Valuing Real Options by Spreadsheet

advertisement
Valuing Real Options by Spreadsheet:
Parking Garage Case Example
Richard de Neufville,§ Stefan Scholtes,† and Tao Wang‡
Abstract. This article proposes a simple spreadsheet model for estimating the value of real
options in engineering systems. The model has several advantages compared to alternative
procedures based on financial mathematics: it is a natural and gentle advancement of the familiar
discounted cash flow model; uses standard spreadsheet procedures; is based on data readily
available in practice; and provides graphics that explain the results intuitively. This approach
should thus be easily accessible to practicing professionals responsible for engineering design
and management. A practical example for the design of a parking garage demonstrates the ease
of use and presentation of results of this approach.
Introduction
A “real option” embodies flexibility in the development of a project. It represents a “right, but not
an obligation” to take some course of action that may be advisable either if there is some
unfortunate turn of events or some new opportunities. A “real option” thus represents either a
form of insurance or a means to take advantage of a favorable situation. The use of real options
originated in the field of finance (Myers, 1984) and has been developed for the use of
management since the early 1990s (see for example Dixit and Pindyck, 1994; Trigeorgis, 1996;
Amran and Kulatilaka, 1999; Copeland and Antikarov, 2001).
Real options have more recently been applied to the design of infrastructure systems. For
example, Leviakangas and Lahesmaa (2002) discuss their application to toll roads; and Ford et al.
(2002) to strategic planning. Ho and Liu (2003) present a method for evaluating investments in
construction technology; Zhao and Zheng (2003) provide an alternative approach and apply it to
parking garages; Zhao, Sundararajan, and Tseng (2004) extend this work to highway
development; and de Weck, de Neufville and Chaize (2004) demonstrate how the use of real
options could lead to major improvements in performance, on the order of 30%.
However, real options have not been widely used in engineering practice. This is probably due to
the fact that the standard approaches to their analysis requires an understanding of financial
theory; advanced mathematical techniques (such as lattice valuations and stochastic dynamic
programming, Wang and de Neufville, 2004); and statistical data that are inaccessible to most
engineers. Moreover, even when practitioners are skilled in the use of the financial techniques
for evaluating options, the results they produce are difficult to explain to the senior engineers and
managers who are ultimately responsible for approving the configuration and design of
infrastructure systems.
To make the use of real options readily accessible to designers, this article proposes a simple
spreadsheet model for estimating the value of real options in engineering systems. The model
has several advantages compared to alternative procedures based on financial mathematics: it is
a natural and gentle advancement of the familiar discounted cash flow model; uses standard,
§
Professor of Civil and Environmental Engineering and of Engineering Systems, MIT, Cambridge, MA, 02139, U.S.A.
Email: ardent@mit.edu
† Professor of Management Science, Judge Institute of Management, Cambridge University, Cambridge CB2 1AG, U.K.
Email: s.scholtes@jims.cam.ac.uk
‡ Doctoral candidate, Engineering Systems Division, MIT, Cambridge, MA, 02139, U.S.A. Email: tao@mit.edu
1
readily available spreadsheet procedures; is based on data available in practice; and provides
graphics that explain the results intuitively.
An options view of capacity
Before we explain a realistic application of our approach to options valuation, we will use a
simplistic example to lead the reader’s intuition. Suppose we need to determine the capacity of a
new infrastructure system. Projected demand for the system is 60,000 units, the operational
margin is $800 per processed unit, and the capacity costs are $700 per unit capacity. What
capacity should be installed to optimize the value of the system? The naïve view is that for every
unit demanded, you will have a net gain of $100, therefore the system can be operated
economically and the optimal decision is to install capacity for the full demand of 60,000 units.
The corresponding value of the system is $ 6 Mio. The problem with this back-of-the-envelope
calculation is obvious to every planner: Capacity must be installed before demand is observed.
