COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 1 OF 21 Competition News, Edition 12, June 2003 IN THIS EDITION 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. OECD Peer Review Competition Conference 2003 Restructuring the Electricity Supply Industry in SA Assessing Code-share Markets in Aviation Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) in Mergers and Acquisitions Merger Cases Implications for Commission Investigations Commission Investigates the Private Healthcare Industry The Carrot or the Stick? (Enforcement vs. Advocacy) Contact Details 1 1. OECD Peer Review Finds Competition Authorities 'Impressive and Sophisticated' For the first time, a global peer review panel has assessed South Africa's competition policy institutions. In the peer review submitted by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) Global Forum on Competition, its findings stated that "the competition policy bodies are recognised in South Africa as notably competent and serious.” The summary paragraph that follows is reviewed by competition authorities from around the world - representing both developed and developing nations: "South Africa aspires to a modern competition policy regime, to deal with the well-resourced sophistication of much of the South African economy. Its new institutions, whose novelty responds in large part to the post-1994 imperative for fundamental restructuring of government institutions, have shown a confident capacity to deal with complex structural issues in deciding dozens of merger cases. A legalistic business and government culture has challenged these new bodies to prove their competence and tested their jurisdiction. Now that the merger review process has been established, more attention should be paid to nonmerger matters and probably to advocacy as well. Resources are stretched, and there is a critical need to improve the depth and strengthen the capacity of the professional staff." Trade and Industry Minister, Alec Erwin, said he was particularly pleased with the outcome of the survey. "In line with the objectives of NEPAD, to adopt and indeed surpass international best practices and subject our institutions to the rigor of ongoing peer reviews, the assessment by the OECD of our competition authorities against the most entrenched and mature in the world was highly favourable and well timed." The Minister cited one comment from the OECD in particular, which he believed accurately described the current arena: "They (competition authorities) are striving to follow best practices from the experience of other enforcement agencies around the world, knowing that is the measure being applied to them by South Africa's legal and business communities." The survey found that "To a surprising extent, competition policy in South Africa is merger COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 2 OF 21 policy. The decisions to date show that, in terms of substantive economic analysis and sensitivity to policy context, merger review in South Africa is done at a high level of sophistication...the range of issues the Tribunal and the Commission have addressed is impressive, as is the economic sophistication of their approach. The decision-making independence of the Commission and the Tribunal is well established and the new system of pre-notification and control produces a stream of public decisions demonstrating quickly how the law is making a difference." The authorities are addressing several areas for improvement that were noted in the report. The shortage of personnel in the Commission's Enforcement and Exemptions division, for example, has been rectified with only two positions remaining to be filled. The Commission has also stepped up its advocacy role and has been working with both parastatals and government departments to help unravel anti-competitive practices, some of which flow from government policies. The review is positive in that it vindicates the Government's decision to review competition policy in South Africa and to put in place strong competition authorities. "This shows - contrary to earlier domestic criticism - that our efforts and practices are in line with those of competition authorities in the rest of the world," says Adv. Simelane, Competition Commissioner. The Commission has already concluded agreements in respect of concurrent jurisdiction with other regulators and is increasingly focusing on enforcement and exemptions to improve turnaround time for investigations. It has also spent considerable effort increasing the skillsbase and professionalism of our staff through training. The Commission is confident that its attentions will continue to extend beyond that of merger review and is committed particularly to educational and outreach programmes to various stakeholders. The recommendations for policy options from the OECD are listed below: 1. Complete the agreements with other regulatory bodies providing for concurrent jurisdiction, to ensure consistent application of competition policy in all sectors. 2. Improve handling and increase priority and resources for non-merger matters. 3. Bolster resources by accepting offers of third-party support. 4. Discourage abuse of the interim relief process. 5. Make more use of formal substantive guidelines. 6. Use economic resources of the Commission more effectively in advocacy settings. The OECD Peer Review Report - 2003 can be viewed on the Commission's website at www.compcom.co.za COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 3 OF 21 2. Competition Conference 2003 On the 6th of March the Commission and the Tribunal hosted the third Competition Authorities Conference at the Hilton Hotel in Sandton. As in the past, the 2003 Conference drew speakers from around the globe. As specialists in their respective fields they greatly contributed to the insightful discussions that ensued. The theme of the conference was "Competition and Development: promoting competition in a protected economy". Stakeholders invited included practitioners, parastatals, regulators, trade unions, consumer organisations, SMEs and selected others. One hundred and ninety five people attended the conference. The speakers comprised international and local speakers, with a wealth of experience on competition issues. Amongst the speakers was Mr. Michael Wise, an OECD consultant, who spoke on the importance of peer review and its benefits. He also discussed the recent South African competition authorities' peer review. Mr. William Kovacic, the General Counsel of the Federal Trade Commission, USA (FTC) in his talk entitled "Does Competition Law promote Economic Development?", asserted that Competition Law does indeed promote economic development for many reasons. Some of these are listed below. A competition policy system: Can be an effective bridge to economic liberalisation, especially in a country such as South Africa making the move from heavy state control towards one of less control. Can be a barrier to more intrusive regulation by acting as a political shock absorber; for example preventing the introduction of more intrusive forms of control such as price fixing. Promotes market entry by giving those with good business ideas a chance to test those ideas in the market. Impedes the private exercise of market power through cartels. Discourages