Egypt Unwrapped We wish to wholeheartedly thank the sponsors of this report, whose kind support made it possible: Diamond Technology Partners, C-N-A, Deutsche Bank, and Pfizer. Introduction Egypt is the Nile. The vast majority of its growing population lives in a fertile, narrow stretch along this life-sustaining river. The rest of the country is essentially uninhabitable desert. This particular fate of geography has shaped Egyptian life for more than five thousand years, and its legacy lives on today. The need to control the Nile has forever promoted the existence of a dominant Egyptian state. The reason is simple: if a state could control this single critical resource, it could control the population narrowly confined to its banks. Thus, the state has always played a central role in Egyptian society, from the time of the pharaohs down to the present day. This central state, and its strong instinct for self-preservation, is therefore the crucial variable for understanding the political and economic future of Egypt. Faced with a large and growing population which strains existing resources, every move taken by the Egyptian government is intended to preserve or strengthen its own control. Politically, this means domination of domestic politics, brutal suppression of Islamist opposition, and control of the media. Economically, this means advancing economic reforms, but only those which do not threaten political stability or undermine the 1 power of the regime. Socially, this means an attempt to co-opt the world’s most important seat of Sunni Islam – al Azhar University. And externally, this means support of the Middle East peace process, but more importantly, a policy which allows its citizens to blame Israel for many of Egypt’s own economic and political shortcomings. (Denial isn’t just a river in Egypt, it seems). This crucial variable of the state, and its relationship with economics, religion, and foreign policy forms the basis of our report and resulting conclusions. It also provides the paper with a natural structure. We begin with a look at Cairo’s current modern-day pharaoh, President Hosni Mubarak, and his one-party government. I. The State The prominent Cairo journalist, Max Rodenbeck, has called Egypt the “in name only” state1. It is a democracy, in name only. It has an independent parliament, in name only. Opposition parties exist, in name only. In reality, the only name that matters in Egypt is Mubarak. The president, along with a small group of mostly military elite, firmly controls the country through domination of Egypt’s political process and brutal suppression of any and all opposition. Most policies exist to strengthen or maintain the power of this ruling elite, where the instinct for selfpreservation trumps all other concerns. A. The Presidency On October 6th, 1981, Egypt’s Vice President Hosni Mubarak was standing near President Anwar Sadat when the Islamic group Al-Jihad opened fire. Sadat was murdered, and eight days later, the 53--year old Mubarak was sworn in as president. 1 Max Rodenbeck, “Cairo, The City Victorious.” 2 Over these past 18 years, Mubarak has ruled Egypt with a cautious mix of economic liberalization and domestic authoritarianism – taking great care to emphasize domestic social stability, no matter the cost. He has continued the economic liberalization policies launched by his predecessor, though these efforts have slowed in recent years as privatization of domestic industry threatens to exacerbate unemployment and social unrest. Externally, Mubarak has strongly supported the Middle East peace process, and has been broadly successful at rebuilding Egypt's ties to the Arab world.2 Egypt’s 1971 Constitution grants broad powers to the President – a legacy of the Gamal Abdel-Nasser era. The president has the ability to veto all legislation, appoint prime ministers, provincial governors, armed forces and security heads, major religious figures, and High Court judges. He is also supreme commander of the armed forces. Moreover, the president has the power to rule by decree, and for all but eight of the past 61 years Egypt has lived under an official state of emergency whereby laws are created by the mere utterance of the president.3 In addition, all elections are “forged” to maintain the regime’s power base. 4 The result of this government structure (and its robust system of political patronage) is near total domination of the Egyptian state by one individual. This concentration of power raises serious questions about stability in the event of the sudden departure of Mubarak (not an idle worry following three known assassination attempts against the president).5 In particular, the absence of an obvious successor to Mubarak is of some concern. The president has steadfastly 2 Egypt finally rejoined the Arab League in May 1989, after its 1977 Camp David Accord with Israel left the country a political pariah throughout the Arab world. 3 In recent years this official state of emergency has been a response to domestic terror attacks by radical Islamists. Since this threat has receded a bit, more cynical observers point to this year’s three year extension of the emergency laws as evidence of the regime’s continued opposition to political pluralism in general. This official state of emergency also legitimizes the state’s control of the media. Article 48 of the Egyptian constitution reads: “In a state of emergency or in time of war a limited censorship may be imposed on the newspapers, publications and mass media in matters related to public safety or purposes of national security in accordance with the law.” 4 From interviews with Professor Gehad Auda, Political Science Department, Helwan University, Cairo. 