group CORE PERIPHERY .4 .3 .3 Fraction Fraction .2 .2 .1 .1 0 0 1 5 10 analysis time 15 20 1 5 10 analysis time 15 20 It is interesting to note that these two groups roughly correspond to those found in Jacquemin and Sapir (1996), applying multivariate analysis techniques (i.e., principal components and cluster analysis) to a wide set of structural and macroeconomic indicators, to form an homogeneous group of countries. Moreover, these two groups are basically the same that those found in Fernández-Rodríguez, Sosvilla-Rivero and Andrada-Félix (1999) to have relevant information helping to improve the prediction of currencies in each group based on the behavior of the rest of currencies, information that can be used to generate simple trading rules that outperform the moving average trading rules widely used in the markets [see Fernández-Rodríguez, Sosvilla-Rivero and Andrada-Félix (2002)]. Figure 6 plots the estimated survival functions for the currency groups. As shown, the probability of maintaining a given regime quickly decreases in the short durations (less than five quarters) for both groups. It is interesting to observe that the probability of maintaining the regime in the periphery is smaller than in the core, with graded changes that occur more often and are registered until the end of the period. However, in the core, the probability of maintaining the regime is roughly constant as duration increases. This result would suggest that the currencies in the core have been more stable. Nevertheless, it should be note that the accuracy of the estimator is better for shorter durations, since inferences about very long duration are based on fewer observations. Figure 6. Kaplan-Meier survival estimates by group Kaplan-Meier survival estimates, by group 1.00 0.75 CORE 0.50 0.25 PERIPHERY 0.00 0 5 10 analysis time 15 20 Finally, based on the results from Section 4, for each set of alternative explanatory variables, we have re-estimated the model more appropriate to fit our data (log-normal for the fundamental and nominal variables, and Weibull for the real variables), this time including heterogeneity by groups of currencies. As can be observed in Table 9, the results are consistent with those obtain in tables 5 to 7 in terms of statistically significance and sign of the coefficients, except for the money supply differential (M1-M1*) in the case of the nominal variables and the CA/GDP ratio in the case of the real variables. Notice that the variable “group” (that takes value one for the group of currencies we have denoted as “core”) always shows the correct sign and is significant in two of the three cases. Table 9: Parametric estimation with group heterogeneity Fundamental Monetary Real - - - - - - - - Varitation of Reserves 0.086** (4.50) -2.801** (-2.27) -1.369** (-4.44) -1.120** (-5.54) - - M1 – M1G - Share Index - IPI - -0.888** (-3.22) 0.040 (0.73) -0.782** (-3.44) - C. Account/GDP - - Group -0.482** (-2.13) 0.261 (0.75) - -0.464** (-2.16) -0.814** (-4.27) - -0.007 (-1.41) -0.068 (-0.26) 0.237 (0.30) 1.203** (14.94) Sigma 0.936** (15.57) 1.021** (14.05) Log Likelihood No of subjects No of failures -132.17 -142.48 Ln M3 – Ln M3G Pr. Index – Pr. IndexG Credibility Reserves/GDP Constant Theta Absolute z-statistics in parentheses. Robust variance-covariance matrix used significant at 10% ; ** significant at 5% G refers to Germany -2.813** (-3.12) -151.67 154 72 6. Concluding remarks In this paper we have examined the regime changes in the Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM). To that end, we have applied the duration model approach to quarterly data of eight currencies participating in the ERM, covering the complete EMS history. We have studied the time spells between two consecutive changes in the ERM, estimating the survival and hazard functions of such variable. First, we have made used of the nonparametric (univariate) analysis, concluding that the probability of maintaining the current regime decreases very rapidly for the short durations (less than 4 quarters), to register then smoother variations as time increases. Therefore, for those regimes with high durations, the ERM