DOING GOOD: - Boston University

advertisement
What is the Bottom Line for Nonprofit Organizations?
A History of Measurement in the British Voluntary Sector
Emily Barman
Department of Sociology
Boston University
October 26, 2006
Abstract
Over the last two decades, nonprofit organizations in the United Kingdom
have faced increased pressure to measure their activities in order to
demonstrate their competency, to achieve legitimacy, and to obtain
funding. This paper draws from recent literature in the sociology of
science to examine quantification in the British nonprofit sector as a
historically situated and socially constructed process. Using archival and
secondary documents, I find that quantification is not a new pressure for
charities in the UK; moreover, while they have employed metrication in
the past, what activities nonprofits have measured, and the importance of
measurement for their organizational success, has altered over the course
of the century.
NOTE: This is a working paper that should not be cited without permission of author.
What is the Bottom Line for Nonprofit Organizations?
A History of Measurement in the British Voluntary Sector
Emily Barman
Over the last two decades, nonprofit organizations (NPOs) in the United
Kingdom, the United States, Canada, and elsewhere have faced increased pressure to
measure their activities in order to demonstrate their competency, to achieve legitimacy,
and often to obtain funding (Connor 1993; Murray and Tassie 1995, Jones 1996; National
Council for Voluntary Organisations 2003; Paton 2003; Cairns, Harris, Hutchison, and
Tricker 2005). Performance measurement has been defined as the reporting of the
observable, quantifiable characteristics of charities’ programs and practices (Volkman
1999:27). In the United Kingdom, various methods of performance measurement have
appeared, including quality assessment, such as Practical Quality Assurance System for
Small Organisations, Excellence Model, Investors in People, ISO 9000, Charter Mark,
and Quality Mark; analysis of the social impact of charities, through Social Audit;
benchmarking; and outcome measurement (Charities Evaluation Services 2002; National
Council for Voluntary Organisations 2003; Paton 2003). All of these modes of
metrication are concerned with quantifying charities in relationship to effectiveness: that
is, assessing their successful provision of services or goods.
Performance measurement has been the subject of much concern and interest
among participants, observers, and academics of the nonprofit sector. Scholarship has
focused on its consequences for voluntary and community organizations, their programs,
and their clients. The use of performance measurement has been shown to result in the
standardization of services, inhibit innovation, produce mission drift, and lead to conflicts
over accountability to different constituencies (Kanter and Summers 1987; Ospina, Diaz,
and O’Sullivan 2002; Paton 2000). However, we know less about the historical
determinants of this move towards performance measurement. The turn to quantification
is typically understood as a recent pressure for NPOs. Its growth has been explained by
the appeal of the universal criteria of neutrality and objectivity, as the field has become
increasingly rationalized, bureaucratized, and made subject to market forces (Murray and
Tassie 1995; Paton 2003; Salamon 2003; Cairns, Harris, Hutchison, and Tricker 2005).
In his assessment of the rise of performance measurement, for example, Frumkin
(2004:52) concludes that “as philanthropy has moved from something individual donors
did during their retirement to something carried out by professionals in perpetuity, both
effectiveness and accountability have become central concerns.”
However, recent literature in the history of science provides an alternative
perspective on the rise of performance measurement for charities. This research has
sought to demonstrate that quantification is not a neutral technique employed for reasons
of efficiency and rationality. These authors put in question the traditional assumption
that metrication captures an already existing and independent reality; measurement does
not reflect but constitutes social reality (MacKenzie 1978; Fineman 2004; Miller 2006).
In consequence, calculation is viewed as a product of contestations between actors over
legitimacy and resources (Porter 1995; Power 1997; DesRosieres 1998; Espeland and
Stevens 1998; Mennicken 2002): it is “‘constructed,’ conventional, and arrived at through
negotiation” (DesRosieres 2001:340). In all, these scholars work to specify the
conditions under which particular modes and systems of calculation are made possible
2
and enacted across different social arenas and historical time periods (Anderson 1988;
Carruthers and Espeland 1991; Callon 1998; Miller 2001).
As the use of performance measurement in the voluntary sector becomes
naturalized and taken for granted, we risk losing sight of how quantification for charities
has been shaped by specific social, political, and professional interests and contexts.
Focusing on the case of the United Kingdom, this paper is the first to approach
measurement in the nonprofit sector as a historically situated and socially constructed
process. To do so, it begins by specifying the challenge of measurement for voluntary
organizations. It next places performance measurement within a historical context:
analyzing whether and how nonprofit organizations in England have employed
metrication over the course of the last century. I find that, in contrast to recent claims, a
concern for quantification is not a new pressure for charities in the UK. Moreover, while
they have employed metrication in the past, what activities nonprofits have measured,
and the importance of measurement for their organizational success, has altered over the
course of the century.