5 Most experts believe that if Mubarak departs suddenly, constitutional procedures of succession (Article 84) would likely be enacted; namely, the Speaker of the People’s Assembly, Fathi Sorour, would assume power until the military’s National Defense Council put forth a candidate for the assured approval by the People’s Assembly. In short, a few weeks of nervousness would be followed by a return to state-controlled stability. 3 refused to name a vice president. The reason, not surprisingly, goes back to Mubarak’s prime goal of stability. If there is no alternative to the president, there is almost no chance of a rival power rising from within the government to challenge him.6 B. The Military Another critical component to state power in Egypt is the military. It has produced every leader since 1952 (including former Air Force Commander Mubarak), and sees itself as the ultimate arbiter of power in the country.7 Egypt’s military is among the largest in the Middle East. Active armed forces number some 450,000 -- with more than half in the army.8 Conscription is selective, with service for three years. Aided in large part by an ongoing, U.S.-supplied military modernization program, Egypt’s air force is formidable. Meanwhile, the wellarmed, British-trained navy, in the words of one retired Egyptian diplomat – is “crackerjack.”9 Backed by this political and armament power, Egypt’s military plays a crucial role in the administration of the state. It must be viewed as a significant player in all domestic, foreign, and as will be demonstrated below, economic affairs of the country. C. The Parliament A third, though in many ways less important, component of the Egyptian state is the Parliament. It consists of a 454-member People’s Assembly, and a 210 member Several of our interview subjects quietly suggested that Mubarak, if he did not orchestrate Sadat’s assassination, at least had some prior knowledge of it. Thus, the lack of an obvious successor suggests the president does not want this bloody history to repeat itself. This conspiracy claim is, of course, impossible for us to prove. 7 This is more than just custom. The military’s right (through the creation of a National Defense Council) to ensure the “safety and security of the country” is enshrined in the Egyptian Constitution (Chapter VII, Articles 180-83). 8 The International Institute for Strategic Studies, London. 9 From interview with retired Egyptian diplomat Taksim Bashir. 6 4 Advisory Council. Both bodies are dominated by the ruling National Democratic Party, but do not be fooled by the name. The National Democratic Party (NDP), which effectively controls local government, the mass media, organized labor, and Egypt’s substantial public sector, is securely under Mubarak’s thumb. 10 The NDP (the successor of Nasser’s Arab Socialist Union) is protected by elections that are conducted to ensure large ruling party majorities. The most egregious example of this occurred during parliamentary elections in 1995, when after severe violence (including the deaths of more than 70 people), and government interference, more than 94% of the parliamentary seats went to the NDP – a margin of victory that strains the credulity of even the most liberal interpretations of Egyptian democracy. Perhaps the most striking feature of Egypt’s parliamentary structure is the lack of a viable opposition. In theory, fourteen opposition parties exist. In reality, these parties have had to operate under numerous restrictions, and have been “insulated from decision-making with an efficiency that can hardly be found elsewhere in the world.”11 A democracy, in name only, indeed. (There is a serious and perhaps self-defeating downside to this brutal suppression of political opposition: it drives disenchanted Egyptian citizens into the arms of radical Islamic groups – a topic explored below in greater detail). D. The Bureaucracy To most Egyptians, however, the State does not mean the president, the military, or even their “elected” parliament. Rather, the day-to-day relationship with the ubiquitous Egyptian government is experienced through an oppressive, highly inefficient, and ever maddening bureaucracy. According to our various interview subjects, significant legislative measures – such as the recent law giving Egyptian women the right to divorce their husbands – only pass when the President demands it. And if you do not support him, you do not remain in the parliament. 11 Eberhard Kienle, “More Than a Response to Islamism: The Political Deliberalization of Egypt in the 1990s” Middle East Journal, Spring 1998. 10 5 Nasser’s 1960s-era promise of a guaranteed government job for every graduate has resulted in a 21st Century army of ridiculously under-worked, underpaid, low-skilled time-killers.12 They can be seen throughout the country, from army officers loitering on nearly every street corner, to sleepy ticket tellers, to our group’s personal favorite example of this over-bloated workforce – a man operating the automatic teller machine at a Cairo bank. You hand him your card -- he punches in the numbers and hands back your money and card.13 The symbol of this government waste is the Mogamma -- an imposing, Kafkaesque monument to bureaucracy in Downtown Cairo where 18,000 civil servants “work”. For those Egyptians unlucky enough to require a simple service such as a new drivers’ license or passport, this often means several days of long lines, endless delays, and countless trips back and forth to various teller windows. 