Endogenous Climate Policy in a Rich Country: A CGE Study of the Environmental Kuznets Curve Annegrete Bruvoll, Taran Fæhn and Birger Strøm, Statistics Norway PRELIMINARY VERSION PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE Abstract: Observed Environmental Kuznets Curves (EKC) indicate an inverted U-relationship between several pollution problems and per capita income. By means of dynamic, applied, general equilibrium simulations we investigate this relationship in projections for a rich, open economy, and quantify the relative importance of central hypotheses launched. One theory is that demand for environmental quality increases with growth and provides acceptance for environmental policy. Another emphasizes technological progress. A third claims the role of compositional changes. A cleaner industry structure may, however, come at the cost of pollution leakages through import. Our results indicate that emissions of local and regional pollutants will continue to fall, while climate gas emissions will increase, but less than GDP/cap. Contributions from endogenous policy and structural changes are important to these results, as is improved abatement technology for local and regional pollutants. However, the counterpart of domestic environmental achievements is increasing pollution leakage abroad. Keywords: The Environmental Kuznets Curve; Endogenous Policy; Pollution Leakage; Dynamic CGE Model JEL classification: D58; O11; Q25; Q28; Q48 Corresponding author: Taran Fæhn, Research Fellow Statistics Norway, Research department, P.O.box 8131 DEP, N-0033 OSLO, Norway Telephone: +47 21 09 48 37 Fax: +47 21 09 00 40 E-mail: tfn@ssb.no 1 1 INTRODUCTION Over the last decade, a long series of studies have investigated the relationship between pollution and economic growth per capita. Initial papers by Grossman and Krueger (1993, 1995), Shafik and Bandyopadhyay (1992) and Selden and Song (1994) presented evidence that some pollutants have historically followed an inverted U-curve with respect to per capita income. These observations are usually referred to as Environmental Kuznets Curves (EKC). Different theories for these observations are launched (see e.g. Borghesi 1999 or Stagl 1999 for overviews and comparisons of the theories and empirical results from the literature). One branch of explanations is based on political economy mechanisms. Environmental goods are normal goods in the economic sense, so that higher income increases the demand for a cleaner environment. Agents influence the government through economic policy mechanisms like lobbying, voting and other political activities. An increased willingness to pay for the environment is demonstrated by a higher acceptance for environmental regulations and taxes. Another theory emphasizes technological change as a main explanation. General productivity growth promotes more efficient use of resources and less pollution per produced unit. Increased factor mobility, international trade and widespread use of ICT are characteristics of the growth process that contribute to an effective diffusion of innovations. In addition, increased willingness to pay for a cleaner environment, in accordance with the above-mentioned hypothesis, pushes abatement technology forward (see e.g. Anderson and Cavendish 2001). A third branch of explanations claims that at high income levels, structural changes contribute to less emissions/GDP. Economies become more service based and reliant on human capital, andrelatively less material- and energy-intensive. To the extent that industry patterns rely on comparative advantages, a cleaner production pattern in rich countries will partly be obtained by raising the import shares of dirty products. Environmental policy may be one of the factors behind altered comparative advantages. The counterpart will be environmental degradation in other countries through so-called pollution leakage. Typically, pollutionintensive production tends to shift to less developed countries, with less preferences for a clean environment and hence lower policy ambitions. De Bruyn (1997), Suri and Chapman (1998), Hettige et al. (1992) and Hettige et al. (1997) indicate that there may be empirical support for such an hypothesis. There are two main reasons to concern about pollution leakage: First, a redistribution of environmental goods is of ethical concern, not only in the short run, but also in a dynamic perspective. Countries that 2 lag behind in terms of welfare and abatement policy, will be less in position to obtain environmental improvements along with growth, as the potential for exporting pollution problems will gradually diminish. De Bruyn and Opschoor (1997) claim that reduced domestic emissions resulting from import substitution should not be credited as environmental improvements. Secondly, if the leakages include emissions that have transboundary or global effects, no environmental benefit will be obtained by a pure relocation of the source. In case of climate policy, a long range of studies has been performed to quantify the extent of carbon leakage (see e.g. Jacoby et al. 1997, Barker1999). For these reasons, we argue that a possible negative coherence between economic welfare and emissions may have very little to do with environmental gains, if it is based on increasing import shares and pollution leakage abroad. The econometric literature on EKC and the various hypotheses is comprehensive, but still the empirical contributions from applied model studies have been modest. Model analyses are capable of isolating effects and shed light on the various hypotheses on EKC. Two exemptions are Jansen (2001) and Andersen and Cavendish (2001), who by means of AGE models treat respectively the endogenous environmental policy hypothesis and the technology hypothesis. Another method is illustrated by Bruvoll and Medin (2002), who use a decomposition analysis to isolate the driving forces behind historically observed emission changes. They find that composition effects as well as more efficient use of energy and abatement have been the main reasons for the de-linking between emissions and economic growth the last decades. In this study, we combine the use of a detailed, dynamic CGE model for Norway that integrates economic and environmental mechanisms, and the decomposition principle, in order to address and quantify contributions from all the above-mentioned hypotheses; The endogenous policy hypothesis, The composition (and leakage) hypothesis, and The technology hypothesis. We investigate whether the respective contributions of these driving forces may be capable of counteracting the environmental implications of increased GDP and consumption activity in the next two decades. We also take into account cross-border leakages. In principle, a proper modeling of environmental policy should include mechanisms that endogenously regulate all detrimental emissions. This study concentrates on climate policy. The main reason for assuming unaltered abatement policy towards regional and local pollutants, is that achievements in these fields are already high. For example, Norwegian emissions of SO2 have fallen 80 percent the last two decades, while lead emissions are close to eliminated. As Norway is the fourth richest country in the world (OECD 2001), this is well in accordance with EKC predictions for local environmental problems. Today, the climate problem is considered to be one of the greatest challenges in rich countries' future environmental policy. According to the EKC, the income level should indicate that Norway may be one of the leading countries when comes to future CO2 abatement policy. Relative to 3 emissions with local effects, empirical EKCs studies of CO2 indicate that the downward sloping range of the EKC appears at very high income levels (see e.g. Holtz-Eakin and Selden 1995). Many studies point to substantial co-benefits of greenhouse gas regulations on the local/regional environment (see OECD 2000 and Aunan et al. 2001). Thus, future political actions against CO2 emissions will also significantly affect energy related emissions with locally damaging effects. We measure environmental impacts in terms of changes in emissions to air of all six climate gases in the comprehensive approach of the Kyoto Protocol: Carbon Dioxide (CO2), Methane (CH4), Nitrous Oxide (N2O), Perflourocarbons (PFCs), Sulphur Hexafluoroides (SF6), and Hydrofluorocarbons (HFCs). We further study the effects on emissions of Sulphur Dioxide (SO2), Nitrogen Oxides (NOx), Carbon Monoxide (CO), Non-Methane Volatile Organic Compounds (NMVOCs), and Suspended Particulates (PM1). The paper proceeds as follows; section 2 describes the method, section 3 presents the main set of results, while section 4 concludes and summarizes the analysis. 