Measurement and the Voluntary Sector
Measurement has been defined as “any process by which a value is assigned to
the level or state of some quality of an object of study” (Bulmer 2001:455). In the
nonprofit sector, measurement occurs when charities make numerical worth of some
aspect of their organizational support, structure, or practices. As Paton (2003:1) asks,
“how good are we at doing good?” The task of assessing performance in the voluntary
sector is complicated by the absence of a single and shared criterion for success (Kanter
3
and Summers 1987). In contrast, organizations in the for-profit sector can be assessed for
goodness based on their rate of profit – the financial return received on a business
undertaking after all operating expenses have been met. But, voluntary organizations’ do
not pursue profit: in result, the goal of effectiveness in the voluntary sector is complicated
by the “lack of any suitable overall performance measure analogous to ‘return on capital’
in industry” (Handy 1981: 3). As Peter Drucker (1990:107) concluded in his study of
nonprofit organizations’, “what is the bottom line when there is no ‘bottom line’”?
This challenge of measurement is compounded by the extent of external oversight
faced by the voluntary sector. In both England and the United States, the central
government historically has not held voluntary organizations to any standards beyond
compliance with the legal requirement of the non-distribution constraint.1 Further, unlike
firms, nonprofits are not responsible to a body of owners or shareholders. Legally,
donors and recipients of goods/services have no rights over the actions of NPOs
(Frumkin 2002; Kendall and Knapp 1995).
And yet, despite the absence of the standard of profit and nonprofits’ freedom
from regulatory and statutory oversight, my claim in this paper is that we can identify
definite trends in the types and availability of modes of measurement for charities in the
United Kingdom over the 20th century – and charities only, as trusts or foundations are
not included in this analysis. Drawing from archival research and secondary documents,
1
Over the last two decades, however, the central government in England and Wales has
extended its oversight of voluntary and community organizations to increasingly more
aspects of their structure and activities. Similar steps are being considered in the United
States at the state and federal levels of government as well (Wolverton 2005).
4
specifically examining government reports, the publications of individual charities and
trade associations, and academic and advisory texts on the voluntary sector, this essay
articulates three distinct but interrelated claims. First, I show how the use of
measurement is not limited to the contemporary period: instead, different historical
periods in England have been dominated by different standards of measurement.
Secondly, I claim that the prevalence of measurement for the English voluntary sector
waxes and wanes over time in response to shifting understandings of which social sphere
is responsible for the public good. Finally, I show how the rise of various standards of
measurement has been shaped by specific social, political, and professional interests and
contexts, both internal and external to the sector itself.
Philanthropy and the Assessment of Community Need
The first point here is that measurement in the voluntary sector is not limited to
the present day. The current concern for performance measurement is often discussed as
a recently emergent dynamic for voluntary organizations’ in England, the U.S., and
elsewhere (Paton 2003; Salamon 2003; Cairns, Harris, Hutchison, and Tricker 2005). In
contrast, measurement, that is the use of quantification, first appeared in the English
voluntary sector in the early 20th century. From about 1900s to the World War I period,
an emerging group of social service professionals, committed to a new vision of the task
of philanthropy, employed measurement as a means to justify their methods and modes of
social change. In so doing, they formed part of a larger and ongoing attempt to
systematize the provision of philanthropy that had appeared in the Victorian period, but
5
they replaced an earlier attempt to intervene at the level of the individual with that of the
community. Measurement was central to their project.
Prior to this point, the Victorian age had been characterized of the “organization
of charity” – the rationalization of the delivery of social assistance (Prochaska 1988). As
represented by the Charity Organisation Society (COS) in the mid-19th century, for
example, charity would now be provided in the most efficient and effective manner
possible. First, the COS attempted to streamline the provision of services, by replacing
charities’ individual, arbitrary provision of care with the centralized and coordinated
provision of services. Secondly, only worthy individuals and families would be assisted
(Humphreys 1995). Morris (1955:30) summarized this view, noting that “man was
master of his personal destiny even in a complicated industrial society, and that he should
be able by his own efforts to provide for himself and his dependents in sickness,
unemployment, and old age if he worked hard and practiced thrift and temperance.” In
the eyes of its leaders, previous charitable efforts had been based in sentimentalism: in
contrast, the COS would distinguish between the deserving and undeserving poor through
the use of case work and a central registry of recipients (Charity Organisation Society
1922; Thane 1982; Humphreys 1995; Lewis 1995).
But a new vision of philanthropy, led by a new group of social service
professionals, was emerging by 1900. The Edwardian period saw a similar emphasis on
the rationalization of philanthropy but at a new level or unit of intervention. As with the
Victorian period and the COS, coordinating agencies, such as the Guilds of Help,
Councils of Social Service, Rural Community Councils, and the National Council of
Social Service, were established to assure the effective and efficient provision of
6
assistance. But, while the emphasis of coordination and centralization remained from the
earlier period, the unit of attention in the Edwardian period was different. While the COS
had argued that social amelioration occurred at the level of the individual, now the
solution was to be found at level of the community (Owen 1966; Prochaska 1988). A
new group of professionals sought to replace the fragmented and atomistic provision of
assistance to individuals with a new holistic concern for the health of a geographically
bounded and interdependent notion of community (National Council of Social Service
1926). The “essential characteristic” of this new vision of social service was its “relation
to the idea of community. It was concerned not so much with relieving the destitute
individual…as with creating and fostering the spirit of community among a generation
which seemed to have lost a great of its traditional social cohesion” (Cole 1945:24).