would have been relatively stable, while for the (more common) regimes associated with short durations would have been more unstable. The probability of maintaining a certain regime is estimated to be 0.56. Second, we have applied a parametric (multivariate) analysis to investigate the role of other variables in the probability of a regime change. In particular we consider three alternative theoretical frameworks to select potential explanatory variables: exchange-rate determination models, first generation models of currency crisis and second generation models of currency crisis. Our results suggest that the money supply differential with Germany would have negatively affected the duration of a given regime, while credibility, price differential with Germany, the reserves/GDP ratio, changes in reserves and the evolution of the Share index would have positively influenced such duration. On the other hand, we have undertaken an exhaustive analysis to compare and validate alternative models, concluding that the log-normal model would be the more appropriate to fit the data in the cases of the variables suggested by the exchange-rate determination models and the first generation models of currency crisis, while the Weibull model could be better in the cases of the explanatory variables proposed by second generation models of currency crisis. Third, when distinguishing between groups of currencies, we observe that those in the core are more stable than those in the periphery. After repeating the estimations including a dummy variable to control for the heterogeneity by groups of currencies, previous findings remained unaltered. We consider that our results are of interest, not only for the European experience in the 1979-1998 period, but also for the analysis of other possible target zones as the new ERM (ERM II), linking the currencies of non-euro area Member States to euro (both current European Union Member States and future candidates) (see ECOFIN, 2000). References: Aalen, O. O., (1978): “Nonparametric Inference for Family of Counting Processes”, Annals of Statistics, 6, 701-726. Akaike, H. (1974): ”A New Look at the Statistical Model Identification”, IEEE Transactions on Automatic Control, AC-19,716-723. Bajo-Rubio, O., Sosvilla-Rivero, S. and Fernández-Rodríguez, F. (2001): “Asymmetry in the EMS: New Evidence Based on Non-linear Forescasts”, European Economic Review, 45, 451-473. Bertola, G. and Caballero, R. (1992): “Target Zones and Realignments”, American Economic Review, 82, 520-530. Bilson, J. F. O. (1978a): “Rational expectations and the exchange rate”, in Frankel, J. A. and Johnson, H. G. (eds.), The Economics of Exchange Rates (Reading, Mass: AddinsonWesley), pp. 75-96. Bilson, J. F. O. (1978b): “ The monetary approach to the exchange rate: Some empirical evidence”, IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 25, pp. 48-79. Commission of the European Communities (1993): “The ERM in 1992” European Economy, 54, 141-157. Cox, D. R. (1972): “Regression Models and Life Tables”, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series B, 34, 187-202. Cox, D. R. y Snell, E. J. (1968): “A General Definition of Residuals (with Discusión)”, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society B, 39, 248-275. ECOFIN (2000): “Questions relating to the applicant countries economic stability and exchange rate strategy: Conclusions”. 2283rd Council meeting, Brussels, July 17 (available at http://ue.eu.int/newsroom/main.cfm1). De Grauwe, P. (2000): Economics of Monetary Union. Fourth Edition,. Oxford: Oxford University Press. De Grauwe, P., Dewachter, H. and Veestraeten, D. (1999): “Explaining recent European exchange-rate stability”, International Finance, Vol. 2, pp. 1-31. Dornbusch, R. (1976): “Expectations and exchange rate adjustments”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 84, pp. 1161-1176. Edin, P. A. and Vredin, A. (1993): “Devaluation Risk in Target Zones: Evidence from the Nordic Countries”, Economic Journal, 103,161-175. Fernández-Rodríguez, F., Sosvilla-Rivero, S. and Andrada-Félix, J. (1999): “Exchange-rate Forecasts with Simultaneous Nearest-neighbour