2 METHOD 2.1 The design of the analysis In order to study the changes in emissions, we decompose future emission projections into four different effects, by means of model simulations: 1) changes in the scale of the economy, 2) changes in technology, including changed energy and material intensity within production, changes in energy technology and some projected environmental technology improvements, 3) changes in the composition of production and consumption, which also involves changes in international trade and thus pollution leakages, and 4) changes in environmental policy. Two scenarios are constructed in order to carry out this decomposition. The climate policy scenario represents a projection of emissions to air, which takes into account various exogenous variables decisive of the general economic development for the next 20 years, including a possible conjecture of endogenous climate policy changes. The reference scenario leaves out climate policy changes, in order to isolate effects of the general economic development. We analyze this scenario to obtain first 1 PM includes PM 2,5 and PM10 . 4 order approximations of the scale, composition and technology components determining total emission changes. The differences between the two scenarios, in terms of average annual percentage growth, constitute the first order approximation to the simulated, isolated effect of the climate policy. 1) Scale effects Due to general growth factors like productivity progress, labor force changes and improved world market conditions, GDP and consumption grow steadily over time. This scaling up of aggregate production and consumption increases emissions over time, given constant emissions per GDP/consumption unit. A crucial question in the EKC literature is whether positive environmental effects of changes in composition, technology and policy are sufficient to counteract these scale effect on emissions. 2) Technological change effects One theory in support of EKC is based on the role of technological change. In our projections, technological change is, first, represented by the increasing total factor productivity, implying that inter alia polluting inputs are more efficiently used. Secondly, the composition of energy production based on hydropower and gas power, respectively, is endogenously changing in the model dependent on profitability calculations. Thirdly, some changes in emission coefficients that are expected to be realized in the near future are built in as assumptions. Finally, energy and material intensities change due to factor substitution. We identify the effect of these technology changes. They do, however, constitute only a fraction of potential innovations that may occur within the next two decades. We have not yet accounted for technology shifts in response to the conjectures concerning altered policy. We also regard it beyond the scope of this paper to take into account effects of endogenous technology growth mechanisms and future innovations with characters and costs not yet possible to identify. 3) Composition effects and leakages Our disaggregated model provides very detailed information on the changes in industrial patterns, as well as the composition of consumption. This provides the opportunity to isolate the effects of structural changes on emissions. Explanations of EKC include the hypothesis that rising income beyond a certain level correlates with stronger emphasis on non- or low-polluting activities, like production and consumption of services. Linked to this hypothesis is the assumption that a cleaner production pattern partly originates from altered comparative advantages in favor of cleaner products. The shift towards less pollutive activities that takes place, may imply that consumption becomes more reliant on imported goods and thus on emissions abroad. In order to conclude on the net leakage effects, we study the changes in import and export shares, and combine our results concerning import and export changes with emission 5 coefficients that apply to our trade partners, in order to conclude on pollution leakages of CO2 (carbon leakages), the greenhouse gases NH4 and N2O, as well as SO2, NOX, CO and NMVOC. 4) Policy effects Through a shift analysis on the CGE model, we may isolate effects of tighter environmental policy, in order to investigate the EKC hypothesis of changing political preferences.. There are three design options. One is to treat environmental policy as an exogenous decision variable. Another is to exogenously allow for a maximum emission limit, and deduce the necessary policy action, for instance by means of environmental taxes. A third approach is to treat policy as endogenously determined by the welfare level of the inhabitants. The latter is most neatly adapted to the EKC hypothesis. Nevertheless, very few applied model studies have tested the implications of such mechanisms. Jansen (2001) reports effects on emissions of suspended particulates from trade liberalization by means of a static, applied CGE model with endogenous abatement policy. In order to obtain a more complete picture of the EKC mechanisms, we aim to treat climate policy as endogenously determined by the welfare level of the consumers. We explore the implications of applying an endogenous policy rule as explored in Jansen (2001) in case of climate policy. In the context of EKC, one could imagine similar rules simultaneously applied to all environmental problems. We choose climate policy as the case in this study of Norway, as many of the other emission problems have diminished markedly over the last few decades. Previous econometric results when it comes to EKC curves for CO2 are mixed. Results concerning a possible turning point of the emission curves suggest that it appears at very high income levels, varying between about the level of Norwegian GDP/cap today (40 000 Euros in 2000) and several millions Euros (see e.g. Holtz-Eakin and Selden 1995 or Lucas 1996). Econometric representations of the relationship between emissions and per capita income usually use a functional form that is quadratic or cubic in GDP per capita (Y), either linear or logarithmic, and with a trend term, T. Cross sectional analyses also include land specific variables, such as population density and temperature (for an overview of such studies, see e.g. Agras and Chapman 1999). For our time series data of CO2 for Norway over the years 1949-2000, we have used the following model: (1) ln CO 2,t 1 ln Yt 2 (ln Yt ) 2 3 (ln