The politics of the public sector: Political accountability in post-apartheid South Africa Paper for a PARI symposium on public sector reform 19 January 2011 Anthony Butler (Wits University) anthony.butler@wits.ac.za/072 325 8139 Most of the states that moved from authoritarian to purportedly democratic government in the 1990s have been “haunted by old demons” (Diamond et al 1999, 1). One way to understand the endurance of governance and human rights pathologies from the authoritarian era is in terms of a failure to introduce effective mechanisms of political accountability. Without systems to restrain and guide the exercise of executive power, newly democratic regimes remain corrupt and unable to guarantee civil liberties (Diamond et al 1999, 2). African National Congress (ANC) leaders increasingly identify an active state as the central instrument of social and economic development (ANC 2007a, 2007b, 2009, Butler 2010a). On one widespread view, a “developmental state” is necessary for both economic prosperity and socio-political “transformation” (Edigheji 2010, Butler 2010b). A key challenge for the proponents of such state intervention is that the South African state is currently unable to promote improved economic performance and social welfare. The modern state is a system of institutionalised authority that facilitates public action and makes possible binding collective choices. Without a capable state, citizens are unable to work together to improve the conditions in which they live. In the absence of a reliable and accountable system of public authority, binding decisions will not bind and ordinary people will find themselves in a state of conflict. The modern state, moreover, creates dangers of political subjugation. It implies a system of authority in which those who obey can be exploited and oppressed by those who are empowered to command. A state that is not accountable to citizens can also become a vehicle for the advance of individual and sectional interests at the expense of wider social objectives and for the emergence of corruption. 1 A central task of modern politics is therefore to build a powerful system of public authority, capable enough to advance the interests of ordinary citizens, but limited in the range of its powers and accountable to the people whose name it claims to rule (Dunn 1999, 329). The idea of accountability A range of accountability is mechanisms is required to keep the executive under control, protect political rights, keep public officials law abiding and responsive, and deter them from exploiting their offices for private gain. Schedler (1999, 13) observes that “accountability represents an unexplored concept whose internal meaning remains evasive”. Schedler’s own (1999, 17) definition is as follows: “A is accountable to B when A is obliged to inform B about A’s (past or future) actions and decisions, to justify them, and to suffer punishment in the case of eventual misconduct.” This definition forefronts three key aspects of political accountability: answerability; justification, and enforcement (Schedler 1999, 14-5). In order to be accountable, public officials are obliged to be answerable in the sense that they must provide information about their decisions and about how they were taken. Accountability also requires justification: this is the demand that ministers and officials explain – give reasons for – their actions. Accountability therefore implies the subordination of the policy process to reason and the creation of a culture of justification among policy makers. Finally, accountability embraces enforcement. It involves the application of sanctions, even if only the “soft” ones of exposure and shame, to those found to have acted improperly. Two dimensions of accountability Scholars conventionally divide accountability into vertical and horizontal dimensions (O’Donnell 1998). Vertical accountability refers to citizens’ efforts to enforce standards of proper conduct on the state and its officers. The key mechanisms of vertical accountability in a democracy are exposure (usually transmitted through the news media) and electoral sanctions. Horizontal accountability refers to the capacity of state institutions and bodies themselves to check the abuse of state power. This form of accountability is sometimes felicitously described as “intrastate accountability” (Mainwaring 2003, 18-19). 