corruption by upsetting corrupt deals. Mr. Kovacic said that analysis of data indicates that competition law reduces the vulnerability to cartels, limits the acquisition of private market power and can work to curb public restraints on rivalry. There is also evidence to suggest that well-designed competition policy promotes market entry, reduces corruption (especially in public procurement markets), and has desirable distributional consequences. Answering the question on how the US economy would have unfolded if it hadn't introduced competition policy in 1890, he said that a no-ban on cartels would mean that today America would have had powerful, durable cartels with a profoundly negative impact on new entrants to the market. Data suggests that without merger control policies there can be no growth. The conference gave delegates a balanced overview on restructuring, privatisation and competition considerations. The presentations made at the conference can be viewed on the Competition Commissions’ website at www.compcom.co.za under events/conferences. COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 4 OF 21 3. Restructuring the Electricity Supply Industry in SA: Competition Considerations The restructuring of Eskom forms part of a broader initiative by government to restructure its four largest state-owned enterprises: Eskom, Telkom, Transnet and Denel. The electricity industry plays a crucial role as a driver of economic growth. As such, policies around the industry should send clear signals to investors and avoid some of the pitfalls witnessed elsewhere in the recent past. This article gives an overview of the restructuring initiative in the electricity supply industry (ESI) in South Africa, and some of the policy concerns around the process. Restructuring at the generation stage will involve the following: Establishment of Eskom Generation as a wholly owned subsidiary of Eskom Holdings. Eskom Generation will retain 70% of the market. 30% will go to private sector through bidding process. - Private independent power producers will have 20% of the market. - BEE to be allocated 10% of the market. Eskom's 24 power stations will be grouped into a few competing clusters. Generators (IPPs & Eskom Generation) will not be allowed to be involved in transmission or distribution. In order to ensure meaningful participation of the private sector in the electricity market, Eskom might not be allowed to invest in new generation capacity in the domestic market. Reform at the transmission level in South Africa will involve setting up an independent stateowned transmission company, Transco. In the long term, Transco may be privately owned. The rationale behind unbundling transmission from generation is to avoid discrimination and other anti-competitive behaviour. A transmission owner who is also involved in generation has an incentive to discriminate against other generators in terms of access to the grid. Such discrimination can take various forms: Setting high access prices for competitors. An outright refusal of access to the grid. Reserving transmission capacity for its own generation businesses. Permitting unequal access to crucial technical information. Cross-subsidising between regulated and unregulated activities where these were previously jointly operated. In order to facilitate wholesale competition, the establishment of a multi-market model (MMM) has been proposed. Here, the various market participants (generators, traders and buyers) will interact through a variety of mechanisms including bilateral agreements, futures markets, day-ahead markets and real-time markets. The existing Eskom power pool (EPP) with some modifications, is considered an appropriate basis for forming the MMM. However, this might put Eskom's generation clusters at an advantage since they are already familiar with the functioning of the power pool. COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 5 OF 21 Approximately 360 municipalities, Eskom and about 13 private distributors1 are currently engaged in the business of distributing electricity in South Africa. Municipalities are required by law to provide infrastructural services like roads, water and sanitation, health services, and electricity. Since few municipalities generate their own power, the majority of them purchase power from Eskom for resale to consumers within their boundaries. Amongst the municipalities there are a small number of large distributors 2 and a large number of small distributors. At the moment the sector is facing numerous difficulties that need immediate attention if the reform process is to succeed. These relate to financial instability, the inequitable treatment of customers and operational/management inefficiencies. With regard to distribution, the EDI blue-print report3 recommends the establishment of a holding company (EDI Holdings), with a 100% ownership by government, to which municipalities and Eskom distribution will be transferred. These will form six regional electricity distributors (REDs) who will be responsible for the distribution of electricity to consumers within their respective boundaries. EDI Holdings will be mandated to consolidate the fragmented and inefficient distribution industry and to oversee its restructuring. EDI Holdings will be established for an initial period of six years after which its role will be reviewed to determine whether it should continue, and if so what role it should fulfil. As a starting point, large customers (consuming at least 100GWh of electricity per annum at a single site)4 will be able to purchase power directly from generators of their own choice. In the short term, smaller customers will remain captive under a particular RED, and hence will require some form of regulatory protection through control over tariffs and quality of service. 5 Eventually, full retail competition should be possible where all customers, of all sizes, should be able to choose their supplier. Labour South Africa's organised labour position on the restructuring of the electricity industry can be summarised thus: "If it ain't broke, why fix it?" Eskom is seen as one of the most successful utilities in the country, offering the best prices consumers can find in the world. There is excess capacity to last at least another four years. Moreover, most of the poorer sections of the country are now connected, and government's electrification programme targets continue to be exceeded. According to organised labour, restructuring will compromise Eskom's universal service obligations and cross-subsidisation across customers. Furthermore, the introduction of competitors might trigger price increases in the sector and lead to job losses. Government, in its policy development around the sector, is addressing the issues of universal service and cross-subsidies. Clark, A. 2001.Power sector reforms in South Africa: Plans and progress. www.energypublicbenefits.com The 12 largest municipalities account for about 75% of total electricity sales by the sector 3 DME. 2001. Reform of the electricity distribution industry in South Africa: Strategy and blueprint. EDI Blueprint Report 4 http://www.ner.org.za/industry/industry_distribution.htm 5 Winkler, H & Mavhungu, J. 2001. Green power, public benefits and electricity industry restructuring. Energy and