What if demand is lower or higher than projected? In the case of high demand the system will be
over utilized, with the consequence of service level deterioration, long waiting times and
unsatisfied customers. In the case of low demand the system becomes a “white elephant”.
Millions of dollars have been wasted for a system that will never earn its set-up costs.
We need to be able to deal with uncertainties in demand when we make capacity decisions.
Suppose, for example that there is a 50/50 chance of a demand of 40,000 or 80,000 units,
respectively. The expected demand is still 60,000 units. But what is the expected profit?
Suppose we install 60,000 units capacity. In the case of a realized demand of 40,000 units we
have operating profits of $800 per unit * 40,000 processed units = $32 Mio against set-up costs of
$700 per unit * 60,000 units capacity = $ 42 Mio. This results in a loss of $10 Mio. On the upside,
we have a demand of 80,000 units but can only process 60,000 units, resulting in a value of $ 6
Mio. Given the 50/50 chance of the two scenarios, the expected value of the system is -$ 2 Mio;
the system makes losses on average.
Expected Value of the System
Choosing capacity so that the expected system value is maximized is different from maximizing
the system value for the expected demand level, which was our first, naïve approach. The
optimal capacity for the example equals the low-scenario demand and the corresponding
expected value is $ 4 Mio1, see Figure 1.
$10,000,000
$5,000,000
$0
-$5,000,000
-$10,000,000
0
10000
20000
30000
40000
50000
60000
70000
80000
Capacity
Single Scenario
Two Scenarios
Figure 1. Expected system value as a function of capacity
1
Notice that the optimal value is lower than the naïve optimal value. This is not a coincidence but a general phenomenon:
Capacity induces a constraint on the system; the system value suffers in case of a downside demand scenario and this is
not fully balanced out by the possible upside demands since upsides are capped at the capacity limit.
2
High capacity has the advantage of exploiting economies of scale, a fact that we haven’t included
in our example. Whilst the introduction of scale economies in the example might well increase the
optimal capacity level, it would need extreme scale economies to increase it to the level of the
naïve solution.
The loss in scale economies of a low capacity solution is often more than balanced out by one
significant advantage: Low capacity can be regarded as a first stage, enabling future expansion if
demand is high. However, in many infrastructure systems, low-cost expansion is only possible if
this option is accounted for in the initial design. An, often small, amount of money needs to be
invested early on, when the low capacity is installed, to enable a cost-efficient expansion of the
system if and when desired. This is the options view of capacity: Build small but invest in the
option to expand if needed.
To see how this effects our example, suppose we install a low initial capacity now, then observe
demand, and can then make an expansion decision which will allow us to capture 50% of the
residual demand, i.e. of the demand that we have not satisfy with our initial capacity. It is easy to
see that in this example the optimal policy is to install the low-scenario capacity first and then
install 50% of the residual capacity later, provided the high-demand scenario occurs. This
increases the expected value of the system from $ 4 Mio to $ 5 Mio. The difference of $ 1 Mio is
the expected value of the option to expand. A proportion of this option value may have to be
invested now, before the scenario is observed, to enable later expansion. The initial investment to
“buy the option” is often considerably lower than the expected gain from the option.
It is intuitive that the expansion option should become more valuable with increasing demand
uncertainty. To see this effect, let us assume the upside and downside scenarios are 60,000 units
plus or minus some uncertainty level, measured in percentage deviation; the uncertainty level in
the example is thus 33%, leading to a downside of 40,000 and an upside of 80,000 units. Figure 2
shows how the value of the staged system changes as the uncertainty increases. The total value
of the staged system decreases but the value of the expansion option, i.e. the difference between
the value of the staged system and the value of the non-staged system, increases.2
$7,000,000
$6,000,000
$5,000,000
$4,000,000
$3,000,000
$2,000,000
$1,000,000
$0
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
Uncertainty Level
Value of non-staged system
Value of staged system
Option Value
Figure 2. System and option value as a function of uncertainty
This is a general phenomenon, formally provable using Jensen’s inequality. The value of an option increases as the
underlying uncertainty increases. This is in contrasts to the effect of high capacity, which becomes more detrimental to the
system value as demand uncertainty increases. In other words, the higher the uncertainty the lower the optimal initial
capacity and the higher the optimal expansion capacity.