Yt ) 3 4Tt et The results of this regression show a concave relationship between income and emissions of CO2 with statistically significant estimates.2 The projections imply that emissions will continue to grow, with a falling rate. In our simulations, we use this model to account for a climate policy that is endogenously determined by income per capita. In order to model a comprehensive climate policy approach, we 6 assume that this model applies to emissions of all climate gases. The difference between the two simulated paths with and without an endogenous climate tax makes up the contribution of abatement policy. The inferred climate policy may assume different forms. We model it as a uniform tax rate applied to all the six climate gases included in the Kyoto protocol. It would be of high interest to coherently study the cases with and without a multinational climate policy agreement and compare the effects in overall emissions and, in particular, the extent of emission leakages. While this is an interesting topic for future research, we restrict this particular study to unilateral actions. Unilateral actions in the field of greenhouse gas abatement may be motivated by a desire to stand out as good examples and be at the front in climate policy development. The final objective of abatement policy is of course much more ambitious. The challenge is to counteract the ongoing climate changes. This will only be realizable within a broad international context. One reason for studying unilateral actions in the EKC context is that observations on CO2 abatement efforts until date have not been influenced by international agreements on climate policy, and available empirical results on the relation between growth and climate policy are thus interpreted as indicative for what we can expect of unilateral actions. Though there are difficulties with interpreting the correlations in the data3, we do regard the deduced policy actions as a best guess of the national climate policy in the near future, conditioned on the possible case of no ratified Kyoto Agreement.4 The case of a Kyoto ratification would more fruitfully be approached by restricting the total Kyoto gas emissions exogenously to the commitments made in the negotiations, and deduce the necessary policy measures. Several studies of this kind are already made, both in global, regional and national studies. For Norway, see e.g. Norwegian Ministry of the Environment (2001) and Strøm (2001). 2.2 The model The applied CGE model of the Norwegian economy, MSG6, is an integrated economy and emission model, designed for studies of economic and environmental impacts of climate policy. A more detailed description, with references, is provided in Fæhn and Holmøy (2000). The model specifies 60 commodities and 40 industries, classified with particular respect to capturing important substitution possibilities with environmental implications. The model is dynamic, based on rational agents with 2 The results show the following relation: lnCO2,t=-709.5+176.2lnYt+14.6(lnYt)2+0.4(lnYt)3+0.01Tt. All coefficients, except for 4, are significant on a 0.03 percent level. 3 As an international agreement has been on the agenda for many years, the observed actions may of course have been influenced by anticipations of an agreement to be established. We find it difficult to correct the estimates for this, however. So far, EKC studies of CO2 have not corrected for actions abroad, a factor that ex ante have an ambiguous effect: It could stimulate to follow, in order to be able to reach a common goal, or the temptation of free-riding could be dominating. 4 In Norwegian Ministry of the Environment (2001), where the Government states its future climate policy intentions, this scenario is not concretised in much detail. 7 intertemporal behavior and perfect foresight. This opens for interesting endogenous trade dynamics, which will have implications for the pollution leakage effects. Since the Norwegian economy is small, and the exchange rate is normalized to unity, all agents face exogenous world prices and real interest rates. While financial capital is, thus, perfectly mobile across borders, real capital and labor are assumed immobile. Policy variables like trade policy, subsidies and tax rates, as well as government spending, are exogenous. The model may be adapted to endogenously determine the climate policy, as a function of per capital GDP, a formulation we make use of in this study. An exogenous public budget constraint is satisfied through endogenous lump-sum transfers. Parameters are estimated, or calibrated on the basis of the 1995 Norwegian National Accounts and relevant micro-econometric studies. Household behavior Consumption and savings are derived from standard welfare-maximizing behavior over an infinite horizon of one representative, price-taking household. External effects, and in particular repercussions from the environment to the utility of the household, are not modeled explicitly. The modeling of endogenous policy is nevertheless based on reasoning of this kind; increased income stimulates demand for environmental quality and thus policy. The intratemporal household decision can be solved by a stepwise budgeting procedure due to a nested CES structure of the utility function (see Appendix, Figure A1), where the goods in each aggregate are imperfect substitutes. The classification of consumption goods distinguishes between activities with different pollution profiles and reflects relevant substitution possibilities. Most of the emissions from households are due to heating and transport. In the heating process the dirty energy carriers fossil fuels and wood can be substituted by electricity, which is more or less based on clean hydropower (see section on the energy market below). Own transport is based on polluting petrol and diesel. Four substitutable public alternatives are specified, transport by road, sea, air and rail/tramway, all with individual emission intensities. Consumption of most material goods generates solid waste for deposition, which in turn emits Methane. Emission coefficients are not calculated for public consumption. Market Structure and Producer Behavior All firms in the private business sector are run by managers who maximize the net present value of the cash flow to owners. A list of the industry classification in the model is provided in Table A1 in the Appendix. Commodities produced by primary industries are assumed to be homogenous and traded in perfectly competitive markets. Domestic markets for manufacturing goods and services, which constitute the main part of the economy, are described by monopolistic competition among firms. The model captures that output and input in an industry may change both because of changes at the firm level and as a result of entry or exit of firms. The model includes a rough description of productivity 8 differentials between firms within the same industry causing firms to differ in size and profitability. As in most models in the CGE tradition, all goods, services and factors are perfectly mobile across industries within the economy, and supply equals demand in all markets in all periods. In all industries the demand for input factors is derived from a nested structure of linearly homogeneous CES-functions (see Appendix, Figure A2). Emissions from firms are dependent on the composition of energy use for stationary purposes, which is determined by the relative prices of the sources fuel and electricity, respectively. Transport services are partly provided internally, with associated emissions from use of petrol and diesel, and partly