Development Research Center, University of Cape Town. 1 2 COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 6 OF 21 Municipalities Municipalities are principally concerned that the restructuring initiative might impact negatively on their financial viability. Most of them derive a substantial amount of revenue from electricity sales. Distribution assets, liabilities, staff and systems will have to be transferred to the REDs as consolidation of the distribution sector takes place. This will dry-up the income stream and threaten their financial viability. The transfer of assets will also result in weaker credit ratings for municipalities. In addition, some municipalities use the revenue from electricity sales to cross-subsidise the provision of other services such as water and sanitation. According to the recently published Electricity Distribution Industry Restructuring Bill, REDs will be subject to the multi-jurisdictional ownership of the contributing municipalities. This should allay the municipalities' fears and concerns. Eskom Eskom would prefer to maintain the status quo where it is the only player in the market. Government differs with Eskom with regard to the timing and method of introducing competition. Whilst the DME supports immediate restructuring and open competition, followed by full privatisation, Eskom would prefer to view restructuring and partial privatisation as longterm goals. Eskom also sees itself as a champion of government's social upliftment through its electrification programme. The mistaken view is that once competition is introduced, universal service will die a natural death. This is not necessarily the case. Proper and effective regulation should guard against this. In any event, universal service in the future would be the mandate of the REDs, not Eskom. The EDI Restructuring Bill should therefore address the question of compensating Eskom for its distribution assets. Policy Issues and International Lessons The proposed market structure will see Eskom retaining no more than 70% of the market, with IPPs and BEE companies owning the remaining 30%. The industry will be oligopolistic with one dominant firm and a few small players. This structure immediately raises some concerns from a competition policy perspective. Although the current Competition Act does not condemn concentrated market structures per se, oligopolistic industries are notorious for stifling competition. Common anti-competitive practices associated with structures where there is one dominant firm include the abuse of a dominant position, price fixing, market sharing and excessive pricing. Lessons from international experience indicate that getting the structure of the market right is the first and most crucial step in restructuring the ESI. According to Binz and Frankena, 6 "If legislators do not get market structures 'right' as current restructuring plans are being developed, it is unlikely they will have an opportunity to go back and fix structural problems at a later date." Eskom will still wield the majority of market power, which will insulate it from the threat of competition. The 30% private sector participation is certainly not sufficient to provide an antidote to abuse and does no justice to effective competition. Furthermore, there will be institutional barriers to entry, preventing further entry by IPPs for a certain period of time. If restructuring is to be done, it should be done properly; otherwise changing the status quo of Binz , RJ & Frankena, MW. 1998. Addressing market power. The next step in electric restructuring. Competition Policy Institute. Policy Paper. 6 COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 7 OF 21 the industry will not fully achieve, the desired outcomes. In order for the entry of new firms to have an impact on the conduct of the incumbent firm it must be timely, likely and sufficient. It is questionable whether the entry of IPPs, which will take up 30% of the market, will be timely, considering the current performance of shares in the energy markets. Add to that the current regulatory and policy uncertainty surrounding the ESI restructuring process, it must be contemplated that investors will need a little more persuasion to commit their funds to the industry. The second lesson from jurisdictions where ESI restructuring has succeeded, e.g. in the UK, is the presence of two or more equal-sized competitors and a few small players to start with. Here the market has been opened up gradually. This reinforces the viewpoint that effective competition at the beginning of the process is paramount. Thirdly, successful restructuring needs to be undertaken against the background of excess generation capacity. This is done in order to contain price increases and enhance consumer welfare. Excess capacity is running out in South Africa. The market system, as envisaged, may still work, but it may not produce the desired benefits of lower prices for consumers. Government has indicated that IPPs and not Eskom should install new generation capacity. Considering the long lead-times needed for such investments, and the lack of interest by private investors at this stage the only plausible option would be to put the generation of new capacity up for tender. This would allow Eskom to participate without having to wait for an emergency request to approach the company as 'supplier of last resort', when there is no investment forthcoming. A fourth observation from international experience is the presence of gas as a very close substitute for electricity. South Africa has begun the exploration for gas in Mozambique and Namibia. These efforts should be encouraged, as they will strengthen competition. The viability of gas as an alternative source of energy will depend on its cost advantages relative to coal. In Conclusion The ESI has undergone various reforms worldwide, some more successful than others. The choice of a restructuring model depends on the specific characteristics of each country. However, competition at the generation and retail stages is important if consumer welfare is to be enhanced. Getting the structure of the markets right before introducing competition is also crucial, as is taking cognisance of the international investment climate. Government should look at the realities of the industry and employ a cautious approach by developing policies that are clear and that send proper signals to investors. At the moment, however, the industry is clouded with many uncertainties. COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 8 OF 21 4. Assessing Code-share Markets in Aviation Over the past decade, code-sharing has shaped the international airline industry in a manner similar to the transformation of domestic airline operations into hub-and-spoke networks after deregulation. Airline code-sharing is a form of co-operation by which an airline sells tickets on another airline's flight. In essence, code-sharing amounts to an operational merger on the affected routes1, should they be serving the same routes. Some economists have alleged that the airline industry is moving from the one extreme of regulation and ownership, to another extreme of global consolidation - with little or no exposure to competition in between2. On closer enquiry into the nature of the industry this is understandable. Large