2
3
Spreadsheet model
This valuation of flexibility is based on standard discounted cash flow (DCF) analysis used to
evaluate projects (see Riggs and West, 1986; de Neufville, 1990; White et al, 1998; DeGarmo et
al, 2000). The process discounts future revenues and expenses to place them on a comparable
basis, typically the present. The sum of these discounted cash flows is the net present value
(NPV). Engineers and managers regularly use computer-based spreadsheets, such as Excel®,
to value projects.
The process of estimating the value of real options using spreadsheets is simple and easy to
execute. Once the basic data have been placed in the spreadsheet, the calculations can be done
in minutes. The authors have posted a version of the model at http://ardent.mit.edu/real_options.
The process involves 3 steps:
1. Set up the spreadsheet representing the most likely projections of future costs and
revenues of the project, and use the Data Table function to calculate its value for a range
of design parameters to determine the optimum design for this deterministic case. The
result is the base case against which flexible solutions are compared, so as to derive the
value of these alternative designs.
2. Explore the implications of uncertainty by simulating ranges of possible scenarios (for
example, of the uncertain future revenues) using the Excel® random number generator,
Rand(). Each scenario leads to a different NPV, and the collection of scenarios provides
the distribution of possible outcomes for a project. In general, a project that is worthwhile
on average might turn out to be either unprofitable or highly profitable, depending on the
actual circumstances. Use the Data Table function again to determine the best design
when the future is uncertain, which is normally different than the one for the unrealistic
base case that assumes the future is known. (The difference is due to non-linearity in the
data, which means that the value of the project based on expected demand is not the
same as the expected value of the project based on actual values – Jensen’s Inequality,
see Planetmath)
3. Explore the implications of various ways to provide flexibility by changing the costs and
revenues to reflect these design alternatives. The resulting expected values can be
compared to the base case to define the value of flexibility. Moreover, the graphical
display of the cumulative distribution of the results demonstrates the Value at Risk (VaR)
or the worse cases that could occur. This information is often a key factor in decisions
about the design of major projects.
Practical Demonstration
An application to a hypothetical design of a parking garage, inspired by Zhao and Tseng (2003),
demonstrates the ease of use of the model. This situation was extrapolated from an actual
project in the Bluewater development in England (http://www.bluewater.co.uk/). It assumes that
the car park is next to a new commercial center in a region that is growing as population expands.
The basic data used are that:
 The immediate demand is for 750 spaces, and is expected to rise exponentially by
another 750 spaces over the next 10 years;
 Average annual revenue per space used will be $10,000, and the average operating
costs (staff, cleaning, etc.) will be about $2,000 per year for each space available (note
that the number of spaces used is often lower than the spaces available);
 The lease of the land will cost $3.6 Million annually;
 The construction will cost $16,000 per space for pre-cast construction, with a 10%
increase for every level above the ground level;
4


The site is large enough to accommodate 200 cars per level; and
The discount rate is taken to be 12%.
Additionally, economic analysis needs to recognize that actual demand is uncertain, given the
long time horizon. The case assumes that the additional future demand could be 50% off the
projection, either way, and that its annual volatility for growth is 10%.
The designers can design the footings and columns of the original building so that additional
levels of parking can easily be added, as was the case for the Bluewater development. The case
assumes that doing so will add 5% to the total initial construction cost. This premium is the price
to get the real option for future expansion, the right but not the obligation to do so.
Step 1: Table 1 represents the basic spreadsheet for calculating the NPV of the parking garage
assuming that the demand for spaces grows as projected. This particular version is for 6 levels
that provides 1200 spaces. Note that when demand grows beyond the capacity of the facility it
cannot benefit from addition demand.