Social problems were no longer those of individuals but rather those of the
community and, accordingly, the task of professionals, voluntary organisations, and
coordinating bodies changed as well (Macadam 1934). At the local level, Guilds of Help
were formed in many English town and cities, for which civic betterment by the
community was the desire (Laybourn 1994:10). Similarly, settlement houses were
created in some large cities: according to Standish Meacham (1987:50), the settlement
house constituted the “machinery of connection” – an attempt to create community
amidst social disintegration through face-to-face interactions. At the national level, the
National Council of Social Service was established in 1919, premised on the belief that
the “old fashioned-conception of social work as an effort to help other people must give
place to a new conception of social service as the common effort to achieve social wellbeing” – to quote from a 1927 edition of Social Service Review (Morgan 1948:80).
7
This turn to the community was both shaped by but also reflected in the use of
measurement by leaders of this new movement; specifically, the employment of social
surveys to quantify and demonstrate the community-wide nature of poverty and other
pressing societal challenges (Bulmer, Bales, and Sklar 1991) . Booth’s (1892) and
Rowntree’s (1902) influential social surveys of London and York were followed by a
multitude of analyses of other cities and towns across the nation (Bosanquet 1912;
Freeman 2002). These social surveys sought to present aggregate data on the scope and
composition of each locale (Morris 1955); they “located social problems in their
historical context and promoted local, community-based solutions” (Freeman 2002:74),
As Pat Thane (1982) has shown, aggregate statistics – averages and percentages – were
used to represent the status of the community and the causes of those social problems. In
his 1892 survey of London, for example, Booth (as quoted in Morris 1955:1978) urged
readers that “to judge rightly we need to bear both in mind, never to forget the numbers
when thinking of the percentages, nor the percentages when thinking of the numbers.
The last is difficult to those whose daily experience or whose imagination brings vividly
before them the trials and sorrows of individual lives.”
Measurement, then, appeared in voluntary sector in the early twentieth century as
a tactic by which a new set of actors could both frame and justify their new understanding
of the causes of social problems and the corresponding modes of intervention and
amelioration. Unlike the current day, in which nonprofits numerically assess the success
of their efforts, charities in the 1900s and 1910s sought to quantify the target of their
intervention. While still concerned with efficiency and effectiveness in organizational
form, as had been the case with leaders of the COS movement, these nonprofit
8
professionals employed the quantification of community need to propagate and to
legitimate their particular view of how the voluntary sphere should move forward.
Voluntary Action and the Welfare State
Yet, and this is my second point, a historical review of the English voluntary
sector in the 20th century does not see a continuation of this concern over the
rationalization of assistance, and the corresponding measurement of community need.
Instead, beginning in the 1930s and on, we see a marked change in the discourse
surrounding the voluntary sector – from efficiency to inefficiency, and from rationality to
irrationality. Understandings of the voluntary sector radically altered with the gradual
growth of the welfare state from the 1910s and on (Finlayson 1990). Beginning with the
Unemployed Workmen Act of 1905, the Education (Provision of Meals) Act of 1906, and
the National Insurance Act of 1911, the role of the central state in providing social
services began to expand to include an increasingly larger proportion of services
previously provided by the voluntary sector.
The growth of the welfare state influenced understandings of the proper scope and
role of NPOs. While there was recognition of the increasing domain of government, this
did not mean that the voluntary sector should disappear. Instead, it was seen as taking on
a supplemental role to central government, what Sidney and Beatrice Webb (1912)
labeled the “extension ladder” view of the voluntary sector (Kramer 1981). Also called
the New Philanthropy by Elizabeth Macadam (1934), the state was understood to provide
a minimum standard of living for all while the voluntary sector would provide critical but
essentially supplementary work.
9
What then were the scope and responsibilities of the voluntary sphere? To begin,
it was implicitly opposed to the state, which was perceived to run along lines of
bureaucracy, of rational action, and of efficiency and effectiveness (according to one
1937 government report, as cited in Finlayson 1990). Correspondingly, a popular view
emerged of the voluntary sector as the site in society of flexibility, innovation, and
meaning (when observers were feeling positive, and as a site of inefficiency, amateurism,
and waste, when others were not), thus representing a fundamental shift from earlier
attempt to organize the provision of philanthropy in the Victorian and Edwardian periods
(Kendall and Knapp 1996; Lewis 1995). Even professionals in the sector professed this
perspective, with a 1959 report by social workers concluding that voluntary bodies
possess the right to be inconsistent (as quoted in Owen 1966).
In its basis in sentiment, flexibility, and inefficiency, the nonprofit sector would
nonetheless provide many useful functions for attaining the public good (Macadam 1934;
Simey 1937; Prochaska 1988). First, it was the social space in which pioneer work could
occur. According to authors such as Constance Braithwaite in 1938, charities could
experiment and innovative more easily than government agencies. “Where flexibility is a
special requirement, the contribution of voluntary agencies can be of critical importance.