economies of scale and scope prevail, which facilitate the formation of consolidated but diversified structures such as code-share arrangements3. In addition, in many countries bilateral agreements, designation rules, and foreign ownership restrictions prevail, which means that "natural" consolidation (via mergers) in the airline industry is hindered. Airline alliances, like code-sharing, are the partial and provisional answer to the need for restructuring4. Of all strategic alliances in the airline industry, code-sharing is the most common form of collaboration5. Because of the competitive complexity of code-sharing, any market definition analysis needs to be thoroughly defined because both supply and demand-side considerations are at stake. The supply-side a) The routes concerned When defining a relevant market in the airline industry the main consideration is the applicable route or bundle of routes. Each point-of-origin / point-of-destination (O&D) pair should constitute a relevant market, and should include the overlap of the direct and indirect services: Between the two applicable airports; Between those airports whose respective catchment areas significantly overlap with the catchment areas of the airports concerned; as well as The overlapping services where only one party operates direct flights. Generally, indirect routes are not good substitutes for direct routes, especially over short distances. With regard to longer routes, the degree of substitutability would depend on flight times, frequencies, schedules and travel conditions. b) Networks Gurrea, S.D. (2001) Measuring the Competitive Effects of International Airline Code-sharing. Economists Incorporated, Fall 2001. Economist, "One World, Few Airlines", 26 September 1998. 3 See the argument on economies of scale and scope on page 33: Directorate for Financial, Fiscal and Enterprise Affairs Committee on Competition Law and Policy (2000) Airline Mergers and Alliances. OECD, Paris. 4 Stragier, J. (2001) Airline Alliances and Mergers - The Emerging Commission Policy. European Air Law Association, Zurich. 5 NZ Institute of Economic Research (2002) Air New Zealand - Singapore Airlines: Ownership Issues. Wellington. 1 2 COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 9 OF 21 Airlines with large networks have a strong competitive advantage, especially on routes connecting their hub airports. As a result, in a deregulated market, competition occurs between relatively dominant, regionally based airline networks 6. However, the phenomenon of "network competition" does not replace the traditional approach to market definition, i.e., that each city pair constitutes a distinct market. Still, the consumer insists on a transport service between two points and, despite the evolution of the supply-side, in the short term airlines are not readily able to market and operate services between all transoceanic city-pairs without incurring significant additional costs and risks. The possible impact of network competition on the definition of the market is even less with respect to local air services7. The demand-side a) Airport substitution The question arises whether flights from two airports belong to the same relevant market. First, the answer depends on the number of passengers that live in the catchment area of both airports. If sufficient passengers were present, airlines at both airports would compete. Secondly, the services offered by the airports would play a role as frequencies, schedule, connectivity and overall quality of airport service are important to time-sensitive travellers. b) Other transport services The Commission must consider whether other transport services such as car, coach or train, which in view of their physical and technical characteristics, are functionally interchangeable with air transport services at a given price. This is especially important in European countries where high-speed trains over medium distances offer viable substitution possibilities8. c) Time-sensitive and non time-sensitive passengers Time-sensitive and non time-sensitive passengers must be distinguished from each other, as time constraints could be an important factor in the choice among airlines. In addition, other factors that influence the time-sensitive passenger's choice are schedule, frequency, quality of service and overall travel comfort. Generally, the timesensitive passengers require the flexibility to change routes and flight times, and are therefore willing to pay more. The Potential Competition Consideration In developed countries, aviation markets mostly consist of many competing airlines. However, in many markets (for example African markets) potential competition is the most relevant consideration. To be regarded as a potential entrant in the airline industry an entrant would Directorate for Financial, Fiscal and Enterprise Affairs Committee on Competition Law and Policy (2000) Airline Mergers and Alliances. OECD, Paris. 7 Stragier, J. (2001) Airline Alliances and Mergers. European Air Law Association, Zurich. 8 See British Airways/TAT (II), Case no. VI/M.806. 6 COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 10 OF 21 need to show: An appropriate business plan; The amount of finance available for the business plan proposed; The airline experience of senior management; The airline's current airport presence; Steps towards securing aircraft; Steps towards obtaining an air operators certificate and an airline license from the appropriate authorities; Steps towards obtaining access to a computer reservation system; Steps toward securing airport facilities (take-off and landing slots at peak times); and Steps towards establishing a sales network9, which would include frequent flyer programme and corporate contracts10. In addition, major airlines have transformed their route structure from a point-to-point network to a "hub-and-spoke" network. Possible new entrants would therefore only consider entry if the new service could be operated from their current hubs. In the process, the potential entrant would also need to generate sufficient point-to-point and connecting traffic to allow operation at the minimum efficient scale11. The question may arise whether an external potential code-sharer is also a potential competitor. This may be the case, but under the circumstances the alliance, and not the actual potential code-sharer, would be regarded as the competitor. Conclusion When assessing code-share markets, a strict enforcement of antitrust restrictions towards parallel alliances should be guarded against. Although some theoretical models predict higher prices from co-operation among rivals on the same routes, empirical evidence has demonstrated the beneficial effects of code-sharing on connecting flights (new entry creation, consolidation and improvement of services and yields from economies of scale and scope). It has failed to provide conclusive evidence supporting the hypothesis that parallel alliances result in higher fares12. Correspondence with Russell Phillips, ACCC. Stragier, J. (2001). Airline Alliances and Mergers - The Emerging Commission Policy. European Air Law Association, Zurich. 11 Stragier, J (2001) Airline Alliances and Mergers - The Emerging Commission Policy. European Air Law Association, Zurich. 