Equity Returns and Monetary Policy: Evidence from the UK Georgios Chortareas* John Nankervis** and Emmanouil Noikokyris*** April 2009 Abstract This paper is an empirical study of the relationship between equity prices and monetary policy in the UK. The results, produced by an event study like methodology, indicate that equity prices react significantly and in an opposite direction to monetary policy shocks. Moreover, we find that although equities react significantly both to timing and level shocks in monetary policy, the latter trigger more significant reactions. The introduction of an Inflation Targeting regime has triggered changes in this relationship, altering the direction of equities response to both timing and level shocks. On days when there is a release of an Inflation Report the timing shocks appear to exert stronger effects than the level shocks, suggesting that the Inflation Report reveals valuable information about the timing of policy shocks. The Minutes of the MPC do not appear to trigger significant reactions on the same day; however, we find evidence that a release indicating a unanimous decision causes significant overreactions at the following MPC meeting. Finally, the effects from a monetary policy action are not only restricted on the day of the announcement but they extent for a period of up to 8 trading days ahead. JEL. No.: G14, E44, E52. Keywords: Monetary Policy, Inflation Targeting Framework, Event Studies. * Department of Economics, University of Athens, 14 Euripidou Str., 105 53 Athens, Greece email: gchortar@econ.uoa.gr ** Finance Group, Essex Business School, University of Essex, Wivenhoe Park, Colchester, CO4 3SQ, UK email: jcnank@essex.ac.uk *** Finance Group, Essex Business School University of Essex, Wivenhoe Park, Colchester, CO4 3SQ, UK email: enoiko@essex.ac.uk 1. Introduction This paper is an empirical examination of the relationship between monetary policy and equity prices in the UK. This relationship has seen much attention lately, as it features in major monetary policy debates about whether central banks should intervene in the capital markets to correct for any pricing misalignments. The increased emphasis that is attributed to the stock price channel of monetary policy has made the examination of this relationship a top priority in the agenda of policymakers, and Bernanke and Gertler (2000) even claim that the effects of monetary policy on asset prices might overshadow inflation stability as the primary objective of central banks. In this paper we address issues concerning the following three research objectives. First, we examine the contemporaneous relationship between monetary policy shocks and equity prices, and in particular we extract quantitative estimates of the equities’ reaction to changes both in the timing and the level of future policy actions. Second, we provide some empirical evidence about the effects from two types of communication from the Bank of England (hereafter, the Bank), the Inflation Report and the Minutes of the MPC. Finally, we examine whether the effects of monetary policy on equities materialise in full on the day of the policy decision, or the period of adjustment to the new monetary policy conditions extends for some days after the decision. The analysis in this paper contributes to the discussion about the relationship between monetary policy and asset prices by providing evidence from the UK equity market which is up to now scant. A discussion about the role of the Bank to the financial markets cannot be undertaken independently from a detailed analysis of the effects that monetary policy actions can have on 1 financial assets in the first place. The identification of monetary policy’s effects on equities can provide us initially with evidence regarding the significance of the stock market channel of transmission, as for such a channel of transmission to exist the monetary policy actions should exhibit some kind of impact on equities. Although the objectives of monetary policy refer to macroeconomic variables, the equity market constitutes a favourable area to conduct research about the effects of monetary policy as there the most direct effects of monetary policy materialise. This is an easy to grasp concept once one realises that if a monetary policy decision has informational value for investors this, according to the efficient markets paradigm, should be reflected in equities in a timely and unbiased manner. Theoretically, two different traditional mechanisms of how monetary policy affects equity prices exist (Mishkin, 1996). In the monetarist tradition a fall in the money supply results in a reduction in consumer spending which in turn leads to a fall in the demand and hence the price of stocks. The traditional Keynesian approach on the other hand suggests that a rise in interest rates drives investors to rebalance their portfolios including more bonds than stocks, in this way reducing the demand and hence the price of the stocks. Although the initial point of these two approaches is different, they both indicate that a monetary policy tightening (expansion) affects the financing conditions in the market and can have significant downward (upward) effects on stock market prices. The recent trend in policymaking has been to attribute the real effects of monetary policy mainly to its ability to shape inflation expectations and not just to the determination of the level of a nominal interest rate (see indicatively King, 2005; Bernanke, 2004). The inherent difficulty in quantifying expectations impedes the accurate estimation of the real effects of monetary policy, and thus complicates the work of central banks to achieve their macroeconomic objectives. The MPC of the Bank acknowledges the significance of 2 expectations in the transmission mechanism of monetary policy and for this reason it has introduced the Inflation Targeting regime since 19971. Although the overall efficiency of a monetary policy regime requires an assessment of its capacity to help economy recover when it is confronted with a serious downturn, in this paper we focus our attention on the effects from improved communication which constitutes an important feature of this new regime. The reason for this is that under such a framework communication obtains a central role in the efficient conduct of monetary policy, as it can be used along with the direct interest rate setting function of the Bank to trigger the desired reactions in the economy and make future policy actions more predictable. The existing empirical evidence regarding the relationship between equities and monetary policy mainly concerns the US and the bulk of the evidence supports the hypothesis that a contractionary (expansionary) monetary policy action is associated with a drop (hike) in equity prices2. The size of the reported responses depends on the sample selected, the empirical methodology used, and the identification of the monetary policy shocks. However, in all cases the response size is large enough to signify on the one hand that central banks’ actions are an important input in asset pricing models, and to support on the other hand the existence of a stock market channel of monetary policy transmission. Moreover, the rising importance of expectations in the identification of the effects of monetary policy has motivated researchers’ search for asymmetries in the relationship between equities and monetary policy shocks. The ambiguity in the factors that change expectations in the 1 The starting date for the inflation targeting framework in this paper is considered to be June 1997, after the establishment of the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC hereafter) setting. The reason for this is that until May 1997 the monetary policy decisions were taken by the Chancellor of Exchequer, and this could create uncertainty about the rationale of the action (Bernanke et al, 1999). 