Table 1. Discounted Cash Flow Model (6 levels)
Year
0
1
Demand
750
Capacity
1,200
Revenue
$7,500,000
Recurring Costs
Operating cost
$2,400,000
Land leasing cost
$3,600,000 $3,600,000
Cash flow
$1,500,000
Discounted Cash Flow
$1,339,286
Present value of cash flow
$32,574,737
Capacity costs for up to two levels
$6,400,000
Capacity costs for levels above 2
$16,336,320
Net present value
$6,238,417
2
3
893
1,015
1,200
1,200
$8,930,000 $10,150,000
$2,400,000
$3,600,000
$2,930,000
$2,335,778
19
20
1,688
1,696
1,200
1,200
$12,000,000 $12,000,000
$2,400,000
$3,600,000
$4,150,000
$2,953,888
$2,400,000
$3,600,000
$6,000,000
$696,641
$2,400,000
$3,600,000
$6,000,000
$622,001
Expected NPV ($, Millions)
The Data Table function in Excel® enables the analyst to compute the NPV for parking garages
with many different levels, provided that the cost of construction and the capacity in the
spreadsheet has been expressed as a formula in terms of the number of levels, as it has in this
case. Figure 3 correspondingly displays the NPV for various levels of design for the deterministic
case. As can be seen, the optimal design for this base case, that unrealistically assumes that
demand is known in advance, is to build 6 floors. The NPV in this case is $6,238,417.
10
5
0
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
-5
-10
-15
Number of Floors
Traditional NPV
Recognizing uncertainty
Figure 3. Expected NPV for Different Design (Number of Floors)
5
Step 2: Recognizes the uncertainty in the forecast demand by simulating possible scenarios.
The analysis applies the Rand() function and uses the Data Table functions to change the input
demand. This example analysis ran 2000 scenarios, which took about 1 minute on a standard
PC. Figures 4a and 4b illustrate the results for a 5-level design both in terms of a histogram
representing the probability distribution (PDF), and the associated cumulative probability diagram
(CDF). The expected results for different levels of design appear in Figure 3.
This analysis provides useful insights that motivate the use of flexibility. It shows that:


Uncertainty can lead to asymmetric returns. In this case, although the chance of higher
and lower demands are equal, the upside value of the project is limited (because the
fixed capacity cannot take advantage of higher demands) while the downside risks are
substantial and can lead to great losses.
The expected value of the project when uncertainty is recognized is thus not equal to its
value in the deterministic case (as Figures 3 and 4a indicate).
The CDF in Figure 4b shows the Value at Risk (VaR), that is, the chance that a loss will
exceed any specific threshold. It shows for example that there is about 10% chance that
the losses from a 5-level parking garage would equal or exceed $4 million.
600
5-floor design
500
Frequency

Simulated Mean
400
6-floor design
300
Deterministic
Result
200
100
0
-17.8 -15.6 -13.5 -11.3
-9.2
-7.0
-4.9
-2.7
-0.6
1.6
3.7
5.9
8.0
Figure 4a. Histogram or Probability Distribution Function for NPV’s (in Mio $) for 5-level
design recognizing demand uncertainty compared to deterministic optimal design
6
1
0.9
Probability
0.8
0.7
0.6
CDF for Result of
0.5
Simulation Analysis (5floor)
0.4
Implied CDF for
Result of
Deterministic NPV
Analysis (6-floor)
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
-20
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
Figure 4b. Cumulative Distribution Function for NPV’s (in Mio $) for 5 level design
recognizing demand uncertainty compared to deterministic optimal design
Step 3: In this phase the analyst explores ways to limit the downside risk (VaR) and take
advantage of upside potential. For example, the above analysis easily shows how the designers
can reduce the VaR by creating smaller designs that lower the chance that demand will not fill the
facility. Using the available information, Figure 5 compares the cumulative distribution function of
NPV for 4-floor design and 5-floor design. In this case, the smaller design eliminates the chance
of really big losses, but at the cost of never making any substantial profit. Thus, although building
smaller provides good insurance against losses, it is not sufficient to make the project attractive.