12 Gurrea, S.D. (2001) Measuring the Competitive Effects of International Airline Code-sharing. Economists Incorporated, Fall 2001. 9 10 COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 11 OF 21 5. Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) in Mergers and Acquisitions Competition policy and its contribution to the economy in terms of FDIs The South African competition policy has a major role to play in the development of the South African economy. Apart from looking at the effect that a merger will have on a particular market or sector, the Act also considers certain public interest issues to be of importance. These include employment, development of SMMEs, international competitiveness, black economic empowerment and foreign direct investment (FDI). By guarding against anticompetitive behaviour and ensuring that barriers to entry are minimised, the Competition Act no 89 of 1998 induces foreign companies to penetrate and invest in the country's economy. This is evident from the number of foreign companies that have entered the country's markets in terms of mergers and acquisitions. Though competition policy seems to be contributing to the development of the country's economy, as mentioned above, it is important to note certain complicating factors associated with the FDI data as captured in the Commission's database. Certain deals or mergers might be incorrectly captured as involving FDI, for at least three reasons: First, where the acquisition is by a local subsidiary of a foreign parent, the transaction is not always recorded as FDI, whereas strictly speaking it probably should be. There may be no immediate inflow of forex if the local subsidiary does the acquiring, but that overlooks the fact that the implication of the acquisition is that those funds are not available as remittances to the foreign parent. Second, some transactions have complex payment arrangements: the acquiring firm may agree to assume the target firm's obligations, in return for its shares. In some cases, these obligations and other such arrangements might not have been explicitly valued and included as FDI. Third, some transactions relate to acquiring a firm's worldwide interests, and the stated purchase price as captured relates to the value of the whole group, of which the SA subsidiary might only be a small part. The table and pie graph below show the number of mergers involving foreign companies in various sectors of the economy. It is clear that the manufacturing sector has had the most transactions involving FDI. Mergers & Acquisitions cases with Foreign Direct Investment (April 2000-December 2002) COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 12 OF 21 Merger Cases and Foreign Direct Investments (FDIs) (April 2000- December 2002) From a sample of 769 cases filed with the Commission between April 2000 and December 2002, 109 (14%) involved foreign companies buying assets or investing in the country. 55 (50.5%) of the total cases were within the Manufacturing Sector; 14 (12,8%) were within the Wholesale Sector; 10 (9,2%) in Retail Trade; 6 (5,5%) within Financial Services; 4 (3,7%) in Transport, and Mining accounted for 4 (3,7%). Business Activities filed 10 cases, accounting for 9,2% of the total cases and the Information Technology sector filed 2 cases, contributing 1,8% of the total number of cases filed. Other sectors, encompassing Telecommunications, Electricity, Gas and Water, Construction and Real Estate accounted for 3,7% of the total FDI cases handled by the Commission. The above statistics reflect the relevance and contribution of competition policy in evaluating the effect of FDI in mergers in the South African economy. By ensuring that markets are less concentrated and not dominated by a few large firms, the policy provides an incentive for foreign companies to invest, which ultimately benefits the country. With FDI supported by numerous grants and incentives directed by the dti, the government hopes to benefit the South African economy by attracting the right type of FDI. COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 13 OF 21 6. Merger Cases Commission recommends unconditional approval for Tiger Brands-Enterprise Foods merger The Commission has referred a large merger between Tiger Brands Ltd. and Enterprise Foods (Pty) Ltd. to the Competition Tribunal, recommending that the proposed merger be approved unconditionally. Tiger Brands already holds a 50% shareholding in Enterprise Foods (Pty) Ltd. The transaction will allow Tiger Brands to acquire the remaining issued ordinary share capital of Enterprise Foods from Foodcorp (Pty) Ltd. Foodcorp told the Commission that it is seeking to exit its non-core business ventures. The Commission found that there was no relevant product market overlap between the parties. The Tiger Brands Group is involved in a diverse range of businesses and branded consumer products. Enterprise Foods (Pty) Ltd. manufactures chilled processed meat and canned meat products. However, the Commission was of the view that the change from joint to sole control does strengthen the vertical integration (up or down the supply chain) between Tiger Brands, Enterprise and SPAR, which is a subsidiary of Tiger Brands. Nevertheless, the Commission believes that this will not give rise to customer and competitor foreclosure - the kind of anti-competitive behaviour that may result from vertical mergers, which can limit consumer choice or competitors' ability to distribute products or services and will therefore not negatively affect the competitive landscape. There were also no significant public interest issues. Commission recommends unconditional approval of Kulungile Metals and Abkins Steel merger The Commission has referred a large merger between Kulungile Metals (Pty) Ltd. (Kulungile) and Abkins Steel Corporation (Pty) Ltd. (ASC) and Abkins Steel Services (Pty) Ltd. (Steel Services) to the Competition Tribunal, recommending that the proposed merger be approved unconditionally. Kulungile proposes to acquire the steel merchandising businesses of the target firms. Kulungile consists of two divisions namely Baldwins Steel, which trades in carbon steel products and Stalcor, which trades in stainless steel and aluminium products. ASC and Steel Services on the other hand only deal in carbon steel products. The proposed transaction was initially filed as an intermediate merger because the ABSA Group jointly controls both the ultimate parent companies of the target, and the acquiring firms. The merger was subsequently re-filed as a large merger, necessitating referral to the Tribunal. The Commission had identified a product overlap in five markets. Whereas the identified markets are concentrated, the change in concentration levels are not substantial and COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 14 OF 21 customers and competitors of the primary acquiring firm have indicated that they have no objection to the proposed transaction. Furthermore, no significant public interest concerns arise from the merger. The Commission believes the proposed transaction will not substantially prevent or lessen competition in any of the identified markets, and have recommended to the Tribunal that the transaction be unconditionally approved. The parties' rationale for the proposed transaction is that the growth prospects of the