Methods: Evidence from the EMS”, International Journal of Forecasting, Vol. 15, pp. 383-392. Fernández-Rodríguez, F., Sosvilla-Rivero, S. and Andrada-Félix, J. (2002): “Technical Analysis in Foreign Exchange Markets: Evidence from the EMS”, Forthcoming in Applied Financial Economics. Fernández-Rodríguez, F. Sosvilla-Rivero, S. and Martín-González, J. (2002): “Credibility in the EMS: New Evidence Using Nonlinear Forecastability Tests”, forthcoming in European Journal of Finance. Flood, R, P. and Garber, P. M. (1984): “Collapsing exchange-rate regimes: Some linear examples”, Journal of International Economics, Vol. 17, pp. 1-13. Frankel, J. A. (1976): “A monetary approach to the exchange rate: Doctrinal aspects and empirical evidence”, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 78, pp. 200-224. Hendry, D. F. (1995): Dynamic Econometrics (Oxford: Oxford University Press). Jacquemin, A. and Sapir, A. (1996): “Is a European Hard Core Credible? A Statistical Analysis”, Kyklos, 49, 105-117. Kaplan, E. L. And Maier, P. (1958): “Nonparametric Estimation from Incomplete Observations”, Journal of the American Statistical Association, 53, 457-481. Kiefer, N. M. (1988): “Economic Duration Dat and Hazard Functions”, Journal of Economic Literature, 26, 646-679. Krugman, P. (1979) : “A model of balance-of-payments crises”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 11, pp. 311-325. Krugman, P. (1991): “Target Zones and Exchange Rate Dynamics”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 669-682. Ledesma-Rodríguez, F., Navarro-Ibáñez, M, Pérez-Rodríguez, J. and Sosvilla-Rivero, S. (2001): “Assessing the Credibility of a Target Zone: Evidence from the EMS”, Documento de Trabajo 2001-04, FEDEA (available at ftp://ftp.fedea.es/pub/Papers/2001/dt200104.pdf). Mussa, M. (1976): “the exchange rate, the balance of payments, and monetary and fiscal policy under a regime of controlling floating”, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 78, pp. 229-248. Nelson, W. (1972): “Theory and Applications of Hazard Plotting for Censored Failure Data”, Technometrics, 14, 945-965. Obstfield, M. (1986): “Rational and self-fulfilling balance-of-payments crisis”, American Economic Review, Vol. 76, pp. 71-81. Obstfield, M. (1996): “Models of currency crisis with self-fulfilling features”, European Economic Review, Vol. 40, pp. 1037-1048. Sosvilla-Rivero, S., Fernández-Rodríguez, F., and Bajo-Rubio, O (1999): “Exchange Rate Volatility in the EMS Before and After the Fall”, Applied Economics Letters, 6, 717-722. Svensson, L.E.O. (1991): “The Simplest Test of Target Zone Credibility”, IMF Staff Papers, 38, 655-665. Svensson, L.E.O. (1992): “An Interpretation of Recent Research on Exchange Rate Target Zones”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 6-4, 119-144. Weber, A. (1991): “EMS Credibility”, Economic Policy, 12, 58-102. APPENDIX: Definition of the variables and data sources for the parametric estimation A) Variable names and definitions: Dependent variable: Probability of change Explanatory variables: CA = current account balance (IFS, line 78ald). credibility = marginal credibility indicator αt, defined as: st - Et-1(st) = γ + αt [ct - Et-1(st)] + ut (16) where ct is the logarithm of the central parity, the expectation operator is conditional to the information available in t-1, and ut is a random disturbance. Note that different value of αt is obtain for each time period in the sampler. Share Index = share price index (MEI). i= short-term interest rate (IFS, line 60c). M= money supply: M1= local currency (IFS, line 34 a.u) + deposits (IFS, line 34.b.u) M3= M1 + quasi-money (IFS) ΔM = changes in money supply M/R = the ratio money supply to reserves Y= real income: GDP = gross domestic product (IFS line 99b.c) IPI = index of industrial production (MEI) P= consumer price index (IFS, line 64) R= international reserves (IFS, line 1l.d) UR = unemployment rate (IFS, line 67r) B) Data sources The data base is the International Financial Statistics (IFS) published by the International Monetary Fund and Main Economic Indicators (MEI) published by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.