outsourced. Industries differ significantly with respect to the extent to which transport services can be profitably purchased from one of the commercial transport sectors. As for consumption, the use of several input factors involves solid waste generation. Import and export In the case of services and manufactured goods, imported products are considered as close, but imperfect substitutes for the corresponding differentiated products supplied domestically. It is assumed that both Norwegian and foreign consumers consider Electricity, Crude Oil and Natural Gas, as well as commodities produced by the primary industries Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries, as homogenous. The domestic prices of these commodities are equal to the corresponding import prices, and the model determines net imports as the residual between domestic production and domestic demand. Producers of manufactured goods and tradable services allocate their output between the domestic and the foreign market, which are assumed to be segregated. It is assumed costly to change the composition of these deliveries. This aspect of the technology is captured by assuming that output is a Constant-Elasticity-of-Transformation function of deliveries to the export market and deliveries to the domestic market. World prices of exports are exogenously determined in the world markets. The energy market The energy market is especially important in studies of the links between economic and environmental effects. It has therefore been given a relatively detailed treatment in the model. On the demand side particularly large amounts of energy are needed to generate power on oil platforms, because the efficiency of this process is very low. Extraction and Transport of Crude Oil and Gas is a large and heavily regulated sector in the Norwegian economy, and its activity is exogenous in the model. The exposition above summarizes how households and firms may change their demand for electricity and fuels in response to changes in relative prices and households' real income. 9 On the macro level, changes in industry structure may contribute significantly to the price sensitivity of energy demand. By its disaggregated structure, the model captures many interesting composition effects. The separation of transport and communication into six sectors, Post and Telecommunications, Railway and Tramway Transport, Air Transport, Road Transport, Coastal and Inland Water Transport, and Ocean Transport, is one example in this respect. Another is the specification of the three extremely electricity-intensive industries Manufacture of Metals, Manufacture of Industrial Chemicals and Manufacture of Pulp and Paper. These industries are also substantial polluters in terms of dirty industrial processes. On the supply side the model specifies three potential sources of electricity supply. First, hydropower is produced domestically with virtually no emissions to air. This sector is characterized by large irreversible investments, and capacity expansion is limited by sharply decreasing returns to scale. In this study the production of hydropower is exogenously controlled in accordance with recent practice and intentions expressed by the government. As a potential second domestic source, the model specifies the technology of gas combustion for electricity production, which would involve national emissions to air of several gases - see section on the modeling of emissions below. The production of gas power is determined in the model according to standard investment behavior. The third source of electricity is import from the Nordic market. In 1998, 3 per cent of the total Norwegian electricity consumption was covered by net imports. The electricity price is determined by conditions in the Nordic electricity market, which again determine electricity net imports as the residual between domestic production and consumption. In order to satisfactorily get a grip on Nordic circumstances, we have simulated a model for the Nordic electricity market (Johnsen, 1998) in iterations with our scenarios. The modeling of emissions The model calculates emissions of 12 air pollutants. Table 1 provides an overview of the specified air pollutants reported in this study, and their sources. The description of household and firm behavior above outlines the most important activities in terms of discharges of pollutive gases. The calculations of emissions are based on exogenous coefficients for each source in each sector (Strøm, 2000). The coefficients are generally linked to economic variables in the model. For example, stationary emission from combustion in an industry is linked to the input of fuel, whereas mobile emission from road transport is linked to the input of petrol and diesel. Several process emissions are linked to the input of intermediates. 10 Table 1: Air pollutants and important sources in MSG-6. Pollutant Important sources MSG-6 sector in parenthesis Kyoto gases Carbon Dioxide (CO2) Methane (CH4) Nitrous Oxide (N2O) Perflourocarbons (PFKs) Sulphur Hexafluoroides (SF6) Hydrofluorocarbons (HFKs) Other pollutants Sulphur Dioxide (SO2) Combustion of fossil fuels (Several), reducing agents (Manufacture of Metals) Livestock, manure management (Agriculture), landfills, production and use of fossil fuels and fuel wood (Several) Fertilising (Agriculture), fertiliser production (Manufacture of Industrial chemicals), road traffic (Road Transport) Aluminium production (Manufacture of Metals) Magnesium production (Manufacture of Metals) Cooling fluids (Several) Combustion (Several), process emissions (Manufacture of Metals) Nitrogen Oxides (NOx) Combustion (Several) Carbon Monoxide (CO) Combustion (Several) Non-Methane Volatile Organic Compounds (NMVOCs) Oil and gas-related activities, road traffic, solvents (Oil Refining, Road Transport, Households) Suspended Particulates (PM2,5 and PM10) Road traffic (Households, Agriculture, Road Transport), fuel wood (Households) Source: Statistics Norway (1999a, Box 4.1). 3 RESULTS 3.1 Economic projections The reference scenario The reference scenario represents a projection of the general economic development for the next 20 years. It is conditioned on constant economic policy variables, at the levels of 19955, including constant climate policy. In 1995, the climate policy consisted in a differentiated carbon tax system see Table 2, both with respect to different kinds of fossil fuels and with respect to industries. Carbon taxes applied both to final consumption of fossil fuels and when used as input in production, regardless of whether they were used as energy or as reducing agents in industrial processes. Other greenhouse gas emissions were not taxed. Both scenarios start with 1995 as a base year, and exogenous estimates are developed until 2020. Long run projections reported in the study are the steady-state results based on the exogenous estimates of 2020, i.e. results of the 2020 state-of-the-art after all intertemporal general equilibrium adjustments are emptied out. Based on this interpretation, long run and 2020 are used synonymously in the following text. Most exogenous estimates, apart from the policy variables, are in line with long-term projections in The Norwegian Ministry of Finance (2001). 