2 Ehrmann and Fratzscher, 2004; Farka, 2009; Bernanke and Kuttner, 2005; Craine and Martin, 2003; Thorbecke, 1997; Murdzhev and Tomljanovich, 2006; Honda and Kuroki, 2006; Rigobon and Sack, 2004; Lastrapes, 1998, Darrat, 1990; Fair, 2002; Jensen, Mercer and Johnson, 1996; Jensen and Mercer, 2002; Bredin et al, 2007 3 financial markets suggests that the impact of monetary policy actions on them is likely to differ across the different policy decisions, and as a result the reaction of the equities is likely to be asymmetric. A popular categorisation of monetary policy shocks that has only recently been developed is that between “timing” and “level” shocks (Bernanke and Kuttner, 2005; Farka, 2009; Kearns and Manners, 2006; Gürkaynak et al, 2005). In particular, the timing shocks refer to news about moving forward or postponing an expected policy action, while the level shocks refer to an unexpected change in the future level of interest rates. Intuition and empirical evidence suggest that persistent changes in the expectations about the level of future policy rates would exert larger impact on equities than changes in the expectations about the timing of a policy action (Bernanke and Kuttner, 2005; Farka, 2009). However there is also empirical evidence from Gürkaynak et al. (2005) which contradicts this finding, and the explanation they put forward is that the rise in equity prices following the better economic output as this is associated with positive level shocks is offset by the negative reaction of equities to higher discount rates. Other cases of asymmetries in the relationship between equity returns and monetary policy shocks that have seen much attention are those attributable to overreactions to “bad news”, to the direction of the policy actions, and to inactions of the Bank on a day of an MPC meeting (“non-announcement effects”). Bomfim (2001) has found that in the US the arrival of bad news (positive shocks) causes overreactions in the equity market, while the results of Bernanke and Kuttner (2005) support symmetric reactions. Moreover, the examination of the differences in markets’ response across tightening and easing policy actions, can reveal whether monetary policy actions can be used in a similar manner both to increase and decrease equity prices. The evidence about this type of asymmetric response in the US is still 4 inconclusive; Lobo (2000) reports an overreaction to rate hikes while Bernanke and Kuttner (2005) find no evidence in favour of this asymmetry. Finally, since King (2005) states that under the new regime “market interest rates react to what the central bank is expected to do [...] without making large moves in official interest rates” it would be useful to examine whether this pattern holds for the equity markets as well (Roley and Sellon, 1998; Bernanke and Kuttner, 2005). Considerable attention has also been drawn to the identification of the response of stock portfolios and industries to monetary policy shocks and in this vein we also examine in this paper the response of “size” and “value” portfolios (Perez-Quiros and Timmermann, 2000; Thorbecke, 1997 and Ehrmann and Fratzscher, 2004). In the second part of this paper we address the issue of improved communication under the Inflation Targeting regime. The transparency, which constitutes a basic feature of this new regime, is reputed to offer new ways of monetary policy transmission and to reinforce the efficiency of central banks’ actions (Bernanke, 2004 Reeves and Sawicki, 2007; King, 2007). In this vein, we examine the effects from Vickers’s (1998) “two main vehicles” of transparency, the Inflation Report and the MPC minutes, on equity prices as the identification of their effects on financial market expectations can be used to shed some light to the way that it can be employed by central banks to implement their policies. If the Bank wants to utilise the Inflation Report and the Minutes of the MPC to “increase awareness and understanding of its activities”, it should have a clear view initially as to how these types of communication are perceived by financial market participants. It needs an assessment of the relevance of these types of communication for the markets and of the way that their effects materialise. The Bank claims that an Inflation Report “sets out the detailed economic analysis and inflation projections on which the Bank's MPC bases its interest rate decisions”. Preliminary evidence on its role, set out in Fracasso et al. (2003), 5 suggests that an Inflation Report of improved quality is associated with the diminished impact of stock prices on monetary policy. Moreover, empirical evidence about the Minutes’ release indicates that the voting records add to the transparency and that they do not appear to trigger any unnecessary volatility in cases of divided opinions among MPC members (Gerlach-Kristen, 2004; Siklos, 2003). King (2007), on the other hand, asserts that the voting pattern is not a suitable means for forecasting future policy actions; the pattern should be perceived primarily as a guideline of how members of the MPC assess recent economic developments. Existing empirical research has studied how the communication method has affected the magnitude of the surprises in the financial markets and whether the desired reactions of asset prices occur (Ehrmann and Fratzscher, 2007). Reeves and Sawicki (2007), and Kohn and Sack (2003) examine the effects of the publications on the volatility of the prices of some financial assets, omitting however to provide any results for the direction of the reactions. Ehrmann and Fratzscher (2007) use a somewhat more refined technique, albeit subject to criticism due to the subjectivity in extracting the news from the communication, and the focus of their research is apart from examining the effects of communication on the monetary policy shocks also to examine the effects of communication on the level and the volatility of the financial asset prices. The existing evidence regarding the effects of the release of Bank’s Inflation Report and the MPC’s Minutes suggests that although it achieves to reduce the volatility of the surprises and to trigger reactions in the financial markets, the magnitude of these effects is smaller than those occurring from the Fed and the ECB’s communication (Ehrmann and Fratzscher, 2007; Reeves and Sawicki, 2007). In this paper we examine how the benchmark relationship between equities and monetary policy shocks is affected by the Bank’s communication. Reeves and Sawicki 6 (2007) and Kohn and Sack (2003) distinguish the monetary policy shocks from the communications’ shocks and measure the reactions of asset prices on the latter. In this paper we measure the reactions of equities to monetary policy news extracted from the communication of the Bank, and unlike Ehrmann and Fratzscher (2007) we choose to extract the monetary policy information from monetary policy shocks on the day of the release. We postulate that the monetary policy shocks on days of a communication encapsulate any monetary policy news from the communication released on that day, and as a result their comovement with equities reveals the way expectations about monetary policy change due to these publications. Moreover, in this paper we examine whether the effects from monetary policy actions materialise only on the day of the announcement or their effects materialise for a period following the announcement. The monetary policy action is an event acutely observed by the markets and the effects from a change in the levels of interest rates is not likely to be one-off on the day of the announcement, not only because a monetary policy action might proxy for changes in other macroeconomic variables relevant for asset pricing, but also because the markets might need more than one day to fully adjust to the new monetary conditions. The identification of the time horizon of the impact from a monetary policy action offers policymakers and investors more information for decision making, and for assessing and measuring the ultimate effects from monetary policy on equities. 2. UK monetary policy and the equity market. 2.1 The impact of UK Monetary Policy on Equity Prices. 