2 The exercise of horizontal accountability occurs in different sites within the state. Such accountability inheres in the relationship between executive, legislature and judiciary when these three branches are able to serve as monitors of and checks on each other’s actions. Most states possess additional internal “agents of accountability” (Schedler 1999) such as electoral commissions, anti-corruption bodies, ombudsmen, human rights commissions, and audit commissions. Limits to vertical accountability in South Africa Electoral accountability is a much weaker mechanism of accountability than is generally recognised (O’Donnell 1998, 112-3). As Manin, Przeworski & Stokes (1999, 49) have noted, elections “are inherently a blunt instrument of control” because “voters only have one decision to make with regard to the entire package of government policies”. Elections occur only periodically, issues are poorly defined and understood by electors, and voters find it impossible to identify and target particular political leaders for alleged misdeeds. For these reasons, elections are only part of the wider armory needed to render political elites accountable. Vertical accountability is also hampered in South Africa by racialised voting patterns, declining turnout if eligible electors, and the absence of a viable national opposition. The countervailing power of opposition parties is in some respects more limited than ever: the Congress of the People (COPE) survives primarily because it serves the interests of the current ANC leadership. The Inkatha Freedom Party is close to dissolution. And the Democratic Alliance is becoming a regional party of the Western Cape. Local elections typically do not function as mechanisms for holding local political leaders to account. Communities perceptively recognise that a community that votes against the ruling party in a province is likely to encounter greater difficulties accessing state resources and public services that one that votes strongly for the ruling party. Civil society groups can monitor the performance of public officials and attempt to provide systematic oversight of their actions. There has been particular interest in recent years in “societal accountability” -- the broad variety of nonelectoral strategies that civil society organizations adopt to monitor political leaders (Goetz and Jenkins 2004). This exercise of soft power is especially important where parliamentary oversight is limited (Burnell 2008, 13). Autonomous and variegated media and civil society organizations are essential if this role is to be adequately performed. There is at best ambivalence within the ANC about the value of societal accountability and deep intellectual 3 confusion about the notion of media and civil society independence from the state. Money in politics The flow of money into politics is forming an increasingly severe barrier to effective vertical accountability in South Africa. Democratic politics is expensive because parties need to organise citizens, to educate them, to formulate alternative public policies, and to campaign energetically for office. But unregulated funding has repeatedly been implicated in political corruption because money can be exchanged for policy influence or government contracts. Money given in return for favours has a corrupting effect on a political system. It also undermines the trust upon which a flourishing democracy depends. Parties with disproportionate access to resources can buy votes, monopolise media coverage, and dispense patronage to supporters (Butler 2010c, 237-8). Entrenched special access to private and public resources can allow a dominant party to secure an unhealthy stranglehold over electoral politics. Within parties, factional war chests can become essential for success in internal elections. For the first ten decades of democracy, ANC leaders’ concerns centred on ‘careerism’ – the pursuit of party office for personal gain. Today, however, money is flowing back into internal party politics where it is used to finance inter-factional struggles. Unfortunately conventional party funding reforms are largely ineffective. Rules on private donations are hard to implement and produce unintended consequences. Parties or candidates can fail to disclose payments. They can produce inaccurate accounts, identify loopholes or use financial instruments that regulators and auditors cannot understand. They can disguise donations as loans, hide them in commercial transactions, package them to fall under thresholds, create opaque legal trusts or divert funds to political foundations or other party-aligned institutions (Butler 2010c, 240-2). Controls on private donations push money underground so creating instability within party structures. Bans and caps on party donations result in the diversion of funds to non-governmental organisations, political foundations, or party-aligned news media. This encourages spillover legislation as governments move to clamp down on donations to such institutions too. Public funding, a widespread response internationally to the challenges of private funding, limit parties’ reliance on benefactors and so arguable reduces potential corruption (Taljaard 2010). Unfortunately, state transfers usually add to the flow of undesirable private money rather than replacing it. 4 Internal party contests are more important than public elections in the exercise of political accountability. Increasingly monetised internal elections within the ANC determine who wields state power. In middle-income developing countries like South Africa, hidden public-sector funding of parties and internal party factions is routine. It is accomplished by the diversion of revenues from state-owned enterprises, the transfer of public funds to