14 The inefficiencies of Mogamma are legendary throughout Egypt. In fact, it is the setting of the popular Egyptian film Irhab and Kebab, where in a moment of maddening frustration, the film’s protagonist takes several hostages in an attempt to win better government service. He fails. So, too, may Egypt if this unsustainable situation is allowed to continue indefinitely. E. Strong State/Weak State The resulting structure of the Egyptian state is, therefore, something of a paradox. On one hand, it is brutally efficient at maintaining firm control on law and order, particularly with regard to any potential threats to its power. In this regard, the Egyptian government is strong, and has the potential to dominate the life of each and every citizen. 12 The full employment for graduates policy was officially suspended in 1990, but Egypt still lives with its effects. 13 Worker productivity is, not surprisingly, non-existent. According to several of our interview subjects, recent studies of Egyptian state workers conclude the average Egyptian government employee spends seven MINUTES a day actually performing work. 14 Interviews with NPR correspondent Dale Gavlack, and Cairo AFL-CIO executive Heba Shazli. 6 But in a more important sense, this almost desperate dependency on order, stability, and dogged suppression of dissenting opinion hides the Egyptian state’s inherent weakness. Its priorities are not building roads or schools, or collecting taxes, or fostering business, or even enforcing basic traffic laws. The focus is on the maintenance of elite power, whatever the broader societal costs. It is this strong state/weak state paradox that colors Egypt’s dealings with economic liberalization, its relationship with Islam, and its foreign policy. We move now to perhaps the country’s most daunting challenge: reform of the economy. II. The Economy The following section is an examination of another crucial variable for Egypt’s short-term future: the government’s attempts to liberalize the country’s formerly socialist economy. 15 In short, economic reform in Egypt gained momentum in the early 1990s, but has slowed dramatically in recent years as the privatization of industry, and greater exposure to foreign competition risks higher unemployment and greater social instability. Thus, in accordance with its primary goal of maintaining power, the government has put a strong emphasis on gradualism.16 This section will briefly explore the two phases of economic liberalization that have occurred in Egypt – macroeconomic and microeconomic reforms – and the 15 Centralized state planning and ownership, social welfare services, state-directed industrial policies, and the nationalization of banks and other key economic sectors characterized the economy under President Gamal Abdel-Nasser. Egypt has been moving toward a free market economic since Sadat declared an Open Door policy in 1974. 16 There is a historical precedent for this government caution: severe rioting in 1977 followed government proposals to withdraw food subsidies. The surest way to incite political unrest in Egypt has been to take the food off the table. This helps explain Egypt’s continued subsidization of food, as well as other crucial commodities like water, petrol, and natural gas. 7 resulting successes and failures. It will conclude with a brief summary of some of the major challenges facing the government as it attempts further economic liberalization. A. Liberalization Phase I (Macro Reforms) In some respects, Egypt can be seen as the poster child of the developing world. The country has, indeed, converted from the Nasser Era’s governmentdominated economy to “a very model of an modern emerging market: the IMF’s star pupil fighting its way out of the central planning stranglehold.”17 There is no better evidence of this transformation than Egypt’s macroeconomic indicators: an average annual growth rate of about 4.5%, inflation below 4%, and foreign reserves of about $15 billion. 18 (See Figure 1 for a more complete picture of Egypt’s recent macroeconomic performance).19 This macroeconomic stabilization has been the most successful aspect of Egypt’s liberalization program. It was, in many ways, the response to severe economic difficulties that Egypt experienced during the 1980s – a crisis that forced Nadine El Sherif, “Skin Deep: Economic Reform in Egypt,” Business Today, March 2000. The Economist Intelligence Unit 19 Figure 1 17 18 91/92 41.8 92/93 93/94 47.2 52.9 GDP ($bn) Population 54 56 (MM) Real GDP 1.9 2.5 growth (%) Trade (6.17) (7.0) balance ($bn) 94/95 60.2 95/96 67.7 96/97 75.6 97/98 82.5 98/99 85.5 57 58 59 60 62 65 3.9 4.7 5.0 5.3 5.7 6.0 (7.3) (7.85) (9.5) (9.8) (11.8) (12.5) Source: Central Bank of Egypt Annual Report, 98/99 8 the Egyptian government into action. Moreover, IMF and World Bank assistance, periodic Paris Club debt rescheduling, and the creation of a European Union sponsored Social Fund for Development which alleviated some of the pain of change – all played a supportive role in the continuance of macroeconomic reform.20 But in addition to the obvious economic advantages, these macroeconomic