7 The identification of the effects of monetary policy actions on equities undertaken in this section follows the “event-study” like methodology popularised by Bernanke and Kuttner (2005). A pioneering attempt to employ such empirical frameworks in the examination of the central banks actions’ impact on asset prices has been undertaken by Cook and Hahn (1989). The empirical implementation of this specification involves the estimation of the following model: ri iiUK i , (1) where ri stands for the daily stock market returns, iiUK is the raw change of the policy rate and the “event days” i are the days when a change in monetary policy rate took place. The error term is assumed to be orthogonal to the regressor and under this assumption the model does not have any omitted variables and/or endogeneity problems. Endogeneity and omitted variables insert bias into the estimation as other factors not reflecting monetary policy enter this relationship. The endogeneity problem arises as it is likely that the relationship between monetary policy and equities does not have only one direction, as the equity prices might also affect the monetary policy (see indicatively, Rigobon and Sack, 2003). As far as the omitted variables problem is concerned, this is due to the fact that both monetary policy proxies and equities are likely to be affected by other variables during the “event window”. The potential bias inserted in our estimation due to these two issues can be addressed by using high frequency data, as a short estimation period reduces the possibility that the effects from other news enter our relationship. The utilisation of daily data is a well established method to address these issues. Some studies, however, have employed intra-day data claiming that this provides stronger evidence (Andersson, 2007; Gürkaynak et al 2005; Farka, 2009). Farka (2009) claims that 8 employing intra-day data yields stronger equity responses while Gürkaynak et al. (2005) claims that the results are virtually the same except for some few observations when the reactions are stronger. In any case, for a paper mainly oriented towards uncovering the general trend in this relationship, conservatism is not such an undesirable feature and for this reason we will use daily data, as in Bernanke and Kuttner (2005). Another controversial issue when dealing with the empirical estimation of the effects of monetary policy on asset prices is the identification of the proxy for the monetary policy action. The utilisation of raw changes in policy rates is not likely to provide strong evidence as it fails to incorporate the fact that central banks’ actions are to a great extent expected by the market, and for this reason, current research opts for the utilisation of monetary policy shocks. A number of studies in this stream of research use residuals from VAR models to identify the monetary policy shocks and the appeal of this method owes to its simplicity and its atheoretical structure (Thorbecke, 1997; Patelis, 1997; Lastrapes, 1998). However, this method, although it is well established among researchers, is not free from criticism, and thus the most up-to-date technique has been the utilisation of revisions in expectations extracted from market instruments (Rudebusch, 1998; Kuttner, 2001) The benchmark empirical specification of Bernanke and Kuttner (2005), given by: ri a 1exi 2 surp i i , (2) proposes a decomposition of the raw policy change into a proxy for the expected (exi) and a proxy for the unexpected element of monetary policy (surpi). The extraction of the expected and unexpected elements of monetary policy actions used in this paper follows the technique developed by Kuttner (2001), and is defined as follows: surp i f i f i 1 exi iiUK surp i 9 . (3). This technique suggests that monetary policy shocks can be defined as the change in the rate of a short term interest rate futures contract (fi) on a day of a policy announcement, and the expected component as the difference between the actual policy change and the surprise component. The absence of a futures instrument which tracks the Bank’s policy rate in the UK financial markets has lead researchers to seek for alternative measures and what has been used so far are the 1-month Libor, the 3-months Libor, and the 3-months sterling futures rate (Kearns and Manners, 2006; Bredin et al., 2007; Ehrmann and Fratzscher, 2007). The dataset used in our estimations spans from the rate hike of the 26th November 1982 until the rate hike of the 9th November 2006 and includes 118 “events”. In Figure 1, we plot the changes of the 3-month sterling futures rate, which is the proxy most commonly utilised by the Bank in its publications to imply future interest rate expectations. The reduced volatility it exhibits during the period after the introduction of the Inflation Targeting regime in 1993 can be perceived as indicative of the improved transparency under this new regime, and stands supportive of King’s (1997) assertion, that within a transparent system the news does not occur from the MPC meetings, but from economic news. - Figure 1 somewhere here In Table 1, we print the results from the empirical estimation of models (1) and (2), and our results are generally consistent with theoretical priors and previous empirical research, and show that monetary policy shocks and equity prices are negatively associated. The weak reaction of equities to raw changes in policy rates reflects the fact that the actions of the Bank are to a great extent expected by the market. The empirical implementation of the benchmark model (2), the results of which are printed in the other three rows of Table 1, provides a clearer view, as they signify a strong negative impact to monetary policy surprises 10 both numerically and statistically and much larger R2 values. The lack of an impact from the expected component of monetary policy is usual in this stream of research and this reinforces the idea that the decomposition of monetary policy actions to expected and unexpected components is a prerequisite for the accurate estimation of monetary policy effects (Bernanke and Kuttner, 2005; Bredin et al., 2007; Fatum and Scholnick, 2008). - Table 1 somewhere here – In the fifth column of Table 1 we report the impact of monetary policy shocks on equities but by employing the “identification through heteroscedasticity” methodology of Rigobon and Sack (2004). This methodology, details of which can be found in the abovementioned article, returns unbiased proxies for the stock market reaction by employing an instrumental variables approach. The estimation using this technique returns a slightly larger coefficient estimate, as is also the case in Rigobon and Sack (2004), suggesting that the least squares estimation suffers from the endogeneity problem, however the magnitude of this bias is not significant enough to compromise the validity of our results. Event study frameworks generally are confronted with issues regarding the selection of the “events”, as some observations might exert disproportionate effects on the outcome of the estimation. In Figure 2, we plot the equity returns and the surprise element along with a trendline, and apart from the negative relationship between them, we also observe that some observations depart significantly from the general trend. To remedy any sample selection problems and ensure that some outlier observations will not dominate our results, we control for the existence of some outlier observations by using the method utilised in Bernanke and Kuttner (2005) which is described in Figure 3. The observations identified as outliers using this procedure are those on the 23rd of October 1987, the 8th of October 1990, and the 22nd of 11 March 1991 with influence statistics larger than 0.20 whereas the vast majority have statistics smaller than 0.02. - Figure 2 somewhere here The three candidate outlier observations concern large equity responses to monetary policy actions during periods characterised by economic turbulence. The rate cut of October 1987 follows “Black Monday” on the 19th of October 1987 and is associated with a large drop in equity prices. The rate cut of October 1990 was met very euphorically by the market, as it signified a measure against the slowdown in the economy, at a point when the UK monetary policy entered the Exchange Rate Mechanism, and its flexibility to initiate actions was naturally hampered. Finally, the rate cut of March 1991 is associated with a significant decrease in equities during a period when the economic situation was unclear due to the recession. As a test of robustness we repeat the tests of Table 1 after the exclusion of the outliers and we report the results in Panel B where we observe that our coefficient estimates are essentially unaffected. - Figure 3 somewhere here The symmetric model of Bernanke and Kuttner (2005) presented so far might miss out some important aspects of this relationship, as not all monetary policy actions are likely to exert homogeneous effects on future policy expectations (Bernanke and Kuttner, 2005; Farka, 2009). A monetary policy shock can reflect both the change in the timing of the policy action (“timing shocks”), and the change in the future trajectory of policy rates (“level shocks”). The