party-owned companies, the allocation of state jobs and contracts, ‘pay to play’ conventions that allow only donors access to government work, and the abuse of state resources for election campaigning. The power of money is a direct threat to political accountability. Parties and individual political leaders become accountable their funders rather than to the people. State institutions designed to check executive power can become subordinate to the dictates of money-politics, and public policies can increasingly become marketable commodities. Weak horizontal accountability in SA The instruments of intrastate accountability are mostly politically vulnerable in South Africa today. Parliament, the judiciary, the public protector, and the various commissions have been subjected to different degrees of political pressure. Intrastate accountability cannot be maintained if state bodies lose their mutual independence or if they become subordinated to central state agencies or ruling party factions. South Africa’s agencies of accountability have performed unevenly in recent years as a result of poor administrative capabilities and politicised appointments. There are four challenges that make a deepening of horizontal political accountability especially hard to achieve: presidentialist tendencies; the turbulent politics of the budget process; the character of the interface between public and private sectors; and the complex relationships between the state and the ruling party. Presidentialism In South Africa’s modified parliamentary system of government, the government is drawn from the parliament which creates a “fusion” between the executive and legislature. The president is elected by the national assembly and appoints a cabinet that is collectively responsible to parliament. Cabinet governs together with the president (RSA 1996, 85.2). A necessary check on executive power in a parliamentary system is that members of cabinet are accountable to the parliament from which they are 5 drawn. The constitution states that, “Members of the Cabinet are accountable collectively and individually to Parliament for the exercise of their powers and the performance of their functions” (RSA 1996, 92.2). Moreover, cabinet ministers must “provide Parliament with full and regular reports concerning matters under their control” (RSA 1996, 92.6). Neither mode of cabinet accountability is currently operational. South Africa has a weak and party-dependent legislature that is unable effectively to oversee executive action. Collective responsibility has curtailed public debate, and ministers evade responsibility for mismanagement in their departments. Party leaders have subordinated the legislature to the executive. Such subordination can only be averted by a deliberate effort to build parliamentary oversight capacity. The ANC caucus code of conduct, however, privileges party authority over that of parliament. The relationship between president and cabinet has been controversial. The Constitution envisages a balance between cabinet government, an executive Presidency and a treasury with wide powers. Cabinet government creates opportunities for the analytical policy deliberation and allows government departments to bring sectoral policy communities and interest groups into that deliberative process. Under former President Thabo Mbeki, tension emerged between the constitution’s parliamentary character and the reality of growing centralisation in the state presidency. Power was pulled from society to state, from provincial to national level, from the legislature to the executive and from cabinet to presidency. Presidential systems can, of course, potentially facilitate political accountability. The executive and the legislature are separately elected and confront one another across a terrain defined by a separation of powers. The legislative branch is obliged to confront and check the executive. Citizens can hold the president to account when he stands for re-election. Presidentialism is more often viewed in this region as antithetical to constitutional stability. Riggs (1988, 1997) has shown that presidential systems have at some point succumbed to authoritarianism in almost every county in which they have been introduced. Zero sum elections and irremovable figureheads with personal mandates to rule are a dangerous combination (Linz 1990). President Jacob Zuma and his predecessor Thabo Mbeki have tried to secure for themselves the personal political advantages of parliamentary and presidential systems while accepting the constraints of neither. They have adopted the 6 mannerisms appropriate to a presidential democracy to raise themselves above the nuisance of parliamentary accountability. At the same time, they have escaped the direct electoral accountability to the people that a presidential constitution would demand. Budgeting and the treasury The effective management and oversight of public sector finances is a central aspect of accountability in all states. At all levels of government in South Africa, scarcity of financial resources has