reforms were allowed to proceed because they did not threaten the Egyptian government’s control. They did not result in sharply higher unemployment, riots, or any other form of social or political instability.21 In short, they strengthened the government’s legitimacy and were, therefore, actively encouraged by Cairo’s ruling elite.22 B. Liberalization Phase II (Micro Reforms) This has not been the case with Phase II of economic liberalization – the microeconomic reforms witnessed largely through Egypt’s 10-year old privatization program. The privatization of Egyptian state industry has slowed significantly in recent years, due mainly to issues of government control. There are several layers to this state unease over continued privatization, which touch upon various economic, political, and social factors. One crucial problem is the state’s concern about rising unemployment. The government has already sold off its most profitable companies; thus, the most inefficient and weakest remain. These companies are invariably overstaffed, and a more efficient management of these remaining firms would require widespread layoffs 20 The Economist Intelligence Unit This scenario is also supported by academic theories of collective action; in particular, the inherent difficulties of large societal groups to oppose society-wide government policies such as monetary or fiscal policies. For further reading see Joanne Gowa’s “Public Goods and Political Institutions: Trade and Monetary Policy Processes in the United States,” International Organization, 42 (Winter 1988) and Mancur Olson’s Logic of Collective Action, Harvard University Press. 22 From interviews with Gehad Auda, Professor at Helwan University, Cairo. 21 9 – raising the prospects for social unrest.23 Hence, the government incentive for further privatization is lessened. Another hurdle to further privatization is the state’s unease with foreign control of key industries – a situation hardly unique to Egypt. The most illustrative example of this dilemma is being played out in Egypt’s cement industry. Several cement companies have been privatized in the last decade and now make up 15% of the capitalization of the Egyptian stock market. This success attracted strong interest from several large foreign cement companies (Blue Circle, British Cement Company and CEMEX to name a few). This interest provoked concern in Egypt that a “sensitive” sector of the economy might fall under the control of foreigners. The latest indications are that the government will now attempt to limit foreign ownership in the sector.24 In both of those examples, government concerns about its own power – manifest in a loss of control due to either social instability, or through foreign ownership – lie at the heart of this privatization slowdown. These government concerns will continue for the foreseeable future, and thus, privatization is likely to proceed only at a slow, gradual pace. C. Other Limitations Somewhat ironically, privatization itself has exacerbated Egypt’s serious unemployment problem, as many state firms raced to trim their bloated labor forces to make themselves more attractive to potential investors. 24 A final obstacle to microeconomic reform has been more cultural in nature. The entry of British grocery chain Sainsbury clearly illustrates this aspect. Most Egyptians frequently purchase small amounts of groceries from small markets at which there are no fixed prices. Sainsbury realized that a larger grocery store with fixed prices would be more efficient by reducing the time (and search costs) customers spent shopping and by reducing the number of people required to sell the groceries. Naturally, the small market owners realized the threat, and applied political pressure to prevent Sainsbury’s expansion. The culmination of the ordeal was for Mubarak himself to intervene and promise that Sainsbury would be able to continue operations. Clearly the private company will be able to offer better services at lower costs -- a net economic gain. However, this illustrates the power politics often has over economics in Egypt. 23 10 Egypt’s economy also suffers from several other limitations -- many of which result from the shortcomings of the country’s strong state/weak state structure. Countless books, articles, and PHDs have been written about these various problems, and rightly so. In the interest of time, a brief mention a few of the most serious hurdles still facing the Egyptian economy follows. i. No effective economic institutions/rule of law As this paper has attempted to demonstrate, the institutions that matter in Egypt are the presidency, and the military. Government institutions to adequately manage, regulate, tax, or police economic activity simply do not exist.25 In addition, Egypt’s legal and regulatory systems remain ineffective. Simple lawsuits can drag on for 1o or more years, while the government lacks the will or capacity to enforce many basic rules (such as traffic regulations) -- to say nothing of more complex issues such as intellectual property or copyright laws.26 In short, this centralization of presidential and military power leads to great economic inefficiencies, and stifles economic growth . ii. State domination alters incentive structures, and fosters corruption The strong state/weak state paradox also breeds a more sinister element. In order for many businesses to survive (to say nothing of prospering), managers must develop relationships with the relevant state powers. This promotes an economic incentive structure based not on higher profits and improved productivity, but rather, 25 Those economic institutions that do exist remain highly ineffectual. We learned that it takes several years for Egyptians to earn a license to start a business (remember the Mogamma!). Thus, budding businessmen must either fight the bureaucracy, or act illegally. In either case, the economy suffers. 