State services must, in general, follow established routines, their rules of procedure
cannot take into account the emergencies that crop up nor cover the infinite variations in
the human plight” (Owen 1966:534). If these new experiments were deemed successful,
they would then be taken up by the state on a larger scale (Mess 1948). “Administration
consolidates, universalizes, and standardizes the ventures of faith” (Lindsay 1945:298).
10
Secondly, the voluntary sphere was to be responsible for the provision of special
individualized care, as opposed to the state’s mass provision of care oriented around the
median citizen. Clement Atlee (from Briggs and McCarthy 1984, as quoted in Prochaska
1988:84), then president of Toynbee Hall, stated that “we shall always have alongside the
great range of public services, the voluntary services which humanize our national life
and bring it down from the general to the particular.” Or, as L.F. Ellis (1927:391)
concluded in his review of the respective responsibilities of the public and private
spheres, “voluntary service is individual in essence, and is seen at its best when it deals
with individuals in an individual way.”
Finally, NPOs took on a new function: they would constitute a mechanism of
citizenship. Voluntary action by individuals would result in both societal and personal
benefits. Collectively, as emphasized in the Beveridge Report of 1948 (Beveridge 1948),
it prevented totalitarianism in the age of the welfare state (Kramer 1981). Individually,
participation in voluntary associations allowed citizens the opportunity for membership
and participation in community, otherwise minimized or denied in a welfare state.
Writing at the time, Mary Morris (1955:207) put forward that the nonprofit sector
“provided for individual citizens who cannot fully exercise their powers in their day-today work and in politics to acquire for themselves that essential ingredient of the good
life – personal participation in the affairs of community.”
Thus, in short, as the welfare state expanded, the voluntary sector no longer bore
the weight of delivering social services and solving social ills. Instead, it was the space
of experimentation, flexibility, and meaning. In result, the use of measurement markedly
declined, if not disappeared. With this new vision of the voluntary sector, its members
11
were no longer intent on quantifying need or results and on justifying their employment
of particular methods and modes of assistance. This relative absence of metrication
stands in contrast to both earlier and later periods in England, when measurement arose
as the nonprofit sector held far larger responsibility for addressing social problems.
Charities and Financial Efficiency
The dominant discourse in England about the accepted inefficiency and
ineffectiveness of the voluntary sector, and the corresponding lack of attention to
measurement, did alter in the late 1960s. In this period, we can see a concern arise over
the legitimacy of NPOs which relied on donations. Metrication reappeared and was
employed by nonprofits to assuage that worry and to demonstrate competency. However,
a new aspect of voluntary organizations was being quantified, in contrast to that of the
early twentieth century and its assessment of community need. Increasingly, nonprofits
were being judged for goodness based on their financial efficiency – the ratio of
fundraising costs to total income.
This turn to the measurement of the financial legitimacy of charities was
expressed in a variety of ways. Newspaper stories examined nonprofits from the
perspective of fiscal efficiency (Clark 1968; The Times 1966). In the late 1960s, the
Community Council (a watchdog organization for consumers) began publishing an
annual report that assessed the largest nonprofits in terms of their financial efficiency –
how much of a pound’s donation went to overhead as opposed to services (Community
Council 1960). Similarly, by the mid 1960s, the Charity Commission, the legal regulator
and registrar of charities and trusts in the England and Wales, had received enough
12
complaints about nonprofit organizations that it requested the National Council of Social
Service to investigate fundraising methods in the voluntary sector (London Metropolitan
Archives 1969; Nightingale 1973). Like the Community Council, the NCSS
recommended that donors examine charities’ financial ratios in order to determine if they
were legitimate or not. Finally, as the documentary evidence of the NCSS’ working party
makes clear, the majority of large charities were employing financial ratios in their
fundraising material in order to demonstrate their legitimacy to donors (London
Metropolitan Archives 1969). Clearly, by the late 1960s, nonprofits were increasingly
being assessed for goodness based on the criteria of financial efficiency.
One important question concerns why the turn to financial efficiency as the
standard of measurement for charities occurred in the 1960s. Two developments seem
significant here. First, in 1960, the Charity Commission extended its sphere of
responsibility in the English and Welsh nonprofit sectors. Previously, the Charity
Commission had only regulated trusts. Beginning in 1960, the Charity Commission
began to supervise operating nonprofits as well. According to its annual report of 1962,
it almost immediately began to receive complaints from donors over suspicions of
financial fraud and other forms of illegitimate activity on the part of voluntary
associations (Charity Commissioners 1962). So, if givers had possessed apprehension
about nonprofits’ use of donations prior to 1960, they had no place for the public
expression of their concern until that point. Secondly, there is a possibility that donors
became concerned about financial efficiency as charities’ fundraising tactics became
increasingly depersonalized and professionalized in the 1960s. Many large nonprofits
had begun employing professional fundraisers and consultants by this period, without
13
government oversight of that relationship (The Times 1962; Clarke 1968; Snell 1972).2
Accordingly, the Charity Commission reported that one of donors’ major complaints was
that these professional fundraisers received too large a percentage of donations, with too
little going to the intended beneficiaries (Charity Commissioners 1962).
