Lecture 8 Practice Question Answers From Browning and Zupan: 14.1. A dominant-strategy equilibrium is a set of strategies (one for each player) in which every player is playing a dominant strategy – that is, a strategy that is best regardless of what the other players do. A Nash equilibrium is a set of strategies (one for each player) in which every player is playing a strategy that is a best response to what the other players’ equilibrium strategies. It is possible to have a Nash equilibrium that is not a dominant-strategy equilibrium; for example, Battle of the Sexes has two Nash equilibria, but neither one is a dominant-strategy equilibrium. 14.3. A prisoners’ dilemma is a game in which every player has a dominant strategy (see above), and the resulting dominant-strategy equilibrium is Pareto-inferior to the outcome that would have occurred if everyone had played a different strategy. This is relevant to analyzing cheating in a cartel, because the members of a cartel usually have a dominant strategy of producing more output (or setting a lower price). As a result, they have a strong incentive to cheat on the cartel’s agreement to produce less output (set higher prices). Additional questions: 1. (a) Here is the strategy-and-payoff matrix for Rock-Paper-Scissors. Player 1 chooses the row, and player 2 chooses the column. Rock Paper Scissors Rock 0, 0 1, -1 -1, 1 Paper -1, 1 0, 0 1, -1 Scissors 1, -1 -1, 1 0, 0 (b) There is no Nash Equilibrium of this game. Why? Because for any pair of strategies, at least one player would wish to change strategy in response to the other person’s strategy. For instance, if player 1 is playing Rock and player 2 is playing Paper (the top middle cell), then player 1 wishes to switch to Scissors. (Also, there is actually a Nash Equilibrium in “mixed strategies,” which means the players randomize over their strategies. Specifically, each player plays each strategy with 1/3 probability. But you don’t have to know this.) 2. (a) Here is the strategy-and-payoff matrix for “Chicken.” Spike picks the row and Biff picks the column. (“K” means 1000.) Continue Stop Continue -10K, -10K -1K, 1K Stop 1K, -1K 0, 0 (b) There is no dominant strategy, because Continue is the best response to Stop, but Stop is the best response to Continue. There is no dominant strategy equilibrium (DSE), because both players must have dominant strategies to have a DSE. (c) There are two Nash Equilibria: (Continue, Stop) and (Stop, Continue). Why? Given that the other guy is going to Stop, you want to Continue. Given that the other guy is going to Continue, you want to Stop. (d) There can be a first-mover advantage if one player can commit in advance to playing Continue. For example, Spike could throw his brake pedal out the window so that he’s incapable of stopping. 3. (a) If firm 2 picks quantity q2, then firm 1's demand curve is P = [1500 - q2] - q1, and his marginal revenue is MR1 = [1500 - q2] - 2q1. Set this equal to MC1 = 300 and solve for q1 like so: [1500 - q2] - 2q1 = 300 1200 - q2 = 2q1 q1 = 600 - ½q2 Doing the same thing for firm 2 (with the quantities reversed and using MC2 = 600 instead), we get q2 = 450 - ½q1. Now solve the system of equations by plugging the equation for q2 into the equation for q1, like so: q1 = 600 - ½[450 - ½q1] q1 = 375 + (1/4)q1 (3/4)q1 = 375 q*1 = 500 and plug this back into the equation for q2 to get q*2: q*2 = 450 - ½[500] = 200 So the Nash Equilibrium is q*1 = 500, q*2 = 200. The total quantity is 700, so the Nash Equilibrium price is P* = 1500 - 700 = 800. (b) Firm 1, which has the lower marginal cost, will set his price just below firm 2's marginal cost. Firm 2 doesn't produce, so firm 1 gets the whole market at P1 = 599. The corresponding quantity is found by plugging the price into the demand curve: 599 = 1500 - Q, and thus Q = 901. 4. (a) Every DSE is a NE, but not every NE is a DSE. (b) In a DSE, each player’s strategy must be a best response to any possible strategies chosen by the other players. But in a NE, a player’s strategy only needs to be a best response to the equilibrium strategies of the other players. 5. Battle of the Sexes, Market Segmentation, Sides of the Road. (There are many other possible examples.) 6. Here is a diagram of Battles of the Sexes converted into a sequential game with Terry choosing first: Terry Opera Fight Pat Opera Pat Fight Opera Fight I have used heavier lines to show the predicted choices of the players (we did this in class using arrows). When Terry has already chosen Opera, Pat compares 1 and 0 and therefore chooses Opera. When Terry has already chosen Fight, Pat compares 0 and 3 and therefore chooses Fight. Terry can predict all this, which means choosing Opera will lead to a payoff of 3 and choosing Fight will lead to a payoff of 1, and therefore Terry will choose Opera. Notice that Terry has a first-mover advantage in this game. 7. (a) In Cournot, firms choose quantities, and the market sets the resulting price. In Bertrand, firms choose prices, and the market sets the resulting quantities sold. (b) Cournot leads to a price and total quantity that are between those that would occur under monopoly and perfectly competition. Bertrand leads to a price and total quantity identical to those that occur under perfect competition. 8. (a) If firm 2 picks quantity q2, then firm 1's demand curve is P = [100 - q2] - q1, and his marginal revenue is MR1 = [100 - q2] - 2q1. Setting this equal to MC1 = 20 (firm 1's MC) and solving for q1, we get q1 = 40 - ½q2. Doing the same thing for firm 2 (with the quantities reversed and using MC2 = 40 instead), we get q2 = 30 - ½q1. Solving the system of equations, we get q*1 = 100/3 and q*2 = 40/3. The total quantity is Q* = 140/3, and the corresponding price is P* = 100 - 140/3 = 160/3. (b) Firm 1, which has the lower marginal cost, will set his price just below firm 2's marginal cost. Firm 2 doesn't produce, so firm 1 gets the whole market at P1 = 39.99. The corresponding quantity is found by plugging the price into the demand curve: 39.99 = 100 - Q, and thus Q = 60.01.