For a careful use of the intangible concept Back to the issue of mobile phone licences Introduction This paper has been written as a kind of reaction about the “UMTS licences” story, and to the tendancy of abusing of the concept of intangible. As it was already noticed, large improvements were introduced in SNA93 in the field of accounting for intangible fixed assets. However, because of the decision to continue to treat all expenditures on R and D as current, some confusion still exists in the classification of assets with regard of produced intangible ones. Very useful clarifications were brought in various papers on this issue. See, for instance, P. Hill (1997) and, for the specific case of software, E. Dalgaard (1999) and Eurostat (1997). By contrast, the area of intangible non-produced assets is less explored. Proposals were made to make use of this category for the treatment of the allocation of mobile phone licences (UMTS licences). And it was more or less proposed to extend their scope to other kinds of (government) permissions. This paper tries to show that this proposal is not in accordance with SNA93, and proposes another solution. Summary The treatment of the allocation by government of mobile phone licences as a sale of an intangible asset is not in conformity with the SNA93 definition of transferable leases. This treatment, if extended for instance to the case of land leases, would have some undesirable consequences. Recognizing that the frequencies spectrum is a government’s non-produced tangible asset, two possible treatments are relevant : to rent it or to sell it. In fact, imputing rents is too hard in this case. The financial difficulties encountered by phone operators and the revision of their expectations of profitability make the estimates of the imputed rents which were previously made completely obsolete and fictitious. So, the most logical solution is to record a sale of the underlying asset : the technical and economical specifities of this asset make this treatment possible. Background of the issue 1. The situation which was addressed in the case of the attribution of the mobile phone licences was the following one : phone operators are given by government the right to have access to the use of the spectrum of frequencies. This use is granted for a rather long period of time. In exchange, operators have to pay an important up-front payment. From a legal point of view, this situation is similar to a lease arrangement in which the lessor keeps the legal ownership of an asset and receives an upfront payment from a lessee in order for the latter to have the use of this asset for several years. 2. For the national accounts purpose, a proposed treatment was to record a transaction on a licence/lease. According to this proposal, a lease may be described as an intangible asset that 2 is substituted for the underlying asset - usually, a tangible one - which is covered by the lease arrangement between the lessor and the lessee. There is in fact a transaction on a lease, and not on the underlying asset, from the initial agreement between the original owner, who becomes the lessor, and the first lessee : the value of this lease is a part of the value of the underlying asset, and it is subtracted from the latter. Leases in SNA93 : what they are not 3. The above-mentionned treatment does not correspond to the lease as it is understood under the heading AN.222 - Leases and other transferable contracts - of the assets classification of SNA93. The extension of the concept of a lease as an asset in the above sense was in fact addressed as an issue prior to the SNA revision process. This was for instance the case in : Provisional international guidelines on the national and sectoral balance-sheet and reconciliation accounts of the system of national accounts (United Nations, Statistical papers-M60, 1977). In §§ 5.1316, this document proposes to introduce leases on land, buildings, etc. as non-financial intangible assets when there is a once-and-for-all lump-sum payment at the time of transaction : this would “ avoid the imputations of financial assets and liabilities in the form of advances, and of rents and royalties ”. All the issues relating to the respective values of the leases and of the underlying assets are also dealt with in this document. Obviously, this approach was not followed in the SNA93 final version. 4. Evidence that the SNA93 concept of a lease as an asset is not as extensive as above may be found in the list of the underlying items covered by AN.222 : are considered here, among others, contracts with athletes and authors, both of which are obviously not considered as assets in SNA93. Thus, the mechanism of transfer of value between the underlying asset and the lease, which is technically possible when land is the underlying asset, is impossible in such a case. Furthermore, this mechanism of transfer of value would be very questionable when a residential building is the object of the lease arrangement, or more generally when the underlying asset gives rise to rentals, and not to property income. Leases in SNA93 : what they are 5. The lease asset dealt with under AN.222 of SNA93 is not the lease arrangement as such, understood as the right to use an underlying asset that is granted to a lessee by the legal owner. It is an asset which comes in addition to the underlying asset which is the object of the contract - and which may be an asset not recognised as such in the System -, and it is not substituted for (part of) this underlying asset. The appearance of this asset is due to the changing conditions which may affect the underlying asset, or incomes generated by it, during the time of the lease contract, specially when prices change. In fact, it is a kind of windfall. 