not been the primary determinant of poor performance. Instead, a lack of appropriate human and managerial resources has obstructed the effective and economic deployment of available financial resources (Levin 2007, 19). It has also hampered the creation of systems of financial accountability. Performance systems are notoriously complex to build and operate. They require measures of expenditure impacts (or outcomes), of the outputs required to bring about those impacts, and of the processes required to realise those inputs (McGill 2001, 376). Impact assessments and efficiency measures are exceptionally hard to create and their presence can result in unintended and perverse consequences. Such measures cannot easily be used to hold specific officials or agency managers responsible for securing precise outputs and outcomes. It is difficult to isolate the causal relationships between inputs, outputs and outcomes. In complex hierarchical organisations, in which most policies have a transversal aspect that cuts across departments and tiers, the allocation of responsibility for outcomes is problematic. The high turnover of officials in the South Africa public service creates further obstacles to linking specific outcomes to the performance of officials. Employment equity policies usually outweigh organisational effectiveness when managerial performance is assessed (Von Holdt, 2010, 258). In the absence of other mechanisms for measuring it, the national treasury has adopted a prominent role in appraising performance and for allocating resources according to such appraisals. The relationship between the head of the executive and the finance ministry is very important in parliamentary systems. One success of post-apartheid governance has been the institutionalisation of mechanisms for allocating resources between competing demands. The budgeting system has exhibited three strengths: public finances have been negotiated within a medium-term 7 framework; budgets have been informed by prior decisions about government priorities; and Treasury representatives have tracked spending proposals from their initiation in departments and Cabinet cluster committees through to the full Cabinet. These three pillars have enhanced predictability and introduced a culture of justification into conflicts over resources. Opportunities for diversion or waste of resources have been minimised because Treasury scrutiny has begun at the policy initiation stage; the finance minister has attended all key ministerial cluster committee meetings; and departments’ draft Cabinet memorandums have been considered in the light of Treasury-ratified assessments of financial implications. The Treasury has enjoyed some success in demanding reasons for expenditure from ministers and officials. As an instrument of intrastate accountability, however, treasury has limitations. New institutions and departments, such as the National Planning Commission and the Department for Economic development, have made it unclear where responsibility for economic and budgetary policy lies. Late in 2009, the presidency announced that the finance minister and his representatives would be excluded from some key ministerial cluster committees and from parallel committees of directors-general. These changes have created space for senior ministers and officials to shape the allocation of financial resources politically. In November 2010, during conflicts over the funding of Eskom’s build programme, cabinet statements prejudged the deliberations of the cabinet committee on the budget and pre-empted the contributions of the finance minister himself, in what appeared to be a concerted attempt to erode treasury authority (Butler 2010d). As a result of cabinet system dysfunctions, moreover, the second order accountability of the treasury itself has become problematic. Government energy policy, for example, has been paralysed by ideological and institutional confusion. The finance minister, acting on the advice of a five member Guarantee Certification Committee staffed only by Treasury officials, allocated a breathtaking R350bn in loan guarantees to Eskom in the course of late 2009 and 2010. To who in such circumstances is the treasury itself accountable? The interface between public and private sectors Economic development has long been associated with “Weberian” characteristics in the public service. Two related studies (Evans and Rauch 1989, Rauch and Evans 1990) revisit and affirm Max Weber’s claim that state administrations characterised by merit-based recruitment and stable long-term career paths facilitate capitalist economic development. Chalmers Johnson’s 8 (1995, 21-37) vision of an “apparatus of plan rationality” in post-war Japan identifies an effective and professionalised senior bureaucracy as a key to economic development; and Evans (1995) uses the notion of “embedded autonomy” to capture the key features of a developmental bureaucracy. In the post-1994 South African state there have been high levels of turnover and mobility (Levin 2007, Cameron 2009). Managers are rarely held