target firms are dependent on their stock availability. The transaction is aimed at increasing the stock breadth and depth of Kulungile to provide clients with a desired "one-stop shopping" facility. Kulungile believes this will enable it to compete more effectively with its main competitors. Unconditional merger approval recommended for Daun-Kolosus transaction The Commission has referred the large merger between Daun Et Cie AG and Kolosus Holdings Ltd., recommending approval with no conditions. The merging parties are active in the animal hide and skins industries. The majority of hides in the country are directed to the automotive industry (leather car seats). Both parties are major players in the procurement and sale of processed leather ("wet-blues") used in the manufacturing of car seats. Daun will be acquiring control of Kolosus. While the structure of the industry did not, in the end, raise significant competition concerns from this acquisition, the transaction did require that horizontal, vertical and public interest issues be assessed. The merged entity will become the dominant player in the procurement of rawhides and the sale of automotive wet-blues. However, local demand for wet-blues exceeds supply by a wide margin because of the Motor Industry Development Programme established by the Department of Trade and Industry to reward manufacturers for using local content. As a result of the local demand, suppliers set prices at import parity levels. Therefore, the Commission believes the merger would not cause the parties to obtain market power they don't already have. (Import parity pricing reflects a price level that cannot be increased without causing buyers to import rather than procure locally.) The Commission concluded that because the majority of skins bought in South Africa are exported, the merger would not harm the consumer. The Commission and the Competition Tribunal have considered various mergers that raised issues of vertical integration. The possible concerns raised by vertical mergers include: Raising rival costs by means of either input or customer foreclosure; Ability to promote co-ordinated conduct between competitors; Ability of a vertically integrated firm to evade price regulation. In this transaction, vertical integration relates mainly to input foreclosure (or the ability to put COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 15 OF 21 competitors out of business) in the automotive tanning market. Because imports are an alternative to local wet-blues, however, the risk of input foreclosure is negated. The merger will most likely lead to some retrenchments, however it is the Commission's view that those job losses (approximately 150) envisaged by the parties are not unreasonable. The Commission decided that the proposed loss of employment does not justify prohibiting the transaction. However, some of the affected trade unions (SAFATU and SACTWU) have signalled that they would like to address the Competition Tribunal more fully on this point during the Tribunal hearing. Imposition of penalties shows how breaches of Competition Act have consequences Imposition of penalties shows how breaches of Competition Act have consequences. The Commission welcomed the Competition Tribunal's rulings in finding both Dorbyl and Edcon guilty of contravening the compulsory Competition Act merger notification requirements. The Commission hopes that the guilty verdicts send a message to businesses that breaches of the Act will not be tolerated. The Commission sought to impose administrative penalties on Edcon and Dorbyl because they proceeded to implement mergers without the prior approval of the Commission as required by the Act. The maximum penalty allowed by the Act is 10% of a firm's turnover. In the Edcon matter, the Tribunal agreed with the Commission's submission that the acquisition of RAG's debtor's book was the acquisition of an asset, giving Edcon control of part of that business, and therefore amounting to a merger about which the Commission should have been notified. However, the Tribunal found that Edcon's failure to notify was a procedural rather than substantive violation of the Act, and set the penalty at R250 000. Edcon could have been fined up to R85 552 610. In the Dorbyl merger matter, the Tribunal issued a symbolic penalty to the amount of R1.00 because while Dorbyl was in breach of the law, their non-compliance was the result of a bona fide mistake. When Dorbyl realised that they had made a mistake they requested an advisory opinion on the notification from the Commission's Compliance Division and they subsequently notified the Commission of the merger, which was later approved. The Commission was however not satisfied with the low fines. In its view, the Tribunal's decisions leave the door open for firms to weigh up the financial benefits of implementing transactions prior to notification as it appears that late filing with the Commission will not attract adequate penalties. In terms of the Competition Act, the Commission cannot appeal the Tribunal's decisions, but it has vowed to continue vigorously prosecuting parties that implement merger transactions without notifying. COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 16 OF 21 Coca-Cola / Appletiser merger approved unconditionally The Commission evaluated the acquisition by The Coca-Cola Company of the Just Juice trademarks, intellectual property rights and formulae from SABMiller Finance B.V. as well as the Valpré trademarks, intellectual property rights and formulae from Appletiser South Africa (Proprietary) Limited. The Commission received a number of complaints from industry participants. The complaints were: That The Coca-Cola Company would acquire market power in the bottled water market; That the acquisition would increase barriers to entry and limit expansion opportunities for other players; That the transaction would have portfolio effects that would enable The Coca Cola Company to unduly strengthen its position in the so-called "new age" beverage market and; That the transaction would increase the ability of industry participants to co-ordinate activity in the bottled water market. The Commission found that the transaction would not substantially prevent or lessen competition in the bottled water or fruit juice markets in South Africa. The Coca-Cola Company will, post merger, not be able to act independently from its customers and competitors in the bottled water and fruit juice markets. The Commission is of the view that the bottled water market is characterised by low barriers to entry. Either new entry into the market or the expansion of the activities of present players will counter any move by The Coca-Cola Company to increase prices above competitive levels. Furthermore, The CocaCola Company is a relatively small player in the fruit juice market where it faces significant competition from other players. With respect to The Coca-Cola Company's distribution network, and the competitive advantage that it derives from it, the Commission is of the view that an efficient system accompanied by low barriers to entry in the relevant market is to the advantage of consumers in South Africa. The transaction will also not affect the distribution channels of the acquired products as, post merger, the status quo will