6. The way the lease covered by AN.222 works may be described by reference to land leases. It is absolutely not necessary to assume that there is an up-front payment ; nor it is necessary to assume that there is any kind of transfer of risks and benefits between the owner and the lessee, which would be more than usual between a landowner and a tenant. 7. A lease on a land appears as an asset, in the SNA93 sense, because the tenant being granted the use of the land for several periods by the lease contract, he may derive some economic 3 benefits from this situation : in particular, if rents on similar land increase over the level of the rent as it is fixed in the lease contract, the tenant is in a position to get a premium if he is allowed to transfer the lease contract to another tenant. The premium is precisely the value of the asset. What happens is that the potential increase of wealth which, in absence of a lease contract, would accrue to the landowner following the increase of the value of land stemming from the change in market rents is in fact captured by the tenant, because of the existence of the lease contract. And only this increase of wealth is considered an asset. 8. This is why transferability of the lease contract is a necessary condition for a lease being treated as an asset, in the AN.222 sense. If the lease is not transferable, the tenant cannot get any benefit from the opportunity offered by the movement of rents 1. This is also why SNA93 underlines, in § 10.130, that there are acquisitions/disposals of lease only between original and/or subsequent tenants. There is no transfer of lease, in the AN.222 sense, between the landowner and the first tenant. In fact, to record a transaction on a lease is the only accounting possibility to account for a payment which occurs between two successive tenants of a land, and which obviously is of a capital nature. The involved asset does not generate any income : its value changes in parallel with prices, and it disappears at the end of the lease contract. 9. A contract with an athlete, a football player for instance, works a bit differently, but it follows similar rules. For the football club in which a player is employed, there is an appearance of a AN.222 type asset when the player seems likely to provide, to the club with which he is under contract, more revenues than previously foreseen. If another club wants to enter in a contract with the player before the end of the present one, the former club will be in a position to require a compensation from the new employing club. Of course, there is no compensation if the new contract is taken after the end of the previous one. Some problems raised by a treatment of the licences as assets 10. Let us now examine some of the consequences which would result from a treatment of the licence itself as an intangible asset, as suggested above in § 2. It may be more convenient to examine some consequences of this treatment in more usual cases, such as licences on land : it is all the more justified that the parallel between land and the phone frequencies spectrum is generally considered as relevant. 11. Let us take the example of a lease arrangement on a piece of land, with an up-front payment taking place for the use of the piece of land for several periods. This implies the recording of two opposite flows of the same value in the other changes in volume of assets account : - a disappearance of land, - an appearance of a non-produced intangible asset, the licence. The disappearance of land stems from the fact that a part of the value of the rents which are expected from its ownership are transferred to the licence asset. This is a volume effect. In practice, this leads to an implicit “ shrinkage ” of the involved country, which may be seen as an undesirable effect of the proposed treatment. 1. Sub-renting may also be an opportunity of benefit for the tenant. 4 12. The same would occur if mineral deposits were the objects of lease arrangements. If this kind of arrangement was the most common one between government and oil companies in a country with large oil reserves, it might happen that, in extreme cases, no figure would be shown under the Subsoil assets heading in this country balance sheet ! The use of this treatment for lease arrangements on commercial buildings would also lead to undesirable consequences. The licence asset would then be substituted for several periods of rentals : production of the subsequent periods would thus be reduced. 13. From a more theoretical point of view, the introduction of such licence types as intangible nonproduced assets in the scope of assets in national accounts would put some confusion in the SNA93 assets classification. It has to be noticed that, for the time being, SNA93 does not recognise as an asset the right to use an asset. The introduction of such a kind of asset may be seen highly desirable by someones. Some others could, on the contrary, find this initiative as questionable, and not very useful from an analytical point of view. Anyway, this kind of asset does not exist in the present SNA. It would be inappropriate to introduce a source of confusion by treating an intangible nonproduced asset as a production factor, in the same way as land. The land is the actual production factor, not the lease on land 2. How to record the case of a lease arrangement on a land involving an up-front payment ? 