11 Table 2: Carbon taxation in the reference scenario. NOK * per tonne CO2. Fuels Gasoline Light fuel oils, diesel Heavy fuel oils Coal for energy purposes Coke for energy purposes Coal and coke for processing (Ferro alloys-, carbide- and aluminium industry) Gas (land-based use not covered by the petroleum tax legislation) 397.00 173.20 148.00 189.40 144.00 0.00 0.00 North Sea petroleum extraction Oil extraction Natural gas extraction 335.10 381.00 Industries with reduced rates: Wood processing industry, herring flour industry Light fuel oils, transport oils (petrol, diesel etc.) Heavy fuel oils 86.60 74.10 Industries with exemptions Air transport Foreign carriage by sea Domestic goods traffic by sea Inshore fishing Fishing and catching in foreign waters Cement and leca production 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 * 1 Euro = 7.90 NOK Source: Statistics Norway The main exogenous driving forces behind the general economic development in our scenarios are population and labor force forecasts, productivity growth estimates, the development in Norwegian oil and gas values, as well as changes in international market conditions. The implemented total population forecast corresponds to the medium population projection by Statistics Norway (1999b). As for most European countries, the growth in total employment will be low the next 20 years compared to previous periods (on average 0.5 percent annually) due to an ageing population. TFP growth rates in the private sector are exogenously set to 1 percent annually; the corresponding rates in the public sector are 0.5. International prices are assumed to grow steadily. Norway's income is heavily dependent on natural resources; share of real GDP from oil and gas exploitation was 13.0 percent in 1995 and has been increasing. Also the real prices of oil and gas increased markedly before the turn of the century. For the subsequent 20 years, we base calculations on constant real oil and gas prices, while the relative importance of the offshore activities gradually declines to a GDP share of 4.2 percent in 2020. However, the former natural resource wealth will to a large extent be turned into financial assets, assuring Norway a substantial currency income flow also in the future. The return flow is based on a 4 percent international real interest rate. 5 The only policy variables that are changing along the path is public consumption, which increase by 0.9 percent annually on average, and unit taxes, which are price index regulated. 12 All these growth factors imply a steadily increasing labor demand in the reference scenario, reflected by wage rate adjustments upwards in order to maintain the labor market equilibrium. The simultaneous determination of the wage rate and consumption also obeys the long-term current account restrictions consistent with the intertemporal budget constraint (i.e. financial wealth is not allowed to explode). In average annual terms, the private consumption increases by 4.2 percent, while the wage rate increases by 3.7 percent. The user prices of capital increase less than wages, causing a decrease in the overall labor to capital ratio. Annual capital accumulation increases 2.0 percent yearly on average. In the land-based industries, GDP growth projections are 2.5 percent annually on average. In per capita terms, GDP grows by 1.6 percent as a yearly average. The per capita growth in consumption averages 3.7 percent. Behind the total GDP changes, substantial structural changes take place. One main effect is that offshore activities fall by 2.4 percent in annual terms, and this affects offshore, as well as land-based, production of goods and services associated to oil and gas exploitation (transport, piping, oil platform construction etc.). Housing is the sector with the highest growth. The annual value added from housing grows by 5.1 percent on average. This is the value of the flow of housing services resulting from housing investments. This housing boom implies an increasing value added in the construction industry of 3.4 percent from 1995 to 2010; the growth slows down in the long run. This investment dynamics is a result of the forward-looking behavior of the agents. Capital prices increase along the path, in accordance with the import prices and the wage rates. This means that capital gains are high by investing in the near future. Shifts in consumption and input patterns are to a large extent explained by relative price changes. Fossil fuel falls somewhat in price relative to electricity, implying a substitution of fuel-based activities for use of electricity. Electricity is totally hydropower-based in the first part of the period, while gas power production takes place from 2002, in accordance with the relative development of prices and long-term marginal costs in the sector (see Table 3). Hydropower production is set to its factual levels until 2001, and from then grows steadily the next 20 years, by an average annual rate of 0.5 percent. Non-polluting long-distant transport gradually looses market shares to polluting air and sea transport. Prices of services increase more than goods prices, both because services tend to be labor intensive, and because the import shares are low. As already discussed, the growth in the user cost of housing is relatively low. For consumption, these relative price changes, along with income growth, imply that expenditure shares increase for cars, housing and furniture, leisure equipment, clothing, some income elastic services, as well as tourism abroad. 13 Table 3: Electricity production based on hydropower and on gaspower in the reference scenario (GWH). Year 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 Hydropower 120650 112670 113001 113333 113666 118100 118602 119105 119611 120119 120600 121695 122799 123914 125039 126200 126786 127375 127966 128560 129157 129757 130359 130965 131573 132200 Gaspower 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 250 318 403 469 595 756 960 1219 1549 1967 2498 3172 4029 5117 6498 8253 10481 13310 16904 The climate policy scenario The climate policy scenario is built on the same exogenous assumptions as in the reference scenario, except from the carbon tax system, which is replaced by a conjectured endogenous relation between climate policy and economic growth per capita, as described in section 2.1. Thus, we capture the effects of the interplay between the general economic development and the endogenous climate policy, which is a two-way relationship. The simulations indicate that the marginal greenhouse gas tax rate will increase from NOK 167 (in real 1995 terms) (21 Euros) in 2000, to NOK 505 (64 Euros) as an average in the Kyoto period 2008 to 2012. It ends up at NOK 829 (105 Euros) in 2020, which is considerably higher than the constant real taxes in the reference scenario (see Table 2), in spite of an extended tax base. For a comparison, the Norwegian Ministry of the Environment 2001 indicates an estimated cost of fulfilling the Kyoto commitments by means of national measures of NOK 11 billions. Previous estimates by the Ministry were much lower and amounted to NOK 6 billions, corresponding to a uniform carbon tax of NOK 350 in 2010. Thus, NOK 505, which we obtain for the Kyoto period seems to be in the vicinity of what is needed to obtain the committed green house gas 14 reductions by the years 2008 to 2012, unless an international emission quota regime is established. Estimates of quota prices in case of a Kyoto quota mechanism vary between 50 and 200 NOK. The climate policy, in turn, affects the economic activity. In the long run, total GDP falls by 1.7 percent, while the GDP fall is 1.8 percent in the land-based part of the economy (exclusive of oil and gas exploitation and international shipping). The first part of the scenario does, however, deviate less from the reference scenario, rendering the average annual growth rate 0.06 percentage points lower than in the reference scenario. Long-run aggregate consumption falls by 0.8 percent; again the fall is lower in the early periods (before 2010). All in all, the shift implies only a 0.01 percentage points lower annual average growth rate when effects of climate policy is accounted for. Though aggregate effects on the annual growth rates of introducing climate policy are minor, interesting composition effects have implications for the emissions of polluting gases. In consumption, the emphasis is shifted even more towards services, while the investments in durables (houses and cars) and use of cars and heating oils fall in relative terms. The latter effect is also significant for firms. Price impulses from the tax rates are the main explanation. Production of electricity is based on hydropower, only, as the tax of CO2 emissions render investments in gaspower plants unprofitable. 