definitions of the level and the timing shocks used in the analysis of this paper are those typically encountered in similar research, and follow those of Kearns and Manners (2006). In particular, the level shocks are extracted as the change in the 3-month sterling 12 futures rate, while the timing shocks are defined as the difference between the path shocks and the current month shocks taken from the change in the 1-month Libor. The definition of the level shocks suggests that a positive (negative) level shock is indicative of expectations about higher (lower) interest rates in the following three months. On the other hand, from the definition of the timing shocks it is suggested that positive (negative) timing shocks are indicative of postponements (advancements) in the policy action. The equation used for the examination of the equities’ reaction to timing and path shocks is: ri a 1timi 2 surp i i (4) and the results from estimating this equation, reported in Table 2, are generally consistent with those in Bernanke and Kuttner (2005) and Farka (2009) for the US, and signify that level shocks have a larger impact on equities than do timing shocks. Moreover, the coefficient estimate for the timing shocks is statistically significant and positive in value and this suggests that the market perceives positively (negatively) the postponements (advancements) of policy actions. We also consider the effects of timing and level shocks on inflation expectations and as we see in Table 2, inflation expectations respond mainly, and positively, to news about changes in the near-term level of interest rates. The five year-ahead inflation expectations respond also to timing shocks, but as we observe in Panel B of Table 2 this impact is highly contingent on the inclusion of the outlier observations. The policy reform in 1997 constitutes an important factor which is likely to cause changes in the relationship between equities and monetary policy shocks, and for this reason we measure the equity reactions across the two subperiods by estimating the equation: ri a 1timi 2 surp i 3 timi post 97 i 4 surp i post 97 i i . 13 (5) In the third row of Table 2, we present the results from this estimation and they exhibit an interesting pattern which should be interpreted cautiously as it is only significant at a 10% confidence level. The opposite signs of the coefficient estimates of the interactive terms capturing the additional impact after 1997 suggest that the relationships reverse during this period. The level shocks after 1997 are associated positively with equity returns, while the timing shocks are associated negatively. Providing an explanation for this pattern requires further research about the transmission channels of monetary policy which is beyond the focus of this paper; however, a preliminary explanation for the positive association of level shocks with equities could be that the level of interest rates is perceived as indicative of future economic growth. The negative association of timing shocks with equities could be explained by the rising uncertainty due to the postponement of a policy action during a regime of transparency where policy actions are to a great extent predictable as is apparent in Figure 1. Another case of asymmetric equity reactions which is examined in this paper are the reactions on days of MPC meetings when no policy decision is taken. In the first line of Panel A in Table 3 we report the results from the estimation of equation (4), but now the sample also includes those observations coinciding with days of MPC meetings when no policy decision took place; similarly to Bernanke and Kuttner (2005). Although the coefficient estimates are more or less the same, the R2 value is significantly reduced suggesting that these observations do not explain the negative relationship between monetary policy shocks and equity returns. To address explicitly this issue, we estimate the equation given by: ri a 1timi 2 surp i 3 timi post 97 i 4 surp i post 97 i 5 (timi noci ) 6 ( surp i noci ) i 14 , (6) which includes interactive terms capturing the additional impact on days of Bank’s inactions, and are calculated by the use of a binary dummy noci taking the value of 1 on days of policy inactions and zero otherwise. The coefficient estimates of the interactive terms, presented in Table 2, are both statistically insignificant suggesting that on these days stock market’s reaction to timing and level shocks is immaterial. Two other cases of possible asymmetric reactions examined are those due to the direction of the policy actions, and the sign of the shocks, and are estimated by the following equations: ri a 1timi 2 surp i 3 timi inc i 3 surp i inc i i (7) ri a 1timi 2 surp i 3 timi posi 3 surp i posi i . (8) The direction of the policy surprise is examined by the estimation of equation (7) which utilises, as in Bernanke and Kuttner (2005), a binary dummy inci taking the value of 1 for observations coinciding with rate increases and zero otherwise, and the results presented in Panel B of Table 3 do not support the validity of such an asymmetry. This result suggests that the Bank can use its interest rate policy instrument in a similar manner both to increase and decrease stock prices. In a similar vein, we examine the symmetry of the benchmark model with regards to the sign of the shock by estimating equation (8). The policy dates coinciding with hawkish market expectations are captured by the binary dummy posi, and the results from this estimation, reported in Panel C of Table 3, again are not indicative of overreactions to the arrival of bad news. In Table 4, we report the results from the examination of the effects of monetary policy on some suitably constructed portfolios, according to their market capitalisation and their book-to market ratios. The empirical model used is that in (4) but now ri refers to the 15 returns of “size” and “value” portfolios. The method used for constructing “size” and “value” portfolios is described in Table 4 and generally it follows that of Fama and French (1993). The results indicate that in contrast to the situation in the US, as can be seen in Thorbecke (1997) and Perez-Quiros and Timmermann (2000), the response of the small portfolio is paradoxically not larger than that of the large portfolio. This finding contradicts the hypothesis that smaller companies are more vulnerable to monetary policy risk, and a possible explanation for this could be the smaller scale assets that these types of companies have. The large and the value portfolio follow a pattern more or less similar to that of the market, while the timing shocks are more important than level shocks for the growth portfolio. What could be explaining the latter is that the cash flows of a growth portfolio are further out in the future and as such a change in the timing of a policy change has a larger impact on its current price than it would on the other portfolios. 2.2 The Bank’s Communication and the Equities’ Response. The publications of the Inflation Report and the Minutes of the MPC prompt lengthy discussions among market participants, as although no policy decisions are taken on these days, they reveal information to the market not only about the future course of monetary policy, but also about the future economic output. In this paper, we extract the co-movement between equities and monetary policy shocks on days of communication, in order to assess how the news about the future interest rates from these two types of publications is perceived by the market. To start with, we examine how the release of the Inflation Report affects the relationship between the monetary policy shocks and the equity returns. This publication 16 features among the most prominent channels through which the Bank transmits information to the public, and the examination of its role is conducted by the estimation of the two following equations: ri a 1 surp i i . (9) ri a 1tim1 2 surp i i We employ an event-study approach as in the previous section, but now the event days i are the days of an Inflation Report release. Although the quarterly schedule of the report’s release leaves few degrees of freedom, some interesting results arise. The results from this examination, printed in Panel A of Table 5, reveal that the decomposition of the policy shocks to a timing and a level component facilitates the examination of the effects from the release of the Inflation Report. When equity