14. If the solution consisting in treating the licence itself as an asset is rejected, it is however necessary to find a solution for the treatment of the case where there is a lease-type arrangement including an up-front payment from the lessee, for the right to use the leased asset for more than one accounting period. Once more, it is useful to take the example of land : the relations between the value of assets and the value of incomes generated by assets - i.e. rents - are simple and, in practice, rather easy to establish. In fact, it is not sure that such a case, i.e. including an up-front payment, be very frequent. It is however worthwhile to examine it. 15. It is sometimes argued that conditions of payment cannot be a decisive criterion for deciding on a treatment. However the presence of an up-front payment, provided that it is not a pure financial advance but that it is linked to an engagement from the owner to give to the tenant the right to use the land for the corresponding length of time, seems to be a sign that a capital transaction may be recorded. In fact, as usually with non-produced tangible assets, there are two ways to use a land : to rent it, or to buy it. The two alternatives are first examined in turn. 16. The first possible solution consists in recording a financial advance from the lessee to the lessor as a counterpart of the up-front payment, and in imputing rents in each period during the length of the lease contract, each rent "payment" being offset by a reduction of the financial advance. Because of the assumed infinite life of land, and under an assumption of constancy of rents, this type of imputation is very easy, and there is no problem of consistency between the imputed rents and the value of the land asset. 17. An alternative solution would be to record the sale of an asset, the asset being a part of the piece of land : this part would not be a spatial part, but a kind of temporal part. The lessee 2. For cattle, the grass of a land is better than the grass of a lease ! 5 would thus buy some kind of slice of time of (use of) land. Of course, in order to record such a sale, it may be that some conditions - such as the transfer of risks and benefits - should be required. This solution is actually not explicitly foreseen as such in SNA93, where a sale of land is generally understood as the sale of full ownership on the land. However its rationale and accounting consequences are not in contradiction with SNA93 general principles and rules. National accounts are not (too much) tied by legal aspects of economic life : from an ownership point of view, the situation is not so far as the one created by a financial lease with a residual value. 18. The calculation secures that there is a full consistency between the original value of land and the values of the two pieces of land created by recording the sale of an asset. This solution would thus avoid the “ shrinkage ” of the land underlying the economy. Moreover, this solution is fully equivalent with the rent imputation one. 19. This solution implies that, at each period, a transfer of value from the lessee to the lessor be recorded, in such a way that, at the end of the contract, the full value of the land should be recorded in the balance sheet of the owner/lessor, and nothing in the lessee’s one. The value which is transferred in this way is equal to the present value of the rent paid in the period which follows the end of the lease. This transfer can be recorded, according to the present SNA, by using the two entries Economic appearance/disappearance of non-produced assets (K.3 and K.6). This may be seen as an extension of the content of these entries, but it is in accordance with their spirit. Some particularities of the electromagnetic spectrum 20. There is a general agreement for considering that the electromagnetic spectrum of phone frequencies - in short, the spectrum - has to be classified as a tangible non-produced asset. The analogy with land is also frequently made. It is nevertheless useful to examine the limits of this analogy. 21. With land, the spectrum shares the fact that, being non produced and thus not reproducible, the number of its users is necessarily limited. So, somebody has to organise its use and takes some economic benefit from this position. For land, it is the role of the legal owner. For the spectrum, it is generally admitted that the government has authority to do so, at least because, prior to its commercial uses, the spectrum used to have military purposes, and is still important for security functions. However, when allocating the spectrum, the government is not acting in its regulatory function, but as its legal owner, as a landowner does. 22. There are, however, some differences between the spectrum and land which may have some economic importance. The issue of the assumed infinite life of the spectrum may first be addressed. Technically, this is true. But, the scope of the possible uses of land has been known for a long time, and looking ahead towards an horizon economically significant - say, 50 years - all uses of land are more or less known. On the contrary, very few uses of the spectrum have been experienced up to now. There was two generations of mobile phones to use the spectrum, a third one is now close to be introduced, while research work is engaged for a fourth one, some specialists predicting its introduction in 10 years. Each generation has a different technological context, in such a way that the possible uses of the 3rd generation are, from a technical point of view, far larger than 6 those of the 2nd generation. In this respect, analogy can be better made with mineral deposits than with land : each generation of mobile phone technology is different from the previous one, and there is no way back. Each generation may be seen as something separate from the other. Anyway, by contrast with mineral deposits, the spectrum itself cannot be exhausted. 