3.2 Emission projections The reference projection provides the isolated effects on emissions of the development in exogenous variables determinant to the general economic development. These effects on emissions may be split into the isolated effect of an upscaling of aggregate economic activity (scale effect), effects of changed technology along the path (technology effect), and altered patterns of activity (composition effect). We also split effects into changes in the adaptation of firms on the one side, and (not input-output adjusted) changes in consumption activities on the other. See Table 1 for an overview of the sources of different pollution components. Scale effects The average annual emission growth due to the upscaling of private consumption, i.e. irrespective of compositional changes, is 4.17 percent, while the GDP growth indicates a scale effect from industrial activities of 2.12 percent. These are identical to the growth rates of consumption and GDP, respectively, as emissions are, by assumption, produced according to constant returns to scale. Technology effects Based on information from Norwegian Pollution Control Unit (SFT) and Statistics Norway, we have accounted for expected changes in unit emission intensities due to technological adjustments. 15 Technology effects on the emissions form households are first of all due to new and less polluting vintages of cars, which will gradually enter the markets and reduce emission coefficients for several gases (CO, NOx, SO2 and PM). For greenhouse gas emissions the technology effects are positive, though minor. They arise from a substitution of the greenhouse gas HFC for Kaliumflourcarbons (KFC) in refrigerators and air-condition equipment, motivated by that KFC is harmful to the ozone layer. Emissions from firms are also influenced by these technology adjustments, In addition, some firms have announced commitments to cleaner technical solutions, and we have let these influence the technical emission coefficients in manufacture of metals, industrial chemicals and mineral and chemical products. Endogenous factor substitution within firms is also classified as technology effects, as is effects from the gradual introduction of gas-based power plants (see Table 3). Technology changes influence all emission components from industries negatively; particularly the emissions per unit of SO2, CO and PM fall drastically along the path. These reductions are first of all explained by new car vintages, which imply cleaner input of transportation services in all industries. There are also some positive contributions, mainly due to the gradual expansion of the gas power sector and to a substitution towards fossil fuel (for energy and reducing agents) and fuel-based inputs (polluting transport). Composition effects We first turn to the composition effects that result from changed consumption patterns within households. For SO2, CO and PM we find that composition effects on household emissions moderate the scale effect, in accordance with the composition argument explaining EKC (see Table 4). Expenditure shares increase for cars, housing and furniture, leisure equipment, clothing, some income elastic services, as well as tourism abroad. This happens at the relative expense of energy use, which mainly explains the reductions when comes to SO2, CO and PM. Composition effects when comes to NOx are positive, mainly due to a relative increase in use of cars. Non-polluting transport gradually looses market shares to polluting transportation, inter alia consumers' use of own cars. This is also the main positive contribution from composition effects in case of greenhouse gases. The relative increase in use of own cars explains app. 70 percent of the composition effect for greenhouse gases. In emissions from firms, changes in the industrial structure make up the composition effect. When emissions of Kyoto gases, NOX and most markedly NMVOC, fall in response to structural changes, this reflects first of all the gradual downscaling of the offshore activities. NMVOC emissions are related to oil and gas activities like exploitation, refining and tanking. 16 Table 4: Average annual growth in emissions decomposed into (1) scale, (2) technology, (3) composition, and (4) endogenous policy effects. Emission changes from households, Emission changes from firms, contribution Changes in contribution from: from: total emissions (1) (2) (3) (4) Scale Techno- Compo- Policy logy sition effects effects effects effects (1) Total (2) (3) Scale Techno- Compoeffects logy effects sition (4) policy Total effects effects Kyoto gases 4.17 0.02 0.21 -0.25 4.20 2.12 -0.82 -0.55 Sulphur Dioxide 4.17 -0.11 -1.44 -0.47 2.15 2.12 -3.36 Nitrogen Oxides 4.17 -5.41 0.32 -0.30 -1.22 2.12 Carbon Monoxide 4.17 -3.56 -0.20 -0.39 0.02 NMVOC 4.17 -3.51 0.48 -0.23 Particulate Matter 4.17 -0.13 -1.97 0.54 -0.06 0.70 1.33 0.89 -0.16 -0.51 -0.38 -1.12 -1.36 -0.10 -0.46 -0.55 2.12 -3.96 0.13 0.00 -1.71 -0.42 0.91 2.12 -0.25 -3.23 -0.12 -1.48 -0.87 1.53 2.12 -3.86 0.20 -0.11 -1.65 0.70 Endogenous climate policy effects The difference between the two simulated paths with and without an endogenous development of the uniform greenhouse gas tax rate, makes up the contribution of abatement policy. We find that the reductions in emissions caused by policy action first of all take place in the households. This is not a result of reduced overall consumption, which only accounts for 0.01 percentage points of these reductions. Neither is technology progress in the wake of climate taxes accounted for. Thus an altered pattern of consumption explains the relatively strong response we find in the household emissions from the tax adjustments. The emphasis is shifted even more towards service consumption, while investments and use of cars, housing, and heating oils, fall in relative terms. The results show that there are strong environmental co-benefits to climate policy in terms of reduced emissions of a variety of local and regional pollutants. Actually, the fall in Kyoto gas emissions is relatively small compared to other emissions. This reflects the need for an integrated approach in the assessment of climate policy, which takes into considerations overall environmental impacts. This point also applies to emissions from firms, though the effects on emissions are not that strong. The scale effect is somewhat stronger than in case of consumption and contributes to a 0.06 percentage point reduction. Thus, the net composition and technology effects are weakly negative for almost all the gases. 