to account for irregular or unauthorised expenditures (PSC 2008) and there has been an increase in financial misconduct cases. A wider “empowerment state” is arguably emerging in which relationships between business people, politicians and the public bureaucracy have become enmeshed in patronage (Butler 2011). Rather than exhibiting “embedded autonomy” (Evans 1995) such a state is characterised by disembeddedness punctuated by the capture of particular officials by sectional interests. Recent public investments, for example in energy or new-generation rail systems, seem to have been secured politically rather than by social welfare calculations. The primary beneficiaries of such processes are established businesses which use empowerment partnerships to maintain traditionally anti-competitive positions. Stronger regulation of public servants’ conflicts of interest is essential if the growth of patronage is to be contained and the energies of state officials are to be focused on their obligations. The management of conflicts of interest between individuals’ roles as public servants and as directors of private companies faces severe political obstacles. Both government and the ANC’s leadership have each been deliberating inconclusively for a decade on the business activities of politicians and officials. No viable political strategy has yet been agreed for containing conflicts of interest, enforcing limits on revolving doors, or curtailing family and social network patronage. Party and state The ANC describes itself as a liberation movement and its conception of democratic revolution is incompatible with constitutional democracy (ANC 2007b). ANC leaders describe the movement as the strategic centre of power. Its activists sometimes view liberal democratic institutions as western impositions that entrench the privileges of the property-owning elite. Even moderate constitutionalists sometimes claim that the movement will regulate the actions of all public officials (Mantashe 2009). A blurring of authority between party and state is now characteristic of all three tiers of government. Relationships of authority between mayors, municipal managers, and regional ANC barons are mediated through contested conceptions of seniority. ANC offices are used to secure control of local state institutions; and public municipal resources are used to fight local party battles. 9 Provincial cabinets are often headed by weak premiers put in place by Luthuli House. Provincial ANC leaders are able to destabilise these appointees and to control resource allocation. ANC barons and executive office holders operate according to dual accountability systems – to party and to state – in which lines of authority and responsibility for action can never be made transparent. At national level, the dominance of government over movement that characterised the Mbeki era has been partially overturned. State officials possess resources of knowledge and public authority that political party functionaries cannot match. Nevertheless ANC policy committees and office bearers intervene endlessly in the business of government. The movement did not use the recent period of economic stability to induct its own cadres into liberal democratic values and respect for public authority. An increasingly factionalised liberation movement is not today ideologically amenable to the introduction of stronger systems of public accountability. Conclusions A more capable state is essential if South Africans are to enjoy a prosperous future. Such a state cannot be created and sustained if those who govern through it are not held accountable for their actions by citizens and intrastate agencies. Without answerability, a culture of justification, and sanctions for improper conduct, state power will be abused and dissipated. The immediate political costs of building an accountable state are significant. An ethically compromised ANC leadership no longer possesses the moral resources to mobilise activists in support of politically divisive reforms. Years of deliberation about the regulation of conflicts of interest and the curtailment of patronage relationships have not resulted in realistic commitments to change. Vertical accountability of the political elite to the people will remain compromised by an unbalanced party system and by the limited legitimacy of liberal civil society institutions. Horizontal accountability will continue to be hampered by the politicised control of state agencies and by the ruling elite’s ambivalence about the predominance of constitutional government. The public service lacks the meta-level skills required to reconfigure its own organisational and accountability systems. Vertical accountability can perhaps be enhanced by political activism, the mobilisation of civil society organizations, and the defence of a variegated media. Exposure of corruption and reputational damage to those who commit it may be made more effective if disenchantment with political leaders deepens. 