23. These technical differences have economic repercussions. As many possible uses of land exist, there is a true competition between users, in such a way that active markets exist for land. Prices are well established, and reliable expectations may be made on their future movements. By contrast, may be because of their novelty, returns which may be anticipated from the use of the spectrum for mobile phones are not known with precision. This is why auctions were organised for the attribution of frequencies for the 3rd generation 3 : in absence of a knowledge of any objective price for them that government could have proposed, it was thought that phone operators were in the best position to propose such price. 24. This has important consequences for economic analysis and for national accounts. Economic benefits which may be derived from the various uses of land being known with rather good reliability, and infinite lifetime of land being assumed, prices may be established for land. On the contrary, even if the spectrum has potentially an infinite technical lifetime, it would be of little sense to attribute a value to the spectrum after the current generation. It is not only a practical issue. Given the uncertainties about the economic perspectives of the present generation, it would have no economic meaning to attribute values to the spectrum after this generation. Mobile phone licences : why a treatment as a financial advance of rents is irrelevant 25. As it is commonly accepted that the spectrum dedicated to the mobile phone technology is a tangible non-produced asset, it would be logical to conclude that payments made for its use are to be treated as rents (see, for instance, SNA93 § 7.87). In this context, if payments are aggregated in a single up-front payment, it has to be treated as a financial advance on future rents. This line of reasoning seems however irrelevant for the UMTS case. 26. A set of conditions have to be fulfilled for a financial advance treatment be considered having an economic signification. When such an arrangement takes place for a land, there is usually an actual agreement on the level of rents, which have an objective value because of the existence of active markets. Moreover, both parties in the arrangement may have some knowledge on the level of rents which is expected in the future, and there may have some clauses for a revision in the case of unexpected changes. Technically, land prices and rents on similar land being known, the up-front payment is derived easily. This payment is thus an advance assessed with objectivity. 27. All these conditions are not fulfilled in the UMTS case. First, it is not common practice for national accounts to make imputations for so long duration as for UMTS licences. Large up-front payments for UMTS licences were encountered in situations in which auctions were organised, or they were assessed on the basis of auctions made in neighbour countries. This was the case because there was no objective "external" value to attribute to the use of the spectrum, because expectations about the benefits it may provide are not reliable. Under these 3. There is an abundant economic literature on this topic. 7 conditions, it was considered that telephone operators were in the best position to estimate the price of the licence. In fact, the profile of the returns which may be expected by operators from the use of the spectrum in the provision of mobile phone services is largely unknown and volatile. In this context, it seems very hazardous to assume a profile for the imputed rents. The profile which was retained in some numerical examples was based on an assumption of a constant rent. It is very improbable to accept such a profile for UMTS licences. 28. The recent actuality provides further arguments against the (imputed) rent treatment. The collapse of the so-called "New economy" has largely changed the expectations of operators, and the public, about the future of mobile phone services. In France, for instance, because their allocation takes place in 2001, and not in 2000, only two of the four UMTS licences which were previously foreseen are going to be allocated according to the pre-established price, because of the defaulting of other operators. This means that the value of the licence, as estimated by operators, has been more or less divided by two, and such is also the case for the expected returns of the activity allowed by the licences. If licences were offered nowadays, their price would probably fall far below their previous price, and the relating imputed rent also. Facing this situation, the rent treatment can hardly continue to seem relevant since, by construction, it assumes a constancy of the imputed rents whereas the contribution of the spectrum to operators' income is decreasing. In fact, the rent profile reflects the conditions of the operators' financing of their purchase of licences, and not the contribution of the licence/spectrum. In other words, would it be meaningful to continue to record the same figure for rents, whereas the value of the rented asset has considerably decreased ? 