17 Leakage effects In the scenario that accounts for all the components that determine emissions, we find that international trade changes considerably along the path. There are high export surpluses in the first part of the simulation period, while the situation turns to high import surpluses in the long run. First, this reflects a gradual downscaling of oil export and more relative reliance on income flows of foreign currency from financial assets. Gross export increases by 0.38 on average, veiling a growth rate of 0.84 percent in the first 15 years, and of -0.3 percent in the last part from 2010 to 2020. Secondly, it is explained by the dynamics of import, which goes in the opposite direction. This is a consequence of a gradual price decrease of imports relative to domestic prices, the latter increasing substantially along with wages and greenhouse gas taxes. The increasing import shares are of course partly reliant on the fact that we study unilateral policy efforts. Along with this development of international trade, the pollution leakage problems will, in net terms, increase markedly over the years. For most gases, the unit emissions in Norwegian production are markedly lower than for our trade partners. Table 5 shows the weighted macro emission factor for our trade partners. These factors are emissions per GDP for each country, weighted with their respective share of Norwegian import, and divided by the Norwegian emissions per unit GDP. The factors for each emission, zz, FACTORzz, are computed as follows: (2) IMPi Ezzi IMP GDPi FACTORzz Ezz Norway GDPNorway where IMPi is Norwegian import from country i, IMP is total Norwegian import, Ezzs is emission of pollution zz and GDPs is gross domestic product, s= i, Norway, where i refers to foreign country i. The computations are done for 1995. The emission database is UNFCCC (2002) and the data source for GDP is United Nations (2002). Table 5: Macro emission factors for Norwegian trade partners. Emission (zz) CO2 CH4 N2O CO SO2 NOx NMVOC FACTORzz 2.24 2.18 1.72 1.57 9.82 1.03 0.72 As we see from Table 5, the emissions per GDP unit are significantly lower in Norway than for our trade partners. For SO2, the emissions per unit GDP for our trade partners are almost 10 times higher. 18 This reflects the 80 percent decrease in Norwegian emissions over the two last decades, which is a result of sulphur taxes and other political regulations. The macro emission factor for climate gas emissions is about the double of the Norwegian. To a large extent this is explained by aggregate energy-mix differences. Norwegian energy production is relatively independent on fossil fuel. NMVOC emissions, however, are lower than in Norway, because of substantial Norwegian oil loading activities. The factors indicate that the computed growth in Norwegian net import underestimates the associated leakage problem, as emissions associated with import deliveries are relatively high compared to those of Norwegian domestic deliveries. It is, however, not justifiable to draw sharp conclusion on this basis. First, composition effects must be taken into account, which would require a detailed account of emission intensities per production unit of the different industries and countries. Secondly, the possible projections of unit emission changes in the near future must be taken more carefully into consideration. The conclusion above relies on the assumption that progress abroad in environmental technology and policy will not be much faster than in Norway. According to the EKC hypotheses, each country will follow its own emission abatement path for each different pollutant, dependent on their welfare development. 4 CONCLUSIONS Based on these projections, one may be relatively optimistic with respect to the environmental development for the local pollutants NMVOC, NOX, CO, and SO2 in the wake of further economic growth. Despite an average yearly growth in per capita GDP of 1.58 percent, the total emissions of these pollutants decrease by 0.87 percent, 0.55 percent, 0.42 percent and 0.38 percent, respectively. The endogenous policy mechanisms are associated with particular uncertainty, and should be interpreted as an illustration of one of many possible policy developments. The induced policy effects are not decisive for the signs of the total emission changes. NMVOC reductions are first of all a result of the downscaling of oil and gas exploitation. Technology changes dominate the reductions in the latter three. The greenhouse gas emissions seem to be a far more difficult challenge, even with the perspective of a small, rich country with a restricted objective of contributing to a fair share of the global combat against climate change by means of national policy reforms. The upscaling of consumption, as well as production, is not sufficiently counteracted by environmentally beneficial changes in technology, climate policy and structural changes, and total emission growth in annual terms reaches a rate of 1.33 percent. This rate is nevertheless lower than growth in GDP/cap of 1.58 percent. A retarding emission growth of greenhouse gases is compatible with EKC findings for high-income countries, though a 19 turning point is far from reached in these simulations. The greenhouse gas emissions are first of all driven upwards by the emission changes from households, which perform a growth rate of 4.20 percent as an annual average. This finds place along with an increase in consumption per capita of 3.68 percent. Such unilateral policy efforts might be motivated by a wish to front climate policies and appear as good examples. The actual objective of abatement policy and climate technology progress is of course much more ambitious. The challenge is to counteract the ongoing climate changes, which are partly man-made. The literature on global greenhouse emissions, international climate policy agreements, abatement costs, and burden sharing, is extensive. This study has no intentions to address these questions, which must be addressed in a global context. A natural and interesting extension of this country study would be to assess the effects on domestic and leaked emissions of joining a multilateral climate policy effort, e.g. the Kyoto Agreement. In this context, comparative advantage effects would be of less importance, and another important channel for leakages would probably be topical, namely leakages through quota purchases. This analysis illustrates and supports the need for broadening up the perspective in studies of climate policy in two other respects: First, assessments of climate policy should apply an integrated approach, which takes into considerations overall environmental impacts. We find strong environmental cobenefits of climate policy in terms of reduced emissions of local and regional pollutants. Secondly, this study points to the need for including counteracting, as well as reinforcing, leakage effects in the overall assessment. We conclude that emissions of greenhouse gases, as well as of locally and regionally harmful gases, are leaking out in the long run, as a result of the economic mechanisms that we have taken into account. Our computations indicate that not only will the local environment improve at the expense of other countries, but the emissions abroad will increase more than the domestic reduction. Though the question of emission leakages is qualitatively analysed in our study, it deserves a more detailed and quantifiable approach. This will be a natural direction to continue in our further research. Another way to progress is to include a broader spectrum of technology mechanisms. First of all, one could open for possible, persistent technological change mechanisms, either driven by productivity growth through learning by doing, or driven by research and development (R&D). The characteristics of such mechanisms in relation to technology shifts of the kind we already account for, are that they may have increasing returns-to-scale effects, so that the more we learn or perform R&D, the more effective will further learning and R&D become. 