26 Patent and copyright laws remain mere suggestions. For instance, we saw several products in the grocery stores where a copyright was violated. Our favorite was seeing “copycat” Disney figures playing with children at a popular Nile resort. This lack of enforcement could have severe economic consequences: Without the proper protection of copyrights, companies will hesitate to invest in their brands and may not enter the Egyptian market at all. 11 on these relationships.27 Taken to extremes, this structure also promotes corruption through outright bribery and other illegal and inefficient means. iii. Lack of education/training A final, though crucial, limitation of the Egyptian economy is the state’s inability to operate an effective educational system. Egypt simply is not producing the kinds of workers that a modern economy requires. This is not due to a lack of effort on the state’s part. Government expenditure on education has steadily increased over the past two decades, and now reaches nearly 5% of GDP.28 Moreover, the government has made university education virtually free. But the state’s education strategy has failed on at least two counts. First, the notion of “free education” is something of a misnomer. Students entering university must first pass an difficult entrance exam; thus, only those students with families that can afford the high costs of private schools and personal tutors are admitted to university. But even for those fortunate enough to win admission, the quality of education in general is substandard. The educational system emphasizes memorization techniques, rather than critical or analytical problem solving. Thus, “their knowledge does not help the society to grow.”29 Moreover, there are no real links between the educational system and Egypt’s business community – further widening the divide between the needs of a modern economy, and what Egypt is capable of providing. We move now to the paper’s third crucial variable – the role of religion in Egyptian society. 27 A Cairo journalist conveyed the best example of this warped incentive structure to us. His close friend is the CEO of Egypt’s largest dairy producer. Every few months or so, a high-ranking general in the military will stroll into his office, sit down, and say, “You know, my friend, the army needs a million gallons of milk. We, of course, cannot pay you.” The CEO has no choice but to provide the milk. But the company is allowed to survive, and even prosper, as a result of this relationship with the military. 28 From interviews with Heba Shazli, and Nadine Sherif’s “Skin Deep: Economic Reform in Egypt,” Business Today, March 2000. 29 Mahmoud Ads El Fadil, Economic Department, Cairo University. 12 III. Role of Religion Religion in Egypt is a way of life, as much a part of the culture as camels and the desert, coffee shops and sheesha. The unmistakable call to prayer envelops Egypt five times daily, as it does throughout the Arab world. The Islamic religion that brings communities together and inspires pious living in the masses, however, also hides a dark underbelly of radical fundamentalist groups. Rallying around common frustrations and feelings of oppression, these groups operate according to specific political and social agendas, usually targeted at the state. Although they represent a minority of the population, these groups are powerful because they attract the most frustrated, vulnerable, and growing segment of Egypt’s population – the unemployed educated.30 We will explore two aspects of the state’s relationship with this crucial variable of religion, beginning with its brutal relationship with radical Islamists. We will then examine Cairo’s attempts to co-opt Al-Azhar University – the world’s oldest university and the very center of Sunni Islam. The Islamic Threat In the wake of the November 1997 slaughter of 58 foreign tourists in Luxor by the Gamaat Islamiya (Islamic Group), Egypt remains wary of all Islamic extremist groups. In response to this incident and others, such as assassination attempts on Mubarak by both Al-Jihad in 1993 and Gamaat Islamiya in 1995, the central government has taken measures to weaken the power structures of these organizations. This involves violent crackdowns on well-known Islamic factions, and 30 From interviews with former Egyptian diplomat Taksim Bashir. 