10 The use of harder legal sanctions for illegal behaviour may conceivably become more widespread when demonstrable abuses of public authority are uncovered. The obstacles to enhanced accountability, both technical and political, are immense. It is evident that political accountability can only ever be a provisional and partial accomplishment. References ANC (2007a) Economic Transformation Policy Discussion Document. African National Congress, Johannesburg. ANC (2007b) Strategy and Tactics of the African National Congress. African National Congress, Johannesburg, SS 188-93. ANC (2009) Manifesto Policy Framework. African National Congress, Johannesburg. Burnell, P (2008) The relationship of accountable governance and constitutional implementation, with reference to Africa. In Journal of Politics and Law, 1, 3, 1024. Butler, A (2010a) The African National Congress under Jacob Zuma. In R Southall et al (eds), New South African Review. Johannesburg, Witwatersrand University Press. Butler, A (2010b) The institutional context of a South African developmental state: Conceptual and sequencing issues. In O Edigheji (ed) Constructing a Democratic Developmental State in South Africa. Cape Town, HSRC Press. Butler, A (2010c) The opportunity and threat of party finance reform in South Africa’. In A Butler 2010 (ed.), Paying for Politics: Party finance and political change in South Africa and the global South. Johannesburg, Jacana. Butler, A (2010d) New Eskom fiasco is a gamble with public funds, Business Day, Johannesburg, 19 November. 11 Butler, A (2011) Black Economic Empowerment since 1994. In I Shapiro and K Tebeau, eds, After Apartheid: The second decade. Charlottesville VA, Virginia University Press. Cameron, R (2009), Public service reform in South Africa, 1999-2008. Paper presented at the University of Cape Town Political Studies departmental seminar, 28 April. Diamond, L, M Plattner and A Schedler (1999) Introduction. In A Schedler, L Diamond and M Plattner (eds) The Self-Restraining State: Power and accountability in new democracies. Boulder, Lynne Rienner, 1-12. Dunn, J (1999) Situating democratic political accountability. In A Przeworski, S Stokes and B Manin (eds) Democratic Accountability and Representation. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 329-44. Edigheji, O (2010) (ed) Constructing a Democratic Developmental State in South Africa. Cape Town, HSRC Press. Evans, P (1995) Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation. Princeton, Princeton University Press. Evans, P and Rauch, J (2000) Bureaucratic Structures and Growth: A CrossNational Analysis of the Effects of Weberian State Structures on Economic Growth. In American Sociological Review 75,1: 49-62. Goetz, A & R Jenkins (2004) Accountability. In A Kuper and J Kuper (eds) The Social Science Encyclopaedia. 4th edition. New York, Routledge. Levin, R (2007) Building a capable developmental state in South Africa. Paper presented at the 7th Africa Governance Forum, Ouagadougou, Burkina Faso, 2426 October. Lijphart, A (1992) Introduction. In A Lijphart (ed) Parliamentary Versus Presidential Government. Oxford, Oxford University Press, 1-27. Linz, JL (1990) The perils of presidentialism. In Journal of Democracy 1,1, 51-69. Mainwaring, S (2003) Introduction: democratic accountability in Latin America. In S Mainwaring and C Welna (eds) Democratic Accountability in Latin America. Oxford, Oxford University Press. Manin, B, A Przeworski and S Stokes (1999) Introduction. In Przeworski A, S Stokes and B Manin (eds.) Democracy, Accountability, and Representation. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1-26. 12 Mantashe, G (2009) Making public representatives more accountable through a clear monitoring and evaluation system. In ANC Today. Johannesburg, African National Congress, 10 July. O’Donnell, G (1998) Horizontal accountability in new democracies. In Journal of Democracy 9,3, 112-26. Picard, L, (2005) The State of the South African State. Johannesburg: Witwatersrand University Press. Rauch, J E and P B Evans (2000) Bureaucratic structure and bureaucratic performance in less developed countries. In Journal of Public Economics 75: 4971. Republic of South Africa (RSA) (1996) Constitution of the Republic of South Africa. Pretoria, Government Printers. Riggs, FW (1988) The survival of presidentialism in America. International Political Science Review 9, 4, 247-78. Riggs, FW (1997) Presidentialism versus Parliamentarianism: Implications for Representativeness and Legitimacy. In International Political Science Review 18,3, 253-78. Schedler, A (1999) Conceptualising accountability. In A Schedler, L Diamond and M Plattner (eds) The Self-Restraining State: Power and accountability in new democracies. Boulder, Lynne Rienner, 13- 28. Taljaard, R (2010) Paying for our democracy. In A Butler, (ed) Paying for Politics: Party finance and political change in South Africa and the global South. Johannesburg, Jacana, 218-36. Von Holdt, K (2010) The South African post-apartheid bureaucracy. In Omano Edigheji (ed) Constructing a Democratic Developmental State in South Africa. Cape Town, HSRC Press, 241-60. PARI paper.doc 13