returns are regressed on monetary policy shocks on these days we find that there is no particular pattern in this relationship, as was found by Reeves and Sawicki (2007). The decomposition of policy shocks to timing and level components, however, signifies significant equity responses to both types of shocks with those to timing shocks being more significant. The strong reaction to timing shocks suggests that the projections included in the Inflation Report seem to have important information about the timing of the realisation of the future monetary policy actions, which is valued more than the information conveyed regarding the future level of interest rates. What seems to be the case about the information content of the Inflation Report, according to the results presented, is that the forward looking projections included in the Inflation Report mainly inform the markets about when to expect the changes in monetary policy, and less about what changes to expect. -Table 5 somewhere here – 17 In Panel A of Table 5 we also report the effects that the publication of an Inflation Report can have on inflation expectations. Intuition suggests that the Bank’s projections about future inflation expectations are relevant for the market, and hence it is expected that on these days any shock would be associated with a change in the expectations about future inflation. Indeed, our results lend support to this hypothesis, as we find that the reaction coefficient is positive, large in size, and statistically significant, contradicting the results reported in Ehrmann and Fratzscher (2007). Moreover, from the decomposition of policy shocks to timing and level components it is extracted that inflation expectations respond only to news about a change in the future level of interest rates, while the timing reaction estimate is statistically insignificant. The efficiency of the Inflation Report as a means of communication depends not only on the quality of its content, but also on the timing of its release (Geraats, 2006). A central bank communication close to a monetary policy meeting might insert bias in the market expectations about future policy actions, and hence cause overreactions. One straightforward way to examine whether there is an impact from the release of the Inflation Report during the next and the past MPC meeting is to examine the behaviour of our relationship on the 38 policy meetings following and preceding the releases. The model we are using is: ri a 1timi 2 surpi 3 (timi post 97i ) 4 ( surpi post 97i ) 5 (timi inff i ) 6 ( surpi inff i ) i (10) and the binary dummy inffi takes the value of 1 for observations either following, or preceding the Inflation Report releases, and 0 otherwise, and the sample includes also the meetings of the MPC when no policy change took place. Also included in this equation are the interactive terms which capture the additional impact after 1997. The results presented in 18 Panels B and C of Table 5 and are not indicative of any particular pattern on these specific dates. The publication of the Minutes of the MPC meetings, which also includes the MPC members’ individual votes, constitutes the other building block of the improved contemporary communication scheme of the Bank which is examined in this paper. In the Minutes of an MPC meeting one finds the first official explanation of the past policy decisions, and thus it constitutes a first-class opportunity for the markets to see how the members of the MPC assess the current economic developments (King, 2007). Moreover, the voting pattern per se is likely to reveal further information concerning the level of uncertainty in the financial markets, as a unanimous decision suggests that all committee members perceive the economic developments the same way and as a corollary this reinforces the information content of monetary policy decisions. To start with the empirical examination, we initially employ the event study methodology of (9) in order to extract the impact of monetary policy shocks on equities on days i when the Minutes of the MPC are released. Our results, printed in Panel A of Table 6, signify a positive correlation between monetary policy shocks and equities which is only marginally significant at the 10% level of significance. This result stands supportive to King’s (2007) assertion that this publication mainly reveals the way that the MPC members perceive the future economic output, and are not indicative of the future monetary policy stance. Moreover, the monetary policy news extracted from the release of the Minutes is strongly positively associated with inflation expectations, but the magnitude of this effect is smaller than that from the release of an Inflation Report. The inclusion of the timing shocks does not offer much to our empirical examination, since the equities’ reaction proxies both to the timing and to the level shocks are statistically insignificant. 19 -Table 6 somewhere here – The voting pattern of the MPC members, also reported in the Minutes of the MPC, is another issue which has triggered heated debates among policymakers not only as to whether they should be published, but also as to whether they can impair the effectiveness of the communication. Ehrmann and Fratzscher (2007) for instance, raise some doubts regarding the efficiency of the MPC’s Minutes because of the individualistic approach that the members of the MPC follow in their voting behaviour with the many cases of dissent voting. Although the same day effects of the release of the Minutes of the MPC on the stock market do not appear to be very strong, the effects of a unanimous decision release might materialise at a policy meeting following this release since after all the Minutes encapsulate news about the discussion surrounding the monetary policy decisions. The empirical model we estimate to capture the additional impact on policy meetings following a unanimous decision is: ri a 1timi 2 surp i 3 (timi post 97 i ) (11) 4 ( surp i post 97 i ) 5 (timi unai ) 6 ( surp i unai ) i where unai is a binary dummy variable taking the value of 1 for observations following the 41 releases of MPC meetings showing unanimous decisions, and zero otherwise. What we observe from the estimation of this model is that for policy meetings following a unanimous decision there is a strong additional negative association between level shocks and equities and a strong additional positive association between timing shocks and equities. Moreover the interactive dummies capturing the additional impact for the period after 1997 also increase in value. Initially this result suggests that the voting pattern of the MPC is a significant factor of the equity market reaction. What could be a possible explanation for this 20 pattern is that a unanimous decision is perceived by investors indicative of a certain economic output, and thus a shock to the following meeting is suggestive of significant revisions and could result in overreactions. 2.3 Delayed and Before-the-Announcement Effects of a Monetary Policy Action. In this last section we examine whether the effects from a monetary policy action materialise in full on the day of a monetary policy meeting, or they are dispersed across a number of days following the announcement. This kind of research is particularly popular when examining the reaction of exchange rates to macroeconomic announcements, and its results can show if the event study methodology employed in the previous section misses out a significant component of the effects of monetary policy shocks on equities (see, e.g., Evans and Lyons, 2005 and Fatum and Scholnick, 2008). In the empirical analysis, we test whether the monetary policy actions exert some kind of delayed effects which do not materialise on the same day of the announcement, but up to jdays ahead. We concentrate our attention on the period after the introduction of the MPC framework, as any discussion about delayed effects is more meaningful under a regime when the markets know when to expect a decision. The empirical methodology used is that in equation (12), which essentially involves a linear regression of the j-period ahead daily equity returns on the timing and the level shocks on days i when a policy action occurred, and is similar to the one employed by Fatum and Scholnick (2008). This way we capture the comovement between the equities and the monetary policy shock for a period of 10 trading days after the action of the Bank. 21 The results from estimation of equation: ri j a 1, j timi 2, j surp i i j (12) are printed in Table 7 and signify that monetary policy actions exert significant delayed effects for a period up to 8 trading days after a change in the policy rate occurred. For the first 3 days the equity markets appear to be positively correlated with level shocks, while this relationship changes direction during the later days of our sample and becomes negative when the markets apparently price the effects of higher discount rates on equities. As far as the timing shocks are concerned, a similar pattern arises as during the first three days they appear to be negatively correlated with equity returns while in the later days the correlation becomes positive. 