29. There may be some secondary arguments against the financial advance, because of some unsolved issues. Two of them are worth being quoted : what to do in case of a bankruptcy of an operator, whose licence would not be repurchased by another one (to continue to impute rents ? or to make a debt forgiveness from the operator to government ?). What to do in the case of an unforeseen obsolescence of the 3rd generation technology 4? The best treatment : the sale of the spectrum itself, as an asset 30. It is worth using the criterion of transfer of the "risks and benefits of ownership" to decide who is the owner - in an economic sense - of an asset, and consequently in whose balance sheet the asset has to be recorded. This criterion is already used in national accounts, for financial leasing for instance. It is proposed here, to treat the attribution of UMTS licences, when there is a large up-front payment and when the above-mentioned risks and benefits are deemed to be transferred, as the sale of the asset which underlies the licence, i.e. the "spectrum". 31. There may be two arguments against the treatment as the sale of the spectrum, which consists in the transfer of full ownership over the spectrum. The first one is the legal situation. In fact, governments usually do not leave their legal ownership on the spectrum, and this abandonment is sometimes forbidden by law. National accounts are not, however, too much tied by legal aspects, and a distinction is usually accepted between legal ownership and economic ownership. The treatment of financial leasing in SNA93 4. This could have as a consequence to impute two different streams of rents - one for the 3rd generation, one for the 4th generation - to the same operator, whereas the former one would have been left. 8 provides a good example of such a distinction. In this context, the "risks and benefits" criterion is perfectly relevant. Another argument is inspired by the business accounting rules and practice; it is true that, in their own bookkeeping, operators will record the licence in their balance sheets. But once again, this is because business accounting is tied by legal constraints : it is impossible to record as asset in an enterprise balance sheet an item of which it is not the legal owner. 32. More important, in a national accounting context, is the argument according to which “the licence does not transfer full ownership over the spectrum … and government still retain the right to sell its remaining interest". In other words, it would not be possible to sell the spectrum when allocating the UMTS licences, since this would imply the sale of the whole spectrum, government withdrawing its future interest in the spectrum development. This argument seems finally not relevant. It was shown in the present paper that, even in the case of land, it was possible to split the ownership along time, the same land appearing twice in balance sheets of different economic owners, but for different periods. Applied to the spectrum, this treatment would show that government keeps an interest in the spectrum. 33. It is however necessary to wonder if it is meaningful to record something in respect of the spectrum in the government's balance sheet, after the allocation of the 3rd generation. First, it has to be noticed that no value was generally recorded for that purpose before this generation, because no value was anticipated before. For the next future, except the military uses, government does not have alternative uses of the spectrum. It is more useful to think of the spectrum as a succession of separate technological generations. Like mineral deposits, each one would have its own value, largely independent from each other. As it was perfectly said : "No value can reasonably be placed on the spectrum before its commercial potential has been established". 34. Under these conditions, which are reinforced by the uncertainties revealed by the recent developments of actuality on this issue, it would be irrelevant : - to assume that the amortisation of the operators' asset leads to a symmetric increase of the government's remaining part of the spectrum, because it is not realistic to assume that implicit rents will be constant in the next generation, - in general, to assume by now a value for the spectrum for its use in a 4th generation. In practice, this means that the residual value to be recorded for the spectrum in the government's balance sheet would better be nil. A new value will be attributed when the 4th generation is allocated, if it is made according to the same method. If, in the future, because of a kind of normalisation of this technology, good estimations may be made by operators about the possible returns expected from the use of the spectrum, it will be possible to attribute a value to it. These arguments are not really of a practical nature. It is a theoretical issue : it is not in general meaningful to attribute values which are very uncertain because of the economic reality. References E. Dalgaard Estimating gross fixed capital formation in software, Workshop on the implementation of ESA95 – Copenhagen, 7-9 June 1999. Eurostat Report from the Task Force on intangibles. Eurostat document B1/CN351 e, 1997 9 P. Hill Intangible assets, patents and copyrights in the 1993 SNA. SNA News and Notes, Issue 6, July 1997 IMF Treatment of mobile phone licenses in the national accounts, by R. J. Dippelsman and N. O. Malhe . IMF working paper, March 2001