be maintained. Furthermore, the transaction does not raise significant public interest concerns. COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 17 OF 21 7. Precedent on the Interpretation and Application of the Competition Act: Implications for Commission investigations The Competition Act is very new when compared to competition law within the United States or European Union. Precedent on the Competition Act in South Africa is therefore still being established, which in turn leads to longer periods of time required to finalise investigations. Over the last six months however, various courts have addressed and interpreted a number of provisions of the Act, and have given guidance to the Commission on their interpretation and application to the investigations. This article provides a brief overview of some of these precedents. It focuses on those that have had an impact on the manner in which the Commission conducts its investigations. Multiple Extensions of the Period of Investigations The question as to whether the Commission is entitled to extend an investigation more than once was the subject, inter alia, of a matter before the Competition Tribunal. Sappi Fine Papers (Pty) Ltd. filed an exception application with the Tribunal in which it argued that the complaint had lapsed before referral to the Tribunal, and that the Commission was not entitled to multiple extensions from the complainant. The Tribunal ruled that there is nothing in the express wording of the text of Section 50 of the Act to preclude multiple extensions of an investigation. In order to be valid however, the extensions must have been granted before the expiry of the previous period. There is no suggestion that the chain of extensions in this case had been interrupted by a period for which a prior consent had not been granted. The Commission's Role and Constitutional Responsibilities In the matter of Menzi Simelane and Seven-Eleven the Commission's role and constitutional responsibilities were dealt with in detail. Seven-Eleven's complaints were the following: 1. The referral by the Commission constituted an administrative decision affecting SevenEleven's rights, and as such is subject to review. 2. The Commission acted on a "hotch-potch" of complaints without investigating whether there was substance to them. 3. The Commission must observe the audi alteram partem rule and failed to do so. 4. The persons making the decisions were biased and motivated by malice. 5. Further, they were moved by an ulterior purpose. With regard to point 1 above, Seven-Eleven was of the view that the Commission's functions were determinative, rather than investigative only. The Supreme Court of Appeal of South Africa concluded that the functions of the Commission were of a preliminary investigative nature (like the police services), and therefore not subject to constitutional challenge in respect of a right to a hearing. In the main, the Supreme Court of Appeal held that: COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 - - PAGE 18 OF 21 The Commission did not, in general, have to apply rules of natural justice, as its findings were of a preliminary investigative nature. The Tribunal would have to apply rules of natural justice, as its findings were determinative/adjudicative; The functions of the Commission would be subject to review only in cases of ill-faith, oppression, vexation or the like. The major impact of this decision is that it defined and circumscribed the role of the Commission. It found that the Commission's powers are only investigative, and therefore do not affect the parties in any final or determinative way. In cases that are referred to the Tribunal, the Tribunal has the final say. In cases that are not referred, the Complainant may take the case to the Tribunal itself, if it disagrees with the Commission's decision. Hence the Commission does not have the same extensive responsibilities to hear the parties as e.g. judicial bodies. This means that the Commission can speed up its investigations and not be hamstrung, as in the past, with challenges relating to administrative fairness and parties insisting constantly during the investigation to be heard on every investigative step and decision, thus delaying the finalisation of investigations. Search and Seizure Powers of CCSA In the matter of Pretoria Portland Cement vs. Menzi Simelane & Others, the Commissioner was taken to the Supreme Court of Appeals (SCA) by Pretoria Portland Cement for the manner in which a search and seizure warrant was executed. The SCA stated that the Commission had abused the execution of its warrant by calling the media at the time, which was not part of the order granted by the Court, and that it amounted to an infringement of the right to privacy. Also, the SCA stated that the warrant was imprecise and overbroad, and that a warrant should be tailored for the occasion, and not simply taken from stock. Parties also have a right to look at the warrant and the affidavit used to obtain the warrant. In accordance with the audi alteram partem the Commission has the obligation to inform parties of the case it has to meet. An unlawful execution will not, by itself, inevitably taint a warrant that is itself regular. However, it appears that mainly for the reason of failing to honour the Constitution (right to fair hearing and privacy etc.), the process was set aside. Investigative Scope of the Commission In the matter of the National Association of Pharmaceutical Wholesalers & Others, the Competition Appeal Court (CAC) determined that the Commission was not limited to investigating only those allegations that have been identified by the Complainant in the Complaint Referral. The CAC decision appears to allow investigators to go beyond the mere contents of the CC1, once the investigator has satisfied himself or herself as to the nature of the complaint. This proposition finds authority in the CAC obiter dicta "The complainant need not identify the complainant with reference to the sections of the Act". One implication of this decision is that should it be discovered through investigation that the respondent has possibly contravened a section of the Act not referred to by the complainant in its initial filing with the Commission (i.e. in the CC1 form), there is nothing stopping the Commission from further investigating, and possibly bringing a case against the respondent to the Competition Tribunal. COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 19 OF 21 8. Commission Investigates the Private Healthcare Industry The Commission instituted an investigation against the Board of Healthcare Funders (BHF), the South African Medical Association (SAMA) and the Hospital Association of South Africa (HASA). These associations are comprised of members that sometimes compete with each other. They then set and publish tariffs to be paid for healthcare services provided for by their members. This is related to price fixing, which is prohibited in the Competition Act. The Commission is concerned that the conduct of these associations may amount to a contravention of the Competition Act of 1998 (the Act). The Commission's investigation into this sector is continuing. For many people "competition policy" is a complicated and remote concept, best left to lawyers and economists. Many