3. Conclusion The debate among policymakers about the role of central banks in financial markets, and the increased emphasis that is attributed to the stock market channel of monetary policy transmission has brought the identification of the effects of monetary policy on equities to the forefront of academic research. Moreover, in an economic environment where the role of expectations has become a sine qua non to discussions about the effects of monetary policy, the recent turn towards Inflation Targeting regimes cannot be ignored and should be included as an important parameter in any empirical examination of such effects. In the first section of our analysis we consider the contemporaneous relationship between Bank’s actions and equity returns, and several aspects of this relationship are 22 examined. Initially, our results highlight the importance of the decomposition of policy actions to unexpected and expected components, as the equities’ reaction on raw policy actions are undersized and thus misleading as to the actual impact. Another case we consider in this paper are the effects on equities of monetary policy shocks signifying changes in the level of the future interest rates and those signifying changes in the timing of the interest rates. The level shocks exert larger impact on equities than the timing shocks, the latter however are significant enough to indicate that investors perceive news about postponements (advancements) as good (bad) news. An interesting result obtained in this paper is that for the period after the introduction of the Inflation Targeting regime in 1997, the relationship between equities and monetary policy shocks reverses and the timing shocks are negatively associated with equities while the level shocks are positively associated. This change in the pattern should be further examined in accordance with the transmission channels of monetary policy through equity prices. As regards the effects of the timing shocks under the new regime, the postponements are bad news signifying possibly more uncertainty, while the advancements are good news reducing the uncertainty. The case of some asymmetric responses is examined in the second section of this paper. The direction of the policy actions and the sign of the shocks do not cause asymmetric reactions in the equity market, while on the policy meeting days when no action has been taken the equities do not respond. Moreover in this paper we categorise firms according to their market capitalisation and their book-to-market ratios, and we find significant variations in the monetary policy effects according to the type of the firm. In our analysis we focus our attention on the effects of two types of communication utilised by the Bank under the new regime, the Inflation Report and the Minutes of the MPC. 23 We find that the Inflation Report reveals important news to investors especially as regards the timing of future policy actions. The Minutes of the MPC do not trigger large reactions to the equity markets although we find indications that on these days markets react to the economic news from the Minutes. Finally, we find empirical evidence that markets’ reactions to MPC meetings are stronger after the news about a unanimous decision suggesting a shock following a unanimous decision causes overreactions in the market. In the last section of this paper we examine the time horizon of the effects from monetary policy actions. Our results indicate that during the period after 1997, delayed effects are significant and strong up to 8 trading days after the action. This result poses new challenges for the empirical examination of the effects of monetary policy actions on equities as the event study frameworks miss out the delayed effects. 24 4. References. Anderson, M. 2007, “Using Intraday Data to Gauge Financial Market Responses to Fed and ECB Monetary Policy Decisions”, European Central Bank Working Paper Series No 726, February. Bernanke, B. Laubach, T. Mishkin, F.S., and Posen, A.S., 1999 (ed.), “Inflation Targeting: Lessons From the International Experience”, Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey. Bernanke, B. And Gertler, M., 2000, “Monetary Policy and Asset Price Volatility”, NBER Working Paper series 7559, February. Bernanke, B., 2004, “Fedspeak”, Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke at the Meetings of the American Economic Association, San Diego, California, January 3, 2004. Bernanke, B.S. and Kuttner, N. K., 2005, “What explains the Stock Market’s Reaction to Federal Reserve Policy?”, The Journal of Finance 60, (3) June, 1221-1257. Bredin, D. Hyde, S. Nitzsche, D. and O’Reilly, G., 2007, “UK Stock Returns and the Impact of Domestic Monetary Policy Shocks”, Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 34(5-6), 872-888. Bomfim, A. N., 2001, “Pre-Announcement effects, news effects, and volatility: Monetary policy and the stock market”, Journal of Banking and Finance 27, (1), 133-151. Cook, T. and Hahn, T., 1989, “The effect of changes in the federal funds rate target on market interest rates in the 1970s”, Journal of Monetary Economics 24, 331-353. Craine, R. and Martin, V., 2003, “Monetary Policy Shocks and Security Market Responses”, University of California, Berkeley Economics Working Paper (Unpublished). Darrat, A.F., 1990, “Stock Returns, Money, and Fiscal Deficits”, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 25, (3) September, 387-398. Ehrmann, M. and Fratzscher, 2004, “Taking Stock: Monetary Policy Transmission to Equity Markets”, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 36(4), August. Ehrmann, M. and Fratzscher, 2007, “Communication by Central Bank Committee Members: Different Strategies, Same Effectiveness?”, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 39(2-3), March-April. Fair, C.R., 2002, “Events that Shook the Market”, Journal of Business 75, (4) 713-731. Fama, E.F. and French, K.R., 1993, “Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds”, Journal of Financial Economics, 33(1), 3-56, February. 25 Farca, M., 2009, “The Effect of Monetary Policy Shocks on Stock Prices accounting for endogeneity and omitted variable biases”, Review of Financial Economics, 18, 47-55. Fatum, R. And Scholnick, B., 2008, “Monetary Policy News and Exchange Rate Responses: Do only Surprises Matter?”, Journal of Banking and Finance, 32, 1076-1086. Fracasso, A. Genberg, H. and Wyplosz, C., 2003, “How Do Central Banks Write? An Evaluation of Inflation Reports by Inflation Targeting Central Banks”, Geneva Report on the World Economy, International Center for Monetary and Banking Studies and Centre for Economic Policy Research. Geraats, M.P., 2006, “Transparency of Monetary Policy: Theory and Practice”, CESifo Economic Studies, 52(1), January, 111-152. Gerlach-Kristen, P., “Is the MPC’s Voting Record informative about future UK Monetary Policy?”, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 106(2), 299-313, June. Gürkaynak, R.S. Sack, B Swanson, T.E., 2005, “Do Actions Speak Louder Than Words? The Response of Asset Prices to Monetary Policy Actions and Statements”, International Journal of Central Banking 1(1), May. Honda, Y. and Kuroki, Y., 2006, “Financial and Capital Markets' Responses to Changes in the Central Bank's Target Interest Rate: The Case of Japan”, The Economic Journal 116(7), 812-842. Jensen, G.R. and Mercer, J.M., 2002, “Monetary Policy and the cross-section of Expected Stocks returns”, Journal of Financial Research, 25(1), Spring, 125-139. Jensen, G.R. Mercer, J.M. and Johnson, R.R., 1996, “Business Conditions, Monetary Policy, and Expected Security Returns”, Journal of Financial Economics 40, 213-237. King, M., 1997,”The Inflation Target Five years on”, Lecture delivered by Mervyn King at the London School of Economics, 29 October 1997. King, M., 2005, “Monetary Policy: Practise Ahead of Theory MAIS Lecture 2005”, Lecture by Mervyn King, 17 May 2005. King, M., 2007,”The MPC ten years on”, Lecture by Mervyn King delivered to the Society of Business Economists, London, 2 May 2007. Kohn, D. L. and Sack, B. P., 2003, “Central Bank Talk: Does it Matter and Why?”, FEDS Working Paper No. 2003-55. Kuttner, K., 2001, “Monetary Policy Surprises and Interest Rates: Evidence from the Fed Funds Futures Market”, Journal of Monetary Economics 47, (3), 523-544. Lastrapes, W.D., 1998, “International Evidence on Equity Prices, Interest Rates and Money”, Journal of International Money and Finance 17, 377-406. 