But, while financial efficiency appeared as a measure of the legitimacy of
collecting charities in the 1960s, no accompanying yardstick or guideline was publicly
generated by watchdog organizations, umbrella associations, or the government. While
donors were encouraged to scrutinize the financial efficiency of charities, and fundraising organizations, by all accounts, were publicizing their financial ratios, there was no
agreed upon percentage that could be employed by observers to differentiate an efficient
charity from an inefficient charity.
This lack of consensus on the part of the Charity Commission, the NCSS, and
watchdog organizations such as Community Council to produce a maximum figure for
overhead costs resulted from the conjuncture of several factors. For one, the basis for
systematic assessment of a charity’s finances was simply not present at the time. By all
accounts, there both was disagreement as to how to define terms such as administration
and an absence of standard accounting of finances by nonprofit organizations
(Nightingale 1973; Yeo 1983). Despite continuing calls for some standardization of
reporting activities, it was not until 1988 that uniform standards were proposed for
charities’ accounting practices by the accounting profession in the UK (Connolly and
Hyndman 2000).
2
The Charities Act of 1992 entailed the first regulation by the central government of
professional fundraisers’ activities in the English and Welsh voluntary sectors.
14
Secondly, the lack of a yardstick for financial efficiency was part of a larger
absence of a code of standards or ethics for voluntary organizations in the 1960s. Here,
umbrella or trade associations, most notably the NCSS which ideally should have taken
on responsibility, refused to put forward a larger code that involved such issues as proper
fundraising ethics, accounting measures, and financial ratios. The NCSS felt unwilling to
take on this job of regulator without the ability to sanction violating NPOs. It saw this
responsibility as properly that of the Charity Commission or another government office
(London Metropolitan Archives 1969). But, by asking the NCSS to assume a regulatory
role over the voluntary sector, the Charity Commission had passed on the task of
overseeing collecting charities except in cases of illegality and fraud. Without the power
to sanction, according to reports at the time, the NCSS did not see any merit in investing
the time and energy needed to monitor voluntary associations (Nightingale 1973).
Nonprofit Organizations and Performance Measurement
Today, a concern over financial efficiency remains present within the nonprofit
sector but an even more important mode of measurement has emerged, centered on the
performance of voluntary associations (Paton 2003; Cairns, Harris, Hutchison, and
Tricker 2005). In his guide for nonprofit management in the United Kingdom, for
example, Hind (1995) concluded that the “concepts of cost and value for money are not at
the core of the performance evaluation process…the emphasis of performance evaluation
is on assessing whether the specific project in question, or the charity’s activities
generally, have been effective. Have the anticipated objectives been achieved?” In Great
Britain, nonprofits possess several options if they seek to assess their performance,
15
including Practical Quality Assurance System for Small Organisations, Excellence
Model, Investors in People, ISO 9000, Charter Mark, and Quality Mark, Social Audit,
and outcome measurement (Charities Evaluation Services 2002; National Council for
Voluntary Organizations 2003; Paton 2003).
The timing of this most return turn to quantification in the voluntary sector
occurred as the welfare state was being dismantled in the United Kingdom. The
Conservative Party, elected to power in 1979, was committed to cutting the central
government’s provision of public goods. It did so through a variety of tactics – by
implementing welfare pluralism through the devolution of programs to local government;
by creating a mixed economy of welfare that transferred the provision of some social
services from state agencies to private and nonprofit organizations; and by eliminating
other social programs altogether (Brenton 1985; Pinker 1992; Milward 1994; Deakin
1995).
Concordantly, increasing concern was expressed about the proper role and
functioning of the nonprofit sector. Multiple publications by government offices, trade
associations, and observers called for an expanded role of the voluntary sector in the
provision of public services (Wolfenden 1978; Gladstone 1979; Handy 1981; Yeo 1983;
Knight 1984; Harris and Billis 1985; Mellow 1985; Woodfield 1987). For instance,
Francis Gladstone’s 1979 report, entitled “Voluntary Action in a Changing World,”
promoted the voluntary sector as a “third way” between the market and state as the
optimal mode by which to reach the collective good. Many of these reports demanded
greater accountability and openness on the part of charities. They encouraged nonprofits
to seek efficiency and effectiveness in their management (Kramer 1981). In its
16
assessment of the proper role of the nonprofit sector in England, the Wolfenden
Committee (1978:192) concluded:
We are certainly not suggesting that all voluntary organisations are
inefficient or that they are not cost-effective. But there still clings to them,
in the minds of many, an aura of amateurishness, and for their own sakes it
would be well that this should be dissolved of their own volition. They
owe it to themselves to earn and deserve a reputation for the maximum
amount of straightforward efficiency which is compatible with the
spontaneity and freedom which are their primary characteristics.