think it doesn't affect the person on the street, but it does. Competition means value, lower prices and, most importantly, choice for consumers. It also means competitiveness for South African industries, including the private health care sector. The process for negotiating tariffs for private healthcare looks much like this: BHF (an association of private hospitals) sets and publishes recommended tariffs according to which medical schemes are prepared to reimburse a service provider in the event that a medical aid member consults a doctor or is hospitalised. On the other hand SAMA recommends tariffs or fees according to which doctors in private practice may charge a consumer for medical services. This implies that individual doctors, who would under ordinary circumstances compete for customers on the basis of fees, may be encouraged to align their fees with those recommended by SAMA. HASA also recommends tariffs according to which private hospitals may charge a consumer or a medical scheme for hospital services rendered to a member. Furthermore, these institutions may bargain as a collective in an attempt to get better deals from each other. The effect of recommending tariffs and fees may result in the lessening of price competition, as may negotiating as a collective. Ideally, as in any service industry, each doctor should independently decide what fee to charge for their services, and each medical scheme should individually decide how much it is prepared to pay for services received by its members. Competition is a simple and efficient means of guaranteeing consumers services of excellent quality at lower prices, because the best deal for consumers only emerges as a result of a contest between service providers. The system of recommending tariffs may have the effect that all or a substantial number of service providers in a given market charge relatively the same price. In such a scenario the consumer has no choice, being unable to choose a service provider on the grounds of lower price because, speaking relatively, everybody is charging the same amount. The Commission has a responsibility to ensure wider consumer choice, technological innovation and effective price competition; thereby contributing to both consumer welfare and the competitiveness of industry in general. This is achieved by ensuring that companies compete rather than collude, that big companies do not abuse their market power and that COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 20 OF 21 efficiencies are passed on to final consumers. The Act entrusts the Commission with the responsibility of promoting and maintaining competition in South Africa and in prohibiting anticompetitive practices. The Commission has the power to prohibit agreements that fix a purchase or a selling price and may impose fines on the offending firms. The Commission itself may initiate investigations into the behaviour of certain companies or into specific market sectors when it suspects possible restrictions of competition. Complaints from competitors or customers of the companies involved or of consumer groups can play a role in bringing such competition problems to the attention of the Commission. 9. The Carrot or the Stick? Enforcement vs. Advocacy In discouraging anti-competitive behaviour in the economy the Commission needs to constantly decide which of the two tools at its disposal to use: the carrot (advocacy) or the stick (enforcement). The choice of which tool to use is somewhat determined according to the structural entrenchment of activities, which either contravene the Competition Act of 1998 directly or result in anti-competitive business practices. In the public sector in particular, the Commission believes that anti-competitive practices which are as a result of government decisions or policy, are often best unravelled with advocacy. An example of advocacy by the Commission is in the transport sector. Provincial authorities require that a specific reflective material be used in the number plates for motor cars. Only one company in South Africa currently has a patent to manufacture this material and therefore has a monopoly with respect to its supply. The Commission is investigating whether the patent for this material is expired and how difficult it would be for other businesses to enter the market as competitors, or to obtain licenses if the patent is still in force. Alternatively, the Commission may recommend that the requirement be scrapped in order to remove the anticompetitive effect it has. The Commission can also make submissions to government departments when laws are being drafted, or make presentations to portfolio committees later in the process, should it determine that a law or regulation permits anti-competitive behaviour. In the private sector the Commission can encourage compliance with the Act in advance of a merger or an acquisition by offering a non-binding advisory opinion as to whether the corporate activity is notifiable. The advisory opinion differs from the American approach, where the authorities are happy to ask a company to unbundle its acquisition after the fact, if it is found to have anti-competitive effects. Furthermore, when investigating the effects of a merger or acquisition that has been notified, COMPETITION NEWS, EDITION 12, JUNE 2003 PAGE 21 OF 21 rather than prevent the activity, the Commission can recommend approval with conditions. These conditions can be either structural or behavioural, but would promote competition and allow the bulk of the transaction to occur. Enforcement (the stick) is the Commission's tool of choice where there has been a clear contravention of the Act. The Commission will conduct an investigation of the contravention with a view to referring and prosecuting. In only three instances has the Commission recommended that a business be fined for failing to notify the Commission of a merger (either the size of the merger fell within the threshold for notification, or the transaction led to a change of control). As a law enforcement authority, the Commission's mandate is to help ensure economic transformation in South Africa. Encouraging competitive behaviour will not only benefit consumers, but allows small businesses to grow and compete, as well as affording historically disadvantaged South Africans a foothold in the economy and an experience of real empowerment. 10. Where to get hold of us Visit the Competition Commission online at www.compcom.co.za for more information about the Commission and the Act, as well as rules and amendments to the Act. You may also forward enquiries, comments and letters to: THE EDITOR Compliance Division Private Bag X23 Lynnwood Ridge 0040 E-mail: CCSA@compcom.co.za Tel: (012) 482 9000 Fax: (012) 482 9003 Competition News is issued quarterly and if you would like to receive future copies, please forward your particulars to enable us to add your details to the distribution list. © Please note that the information contained in this document represents the views of the authors and does not necessarily constitute the policy or the views of the Competition Commission. Any unauthorised reproduction thereof will constitute copyright infringement. Persons interested in this information should not base their decisions thereon without obtaining prior professional advice.