26 Lobo, J.B., 2000, “Asymmetric effects of interest rate changes on stock prices”, The Financial Review 35, 125-144. Mishkin, S. F., 1996, “The Channels of Monetary Transmission: Lessons for Monetary Policy”,NBER Working Paper 5464, February. Monetary Policy Committee, “The Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy”, Bank of England. Murdzhev, A. and Tomljanovich, M., 2006, “What Color is Alan Greenspan's Tie? How Central Bank Policy Announcements Have Changed Financial Markets”, Eastern Economic Journal 32(4), 571-593. Patelis, A. D., 1997, “Stock Returns Predictability and the Role of Monetary Policy”, The Journal of Finance 52, (5) December, 1951- 1972. Perez-Quiros, G. and Timmermann, A., 2000, “Firm Size and Cyclical Variations in Stock Returns”, Journal of Finance 55(3), June. Reeves, R. And Sawicki, M. 2007, “Do Financial Markets react to Bank of England Communication?”, European Journal of Political Economy 23(1), March. Rigobon, R. and Sack, B., 2004, “The Impact of Monetary Policy on Asset Prices”, Journal of Monetary Economics 51, (8) November, 1553-1575. Roley, V.V. and Sellon, G.H., 1998, “Market Reaction to Monetary Policy NonAnnouncements”, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Working Paper No. 98-06. Rudebusch, G., 1998, “Do Measures of Monetary Policy in a VAR Make Sense?”, International Economic Review 39, 907-931. Siklos, P. L., 2003, “Assessing the Impact of Changes in Transparency and Accountability at the Bank of Canada”, Canadian Public Policy, 29(3), 279-299. Thorbecke, W., 1997, “On Stock Market Returns and Monetary Policy”, The Journal of Finance 52, (2) June, 635-654. Vickers, J., 1998, “Inflation Targeting in Practice: the UK experience”, Speech by John Vickers at the Conference on Implementation of Price Stability, 11-12 September, Frankfurt. 27 5. Tables and Figures Table 1 The response of the UK equities to monetary policy. In the first row the results of regression ri = α + β ΔiiUK + εi are printed, and they display the response of stock market returns to raw monetary policy changes. ri is the daily return on the FTSE All Share stock market index, ΔiiUK is the raw daily change in the repo rate of the Bank of England calculated on the day of a policy announcement i, and εi is the error term which is assumed to be orthogonal to the regressors. In the next three rows the results from the Bernanke and Kuttner (2005) model ri = α + β1 exi + β2 surpi + εi are printed, where exi is the expected, surpi is the unexpected part of monetary policy and εi is the error term which is assumed to be orthogonal to the regressors. In this paper we consider three proxies for the unexpected component of monetary policy deriving from the 1-month Libor, the 3-month Libor, and the 3-month sterling futures rate. In the fifth row the reaction of equities to monetary policy shocks are presented by utilising the estimation technique developed by Rigobon and Sack (2004). In the second Panel the results of the benchmark regression after the exclusion of the outlier observations are printed. The t statistics which are reported in parentheses are calculated using Newey-West estimates of standard errors. Panel A: Full sample a ΔiiUK exi surpi (1-m Libor) surpi (3-m Libor) surpi (3-m futures) R2 DW stat -0.66 (-5.06)*** - - - - 0.14 1.49 ri -0.13 (-1.23) -0.07 (-074) - 0.23 (0.79) -1.84 (-5.35)*** - - 0.24 1.60 ri -0.09 (-0.89) - 0.02 (0.12) - -1.82 (-6.64)*** - 0.24 1.45 ri -0.12 (-1.14) - -0.18 (-0.87) - - -1.68 (-3.95)*** 0.21 1.49 ri -0.01 (-0.07) - - - - -1.98 (-3.81)*** - - ri Panel B: Excluding outliers ri -0.12 (-1.21) -0.64 (-4.90)*** - - - - 0.15 1.60 ri -0.06 (-0.69) - 0.06 (0.22) -1.63 (-5.15)*** - - 0.22 1.69 ri -0.07 (-0.73) -0.09 (-0.99) 0.01 (0.07) - -1.73 (-6.67)*** - 0.22 1.59 - - 0.23 1.64 - - - - ri ri - -0.06 (-0.31) -0.21 (-1.09) - -1.75 (-6.15)*** -1.99 (-5.31)*** (*/**/*** means that t statistics are significant at the 10%/ 5%/1%level respectively) 28 Figure 1 The unexpected component of monetary policy decisions This graph depicts the unexpected component of monetary policy as calculated by the methodology of Kuttner (2001). The surprise component is defined as the daily difference in the 3-month sterling futures contract on the day of a policy decision. 29 Figure 2 Scatterplot of equity returns and monetary policy surprises This Figure prints a scatterplot of the UK equity returns and the monetary policy surprises as extracted by market-based instruments and are depicted in Figure 1. The scatterplot includes 118 observations that are described in section 2.1 in the main text. 30 Figure 3 Influence statistics of the observations of the benchmark model This Figure prints the influence statistic of each observation in the benchmark model of Bernanke and Kuttner (2005). The relative effect of each observation is estimated by the formula ΔβιΤΣΔβι, where Σ is the estimated covariance matrix and Δβι is the change in the estimated coefficient vector after excluding observation i. 31 Table 2 Timing vs Level Surprises In the first row the results from regression ri = α + β1 timi + β2 surpi + εi are printed where timi represents the shocks due to the timing of the monetary policy actions described in the main body of the text, and surpi represent the shocks due to the change in the expected level of the policy rate, defined as the change in 3-month sterling futures rate. The second row reports the results from regression einfli = α + β1 timi + β2 surpi + εi where einfli stands for the five year ahead inflation expectations implied from the inflation linked bonds. The third row reports results from regression ri = α + β1 exi + β2 timi + β3 surpi+ β4 (timi x post-97i) + β5 (surpi x post-97i) + εi where post-97i is binary dummy taking the value of 1 for observations after 1997 and zero otherwise. Equations with dependent variable including the term (outliers) report the results from regressions after the exclusion of the outliers. The t statistics which are reported in parentheses are calculated using Newey-West estimates of standard errors. Panel A: Full sample a timi surpi (timi x post-97i) (surpi x post-97i) R2 DW stat ri -0.06 (-0.68) 1.25 (1.85)* -1.88 (-6.03)*** - - 0.25 1.56 einfli 0.11 (0.53) 2.09 (2.13)** 3.47 (6.19)*** - - 0.31 1.63 ri -0.09 (-0.94) 1.43 (1.97)* -1.94 (-5.69)*** -5.81 (-1.93)* 3.50 (1.76)* 0.29 1.52 Panel B: Excluding Outliers ri 0.86 (1.73)* -1.94 (-7.05)*** - - 0.25 1.67 (outliers) -0.07 (-0.81) einfli (outliers) 0.10 (0.49) 1.77 (1.61) 3.71 (6.08)*** - - 0.29 1.50 ri -0.07 (-0.76) 1.06 (2.06)** -1.99 (-6.78)*** -5.44 (-1.81)* 3.58 (1.79)* 0.29 1.65 (outliers) (*/**/*** means that t statistics are significant at the 10%/ 5%/1%level) 32 Table 3 Asymmetries in Equities’ Market Response. In Panel A the results from regression ri = α + β1 timi + β2 surpi+ β3 (timi x post-97i) + β4 (surpi x post-97i) + β5 (timi x noci) + β6 (surpi x noci) + εi are reported, where noci is a binary dummy taking the value of 1 for days of MPC meetings when no policy action is taken. In Panel B the results from regression ri = α + β1 timi + β2 surpi+ β3 (timi x inci) + β4 (surpi x inci) +εi. are printed where inci is a binary dummy taking the value of 1 for observations coinciding with rate hikes and zero otherwise. In Panel C the results from regression ri = α + β1 timi + β2 surpi+ β3 (timi x posi) + β4 (surpi x posi) +εi. are printed where posi is a binary dummy taking the value of 1 for observations coinciding with positive shocks and zero otherwise. Equations with dependent variable ri(outliers) report the results from regressions after the exclusion of the outliers. The t statistics which are reported in parentheses are calculated using Newey-West estimates of