By the 1990s, general worry over the efficacy of the voluntary sector had been
replaced by the appearance and spread of a variety of models and standards of
performance measurement to assess NPOs. As Nicholas Deakin (1995), Rob Paton
(2003), and others (Morrison 1994; National Council for Voluntary Organisations 2003)
have shown, the emergence of and necessity for performance measurement resulted from
the central government’s use of supervisory and monitoring tactics as the provision of
social services was transferred from government agencies to independent organizations.
Drawing their models from those employed by the private sector, government funders
required recipient organizations to account for and measure their performance by
employing quality assessment systems (Power 1997). “Government sought to manage
performance without managing organizations” (Paton 2003:31). These models of
performance from the private sector were diffused through the voluntary sector through
the use of funding restrictions by private and public donors, the growth of professional
schools, and trade associations and consultants’ provision of training and assistance
(Hedley 1985; Feek 1988; Webb 1990; Harris, Mainelli, and O’Callaghan 2002).
In all, as had occurred at the start of the last century, measurement emerged as a
challenge for charities when they held increased, if not a leading, responsibility for
17
meeting the public good. The Nathan Report similarly concluded that the “need for
efficiency and effectiveness in the voluntary sector increases in importance as the
demands upon it become greater” (National Council for Voluntary Organisations
1990:1). This concern to demonstrate effectiveness stands in sharp contrast to the earlier
discourse that characterized the voluntary sphere in the 1930s and on, which had
emphasized its irrationality and inefficiency.
Conclusion
I conclude by highlighting the central arguments of the paper. First, I have shown
that, in contrast to some current claims that measurement in the English voluntary sector
is a new challenge specific to the need to demonstrate success, quantification has been
employed by nonprofit organizations at various moments in the past. However, and here
is another key point, what activities or processes have been measured by charities has
altered over time: while social service professionals in the early 20th century measured
community need to justify their new methods of intervention, charities in the 1960s and
1970s reporting their financial efficiency to demonstrate their legitimacy. Given the lack
of profit as a standard of assessment in the voluntary sector, a variety of criteria of
measurement are possible and have been employed by charities in England over time.
Secondly, the necessity to quantify in the voluntary sphere has waxed and waned
over the course of the last century; metrication is not a constant and/or necessary task for
charities. At particular moments in the past, nonprofit organizations have been celebrated
for their inefficiency, while at other moments, they have been perceived as fully capable
of rationality. Measurement, it appears, largely occurs in historical periods where the
18
nonprofit sector holds substantive responsibility for the provision of social services. We
can view the extent of nonprofits’ need to quantify as the inverse of the size and scope of
the central government. In this, the paper confirms a larger theoretical perspective that
sees the scale and presence of the nonprofit sector as derived from the capabilities and
activities of government in providing public goods (Weisbrod 1977; Salamon and
Anheier 1998).
Finally, I have attempted to show that the use of measurement is never neutral or
objective. Instead, measurement emerges in moments of uncertainty and change as social
actors – whether charity professionals, donors, or government funders, pursue their own
goals and agendas by imposing particular standards of quantification onto voluntary
organizations (Abbott 1988; Dejean, Gond, and Leca 2004). The particular content of
quantification – what activities, practices, or actors get assessed and in what ways–
derives from and reflects larger debates and contestations over the appropriate purpose
and nature of the voluntary sector. Measurement, therefore, is intended to establish,
through a particular mode of assessment, how charities relate to a specific definition of
legitimacy and success. The study of quantification in the nonprofit sector, therefore,
provides one window onto larger and ongoing debates concerning the proper goal/s and
methods of voluntary associations.
19
References
Abbott, A. (1988). The System of Professions: An Essay on the Division of Expert Labor.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Anderson, M. (1988). The American Census: A Social History. New Haven: Yale
University Press.
Beveridge, W. (1948). Voluntary Action. London: Allen and Unwin.
Booth, C. (1892)[1972]. Life and Labour of the Poor in London, Volume 1. FIX
Bosanquet, H. (1912). Social conditions in Provincial towns. London: Macmillan.
Braithwaite, C. (1938). The Voluntary Citizen: An Enquiry into the Place of Philanthropy
in the Community. London: Methuen.
Brenton, M. (1985). The Voluntary Sector in the British Social Services. London:
Longman.
Bulmer, M.K.. (2001). Social measurement: what stands in its way? Social Research, 68,
2, 455-480.
Bulmer, M., K. Bales, and K.K. Sklar, eds. (1991). The Social Survey in Historical
Perspective, 1880-1940. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Cairns, B., M. Harris, R. Hutchison, and M. Tricker. 2005. Improving performance? the
adoption and implementation of quality systems in UK nonprofits. Nonprofit
Management and Leadership 16, 2, 135-151.
Callon, M. (1998). Introduction: the embeddedness of economic markets in economics.
In M. Callon (ed.), The Laws of the Markets. London: Blackwell.
20
Carruthers, B. G., and W. N. Espeland. (1991). Accounting for rationality: double-entry
bookkeeping and the rhetoric of economic rationality. American Journal of
Sociology, 97, 31-69.
Charities Evaluation Services. (2002). First Steps in Quality. London: Charities
Evaluation Services.
Charity Commissioners. (1962). Report of the Charity Commissioners for England and
Wales for the Year 1962. London: Stationery Office.