13 heightened security in tense and highly populated areas, especially those most frequented by tourists. The government’s efforts to undermine the powers of extremist groups, however, fall far short of ensuring that terrorist activity will not resume in the future. In fighting Islamic violence, “Mubarak’s administration is tactically successful but strategically unsuccessful.”31 While the government has acted swiftly and brutally in retaliation against those groups directly responsible for past violence, its ability to foresee where and when future strikes could occur remains handicapped. As such, the ongoing threat of violence is real. Although the government can mandate the most coercive punishment imaginable upon violent offenders, the damage is already done. Despite the existence of violent factions, most Islamic groups are peaceful entities existing primarily to promote their beliefs from an ideological standpoint, and from a social standpoint, to provide basic services (especially those that the government cannot or will not provide). After a 1992 earthquake that left the Cairo slums in shambles, for example, Islamic rescue groups were on the scene days before any government sponsored aid. This poses a problem for the government in that it cannot distinguish peaceful organizations from violent intentions. As a result, the government, operating in a state of paranoia, must suspect any such organization as being potentially dangerous. The best example of this situation occurred in the low-income Cairo neighborhood Imbaba. After coping with years of poverty and neglect, the neighborhood experienced a renewal under the authority of a local Islamic faction. Feeling empowered by its progress, the community sealed itself off from the rest of the city and declared itself “The Republic of Imbaba” (essentially thumbing its nose at the society that neglected it). This obviously raised a red flag and the ensuing reaction was a disaster – the government leveled the neighborhood and destroyed all that the locals had done to improve their meager existence. Other organized, non-violent Islamic groups, notably the Muslim Brotherhood, continue to threaten the stability of the central regime by seeking change through 31 From interviews with former Egyptian diplomat Taksim Bashir. 14 legal, legislative means. Though they have never been held responsible for any violent or illegal activities, members of the Muslim Brotherhood continue to be arrested and imprisoned by government authorities, particularly during election times. A. Al-Azhar University32 No relationship better demonstrates both 1) the reach of the Egyptian state’s power, and 2) the lack of foresight with which it wields this power, than that between the central government and Al-Azhar University, a Muslim institution of higher learning that, not coincidentally, is the country’s official interpreter of Islam. Hence, the state calls upon Al-Azhar to support government policies, thereby reinforcing Cairo’s religious credibility and undermining more radical Islamist views. The state has traditionally maintained this favor by transferring a steady stream of administrative authority to the university. In recent years, however, the stream has increased to a regular flow. So the state may find itself in an unsustainable situation in which its former servant not so slowly becomes its master. i. Some background The state, in its ongoing battle with Islamic fundamentalist groups, originally “recruited” Al-Azhar’s services by putting pressure on the ulama (scholars and clergymen) to support its policies.33 The ensuing resistance led to the resignation of university officials, allowing the state to appoint more sympathetic replacements. Since entering office, however, Mubarak has gone to this well far too many times, ceding more power to Al-Azhar, which is happily pursuing its own agenda. By relying so strongly on this institution as a source of religious credibility, the government, Steven Barraclough, “Al-Azhar: Between the Government and the Islamists”, Middle East Journal. This is hardly a new technique in Egypt. Cairo’s rulers have used Al-Azhar in this capacities for centuries, thus reinforcing the notion that nothing is new in the world’s oldest civilization. 32 33 15 realizing that it has no other means of establishing Islamic credentials, can no longer afford to oppose it. ii. Al-Azhar’s Agenda Al-Azhar’s agenda is to establish itself as legislative decision making authority in its own right by leveraging its position of power between the central government and the Islamic right. It is meeting this goal with great success, as the government has no choice but to comply. Should the government attempt to renege on the arrangement, Al-Azhar simply comes out with a position that is not in accordance with that of the government. As a result, Al-Azhar has managed to wield significant influence over such national institutions as the Egyptian media and the legal system.34 The result has been a gradual, though undeniable, rightward shift in Egyptian society. There is currently no foreseeable resolution to the government’s power struggle with Al-Azhar. If anything, Al-Azhar’s influence is gaining momentum as the government has recently agreed to give the university control over a network of 50,000 private mosques known as ahli mosques, an institution in and of itself that is vital in the recruitment and organization of Islamists. Additional dangers lurk as the ideologies of Al-Ahzar and the Muslim Brotherhood threaten to converge just as the former continues to gain power, and the aforementioned unemployed, educated masses become increasingly frustrated and susceptible to the Islamic right. One is left to wonder how much more power the government can afford to cede to Al-Azhar. B. The Coptic Situation 34 Council of State ruling 58/163 provides Al-Azhar with the power to censor the electronic media. Television scripts, for example, are, according to the magazine Ruz al-Yusif, “as a matter of routine sent to Al-Azhar for its approval.” While the law contains a proviso that limits Al-Azhar’s rulings in such matters to “Islamic issues”, it is left to Al-Azhar to decide what constitutes an “Islamic issue”. Additionally, a Ministry of Health decree forbidding female circumcision was ruled against in 1997 based in part on AlAzhar’s strong support of the practice. The decision was later overturned due to international pressures. 