20 References Agras, J. M. and D. Chapman (1999): A dynamic approach to the environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis, Ecological Economics 28, 267-77. Andersen D. and Cavendish W.: (2001) Dynamic simulation and environmental policy analysis: Beyond comparative statistics and the environmental Kuznets curve, Oxford Economic papers 53,721746. Aunan, K., Fang, J., Vennemo, H., Oye, K., and Seip, H.H. (2001): Co-benefits of climate policy lessons learned from a study in Shanxi, China, submitted to Energy Policy. Barker, T. (1999): Achieving a 10% cut in Europe's carbon dioxide emissions using additional excise duties: coordinated, uncoordinated and unilateral action using the econometric model E3ME, Economic Systems Research, 11 (4), 401-421. Borghesi, S. (1999): The environmental Kuznets curve: a survey of the literature, European University Institute, November 1999. Bruvoll, A. and H. Medin (2002): Factoring the environmental Kuznets curve - Evidence from Norway, under evaluation in Environmental and Resource Economics. De Bruyn, S. M. (1997): Explaining the Environmental Kuznets curve: structural change and international agreements in reducing sulphur emissions, Environment and Development Economics 2, 485-503. De Bruyn, S. M. og J. B. Opschoor (1997): Developments in the throughput - income relationship: theoretical and empirical observations, Ecological Economics, 20, 255 - 268. Fæhn, T and E. Holmøy (2000): Welfare Effects of Trade Liberalization in Distorted Economies: A Dynamic General Equilibrium Assessment for Norway, in Harrison, G. W., S. E. Hougaard Jensen, L. Haagen Pedersen and T. R. Rutherford (eds): Using Dynamic General Equilibrium Models for Policy Analyses, North-Holland. Grossman, G. M. and A. B. Krueger (1993): Environmental impacts of a North American free trade agreement, in The U.S.-Mexico free trade agreement, P. Garber, ed., Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Grossman, G. M. and A. B. Krueger (1995): Economic growth and the environment, Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, 353-77. Hettige, H., R. E. B. Lucas and D. Wheeler (1992): The toxic intensity of industrial production: global patterns, trends and trade policy, American Economic Review, 82, 126 - 141. Hettige, H., M. Mani and D. Wheeler (1997): Industrial pollution in economic development: Kuznets revisited. Washington D.C.: World Bank, Development Research Group. Holtz-Eakin, D. og T. M. Selden (1995): Stoking the fires? CO2-emissions and economic growth, Journal of Public Economics 57, s 85-101. Jacoby, H.D., R. S. Eckaus, A. D. Ellerman, R. G Prinn, D. M. Reiner and Z. Yang (1997): CO 2 emissions limits: economic adjustments and the distribution of burdens, The Energy Journal,18 (3), 31-58. Jansen, H. (2001): Induced Institutional Change in the Trade and Environment Debate, A Computable General Equilibrium Application to NAFTA with Endogenous Regulation Setting, Environment and Resource Economics 18 s 149-72. Johnsen, T.A. (1998): Modelling the Norwegian and Nordic Electricity Markets, Ph.D-dissertation 481998, University of Oslo. 21 Lucas, Robert. E. B. (1996): International Environmental Indicators: Trade, Income, and Endowments, in Bredahl,M. E. et al., eds. Agriculture, trade, and the environment: Discovering and measuring the critical linkages. Boulder and London: HarperCollins, Westview Press, pp. 243-77. Norwegian Ministry of Finance (2001): Langtidsprogrammet 2002-2005 (The Long Term Programme 2002-2005), Stortingsmelding nr.30 (2000-2001). Norwegian Ministry of the Environment (2001): Norsk klimapolitikk (Norwegian climate policy), Stortingsmelding nr. 54 (2001-2002). OECD (2000): Ancillary benefits and costs of greenhouse gas mitigation, Proceedings from an IPCC co-sponsored workshop, 27.-29. March 2000 in Washington D.C., OECD, Paris. OECD (2001): GDP per capita, 1999, National Accounts of OECD Countries, Main aggregates, Volume 1, July 2001. Selden T. M. and D. Song (1994): Environmental quality and development: Is there a Kuznets curve for air pollution emissions?, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, XXVII, 147-62. Shafik, N. and S. Bandyopadhyay (1992): Economic growth and environmental quality, time series and cross-country evidence, World Bank Working Papers 904, Washington. Stagl, S. (1999): Delinking Economic Growth From Environmental Degradation, a Literature Survey on the Environmental Kuznets Curve Hypothesis, Working Paper no. 6, Wirtschaftsuniveristät, Wien. Statistics Norway (1999a): Natural Resources and the Environment 1999, Statistical Analysis 30, Statistics Norway. Statistics Norway (1999b): Population Forecasts, National and Regional Results 1999-2050, http://www/ssb.no/folkfram Strøm, B. (2000): MSG-6, Utslippsmodellens ligningsstruktur, teknisk dokumentasjon, Notater 2000/22, Statistisk sentralbyrå. Strøm (2001): Velferdseffekter og samfunnsøkonomiske kostnader ved Norges oppfølging av Kyotoprotokollen, cand.eocon.-thesis, Economic Institute, Univeristy of Oslo. Suri, V. og D. Chapman (1998): Economic Growth, Trade and Energy, Implications for the Environmental Kuznets Curve, Ecological Economics 25, 195-208. UNFCCC (2002): Greenhouse gas emissions, http://unfccc.int/resource/ghg/tempemis2.html United Nations (2002): Monthly bulletin of statistics online: http://esa.un.org/unsd/mbsdemo/mbssearch.asp 22 Appendix: Figure A1: The preference structure of the household in MSG-6 Welfare (discounted utility) Utility in year t Leisure year t Consumption year t Housing Other Consumption Furniture and Durables Gross rents Food Heatin g Electric Goods Fuel Beverages and Tobacco Electric Appliances Transport Private Transport User Costs Other Goods Communication Electricity Petrol/Diesel and Maintanance Clothes and Footwear Post and Telecommunications Public Transport Road Sea Air 23 Rail/ Tramway Health Expendit ures Purchases Abroad Other Services Figure A2: The separable structure of production structure of the firms in MSG-6. G ro ss p ro d uc tio n Va ria b le Inp ut Mo d ifie d Va lue Ad d e d Ma n-ho urs a nd Me c ha nise d se rvic e s Ma n-ho urs Me c ha nise d se rvic e s Ele c tric ity Co m m o d ity inp uts Tra nsp o rt No n-p o lluting tra nsp o rt Ene rg y Ma c hine ry Struc ture s Ow n tra nsp o rt Fo ssil Fue l Pe tro l a nd Die se l 24 Po lluting tra nsp o rt Co m m e rc ia l tra nsp o rt Tra nsp o rt e q uip m e nt Table A1: Industries in the model. Manufacture of Metals Manufacture of Industrial Chemicals Fish Farming Manufacture of Pulp and Paper Manufacture of Dairy and Meat Products Preserving and Processing of Fish Dwelling Services Air Transport Coastal and Inland Water Transport Wholesale and Retail Trade Fisheries Extraction and Transport of Crude Oil and Gas Oil and Gas Exploration Defence Government Education, Central Government Education, Local Government Health Care, Central Government Health Care, Local Other Government Services, Central Other Government Services, Local Water Supply and Sanitary Services Land Transport Ocean Transport Construction Printing and Publishing Manufacture of Wood and Wood Products Railway and Tramway Transport Other Private Services Finance and Insurance Post and Telecommunications Manufacture of Other Consumption Goods2) Forestry Textile and Clothing Industry Production of Electricity Manufacture of Oil Platforms Oil Refining Agriculture Manufacture of Hardware and Machinery Manufacture of Chemical and Mineral Products Shipbuilding 25