1
0.9
Probability
0.8
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
-20
-15
-10
-5
5-Floor Design
0
5
10
4-Floor Design
Figure 5. Reduction of Downside Risk by Designing Smaller
The analyst can explore options to take advantage of possible growth by building these designs
into the spreadsheet. This case considered the possibility of making the columns big enough to
support additional levels, should demand justify expansion of the parking garage in later years.
(This is exactly what was done in the parking structures for the Bluewater development.) Table 2
7
shows the appropriately modified spreadsheet. It incorporates 3 additional rows for “Decision on
expansion”, “Extra capacity”, and “Expansion cost”. For this example, the “Decision on
expansion” is based on the criterion that the capacity is less than the demand for two consecutive
years, and the assumed decision rule is to construct 2 extra floors or 400 spaces. (This is just an
example, other criteria and rules could be programmed in.)
Table 2. Discount Cash Flow Model for 4 level design with embedded expansion option (for
one demand realization path)
Year
Demand
Capacity
Decision on expansion
Extra capacity
Revenue
Recurring Costs
Operating cost
Land leasing cost
Expansion cost
Cash flow
Discounted Cash Flow
Present value of cash flow
Capacity cost for up to two levels
Capacity costs for levels above 2
Price for the option
Net present value
0
1
1,055
800
2
3
1,141
1,234
800
1,200
Expand
Expand
0
400
400
$8,000,000 $8,000,000 $12,000,000
19
2,075
2,000
20
2,002
2,000
0
0
$20,000,000 $20,000,000
$1,600,000 $1,600,000 $2,400,000
$3,600,000 $3,600,000 $3,600,000 $3,600,000
$8,944,320 $10,822,627
$2,800,000 -$6,144,320 -$4,822,627
$2,500,000 -$4,898,214 -$3,432,651
$36,117,599
$6,400,000
$7,392,000
$689,600
$18,725,599
$4,000,000
$3,600,000
$4,000,000
$3,600,000
$12,400,000 $12,400,000
$1,439,724 $1,285,468
The value of this “call option” that permits expansion in the case of favorable demand is shown in
Figure 6. The capability to add capacity adds greatly increases both the maximum value of the
project (up to almost $30 million) and its expected value (about $10 million). The estimated value
of the option is the difference between the expected value with the option ($10,517,140) and that
without (-$28,800), that is $10,488,340 in this case.
100.0%
90.0%
Mean for NPV
without Options
80.0%
CDF for NPV
with Options
Probability
70.0%
60.0%
50.0%
40.0%
CDF for NPV
without Options
30.0%
Mean for NPV
with Options
20.0%
10.0%
0.0%
-30
-20
-10
0
10
20
30
40
Figure 6. Option to expand adds significant value to design
Beyond the expected value of the option, the flexibility provided by building small at the start with
the option to expand has several further advantages. The spreadsheet approach to the analysis
of the value of options brings these out, as the financial approaches to calculating only value do
not. As Table 4 indicates, the flexible approach to the design of this facility:
 Reduces the maximum possible loss, that is the Value at Risk;
8


Increases the maximum possible and the expected gain;
While maintaining the initial investment costs low.