16 Another important source of religious instability in Egypt arises from the Coptic Christian community that “officially” comprises 10% of the country’s population35. Blatantly discriminated against, this religious group, which is generally relegated to the rural areas of Upper Egypt, demonstrated its frustrations during a violent outbreak in January between the Muslims and Coptic Christians in the town of AlKosheh. While not insignificant, and most definitely indicative of repressed prejudices on the part of the Muslims and frustrations on the part of the Copts, the incident was primarily an isolated one, triggered by the hardships of life in an economically impoverished land.36 More significant are the expatriate Coptic communities around the world that are pushing their own governments to pressure Egypt to recognize the rights of the Coptic population and curb existing discrimination.37 The Coptic situation – and Cairo’s often-brutal repression of it -- harms Egypt’s international image and could affect its foreign aid receipts. Aware of this threat, Mubarak has already enhanced security in certain regions and hosted meetings aimed at religious reconciliation. IV. Egyptian Foreign Policy A final variable crucial to Egypt’s economic and political future involves its foreign policy – in particular, Egypt’s relations with Israel, and Cairo’s role in the Middle East peace process. In short, we argue that a further warming of relations with its traditional enemy, and broader peace in the region, will have a modestly 35 According to several of our interview subjects, the Copts comprise a much higher percentage of the population, perhaps as much as 20%. 36 Every one of our interview subjects shared this belief. 37 There was a recent bill - introduced by the Christian Coalition - before the US Congress, for example, to deny USAID to countries that persecute Christians. Egypt was on the list along with China, Sudan, and Pakistan. 17 beneficial impact on the Egyptian economy. However, the Egyptian government derives some political advantages from maintaining an adversarial role with Israel. A. The Peace Process i. Some (limited) economic benefits Egyptian-Israeli relations reached a "cold peace" after the 1978 Camp David Agreement – a vast improvement from the hostility that had dominated the region since Israel's founding in 1948.38 The agreement has resulted in freer trade and travel between the two countries. However, it has only amounted to limited economic benefit for Egypt. Furthermore, the agreement has actually hurt Egypt's relations with the rest of the Arab world. Improvements on either front will not be a critical factor in Egypt's long-term economic success. However, normalization with Israel, or a broader Middle East peace may marginally improve Egypt's economy. Egypt's relations with Israel are best described as a situation of “tolerance.” 39 This has led to limited trade between the two neighbors. A further normalization of relations would allow for a more open exchange of trade and investment. This could give a slight boost to Egyptian exports (such as cotton, oil, oil products, and shoes), as well as provide Egyptian workers with another potential market for their services. Furthermore, it could create some additional small business and entrepreneurial opportunities for Egyptians. ii. The onus removed? We hesitate to use this “cold peace” cliché, but since every single interview subject referred to it, it is included in the spirit of authentic research. 39 From interview with CNN Jerusalem Bureau Chief Walter Rodgers. 38 18 Warmer relations between Egypt and Israel have also strained Cairo’s relations with the rest of the Arab world, as Sadat's peace with Israel was viewed by many Arabs as a betrayal. In particular, Saudi Arabia and the UAE were so enraged by Sadat's actions that they went as far as to cut off aid to Egypt, and reduce the number of Egyptian workers allowed in the respective countries. Today, twenty-two years after Camp David, Israel and Syria are in the midst of peace negotiations. This creates an opportunity for Egypt to improve its regional role and, perhaps, its economy. In short, Israel-Syrian peace could remove the onus from Egypt's initial move to peace. After Israel makes peace with Syria (and reaches some type of accommodation with the Palestinians), Egypt will no longer have any stigma attached to it in the Arab world. It will no longer be the primary betrayer of Arab principle. This may result in increased Gulf aid, increased Gulf work for Egypt and its people, and greater trade opportunities throughout a more peaceful region. Again, we must stress that these psychological effects of a broader peace, though significant on some levels, will have only a marginal economic impact. B. Israel as useful “enemy” A more important and interesting aspect of Egypt’s foreign policies is domestic in nature. Clearly there are benefits to peace between Egypt and Israel. However, Israel also plays a useful "enemy" role for Egypt, and thus, the government also has a stake in maintaining this status quo. In short, the