Charity Organisation Society. (1922). Introduction. Charity Organisation Quarterly, July,
2, 28-29.
Clark, M. (1968). In the name of charity. Sunday Telegraph, June 9, 8.
Cole, G.D.H. (1945). A retrospect of the history of voluntary social service. In A.F.C.
Bourdillon (ed.), Voluntary Social Services. London: Methuen & Co., Ltd.
Community Council. (1960). Charities: where your money goes. Focus, 3, 12, 9-13.
Connolly, C. and N. Hyndman. (2003). Charity accounting: an empirical analysis of the
impact of recent changes. British Accounting Review, 32, 77-100.
Connor, A. (1993). Monitoring Ourselves. London: Charities Evaluation Services.
Deakin, N. (1995). The perils of partnership: the voluntary sector and the state, 19451992. In J.D. Smith, C. Rochester and R. Hedley (eds.), An Introduction to the
Voluntary Sector. London: Routledge.
Dejean, F., J. Gond, and B. Leca. (2004). Measuring the unmeasured: An institutional
entrepreneur strategy in an emerging industry. Human Relations, 57, 6, 741-764.
Desrosieres. A. (2001). How real are statistics? four possible attitudes. Social Research,
68, 2, 339-355.
21
___________. (1998). The Politics of Large Numbers: A History of Statistical
Reasoning. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Drucker, P. (1990). Managing the Nonprofit Organization: Practices and Principles. New
York: Harper Collins.
Ellis, L.F. (1927). The respective spheres of public authorities and voluntary
organizations in the administration of social services. Public Administration, 5,
391-393.
Espeland, W. and M. Stevens. (1998). Commensuration as a social process. American
Journal of Sociology, 24, 313-343.
Feek, W. (1988). Working Effectively: A Guide to Evaluation Techniques. Bedford
Square Press.
Fineman, S. (2004): Getting the measure of emotion - and the cautionary tale of
emotional intelligence. Human Relations, 57, 719-740
Finlayson, G. (1990). A moving frontier: voluntarism and the state in british social
welfare 1911-1949. Twentieth Century British History, 1, 2, 183-206.
Freeman, M. (2002). The provincial social survey in edwardian britain. Historical
Research, 75, 73-89.
Frumkin, P. (2004). Trouble in Foundationland: Looking Back, Looking Ahead.
Indianapolis, IN: Hudson Institute.
_________. (2002). On Being Nonprofit: A Conceptual and Policy Primer. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press.
Gladstone, F. (1979). Voluntary Action in a Changing World. London: Bedford Square
Press.
22
Handy, C. (1988). Understanding Voluntary Organisations. London: Penguin Books.
_______. (1981). Improving Effectiveness in Voluntary Organisations. London: National
Council on Voluntary Organisations.
Harris, I., M. Mainelli, and M. O’Callaghan. (2002). Evidence of worth in not-for-profit
sector organisations. Strategic Change, 11, 399-410.
Harris, M. and D. Billis. (1985). Organising Voluntary Agencies: A Guide through the
Literature. London: Bedford Square Press.
Hedley, R. (1985). Measuring Success: A Guide to Evaluation for Voluntary and
Community Groups. London: Advance.
Hind, A. (1995). The Governance and Management of Charities. East Barnet: Voluntary
Sector Press, Ltd.
Humphreys, R. (1995). Poor Relief and Charity, 1869-1945: the London Charity
Organization Society. London: Palgrave
Jones, R. (1996). Swimming together: the tidal change in statutory agencies and the
voluntary sector. In C. Hanvey and T. Philpot (eds.), Sweet Charity: The Role and
Workings of Voluntary Organisations. London: Routledge.
Kanter, R.M. and D.V. Summers. (1987). “Doing well while doing good.” In W.W.
Powell (ed.), The Non Profit Sector: A Research Handbook. New Haven: Yale
University Press.
Kendall, J. and M. Knapp. (1995). A loose and baggy monster. In J. Davis Smith, C.
Rochester, and R. Hedley (eds.), An Introduction to the Voluntary Sector.
London: Routledge.
23
Kendall, J. and M. Knight, eds. (1996). The Voluntary Sector in the UK. Manchester:
Manchester University Press.
Knight, B., ed. (1984). Management in Voluntary Organisations, ARVAC Occasional
Paper No. 6. Wivenhoe: Association of Researchers in Voluntary Action and
Community Involvement.
Kramer, R. (1981). Voluntary Agencies in the Welfare State. Berkeley: University of
California Press.
Laybourn, K. (1994). The Guild of Help and the Changing Face of Edwardian
Philanthropy. Lewiston: The Edwin Mellen Press.
Lewis, J. (1995). The Voluntary Sector, the State, and Social Work in Britain: The
Charity Organisation Society/Family Welfare Association since 1869. Aldershot:
E. Elgar.
Lindsay, A.D. (1945). Conclusion. In A.F.C. Bourdillon (ed.), Voluntary Social
Services. London: Methuen & Co., Ltd.