standard errors. Panel A: No actions in monetary policy a timi surpi (timi x post-97i) (surpi x post-97i) (surpi x noci) (timi x noci) R2 DW stat ri -0.09 (-1.26) 1.14 (2.46)* -1.83 (-5.56)*** - - - - 0.14 1.69 ri -0.08 (-1.17) 1.43 (1.96)* -1.94 (-5.73)*** -5.81 (-2.04)** 3.50 (1.58) 6.39 (1.21) -0.78 (-0.18) 0.20 1.68 ri -0.08 (-1.07) 0.79 (1.72)* -1.85 (-7.04)*** - - - - 0.13 1.75 -0.07 (-1.03) 1.05 (2.05) -1.99 (-6.80)*** -5.43 (-1.93)** 3.57 (1.66)* 6.42 (1.22) -0.76 (-0.18) 0.19 1.77 (outliers) ri (outliers) Panel B: Monetary Policy effects on policy hikes a timi surpi (timi x post-97i) (surpi x post-97i) (surpi x inci) (timi x inci) R2 DW stat ri -0.17 (-1.36) 2.60 (2.01)** -2.56 (-5.20)*** -6.52 (-2.19)** 3.86 (1.96)* 0.73 (1.08) -1.89 (-1.37) 0.31 1.53 ri -0.11 (-0.94) 1.70 (1.85)* -2.43 (-4.34)*** -5.86 (-1.92)* 3.83 (1.84)* 0.53 (0.72) -0.93 (-0.89) 0.29 1.65 (timi x post-97i) -6.06 (-1.82)* -5.10 (-1.64) (surpi x post-97i) 3.66 (1.79)* 3.61 (1.69)* (surpi x posi) 0.33 (0.35) 0.48 (0.60) (timi x posi) -0.47 (-0.30) 0.80 (0.76) R2 DW stat 0.29 1.53 0.29 1.64 (outliers) Panel C: Shock Sign Asymmetries ri ri (outliers) a timi surpi -0.10 (-0.87) -0.11 (-1.00) 1.75 (1.14) 0.59 (0.59) -2.17 (-3.07)*** -2.28 (-3.77)*** (*/**/*** means that t statistics are significant at the 10%/ 5%/1%level) 33 Table 4 Monetary Policy on Size and Book to Market Portfolios This table presents the results from regression ri = α + β1 exi + β2 timi + β3 surpi + εi which examines the effects of timing and level monetary policy shocks on UK equity portfolios constructed with regards to their market capitalisation values and their book-to-market ratios in a similar vein to Fama and French (1993). The small portfolio consists of the decile 1 returns of the FTSE All Share firms rebalanced according to their market value on June every year, while the large portfolio is the decile 10. The value portfolio consists of the decile 10 returns of the FTSE All Share firms rebalanced according to the book to market ratio on June every year, while the growth portfolio is the decile 1. The t statistics which are reported in parentheses are calculated using Newey-West estimates of standard errors. Panel A: full sample a timi surpi R2 DW stat ri small 0.17 (1.98)* 1.01 (1.98)** -1.26 (-4.11)*** 0.15 1.64 ri l arg e -0.06 (-0.61) 0.82 (1.37) -1.76 (-6.36)*** 0.19 1.59 ri value -0.08 (-0.81) 1.04 (1.83)* -2.46 (-4.50)*** 0.31 2.01 growth -0.19 (-1.62) 1.51 (1.69)* -1.19 (-1.93)* 0.10 1.54 ri Panel B:Excluding Outliers a timi surpi R2 DW stat ri small 0.17 (1.98)** 0.78 (1.83)* -1.14 (-5.00)*** 0.12 1.52 ri l arg e -0.05 (-0.47) 0.50 (1.03) -1.85 (-5.83)*** 0.19 1.66 ri value -0.11 (-1.03) 0.87 (1.46) -2.25 (-4.27)*** 0.25 1.91 growth -0.18 (-1.67)* 0.71 (1.13) -1.27 (-2.50)** 0.08 1.65 ri (*/**/*** means that t statistics are significant at the 10%/ 5%/1%level) 34 Table 5 The UK equity market and the Inflation Report releases. In the first row of Panel A the results from regression ri = α + β surpi + εi are printed while in the third row we replace the ri with einfli. In the second row of Panel A, we print the results from regression ri = α + β1 timi + β2 surpi + εi while in the fourth row we replace ri with einfli. The dataset in this estimation spans from the Inflation Report release of August 1997 until that of November 2006 and includes 38 observations. In Panel B the results from regression ri = α + β1 timi + β2 surpi + β3 (surpi x post-97i) + β4 (timi x post-97i) + β5 (surpi x inffi) + β6 (surpi x inffi) + εi are reported where inffi is a binary dummy taking the value of 1 at a policy meeting following the release of an Inflation Report and zero otherwise. The sample size includes 200 events and spans from the rate hike of November 1982 until November 2006 and includes also the dates of MPC meetings when no action took place. In Panel C the results from the same regression as in Panel B are reported, but now inffi is a binary dummy taking the value of 1 at a policy meeting preceding the release of an Inflation Report and zero otherwise. Equations with dependent variable including the term (outliers) report the results from regressions after the exclusion of the outliers. The t statistics which are reported in parentheses are calculated using Newey-West estimates of standard errors. Panel A: The effects on equities from the release of the Inflation Report a timi surpi R2 DW stat ri -0.09 (-0.86) - -0.34 (-0.11) 0.00 1.66 ri -0.13 (-1.24) 6.75 (2.74)*** -5.47 (-1.74)* 0.11 1.80 einfli 0.28 (0.83) - 34.46 (3.20)*** 0.26 2.35 einfli 0.26 (0.80) 3.48 (0.30) 31.81 (2.92)*** 0.27 2.37 Panel B: inffi takes the value of 1 for MPC meetings following the release of an Inflation Report (surpi x (timi x (surpi x (timi x a timi surpi post-97i) post-97i) inffi) inffi) -0.10 1.42 -1.94 4.42 -5.24 0.67 0.61 ri (-1.41) (1.96)* (-5.69)*** (1.52) (-2.21)** (0.14) (0.11) ri -0.09 1.05 -1.99 4.53 -4.87 0.57 0.67 (-1.29) (2.04)** (-6.74)*** (1.55) (-2.10)** (0.11) (0.13) (outliers) Panel C: inffi takes the value of 1 for MPC meetings preceding the release of an Inflation Report (surpi x (timi x (surpi x (timi x a timi surpi post-97i) post-97i) infri) infri) -0.10 1.42 -1.94 6.46 -5.51 -4.16 1.27 ri (-1.28) (1.96)* (-5.69)*** (2.39)** (-2.90)*** (-1.03) (0.30) ri -0.08 1.05 -1.99 6.54 -5.14 -4.18 1.30 (-1.15) (2.04)** (-6.75)*** (2.41)** (-2.81)** (-1.04) (0.31) (outliers) (*/**/*** means that t statistics are significant at the 10%/ 5%/1%level) 35 R2 DW stat 0.18 1.71 0.17 1.79 R2 DW stat 0.19 1.70 0.18 1.79 Table 6 The UK equity market and the MPC Minutes releases. In the first row of Panel A the results from regression ri = α + β surpi + εi are printed while in the third row we replace the ri with einfli and the regression is einfli = α + β surpi + εi. The dataset in this examination spans from the Minutes’ release of July 1997 until that of December 2006 and includes 114 observations. In the second row of Panel A we report results from regression ri = α + β1 timi + β2 surpi + εi while in the fourth row we replace ri with einfli. In Panel B the results from regression ri = α + β1exi + β2 timi + β3 surpi + β4 (surpi x post-97i) + β5 (timi x post-97i) + β6 (surpi x unai) + β7 (surpi x unai) + εi are reported. The sample size includes 200 events and spans from the rate hike of November 1982 until November 2006 and includes also the dates of MPC meetings when no action took place. The binary dummy unai takes the value of 1 at a policy meeting following the release of the Minutes indicating a unanimous decision of the MPC. Equations with dependent variable including the term (outliers) report the results from regressions after the exclusion of the outliers. The t statistics which are reported in parentheses are calculated using Newey-West estimates of standard errors. Panel A a timi surpi R2 DW stat ri -0.16 (-1.52) - 4.89 (1.81)* 0.03 1.90 ri -0.17 (-1.60) 2.49 (0.90) 2.54 (0.67) 0.03 1.91 einfli 0.06 (0.32) - 22.48 (4.53)*** 0.17 1.81 einfli 0.05 (0.26) 2.56 (0.42) 20.08 (2.31)** 0.17 1.79 Panel B ri ri (outliers) a timi surpi -0.06 (-0.86) -0.05 (-0.71) 1.44 (1.96)* 1.06 (2.05)** -1.94 (-5.81)*** -1.99 (-6.93)*** (surpi x post-97i) 8.96 (3.68)*** 9.06 (3.73)*** (timi x post-97i) -7.27 (-4.04)*** -6.91 (-4.01)*** (*/**/*** means that t statistics are significant at the 10%/ 5%/1%level) 36 (surpi x omoi) -15.98 (-5.00)*** -16.07 (-5.03)*** (timi x omoi) 12.69 (4.23)*** 12.80 (4.26)*** R2 DW stat 0.24 1.73 0.24 1.82 Table 7 Delayed Effects of Monetary Policy. In this Table we print the results of regression ri+j = α + β1 timi + β2 surpi + εi for j=0, 10. The t statistics which are reported in parentheses are calculated using Newey-West estimates of standard errors. R2 DW stat 0.25 1.56 0.16 1.81 0.05 1.79 0.16 1.48 0.17 1.84 0.25 2.78 0.21 1.98 0.06 1.73 0.10 1.63 2.22 (0.95) 0.04 1.98 -1.17 (-0.94) 0.02 2.34 ri , j 8 a -0.06 (-0.68) 0.00 (0.04) -0.22 (-0.82) 0.17 (1.04) 0.06 (0.31) -0.01 (-0.15) -0.08 (-0.61) 0.21 (1.16) 0.08 (0.37) timi 1.25 (1.85)* -6.17 (-2.28)** -4.48 (-0.96) -6.88 (-2.37)** 7.76 (1.93)* 3.73 (2.13)** 3.66 (2.49)** 3.48 (1.64) 3.45 (1.12) surpi -1.88 (-6.03)*** 3.78 (1.76)* 1.98 (0.65) 2.74 (1.47) -3.95 (-1.35) -4.67 (-4.59)*** -4.47 (-3.74)*** -3.11 (-1.61) -4.32 (-2.15)** ri , j 9 0.07 (0.44) -2.57 (-0.88) ri , j 10 0.02 (0.22) 1.90 (0.91) ri , j o ri , j 1 ri , j 2 ri , j 3 ri , j 4 ri , j 5 ri , j 6 ri , j 7 (*/**/*** means that t statistics are significant at the 10%/ 5%/1%level) 37