Egyptian government uses Israel to channel any anger of the people away from itself. It accomplishes this task to great effect. When disaster occurs, or the economy weakens, the people often direct the blame outward – and almost invariably at Israel. In fact, people tend to go as far as to create conspiracy theories in order to explain Egyptian failures, shortcomings, or tragedies. Moreover, the state-controlled Egyptian media further drives outward blame or conspiracy theories. This strategy helps the government 19 control the population by directing blame and focusing attention away from the ruling elite in Cairo and its problems. In short, an Israel-as-enemy domestic orientation is a useful tool for the government’s primary goal of maintaining power.40 V. Conclusions This paper has argued that for geographical, historical, social, and economic reasons, a dominant central state has always been a crucial factor in Egypt. This variable, therefore, is the key to understanding the country’s economic and political future. In particular, the Egyptian government’s desire for stability and control has resulted in a strong state/weak state paradox: it has absolute power to toss any citizen in jail, yet it is nearly powerless to collect taxes, build a road, or provide much beyond the basic social services that a modern nation requires. This structure then plays out across all aspects of society – from economic policy, to religion, to foreign policy. With that in mind, we offer the following conclusions for Egypt’s short-term political and economic future, as well as its prospects for stability. 40 A recent example of the use of conspiracy to drive blame outwards occurred when Egyptian farmers became concerned with the low market price of potatoes. In order to increase the price of potatoes, the farmers reduced the supply by hoarding a large amount of them in warehouses throughout Egypt. Once market prices of potatoes increased, the farmers began releasing the excess supply for sale to the public. The farmers had, however, used high (lethal) levels of preservatives to keep the potatoes edible while in storage for so long. Therefore, once the public consumed the potatoes, people became ill and even died. Instead of looking to the obvious source, the people looked to the useful "enemy." Over time, a conspiracy theory arose. According to Egyptians, Israel had dug tunnels from Israel to the warehouses in Egypt where they poisoned the potatoes! Israel became a far-fetched, but convenient excuse. This conspiracy theory approach also applies to last year’s Egypt Air crash. In conversation with people on the street of Cairo we heard statements such as, "over thirty bodies have been pulled from the ocean by the American divers, but none of the recovered bodies have been Egyptians." Coupled with the fact that Egyptian Air Force officers were aboard the doomed aircraft, the conspiracy holds that the crash was a joint effort of the CIA and Mossad. 20 A. Political Outlook i. Expect no sudden or dramatic political changes ii. Ruling elite will continue to maintain their control, at any cost iii. Next president will come from the ranks of the military and continue these cautious policies – with the instinct for self-preservation remaining strong B. Economic Outlook i. Privatization will continue, only as long as it supports the legitimacy of the state ii. Weak economic institutions, state domination of economy, a rising population, and, crucially, substandard educational standards, will constrain future economic growth C. Prospects for Stability i. Immediate terrorism threat by Islamists has been brutally suppressed, though a return to violence (however unlikely) remains a possibility ii. Islamists will continue to be the most viable option for opposition, especially as the state fails to provide necessary social services and provide a viable democratic outlet for grievances iii. Poverty, combined with religious tensions (both within Islam and between Islamists and the Copts) has resulted in great tensions beneath the surface of Egyptian society, especially in rural areas. Periodic riots are likely, as is a brutal government suppression of any unrest TEAM EGYPT 21 Tom Mucha Mike Denk Doug Kofoid Laura Zhu Fred Khoury ADDITIONAL SOURCES/CONTACTS Gehad Auda Professor, Political Science Helwan University, Cairo Gauda@idsc.gov.eg Taksim Bashir Egyptian Diplomat (retired) (Sadat Spokesman, Egypt’s Ambassador to Arab League, Egypt’s Ambassador to Canada) Daniel Brumberg Professor Georgetown University Drew Dowell Dow Jones Newswires, Business Monthly (Cairo) 202-338-1050 Dr. Mohammed Abu Elghar 22 Mohandiseen Clinic, Cairo Dr. Ben Johnson Director, The Chicago House (Luxor) The University of Chicago Oriental Institute (312) 702-9513 Dale Gavlack Correspondent National Public Radio (Cairo) Dgavlack@zeus.starnet.com.eg Amy Henderson Reporter The Jordan Times Daniel Lefkovitz Egypt Analyst MZ+A (Chicago) Lefkovitz@mza-inc.com Susan Postlewatie Bridge Financial News (Cairo) 202-340-9248 Max Rodenbeck The Economist (Cairo) 202-340-6723 (home) Walter Rodgers CNN Jerusalem Bureau Chief 972-2-538-1847 Khalid Sewlam 23 Economist The American Chamber of Commerce (Cairo) Heba El-Shazli Regional Representative Middle East AFL-CIO Hebatony@ie-eg.com Andrew Tabler Regional Editor The Middle East Times Editor@metimes.com Ben Weideman CNN Cairo Bureau Chief 202-578-0661 Patrick Werr Business News (Cairo) 202-341-1292 24