London Metropolitan Archive. (1969). Charitable Fund-Raising Report of a Working
Party set up by the National Council Social Service. LMA/4016/PA/C/01/029.
Macadam, E. (1934). The New Philanthropy. London: George Allen & Unwin.
MacKenzie, D. (1978). Statistical theory and social interests: a case study. Social Studies
of Science, 8, 35-85.
Meachan, S. (1987). Toynbee Hall and Social Reform: 1880-1914. The Search for
Community. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Mellow, H.W. (1985). The Role of Voluntary Organisations in Social Welfare. London:
Croom Helm.
24
Mennicken, A. (2002). Bringing calculation back in: sociological studies in accounting.”
Bringing calculation back in: sociological studies in accounting. Economic
Sociology: European Electronic Newsletter, 3, 3, 17-27.
Mess, H.A., ed. (1948). Voluntary Social Services Since 1918. London: Kegal Paul.
Miller, P. (2006). Governing economic life: how sociologists forgot accounting.
www.fek.uu.se/forskning/uppsalalectures/UL_2006_PM_3.pdf. Retrieved 9/28/06
____________. (2001): "Governing by numbers: why calculative practices matter,"
Social Research, 68, 379.
Milward, H. (1994). Nonprofit contracting and the hollow state. Public Administration
Review, 54, 1, 73-77.
Morgan, J. (1948).The national council of social service with appendix on work in rural
areas. In H. Mess (ed.), Voluntary social services since 1918. London: Kegal
Paul.
Morris, M. (1955). Voluntary Organisations and Social Progress. London: Victor Gollanz
Ltd.
Morrison, S.J. (1994). Managing quality: an historical review. In B. Dale (ed.),
Managing Quality. New York: Prentice Hall.
Murray, V. and B. Tassie. (1995). Evaluating the effectiveness of nonprofit
organizations. In Jossey-Bass Handbook of Nonprofit Leadership and
Management. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
National Council for Voluntary Organisations. (2003). The Adoption and Use of Quality
Systems in the Voluntary System. London: National Council for Voluntary
Organisations.
25
____________________________________. (1990). Effectiveness and the Voluntary
Sector. London: National Council for Voluntary Organisations.
National Council of Social Service. (1926). Co-operation in Social Service. London:
National Council of Social Service.
Nightingale, B. (1973). Charities. London: Allen Lane.
Ospina, S., W. Diaz, and J.F. O’Sullivan. (2002). “Negotiating accountability: managerial
lessons from identity-based nonprofit organizations.” Nonprofit and Voluntary
Sector Quarterly, 31, 1, 5-31.
Owen, D. (1966). English Philanthropy, 1660-1960. London: Belknap Press.
Paton, R. (2003). Managing and Measuring Social Enterprises. London: Sage.
_______. (2000). What happens when nonprofits use quality models for self-assessment?
Nonprofit Management and Leadership, 11, 1, 21-34.
Pinker, R. (1992). Making sense of the mixed economy of welfare. Social Policy and
Administration, 4, 244-284.
Porter, T. M. (1995): Trust in Numbers : The Pursuit of Objectivity in Science and Public
Life. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Power, M. (1997). The Audit Society: Rituals of Verification. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Prochaska, F. (1988). The Voluntary Impulse: Philanthropy in Modern Britain. London:
Faber and Faber.
Rowntree, B.S. (1901). Poverty: A Study of Town Life. London: Macmillan and Co.,
Ltde.
26
Salamon, L. (2003). The Resilient Sector: The State of Nonprofit America. Washington,
DC: Brookings Institute Press.
Salamon, L. and H. Anheier. (1998). Social origins of civil society: explaining the
nonprofit sector cross-nationally. Voluntas, 9, 213–248.
Simey, T.S. (1937). Principles of Social Administration. London: Oxford University
Press.
Snell, G.S. (1972). The Charity management consultant. Social Service Quarterly, 45, 4,
127-130.
Thane, P. (1982). The Foundations of the Welfare State. New York: Longman.
The Times. (1966). Charities profit by hard selling. The Times, January 8, 9.
________. (1962). U.S. fund-raising methods help british causes. The Times, March 20,
5.
Volkmann, R. (1999). “Outcomes measurement: the new accounting standard for service
organizations.” Fundraising Management, 30, 26-27.
Webb, S., ed. (1990). Planning Strategy for Voluntary Organisations. London: The
Industrial Society.
Webb S. and B. Webb. (1912). The Prevention of Destitution. London: Longman.
Weisbrod, B. (1977). The Voluntary Nonprofit Sector. Lexington, MA: Lexington
Books.
Wolfenden, J. (1978). The Future of Voluntary Organisations: Report of the Wolfenden
Committee. London: Croom Helm.
Wolverton, Brad. (2005). Taking aim at charity. Chronicle of Philanthropy, 17, 13, 27-29.
27
Woodfield, P. (1987). Efficiency Scrutiny of the Supervision of Charities. London: Her
Majesty’s Stationery Office.
Yeo, T. (1983). Public Accountability and Regulation of Charities. London: Spastics
Society.
28
Download