Table 3. Results from the Spreadsheet Model
Perspective
Deterministic
Recognizing Uncertainty
Simulation
No
Yes
Option Embedded
No
No
Incorporating Real options
Yes
Yes
Design
6 levels
5 levels
4 levels with strengthened
structure
Estimated Expected NPV
$6,238,416
$3,536,474
$10,517,140
Table 4. Comparison of Results with and without Options
Design
Initial Investment
Expected NPV
Minimum Value
Maximum Value
With Options
(4 levels, strengthened structure)
$18,081,600
$10,517,140
-$13,138,168
$29,790,838
Without Options
(5 levels)
$21,651,200
$3,536,474
-$18,024,062
$8,316,602
Comparison
Better with options
Better with options
Better with options
Better with options
Conclusion
A spreadsheet model for the valuation of real options is easy to use and provides insight into the
way that flexibility in design minimizes exposure to risk and maximizes the potential for gain
under favorable circumstances. Compared to alternative approaches that require advanced
mathematics and financial concepts, and that focus narrowly on the expected value of an option
and ignore the ways options change the distribution of outcomes, the spreadsheet approach is
both much easier to use and more useful. Because the spreadsheet model for the valuation of
real options rests on tools and data that are readily available to practicing engineers and
managers, it should be accessible and useful to them.
Acknowledgements
The authors appreciate the advice of senior staff of Laing O’Rourke (UK) who worked with the
lead authors on the application of the spreadsheet model, and its validation through practical
examples, during the Cambridge-MIT Institute Workshop on Real Options in May 2004.
References
Amram, M. and Kulatilaka, N. (1999) Real Options - Managing Strategic Investment in an
Uncertain World, Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA.
Copeland, T. and Antikarov, V. (2001) Real Options - A Practitioner's Guide, TEXERE, New York,
NY.
DeGarmo, E. et al (2000) Engineering Economy, 11th Ed., Prentice-Hall, Upper Saddle River, NJ.
de Neufville, R. (1982) “Airport Passenger Parking Design,” ASCE Journal of Urban
Transportation, 108, May, pp. 302 – 306.
de Weck, O., de Neufville, R. and Chaize, M. (2004) “Staged Deployment of Communications
Satellite Constellations in Low Earth Orbit." Journal of Aerospace Computing, Information, and
Communication, Mar., pp. 119-136.
9
Dixit, A. and Pindyck, R. (1994) Investment under Uncertainty, Princeton University Press,
Princeton, NJ.
Ford, D., Lander, D. and Voyer, J. (2002) “A Real Options Approach to Valuing Strategic
Flexibility in Uncertain Construction Projects,” Construction Management and Economics, 20, pp.
343 – 351.
Ho, S. and Liu, L. (2003) “How to Evaluate and Invest in Emerging A/E/C Technologies under
Uncertainty,” J. of Construction Engineering and Management, 129(1), pp. 16 – 24.
Leviakangas, P. and Lahesmaa, J. (2002) “Profitability Evaluation of Intelligent Transport System
Investments,” J. of Transportation Engineering, 128(3), pp. 276 – 286.
Myers, S. (1984) “Finance theory and financial strategy.” Interfaces, 14, Jan-Feb, pp. 126-137.
Trigeorgis, L. (1996) Real Options: Managerial Flexibility and Strategy in Resource Allocation,
MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
Planetmath.org “Jensen’s Inequality.” http://planetmath.org/encyclopedia/JensenInequality.html
Riggs, J. and West, T. (1986) Engineering Economics, McGraw-Hill, New York, NY.
Wang, T. and de Neufville, R. (2004) “Building Real Options into Physical Systems with
Stochastic Mixed-Integer Programming.” 8th Annual Real Options International Conference,
Montreal, Canada. http://www.realoptions.org/papers2004/de_Neufville.pdf
White, J. et al (1998) Principles of Engineering Economics Analysis, John Wiley and Sons, New
York, NY.
Zhao, T., Sundararajan, S., and Tseng, C. (2004) “Highway Development Decision-Making under
Uncertainty: A Real Options Approach,” J. of Infrastructure Systems, 10(1), pp. 23 – 32.
Zhao, T. and Tseng, C. (2003) “Valuing Flexibility in Infrastructure Expansion.” J. of Infrastructure
Systems, 9(3), pp. 89 – 97.
10
Download